Você está na página 1de 22

Theories and Practice of Ethnic Conflict Management in Nigeria Orji Nkwachukwu*

Introduction

Like many multi-ethnic societies, one major hurdle which Nigeria has had to overcome in its attempts to build a democratic and communal polity is the fact that competitive politics in the country encourage recourse to divisive ethnic identities (Joseph 1987:43). Mobilization of ethnic identities has become an important aspect of Nigerian politics due to the mutual distrust that has grown over time among various ethnic groups in the country. As van den Burghe (1973:222) observed:
people expect members of ethnic groups other than their own to be tribalists, i.e., to be biased in favour of their fellow ethnics and against strangersMost people assume that all others except those in the same circle of intimates (fellow kinsmen/tribesmen) will behave in ways which further the other persons interests at the expense of oneself

Broadly speaking, ethnicity is in itself not a dangerous feature of plural societies. However, it turns out to be problematic when it becomes, or is perceived as object around which discriminatory practices and unjustified use of violence are organized (Otite 1990). When ethnic identities are politicized it can result in inter-ethnic conflicts. Inter-ethnic conflicts also occur when ethnic interests are challenged, identities threatened, and/or communication sufficiently poor that differences cannot be effectively addressed (Ross 2000:28). Ethnic conflicts tend to emerge at moments when groups perceive that they are being excluded from access to what they consider to be their right; be it linguistic, political, economic, administrative, commercial, religious etc (Ibrahim 2003:45).
Lectures at the Department of Political Science and Public Administration, Ebonyi State University, Abakaliki-Nigeria. Currently a Ph.D. Candidate at the Department of Political Science, Central European University, Budapest-Hungary.
*

One can therefore argue, that violent inter-ethnic conflicts are inextricably linked to perceptions of group domination (Osaghae 1992:219). A combination of two powerful elements can be visibly seen to be at work in generating ethnic conflicts. One is identity: the mobilization of people in communal identity groups based on race, religion, culture, language. The other is resource distribution: the means of sharing the economic, social and political resources within a society (Harris and Reilly 1998:9). Where perceived imbalance in resource distribution coincides with ethnic identity differences, as in the case of Nigeria, then the tendency for recurrence of inter-ethnic conflicts tends to be very high.

In Nigeria, ethnic conflict is a highly significant social phenomena because of it complexity and the social and political threats it pose to the society. The complexity of ethnic conflict in Nigeria reflects on its mode of occurrence. In Nigeria, ethnic conflicts occur along a tri-dimensional trajectory (Osaghae 2002, Nnoli 1978). The first is the conflicts among the majority ethnic groups; the second is the conflicts between the majority and the minority groups; while the third is the conflicts among the minority groups.

The positive and constructive handling of ethnic conflicts can be regarded as ethnic conflict management. This occurs when institutions and processes are created to deal with ethnic differences better than the way it had been done in the past and in a way that is likely to lead to continuous improvement. Ethnic conflict management involves a developmental and transformative processes that entail changes in both the disputants

expressed interests and their interpretation of the conflict. Ethnic conflict management is characterized by many small steps that alter the relationship among the disputing parties and improve how they deal with each other in the future; these steps can be slow, but they generate measures that lower the intensity of conflict (Ross 2000).

The main logic of conflict management is therefore, that conflict cannot be eliminated, but that they can be reduced or controlled more readily, by acknowledging and institutionalizing differences rather than suppressing them. Institutionalization of ethnic conflicts entails entrenching ethnic differences within a set of rules agreeable to competing groups. This legal-constitutional strategy requires a constitutional democratic form of governance to thrive. In Nigeria, constitutional democracy could not be entrenched because the military dominated and controlled the reins of government for almost three out of Nigerias four decades of independence. The subsequent section briefly examines the nature of ethnic conflict management under the military.

Ethnic Conflict Management in Authoritarian Nigeria Many scholars see a strong link between despotism, militarism and violent ethnic conflicts in Nigeria (Horowitz 1985, Joseph 1999). They point to the fact that a common strategy of conflict management in Nigeria during military rule was that the state generally intervenes in ethnic conflict, adopting a violent, repressive, and nonparticipatory approach (Mayowa 2001). These scholars associate this strategy with the protracted military rule in Nigeria and the subsequent weakening or rather collapse of the legal-institutional means of conflict management.

Therefore, much of the violent ethnic clashes that occurred during the period of military rule is seen as being generated by the state through militarism (Ibeanu 2000). Because the military disregards clearly stipulated conditions laid down by the state for access to resources, the contest for these resources turns out to be intense; leading to frosty relations among competing ethnic groups. This state of affairs demonstrably worsened the landscape of inter-ethnic relations in Nigeria by increasing inter-group fear/suspicion among the ethnic communities, eroding the confidence of various ethnic groups in the arbitration and mediation capacity of the state as well as by heightening the stakes of inter-group struggles (Ibeanu 1999, 2000; Human Rights Watch 1995).

The outcome of the above development was increasing breakdown of ethnic conflict management system in Nigeria. This manifested visibly in the open suppression of group agitation, at times through state violence; disturbing inter-group clashes; as well as challenge to state/regime legitimacy by ethnic groups (Gunther and Mughan 1993). Based on the foregoing, it has been suggested that it is only a return to democracy that will create opportunities for a carefully planned and constructive approach to ethnic conflict management and improve the atmosphere for inter-ethnic relations in Nigeria (Osaghae 2002, Harris and Reilly 1998).

In a democracy, it is expected that the existence of varied and conflicting interests in the society will be acknowledged by democratic institutions set up to create a balance between competition and consensus among groups. Thus, democracy is seen as a form of government, which can directly channel ethnic conflicts into proper institutional

outlet for peaceful resolution, ensuring that conflicts are expressed in accord with a commonly accepted set of rules.

Ethnic Conflict Management in Nigeria since 1999 The success of democratic management of ethnic conflict depends on the extent to which multi-ethnic democracies create specific institutional arrangements and practices that would regulate interethnic conflicts. In Nigeria, for instance, the May 1999 transition from military to civilian rule, was accompanied by the democratic legitimization of a number of inherited legal and institutional frameworks for ethnic conflict management, and the enactment of some new ones. This section discusses the institutional arrangements for ethnic conflict management inherited or enacted in Nigeria since the emergence of democratic rule in 1999. These institutional arrangements can be classified into three: the human rights, the multicultural, and the power-sharing approaches.

The human rights approach The most classical approach to ethnic conflict management in Nigeria since 1999 is the human rights approach. The human rights approach to ethnic conflict management was first introduced to Nigeria by the Willink Commission (Akinyele 1996). This approach sees the enactment of a bill of rights, with its guarantee of equality, liberty and nondiscrimination in the constitution as a major way of allaying the fears of the minorities and reducing the scope of discrimination against them. Since 1960, all Nigerian Constitutions are embedded with the bill of rights. In the 1999 Constitution, the bill of rights is contained in Chapter Three (sections 41-54) of the constitution. The human

rights approach conceives Nigerian society in liberal terms. A liberal society is one where all citizens are members of a common civic nation and where the state endeavours to treat them in equal terms (Stanovcic 1992).

Although the human rights approach appears necessary for managing ethnic tensions in democratic Nigeria, some scholars insist that it is not sufficient (Osaghae 1996). They claim that the human rights approach as it is being practiced in Nigeria at the present, concentrate solely on individual rights. These scholars therefore, argue for the need to complement individual rights with group rights. Group rights regard ethnic and other social groups in the society as deserving special attention, protection and justice in the process of democratic competition. Proponents of group rights defend their argument by claiming that ethnic conflicts arise from inequalities, discrimination, domination, exclusion and injustices that attend inter-group competition for scarce social, economic and political resources. As such, they maintain that ethnic conflicts can only be effectively managed through the removal or at least toning-down of inequality, discrimination and domination by protecting both individual and group rights.

The multicultural approach The human rights approach can be regarded as a minimalist institutional measure for ethnic conflict regulation. Contrary to the human rights approach, there are more robust approaches, which hope to institutionalize ethnicity (Bieber 2004). Institutionalization of ethnicity entails the official recognition of ethnic groups in the democratic political competition and representation of ethnic groups as ethnic groups in formal democratic institutions such as the executive and legislative systems.

The institutionalization of ethnicity became popular following the fundamental changes that the classical model of liberal democracy experienced, especially since the 1970s. Nation-states and ruling majorities in these democracies were pressurized, and they became increasingly prepared, to respect the desire for special recognition and separateness of small indigenous minorities, immigrants and foreign workers (Kymlicka 1995). This shift away from full assimilation, gave rise to a form of democracy popularly known as multicultural democracy.

In Nigeria, certain aspects of multiculturalism has been has adopted into the ethnic conflict management system (Onu 2004). These multicultural mechanisms address ethnic tensions by attempting to separate the state from the stronghold of a particular ethnic nationality, and also by recognizing the cultural rights of minorities (Van Den Berghe 2002). Multicultural aspects of ethnic conflict management in Nigeria have reflected mainly in language and educational policies (Oyetade 2003, Garuba nd, and Aguolu 1979). Meanwhile, it important to note that the multicultural approach to ethnic conflict management has not been strongly rooted in Nigeria. This is perhaps, because more than the cultural issues, distributive questions are the fundamental sources of ethnic tensions in Nigeria (Nnoli 1978 & 1994).

The power-sharing approach Because distributional issues are at the root of ethnic conflicts in Nigeria, power-sharing has come to constitute the core approach to ethnic conflict management in Nigeria. In one of the constitutional conferences held in Nigeria, it was noted that:

in a country like Nigeria with its diverse peoples and their corresponding diverse political, cultural and economic endowments, true federalism must reflect a genuine attempt to regulate relationship among the groups, as well as a reflection of these identifiable divergences within a framework of national unityThe particular complexion which a countrys federal system takes reflects its diversities, historical experiences and the disposition of its peoples at a particular point in time, and each federating unit within a true federal system should have its powers and functions demarcated and guaranteed in such a way as to strike a compromise between local particularism and national integrationWe in Nigeria must evolve our own power-sharing formula, take our own decisions and develop our own institutions anchored on our historical experiences, since the problem of power-sharing had been responsible for much of the tensions, emotions, conflicts, stresses and strains in most countries (Federal Republic of Nigeria 1995:3).

Power-sharing is a set of principles that when carried out through practices and institutions, provide every significant identity group or segment in a society representation and decision-making abilities on common issues and a degree of autonomy over issues of importance to the group (Sisk 1996:5). These principles ensure a balance of power among competing ethnic groups by specifying not only how the groups are to share power within the polity, but also by allocating power in such a way as to make it exceedingly difficult for any group to dominate the others (Lijphart 1977, Nordlinger 1972).

Power-sharing can occur at three dimensions depending on whether the intention of the political elites is to share power along political, territorial, or economic dimension (Hartzell and Hoddie 2003). The political dimension stipulates the distribution of political and bureaucratic offices among ethnic groups. The territorial dimension defines the exercise of autonomy by the various levels of government on the basis of

federalism or regional autonomy arrangements. While rules regarding the distribution of economic resources controlled or mandated by the state among ethnic groups constitute the economic dimension.

In the past two decades, a greater number of scholars have acknowledged the efficacy of power-sharing as a positive instrument of ethnic conflict management (Binningsbo 2005, Bogaards 2002, Daftary 2001, Akinyele 2000, Hudson 1997, Koelble and Reynolds 1996, Sisk 1996, MacDonald 1992, Steiner 1991, McRae 1991, Lijphart 1991 1985). In fact, one prominent Nigerian scholar eloquently states:
power-sharing arrangements, in which all groups are represented in government, has the advantage of ensuring stability and of getting the parties that would otherwise be locked in conflict to understand each others interests and develop a system of trust in governing the country. Such arrangements have the additional advantage of establishing a basic level of consensus in the management of the instruments of violence as all parties may be represented in the key institutions that deal with security (cited in Abubakar 1998:170).

Despite the wide acceptance the idea of power-sharing enjoys, yet, a major debate rages among political scientists on what constitutes the best approach to power-sharing in divided societies. In the debate, two contending approaches - consociationalism and incentivism battle for analytical and prescriptive supremacy.

Consociationalism Consociational approach to power-sharing was developed by Arend Lijphart in his ground-breaking work: The Politics of Accommodation: Pluralism and Democracy in the Netherlands (1968) and elaborated in his later works (1969, 1977, 1985, 1991, 1996, 2002). Lijphart (1977) argues that democracy and inter-ethnic harmony can be achieved

in deeply divided societies only if their type of government is consociational. He stress the need for institutional designers to recognize the importance of ethnicity in the political process and to make ethnic groups the building blocks of politics by accommodating them in some sort of grand coalition or power-sharing government.

Consociational governance is characterized by two elements: executive power-sharing (which means the participation of the representatives of all significant groups in political decision-making, especially at the executive level) and group autonomy (which means that groups have authority to run their own internal affairs, especially in the areas of education and culture) (Lijphart 1996:859). The effectiveness of the principles of executive power-sharing and group autonomy is guaranteed by two ingredients: the use of proportionality in political representation and mutual veto.

Incentivism Donald Horowitz offers an alternative approach to power-sharing. He argues that if really inter-ethnic tension arises from competition for the control and ownership of the state, for group superiority, and for group prosperity, all measured in relative terms, then the resolution of the tension will be more difficult to achieve than the consociationalists envisaged. For him, progress in the area of ethnic conflict management depends on the ability of institutional designers to create and maximize incentives for moderate and cooperative behaviour.

Horowitz (2002:23) insists that the incentives for moderation and cooperation comes mainly from the electoral system. For him, it is nature of the electoral reward system that can motivate inter-group conflict or cooperation. Electoral system can promote

10

inter-group cooperation through vote-pooling arrangements and the political engineering of political parties.

While political engineering of political parties entails conscious creation of pan-ethnic political parties by legislation, vote-pooling makes the parties to be marginally dependent on the votes of groups other than their own for electoral success. It requires the parties to attract votes from various groups in the society in order to win national elections. Therefore, to secure across-group votes, politicians are compelled to behave moderately (Horowitz 2002:23). Vote-pooling rule promotes inter-group pre-electoral coalitions; coalitions that need to be forged in order to attract voters across group lines.

In theory, consociationalism and incentivism may appear mutually exclusive, but in practice the two approaches compliment rather than contradict each other. Thus, while the incentive approach call attention to the need to make political institutions lean towards national integration, the consociational approach highlight the need to create institutions that would ensure ethnic accommodation.

Power-sharing in Nigeria The notion of power-sharing has been on the discourse of Nigerian politics since the colonial era. The root of power-sharing in Nigeria lie in the administrative federalism, implied in the gradual division of the country into two administrative units the Northern and Southern Protectorates, between 1900 and 1914, by the British colonial administration (Jinadu 2004). The dual administrative system in the Northern and Southern Nigeria, together with the increasing intensity of nationalist agitation for

11

independence, created a dynamic logic in Nigerian politics, in the form of ethnoregional federal structure. Leaders of the various ethnic groups in Nigeria, saw in federalism the strategic advantage of preserving some form of home-rule within their respective homelands in the Nigerian State, while remaining in the federation.

The emergent federal system based on ethnic diversity, with its initial tri-polar constituent units East, North and West, coinciding with the 3 dominant ethnic group (namely the Igbo in the East, Hausa/Fulani in the North, and the Yoruba in the West), provides the basis for the minority ethnic groups being dominated by these 3 major groups, to mobilize and advocate for home-rule within the regions of Nigerian Federation. The ethnic power-sharing structure of Nigerian federalism provided and continues to provide a constitutional and political platform, within which ethnic groups in the country articulate and present their demands (Jinadu 2004, Suberu and Diamond 2002). These demands have gone beyond issues of territorial autonomy to include the quest for resource control as well as rotation and zoning of political offices.

Power-sharing in Nigeria during the late colonial and early independence period was largely informed by insights from consociationalism. The core elements of powersharing during this period include the group autonomy strategy of federalism in the form of regionalism; strong desire for the application of proportionality principle in representation; as well as a bicameral legislature, rigid constitution and the judicial review of the constitutionality of legislations, all of which serve as mutual vote mechanisms. However, after the civil war, power-sharing in Nigeria incorporated several incentivist mechanisms. Prominent among these incentivist instruments are vote-pooling and political engineering of political parties; federalism and states creation

12

exercise that aims at splitting the homogenous majority groups and crosscutting the countrys ethnic groups; and an increased centralization of the revenue allocation system that intends to weaken the states and make them less attractive or viable as prospective independent states (see Orji 2006, Suberu and Diamond 2002, Amuwo et.al 1998, Diamond 1982).

Power-sharing in Nigeria is anchored on the belief that under the unfavourable circumstances of ethnic cleavages, a majoritarian system is highly inapplicable in Nigeria, because the country cannot afford a winner takes all politics and the consequent danger of creating a permanent minority. Joseph (1991:32) notes that:
the capacity for democratic politics in Nigeria appears to be rooted in the subtle awareness of the danger represented by unchecked power, since that power in common thinking has to be used for someones benefits and to anothers disadvantage, and there is a reasonable and even probable chance that one will fall on the wrong side of that equation.

The strict application of majority rule, it is believed, will place a serious strain on unity and peace in Nigeria.

Beginning in 1954, when the first really federal constitution was introduced in Nigeria, the federal structure ensured that two or more ethnic-based political organizations share political power at the center. This state of affairs contrasts with the situation in countries like Ghana and Tanzania, where one nationalist party was able to achieve clear predominance. In the 1954 cabinet, in which Nigerians were subordinate to colonial representatives, the NCNC held six of the nine positions and the NPC the remaining three. The portfolios were allocated on the basis of the parties performance in the federal elections conducted in the three regions that year. After the subsequent 1957

13

elections, the NPC became the dominant partner in the federal government, and its deputy leader, Abubakar Tafawa Belewa, the first Prime Minister of Nigeria. This government was the first case of a real grand coalition in Nigeria (Sklar 1963, Mackintosh 1966).

Drawing on their experience in the all-party 1957-9 cabinet, some Nigerian politicians began to call for a more robust power-sharing arrangement that would allow each of the major parties unimpeded control of its region of strength, with an all-embracing or what Lijphartians would label an overwhelming coalition at the centre (Mackintosh 1966:442). Although many prominent political figures in Nigerias first republic favoured a less competitive system (if only for a transitional or probationary period), such arrangement could not be well entrenched in the pre-civil war and immediate postcivil war years due to the fact that they were not institutionalized. The Nigerian political elites of those years gave priority to struggles to achieve decisive political advantage over the need for inter-ethnic accommodation. However, subsequent generations of Nigerian political elite began to take measures geared toward institutionalizing politics of accommodation in the country.

The first major attempt to constitutionalize ethnic power-sharing in Nigeria came in 1979. Since 1979, Nigerian Constitutions have made special and specific provisions for power-sharing. For instance, in the 1999 Constitution, elements of power-sharing can be found in the following provisions: 1. 2. The relationship between the government and the people Section 22 Political and economic objectives of the federation Sections 23 and 24

14

3.

The rights of citizens to freedom of movement and from discrimination

Section 49 and Section 50. 4. 5. 6. Election of the president Section 141 and 142 Appointment to specific public offices Sections 154, 178, 223 and 225 Formation, constitution and rules of political parties Sections 228 and 229

The most elaborate and formal power-sharing arrangement contained in the Nigerian Constitution is the federal character principle. The purpose of the federal character principle is laudable. According to its framers, the federal character principle is anchored on the:
distinctive desire of the peoples of Nigeria to promote national unity, foster national loyalty and give every citizen of Nigeria a sense of belonging to the nation notwithstanding the diversities of ethnic origin, culture, language or religion which may exist and which it is their desire to nourish, harness to the enrichment of the Federal Republic of Nigeria (Afigbo 1989:4).

The federal character clauses guarantee the representation of major ethnic groups in specified political positions, in public service appointments, and in the allocation of national resources and projects at the federal level to each of the state and local governments.

The federal character principle was inscribed in Section 14(3) of the 1979 Nigerian Constitution and repeated with appropriate modifications in other sections dealing with the executive and legislative functions of the state governments. The federal character clauses stipulates that:
The composition of the federal government or any of its agencies and the conduct of their affairs shall be carried out in such a manner as to recognize the federal character of Nigeria and the need to promote national unity and to command national loyalty. Accordingly, the predominance

15

in that government or its agencies of persons from a few states or from a few ethnic or other sectional groups shall be avoided.

Under section 157(3), section 197, and section 197(2) of the 1979 Nigerian Constitution, the proportionality or quota principle, inherent in the federal character clauses was extended to the appointments and promotions in the public services, appointments of Chairpersons and members of the Boards of Directors of parastatals, appointments and promotions in the armed forces, allocation of public revenue and distribution of public projects, composition of a number of federal executive bodies, and admission to federal secondary schools and federal universities.

Section 153 of the 1999 Nigerian Constitution established the Federal Character Commission, as a federal executive body, empowered in section 8(1) of the Third Schedule of the Constitution to oversee and monitor the implementation of the federal character clauses, as follows: 1. work out an equitable formula subject to the approval of the National Assembly

for the distribution of all cadres of posts in the public service of the Federation and of the States, the armed forces of the Federation, the Nigerian Police Force and other security agencies, government-owned companies and parastatals of the States; 2. promote, monitor and enforce compliance with the principle of proportional

sharing of all bureaucratic, economic, media and political posts at all levels of government; 3. take such legal measures, including prosecution of the head or staff of any

ministry or government body or agency which fails to comply with any federal character principle or formula prescribed by the Commission, and as provided for in section 8(3) of the Schedule,

16

4.

Notwithstanding any provisions in any other law or enactment, the Commission

shall ensure that every public company or corporation reflects the federal character in the appointment of its directors and senior management staff.

The application of the federal character principle in Nigeria has encountered several difficulties. First, the federal character principle has led the political elites to place too much emphasis on inter-state relationships without a corresponding attention to tensions among ethnic groups within the states (Ikime 2002:67). Secondly, because the federal character principle strives to give equal treatment to unequals, many people perceive the policy as being discriminatory (Ayoade 1998:116). Thirdly, the interpretation of federal character, which is based on state and ethnicity is seen by many as inadequate. Of course, social divisions in Nigeria are not limited to ethnic and state; there are also class, confessional, temporal and ideological divisions (Ayoade 1998:116). Finally, the operation of the federal character principle in Nigeria tends to give more powers to the politically dominant groups; creating wider power disparity between the stronger and weaker groups, and thereby, subjecting the politically weaker groups to what Ayoade (1998:117) calls double jeopardy.

Conclusion This paper has attempted to survey the ways in which Nigerian political leaders have responded to the problem of ethnic conflict in the country. The paper discovered that those charged with easing ethnic conflicts in Nigeria have relied greatly on the major theories of ethnic conflict management. The paper has shown that Nigeria have experimented with various forms ethnic conflict management strategies such as vote-

17

pooling electoral system, autonomy deals with outlaying regions/ethnic groups, and the parceling out of top political and bureaucratic posts with a view to accommodating various groups which, if not brought more fully into the tent of national life, could bring it down from outside.

One can therefore, say that Nigeria has provided a rich ground for scholars and practitioners concerned with ethnic conflict management, to try out some of their solutions. In many cases, the application of these palliatives to ethnic conflicts have led to improvements, but in other cases, as in the case of federal character, it rather complicates the entire situation. However, what one needs to understand is that ethnic conflict management is usually a slow, but incremental process, which records modest, yet steady progress. Therefore, intermittent occurrence of ethnic tensions in Nigeria should not be construed as the failure of ethnic conflict management arrangements. This is because, it is almost impossible to completely eliminate ethnic conflicts in a multiethnic society like Nigeria.

References Abubakar, D. 1998. The Federal Character Principle, Consociationalism and Democratic Stability in Nigeria, in K. Amuwo, A. Agbaje, R. Suberu, and G. Herault (eds). Federalism and Political Restructuring in Nigeria. Ibadan: Spectrum. Afigbo, A. 1989. Federal Character: Its Meaning and History, in P. Ekeh and E. Osaghae (eds) Federal Character and Federalism in Nigeria. Ibadan: Heinemann Aguolu, C. 1979. The Role of Ethnicity in Nigerian Education The Journal of Negro Education, 48(4):513-529 Akinyele, R. 2000. Power-sharing and Conflict Management in Africa: Nigeria, Sudan, and Rwanda African Development, XXV(3&4): 209-233 Akinyele, R. 1996. States Creation in Nigeria: The Willink Report in Retrospect African Studies Review, 39(2):71-94

18

Ayoade, J. 1998. The Federal Character Principle and the Search for National Integration, in K. Amuwo, A. Agbaje, R. Suberu, and G. Herault (eds). Federalism and Political Restructuring in Nigeria. Ibadan: Spectrum Bieber, F. 2004. Institutionalizing Ethnicity in the Western Balkans: Managing Change in Deeply Divided Societies. ECMI Working Paper #19. Flensburg: European Center for Minority Issues Binningsbo, H. 2005. Consociational Democracy and Post-conflict Peace: Will Power-sharing Institutions increase the Probability of Lasting Peace after Civil War? Paper Presented at the 13th Annual National Political Science Conference, Hurdalsjoen-Norway. Bogaards, M. 2002. Power-sharing in South Africa: The ANC as a Consociational Party? Paper Presented at University of Western Ontario-Canada (available at www.ssc.uwo.ca/polysci/necrg/powersharingdemocracy/papers/MatthijsBogaards Power-Sharing.pdf). Daftary, F. 2001. Conflict Resolution in FYR Macedonia: Power-sharing or the civic approach? Helsinki Monitor, 4:291 312 Diamond, L. 1982. Cleavage, Conflict and Anxiety in the Second Republic Journal of Modern African Studies, 20(4):629-668

Federal Republic of Nigeria. 1995. Report of the Constitutional Conference Containing the Resolutions and Recommendations, Vol. II. Abuja: National Assembly Press.
Garuba, H. nd. Language and Identity in Nigeria. www.hsrcpress.ac.za Gunther, R. and Mughan, A. 1993. Political Institutions and Cleavage Management, in K. Weaver and B. Rockman (eds) Do Institutions Matter?: Government Capabilities in the United States and Abroad. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution Harris, P. and Reilly, B. 1998. Democracy and Deep-Rooted Conflict: Options for Negotiators. Stockholm: International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance Hartzell, C. and Hoddie, M. 2003. Institutionalizing Peace: Power-Sharing and Post-Civil War Conflict Management American Journal of Political Science, 47(2):318-332 Horowitz, D. 1985. Ethnic Groups in Conflict. Berkeley: University of California Press Horowitz, D. 2002. Constitutional Design: Proposals Versus Processes, in A. Reynolds (ed.) The Architecture of Democracy: Constitutional Design, Conflict Management, and Democracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hudson, M. 1997. Trying Again: Power-sharing in Post-Civil War Lebanon International Negotiation, 2:103-122 Human Rights Watch. 1995. Nigeria: The Ogoni Crisis; A Case Study of Military Repression in Southeastern Nigeria. New York: Human Rights Watch

19

Ibeanu, O. 1999. Ogoni-oil, Resource Flow and Conflict in Rural Nigeria, in T. Granfelt (ed) Managing the Globalized Environment. London: Intermediate Technology Publications Ibeanu, O. 2000. Oiling the Friction: Environmental Conflict Management in the Niger Delta, Nigeria, Environmental Change and Security Project Report, Issue 6 Ibrahim, J. 2003. The Transformation of Ethno-Regional Identities in Nigeria, in A. Jega (ed) Identity Transformation and Identity Politics under Structural Adjustment in Nigeria. Kano: CRD Ikime, O. 2002. The Nigerian Civil War and the National Question: A Historical Analysis, in E. Osaghae, E. Onwudiwe and R. Suberu (eds) The Nigerian Civil War and Its Aftermath. Ibadan: PEFS Jinadu, A. 2004. Explaining and Managing Ethnic Conflict in Africa: Towards A Cultural Theory of Democracy. Uppsala University Forum for International and Area Studies Lecture, 5th February. Joseph, R. 1991. Democracy and Prebendal Politics in Nigeria: The Rise and Fall of the Second Republic. Ibadan: Spectrum Joseph, R. 1999. Autocracy, Violence, and Ethnomilitary Rule in Nigeria, in R. Joseph (ed) State, Conflict, and Democracy in Africa. Boulder: Lynne Rienner Koelble, T. and Reynolds, A. 1996. Power-sharing Democracy in the New South Africa Politics and Society, 24(3): 221-236 Kymlicka, W. 1995. Multicultural Citizenship. Oxford: Oxford University Press Lijphart, A. 1968. The Politics of Accommodation: Pluralism and Democracy in the Netherlands. Berkeley: University of California Press Lijphart, A. 1969. Consociational Democracy, World Politics, 21(2): 207-225 Lijphart, A. 1977. Democracy in Plural Societies: A Comparative Exploration. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press Lijphart, A. 1985. Power-Sharing in South Africa. Policy Papers in International Affairs. Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California Lijphart, A. 1991. Power-Sharing Approach, in J.V. Montville (ed) Conflict and Peacemaking in Multiethnic Societies. New York: Lexington Books Lijphart, A. 1995. Multiethnic Democracy, in S. Lipset et al. (eds) The Encyclopedia of Democracy. Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly Lijphart, A. 1996. The Puzzle of Indian Democracy: A Consociational Interpretation, American Political Science Review 90(2): 258-268

20

Lijphart, A. 2002. The Wave of Power-sharing Democracy, in A. Reynolds (ed) The Architecture of Democracy: Constitutional Design, Conflict Management, and Democracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press MacDonald, M. 1992. The Sirens Song: The Political Logic of Power-sharing in South Africa Journal of Southern African Studies, 18(4):709-725 Mackintosh, J. (ed) 1966. Nigerian Government and Politics. London: George Allen and Unwin Mayowa, O. 2001. State and Ethno-Communal Violence in Nigeria: The Case of IfeModakeke African Development, XXVI(1&2):195-223 McRae, K. 1991. Theories of Power-sharing and Conflict Management, in J. Montville (ed) Conflict and Peacemaking in Multiethnic Societies. New York: Lexington Books Nnoli, O. 1978. Ethnic Politics in Nigeria. Enugu: Fourth Dimension Publishers Nnoli, O. 1994. Ethnicity and Democracy in Africa: Intervening Variables. CASS Occasional Monograph No.4. Lagos: Malthouse Nordlinger, E. 1972. Conflict Regulation in Divided Societies. Occasional Paper #29. Cambridge: Harvard University Centre for International Affairs Onu, G. 2004. Managing Nigerias Ethnic Diversity Through Multiculturalism Nigerian Journal of Management and Social Science, 1(2):176-182 Osaghae, E. 1992. Managing Ethnic Conflicts Under Democratic Transition in Africa, in B. Caron et al. (eds) Democratic Transition in Africa. Ibadan: CREDU Osaghae, E. 1996. Human Rights and Ethnic Conflict Management: The Case of Nigeria, Journal of Peace Research 33(2):171-188 Osaghae, E. 2002. Regulating Conflicts in Nigeria, Peace Review 14(2):217-224 Otite, O. 1990. Ethnic Pluralism and Ethnicity in Nigeria. Ibadan: Shoneson Orji, N. 2006. Parties and Electoral Politics in Nigeria: Before and After Power-sharing. Paper prepared for presentation at the 1st Annual Doctoral Conference, organized by the Department of Political Science, Central European University Budapest-Hungary, 12th 13th April. Oyetade, O. 2003. Language Planning in a Multi-Ethnic State: The Majority/Minority Dichotomy in Nigeria Nordic Journal of African Studies, 12(1):105-117 Ross, M. 2000. Good-Enough Isnt So Bad: Thinking About Success and Failure in Ethnic Conflict Management Peace and Conflict: Journal of Peace Psychology, 6(1): 27-47 Sisk, T. 1996. Power Sharing and International Mediation in Ethnic Conflict. Washington, D.C.: United States Institute of Peace Press Sklar, R. 1963. Nigerian Political Parties: Power in an Emergent Nation. Princeton: Princeton University Press

21

Stanovcic, V. 1992. Problems and Options in Institutionalizing Ethnic Relations, International Political Science Review 13(4): 359-379 Steiner, J. 1991. Power-sharing: Another Swiss Export Product?, in J. Montville (ed) Conflict and Peacemaking in Multiethnic Societies. New York: Lexington Books Suberu, R. and Diamond, L. (2002) Institutional Design, Ethnic Conflict Management and Democracy in Nigeria, in A. Reynolds (ed.) The Architecture of Democracy: Constitutional Design, Conflict Management, and Democracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press. van den Burghe, P. 2002. Multicultural Democracy: Can it Work?, Nations and Nationalism 8(4):433-449 van den Berghe, P. 1973. Power and Privilege in an African University. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul

22

Você também pode gostar