Você está na página 1de 36

March 3, 2003 No.

23

Whither the WTO?


A Progress Report on the Doha Round
by Razeen Sally

Executive Summary
Where does the World Trade which WTO panel rulings fill in the gaps
Organization stand, one year into the Doha of WTO agreements; and a more politi-
Round of multilateral trade negotiations? cized WTO, where interest-group politics
The new round, launched in Qatar in threatens to paralyze the organization.
November 2001, will include negotiations Looking ahead, the round could follow
on reducing barriers to trade in industrial three divergent scenarios: a focus on mar-
goods, farm products, and services and tak- ket access and trade barrier reduction (the
ing the WTO into new territory to cover traditional and preferred focus of multilat-
investment-, competition-, and environ- eral negotiations); an effort, principally by
ment-related trade policies. The new round the European Union, to turn the WTO
presents great opportunities, but it also cre- into a lumbering regulatory agency in its
ates new risks for world trade. own image; and a UN-style future for the
Little progress has been made since nego- WTO, with deep divisions and blanket
tiations in the new round started in January exemptions for developing countries.
2002. Doomsayers prophesy a replay of the For the new round to succeed, the
Seattle disaster—perhaps at the next minis- major players, the United States and the
terial conference in Cancun in September EU, must contain domestic political diffi-
2003—and a marginalized, increasingly culties, defuse bilateral conflicts, and co-
irrelevant WTO further down the line. operate intensively. A Bush administration
Clouding the negotiations at the WTO leading from the front, notwithstanding
are three alarming trends: creeping stan- protectionist blemishes at home, must
dards harmonization, through which forge issue-based and across-the-board
more-developed members seek to impose alliances with market-access-oriented
higher regulatory standards in such areas WTO members, especially within the
as intellectual property on less-developed developing world. Only then will the
members; excessive legalism, through WTO head in the right direction.

Razeen Sally is an associate professor in international political economy at the London School of
Economics and Political Science, director of trade policy for the Commonwealth Business Council, and
a member of the Board of Advisers of the Cato Institute’s Center for Trade Policy Studies.
To the “WTO new WTO round, it surveys the political road-
junkie,” trade policy Introduction blocks impeding progress in the run-up to the
Cancun ministerial meeting and beyond and
begins and ends in Where does the World Trade Organization posits medium- to long-term scenarios for the
Geneva. But this is stand, one year into the Doha Round of multi- WTO. The sections that follow concentrate on
lateral trade negotiations? The WTO manifest- the main items on the negotiating agenda in the
far from the reality. ly goes wider and deeper than its predecessor, new round. The paper closes with an analysis of
the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade; the intergovernmental politics and highly asym-
and the Doha Round, launched at the Fourth metrical national trade policy capacities that will
Ministerial Conference in Qatar in November determine the eventual outcome—successful or
2001, is to take the WTO into new territory to otherwise—of this round.
cover investment-, competition-, and environ-
ment-related trade policies.
On the other hand, the WTO is buffeted by A Multitrack Approach to
hostile forces without and fractured within by
sharp, bitter intergovernmental divisions. The Trade Policy Reforms
accession of so many new members in quick suc-
cession has further slowed decisionmaking. The To the “WTO junkie,” trade policy begins
result is stasis and drift, in striking contrast to the and ends in Geneva. But this is far from the
businesslike diplomacy and negotiating effective- reality. Trade policy proceeds, usually simulta-
ness of the GATT. Furthermore, there has been neously, along three main tracks: the national
little progress since negotiations in the new round (unilateral) track, the bilateral or regional track,
started in January 2002. No wonder doomsayers and the multilateral (WTO) track. Arguably,
prophesy a replay of the Seattle disaster—perhaps trade policy takes place in the first instance at
at the next ministerial conference in Cancun in the national level. It takes place increasingly at
September 2003—and a marginalized, increas- bilateral and regional levels in the form of free-
ingly irrelevant WTO further down the line. trade agreements. The WTO is at best the sec-
These developments should impel all con- ond instance of trade policy.
cerned with the health of the world trading
system to ask a few basic questions—often The Fast Track of Unilateral Liberalization
overlooked by trade policy experts and practi- Trade policy has become progressively more
tioners fixated on the detail of trade agree- liberal in the last couple of decades as part of
ments and negotiations. Where is the WTO wider packages of economic policy reform,
heading, if anywhere? What is right or wrong although this trend is patchy and uneven. The
with the organization? What is, or should be, more-developed countries in the Organization
its raison d’être? Should it have a GATT-style for Economic Cooperation and Development
market access focus? Or should it widen its have gradually opened their markets further,
regulatory circumference to take in environ- consolidating the liberalization of trade and cap-
mental, labor, and other “trade-related” issues? ital controls since the late 1940s. The real trade
Should it have more of a UN-style “develop- policy revolution, however, has occurred in
ment” dimension? Or indeed all of the above? developing countries and countries in transition
How does the new round fit into the picture? (plus Australia and New Zealand). This trend
What difference, if any, is it likely to make to began in East Asia in the 1960s and Chile in the
the WTO’s middle- and long-distance future? 1970s, with other countries and regions follow-
This paper sets the scene by placing the ing only in the 1980s and 1990s (first in Latin
WTO today in the context of wider trade poli- America, then in Eastern Europe, the former
cy developments in the world economy. It then Soviet Union, India, and parts of Africa).
examines the structural shifts in the transition The trend has been far from uniform: coun-
from the GATT to the WTO. Moving to the tries in East Asia, Latin America, and Eastern

2
Europe have liberalized more and integrated times, governments have overcome these
faster and deeper into the world economy, with obstacles and embarked upon radical unilateral
stronger commitments in the WTO. They are liberalization only in situations of national eco-
mostly middle- and higher-income developing nomic and political crisis, especially when it
and transitional countries—China being the has become all too clear that long-standing
significant exception. None except Singapore, policies of protectionism have failed.3
however, comes close to the comprehensive, Given the practical difficulty of undertak-
nondiscriminatory free-trade policies of Hong ing autonomous liberalization in the context of
Kong (now a special administrative region of modern domestic politics, there is some merit
China with separate WTO membership). This to the multilateralized reciprocity that the
group of relatively recent “globalizers” (less GATT/WTO embodies. The mercantilist dis-
recent in the case of Hong Kong, Singapore, advantage of governments haggling over
South Korea, and Taiwan) numbers about 20 export concessions, for which they “concede”
to 25 countries. import access to their own markets, is counter-
The overwhelming majority of developing balanced by the following advantages: 4
countries (not far off 100) are in the low or
least-developed bracket and are concentrated • Most obviously, international treaties act
in South and West Asia, Africa, the Middle as an external prop; they can strengthen
Intergovernmental
East, and parts of the ex-Soviet Union. In the hand of governments and shift the negotiations and
these regions trade barriers are higher, and balance of interest group politics within binding interna-
there has been less liberalization in the last few the domestic sphere. Intergovernmental
decades and relatively few WTO commit- negotiations and binding international tional obligations
ments. These tend to be countries with low or obligations help protect governments help protect gov-
stagnant growth; and many of them, particu- against powerful protectionist interests at
larly the least developed, are mired in political home and mobilize the support of domes-
ernments against
and economic instability. 1 tic exporters. powerful protec-
The bulk of recent trade and investment liber- • WTO rules provide rights to market tionist interests at
alization in developing and transitional countries access for exports and rights against the
has taken place unilaterally: governments have arbitrary protection and predation of home and mobilize
liberalized quotas, tariffs, licensing arrangements, more powerful players. This is particularly the support of
restrictions on foreign investment, and the like important for developing countries. domestic exporters.
independently and not as part of international • Perhaps most important, but often over-
agreements. There are powerful economic and looked, multilateral rules can bolster
political arguments in favor of unilateral liberal- domestic reform efforts and reinforce the
ization. To begin with, national gains from trade clarity, coherence, and credibility of national
result directly from import liberalization, which trade policy reform in the eyes of
replaces relatively costly domestic production and exporters, importers, local and foreign
spurs more efficient resource allocation. One investors, and, not least, consumers. This
important effect of import liberalization is to is another way of saying that the WTO, at
channel resources into profitable export sectors, its best, is a helpful auxiliary to good
removing the bias against exports inherent in pro- national governance.
tectionist regimes.2
Seen in this light, there is every reason to go A Proliferation of Regional Agreements
ahead on the fast track to unilateral liberaliza- Regional trade agreements (RTAs), sand-
tion without wasting time on the slow, cir- wiched between unilateral measures and the
cuitous track of reciprocal negotiations. WTO, have proliferated in practically all
However, given enduring protectionist pres- regions of the world economy since the 1980s.
sures and ingrained mercantilist thinking, this Activity on the regional track has accelerated
route is the exception, not the rule. In recent since the failure of the WTO’s Seattle ministe-

3
rial conference in 1999, especially in the Asia- deeper unilateral reforms. RTAs “in between”
Pacific region, starting with Singapore and have ambiguous effects but will be systemically
involving Japan, South Korea, Australia, New damaging in the absence of accelerated multilat-
Zealand, Mexico, Chile, the United States, eral liberalization and strong WTO rules.
Canada, and now China and Hong Kong. The
WTO Secretariat estimates that there are 170
RTAs currently in force and that this number Alarming Trends in the WTO
could grow to 250 by 2005. 5
So far, there is little evidence that RTAs have The GATT provided rules for progressively
retarded the overall liberalization of trade and more open trade, at the border, in (some) indus-
foreign direct investment (FDI).6 Indeed, RTAs trial goods. As a result of the Uruguay Round
may well have contributed to political stability agreements, the WTO goes much wider and
and economic policy reform in some countries, comes closer to universal coverage, providing
for example, in Mexico through the North market access rules for the bulk (if not all) of
American Free Trade Agreement and the international trade. As important, the agree-
Central and Eastern European countries en ments go well beyond the coverage of border
route to EU membership. Nevertheless, the dis- barriers (tariffs and quotas) to encompass a
criminatory, rule-evading, and power-reinforc- much broader range of behind-the-border non-
ing potential of RTAs cannot be overlooked, tariff barriers, that is, domestic regulations that
especially as multilateral disciplines on them (in hinder international trade.
Article XXIV GATT and Article V of the GATT 1994 (replacing GATT 1947) contin-
General Agreement on Trade in Services, or ues the 50-year-old process of reducing tariff and
GATS) are rather weak. The danger is that nontariff barriers to trade in manufactures. The
RTAs could coalesce into big blocs, competing Agreement on Agriculture and the Agreement
with each other on the basis of power rather on Textiles and Clothing, although relatively
than cooperating on the basis of rules, and par- weak and shot through with loopholes, have
ticularly putting the squeeze on small and poor GATT-style rules and procedures for gradually
countries excluded from preferential access to liberalizing important but hitherto highly pro-
the markets of the major powers. tected sectors of trade in goods. The GATS,
The proliferation of RTAs is a fact of life. A although architecturally complicated and with
weak and demoralized WTO is increasingly over- modest commitments to date, nevertheless estab-
shadowed by events on the bilateral/regional track, lishes the framework for the liberalization of trade
and it is in serious danger of becoming marginal- and factor movements in cross-border services
So far, there is little ized by spider webs of discriminatory trading transactions. The GATS also has provisions for
arrangements. It is therefore vital to accelerate making the domestic regulation of service sectors
evidence that nondiscriminatory liberalization on the multilater- more transparent and nondiscriminatory—a vital
regional trade al track, as well as strengthen WTO rules and pro- consideration given that opaque and discrimina-
agreements have cedures to monitor and discipline RTAs. If that tory domestic regulations hinder services trade far
does not occur, RTAs will have increasingly harm- more than classic border restrictions.
retarded the overall ful effects, particularly for developing countries. New or revamped trade procedures, notably on
liberalization of To sum up, unilateral liberalization should be subsidies, technical barriers to trade (TBT), sani-
pursued on its own merits when and where tary and phytosanitary, or SPS, measures (affecting
trade and foreign politically feasible. However, most developed animal and plant health), customs valuation, and
direct investment. and developing countries lack the domestic import licensing, furnish some of the regulatory
political requisites to undertake and sustain uni- infrastructure for tackling behind-the-border trade
lateral trade reforms. The multilateral track can restrictions and taking better advantage of trade
therefore serve as a helpful auxiliary: WTO opportunities. This is especially important for
agreements not only lock in unilateral reforms; developing countries that lack such regulatory
they also provide a springboard for further and infrastructure. An increasing number of develop-

4
ing countries (but still a relatively small minority of standards harmonization agenda goes by the TRIPS takes WTO
20 to 25) are more active and effective participants name of TRIPS (the Agreement on Trade- rules in a new direc-
in the WTO, eschewing old-style “special and dif- Related Intellectual Property Rights). TRIPS
ferential treatment” that had granted them sweep- is perhaps the strongest agreement coming out tion—not further in
ing exemptions and instead subscribing to basic, of the Uruguay Round, with harmonized legal the direction of mar-
common rules for market access. standards on the protection of patents, trade-
All the agreements mentioned above form marks, and copyrights to be applied across the
ket access, but else-
part of the Single Undertaking, another WTO membership, regardless of differences in where, toward a
Uruguay Round innovation. All WTO mem- levels of development. It differs fundamentally complex, regulation-
bers have to comply with the obligations of all from classic GATT-type market access rules,
the Uruguay Round agreements (with the rel- for its short-term effect is to close, not open, heavy standards har-
atively minor exceptions of agreements on markets: strong patent protection in particular monization agenda.
public procurement and civil aircraft subsidies), increases prices and transfers rents from poorer
rather than choose à la carte (as was the case developing countries to multinational enter-
with the Tokyo Round codes for trade proce- prises headquartered in the West, especially in
dures). Finally, the WTO’s quasi-automatic the pharmaceuticals sector.8 Most controver-
dispute settlement procedures, reliant more on sial, developing countries are concerned that
law and due process than on the vagaries of TRIPS could inhibit cheap and plentiful access
diplomacy (compared with dispute settlement to essential medicines, such as patented drugs
in the old GATT), give rules more teeth and to combat HIV/AIDS.
bite. Developed and developing countries The main point to bear in mind is that
make much more use of WTO dispute settle- TRIPS takes WTO rules in a new direction—
ment than was the case pre-1995. Arguably, not further in the direction of market access,
such a stronger rules-based (or law-based) sys- but elsewhere, toward a complex, regulation-
tem, with beefed-up enforcement mechanisms, heavy standards harmonization agenda intend-
benefits smaller and weaker players to a greater ed to bring developing-country standards up to
extent than the more power-based (or diplo- developed-country norms. It sets the precedent
macy-based) GATT system.7 for artificially raising developing-country stan-
If this were the sum total of the WTO story, dards in a range of other areas, such as labor,
then it could be said that the WTO would be environmental, food safety, product labeling,
performing its ideal constitutional function. It and other technical standards, armed with
would be supplying, and helping to enforce, a stronger WTO dispute settlement and the
wider and deeper, transparent and nondiscrimi- Damocletian sword of trade sanctions in case
natory rule base for market access in cross-bor- of noncompliance.
der transactions. This kind of WTO would be a Let us be clear: these are not negative, pro-
helpful, more effective auxiliary to better nation- scriptive, classical liberal-type general rules of
al governance, dovetailing with unilateral liber- conduct to protect property rights in interna-
alization and domestic regulatory reforms tional transactions, that is, rules that tell actors
“down below.” The WTO, however, like politi- what not to do but otherwise leave them free to
cal life in general, is more complicated than that; do as they wish. The most favored nation and
there is another, more vexing side to the WTO national treatment clauses in GATT Articles I
story. Alarm bells toll on the following counts: and III, respectively, for example, like the rules
standards harmonization, legalism, and politi- of private (commercial) law, are negative in the
cization. Let us take each in turn. sense that they enjoin governments not to dis-
criminate in international trade but otherwise
“Harmonized” Standards and the Trouble leave them free to do anything not specifically
with TRIPS forbidden.9 In stark contrast, TRIPS contains
First, the WTO suffers from creeping stan- harmonized regulations, with detailed prescrip-
dards harmonization. The Trojan horse for a tions on how they should be enforced within

5
domestic jurisdictions. The actual and poten- safety, to be driven by developed-country bench-
tial effect is to hinder, not promote, market marks and political agendas, taking little account
access. To Jagdish Bhagwati, the Columbia of differences in national circumstances and
University trade economist, this is not tradi- capacities in the developing world. Viewed more
tional frontal protectionism against cheap cynically, organized interests in rich countries
developing country imports. On the contrary, it push for legally complex, costly, and rigid stan-
is backdoor intrusionism, an attempt to iron out dards in the WTO, enforceable through dispute
the asymmetries in other countries’ domestic settlement, in order to realize their protectionist
institutions and raise their costs out of line with aims. This is precisely the backdoor intrusionism
comparative advantages. The effect is the same feared by Bhagwati.
as classic protectionism. 10 To cut a long story short, there are limits to
Admittedly, the issue is complicated and to a one-size-fits-all approach to regulatory issues
some extent these pressures are inevitable. As in the WTO, which is in serious danger of reg-
border barriers come down and technology ulatory overload. The organization risks
advances, globalization inexorably runs up neglecting its core purpose of furnishing rea-
against all sorts of new barriers behind borders. sonably simple negative rules to secure and
If the WTO disregarded these regulatory barri- extend market access as it moves into “trade-
There is a tendency ers, lower protection at the border would be nul- plus” issues involving domestic regulation. At
for international lified by higher protection behind it. This means best, trade-plus procedures help improve the
standards to be dri- the WTO has to tackle standards relating to transparency of domestic trade-related policies,
production and processing methods that lie giving effect to basic, negative WTO rules for
ven by developed- deep in the structure of the domestic economy, market access. At worst, they are tantamount
country bench- in addition to tackling remaining (and substan- to an OECD standards harmonization agenda.
tial) border barriers. Negative (proscriptive) rules Standards harmonization poisons the interna-
marks and political continue to be crucially important, but the tional trading system in four ways. Politically, it
agendas, taking lit- WTO needs to have some positive (prescrip- intrudes too far into national regulatory compe-
tle account of dif- tive) procedural disciplines to make domestic tence, that is, it tramples on national sovereignty.
trade-related policies more transparent. The WTO does not enjoy anything remotely
ferences in national Otherwise market access would not be a reality. approaching an intergovernmental consensus for
circumstances and This is the original intention behind the WTO’s this sort of thing; the result would surely be a
capacities in the agreements on subsidies, services, sanitary stan- destructive political backlash. Legally, this
dards, technical barriers to trade, customs valua- approach is Procrustean: it smacks of Cartesian,
developing world. tion, and import licensing. top-down legal symmetry, wonderful for lawyers
Nevertheless, WTO members should pro- and Utopian constructors of “global governance”;
ceed very gingerly on the domestic regulatory but it slams the door on healthy, competitive,
front. In some cases, this approach hinders mar- decentralized, and bottom-up national experi-
ket access (TRIPS), or at least provides a GATT- ments with policies and institutions tailored to
legal floor for existing and future regulatory pro- differing local circumstances. Economically, stan-
tection (antidumping). In other cases, WTO dards harmonization hacks away at the principle
agreements with domestic regulatory content (for of comparative advantage. It ignores the fact that
example, GATS, SPS, TBT) could hold back a policies and institutions differ according to differ-
surge of nonborder protection. However, even on ences in circumstance, not least comparative costs
the latter front one should be very sensitive to that vary with levels of development. Imposing
constraints in developing countries—especially regulations that raise costs out of line with nation-
the least developed among them—with scarce al productivity levels would restrict developing-
administrative, technical, and financial resources country labor-intensive exports as surely as any
to implement high-quality international stan- antidumping action.11 Morally, and of overriding
dards. There is a tendency for international stan- importance, standards harmonization is repre-
dards, such as the Codex Alimentarius on food hensible, for it is tantamount to an extraterritori-

6
al invasion of private property rights. By impos- diplomacy.13 This can only accelerate the trend
ing extra conditions and costs, it restricts the abil- toward standards harmonization and regulatory
ity of employers and workers to strike mutually overload.
beneficial contracts, particularly in impoverished This is a dangerous and slippery slope. The
parts of the world. Individual liberties, therefore, WTO, like the GATT before it, is a “contract
are the first to be sacrificed on the altar of stan- organization” bringing together a large, diverse
dards harmonization. group of sovereign nation-states. Its always-brit-
Furthermore, a bulky domestic standards tle political consensus can only tolerate rules
agenda compromises the traditional GATT interpreted as much as possible according to the
bargaining model: the mercantilist exchange of “letter of the law,” that is, with judicial restraint.
export concessions. This has functioned well This is indeed a principle enshrined in the
enough on old-style market access through Uruguay Round agreements establishing the
reciprocal tariff and quota reductions that are WTO and the new dispute settlement proce-
relatively easy to measure and compare. It is a dures.14 The Dispute Settlement Body simply
different matter with opaque, complex domes- does not enjoy the political consensus to sustain
tic regulations on all manner of trade-related “creative” judicial interpretations of legal texts
issues for which data are lacking and compari- and policy driven by litigation, as happens from
son more subjective. Reducing Tariff A in time to time in the U.S. Supreme Court and the
Country B in exchange for a reduction of Tariff European Court of Justice. And this is for the
C in Country D has a proven record of success. best: unless the views of a wide crosssection of
Playing the same game with standards—for the WTO membership are heard, including
example, reducing Tariff A in return for a those of developing and smaller members, poli-
stronger SPS measure or stronger GATS cy may be driven in crucial areas by those large
Article VI provisions on transparency in ser- and powerful members able to commit signifi-
vices regulation—does not work nearly as cant legal resources to dispute settlement cases.
effectively, and might not really work at all.12 This could conceivably lead to rulings inimical
to developing-country interests, such as an
The WTO’s Creeping Legalism expansive, open-ended interpretation of the pre-
Second, the creeping legalism of the WTO is cautionary principle on food safety issues and
not all good news—except for academic and prac- discrimination against imports based on their
ticing lawyers, of course. Trade negotiators have a production and processing methods.
perhaps unavoidable tendency to conclude vaguely These trends in dispute settlement reinforce
worded final texts that give legal expression to the case for the negotiation of reasonably simple,
political compromise and fudge. In WTO-speak transparent, and negative rules for market access, The Dispute
this is known (not so accurately) as “constructive based on the most favored nation principle and
ambiguity.” Many Uruguay Round agreements, national treatment, which give reasonably clear
Settlement Body
such as GATS, SPS, TBT, and TRIPS, contain direction to dispute settlement. One of the dan- simply does not
numerous gaps and ambiguities, especially in the gers of intrusive and complicated TRIPS-type enjoy the political
dense thickets of domestic regulation. Inevitably, regulation is that it opens new vistas for judicial
there are limits to legal certainty on the nitty-grit- activism powered by rich WTO members able to consensus to sustain
ty of this or that regulatory measure, with ample afford armies of high-fee lawyers. The bottom “creative” judicial
room for diverging legal interpretations—more so line is this: governments and not international
than with simpler, clearer border measures. Given judges should determine the boundary between
interpretations of
quasi-automatic dispute settlement, there is an WTO rules and domestic policy space. 15 legal texts and policy
increasing, indeed alarming, trend for govern- driven by litigation.
ments, pressured by strong, organized interests, to The Politicization and “UN-ization”
fill in these regulatory gaps through litigation in of the WTO
panels and Appellate Body rulings rather than Third, the WTO is manifestly more politi-
through negotiation and quiet, behind-the-scenes cized than the old GATT. Externally, it faces

7
If present UN-style the brunt of the anti-globalization backlash, ating agenda, a small number of key players,
trends continue, the and it is constantly buffeted by a combination and, not least, a high-quality secretariat. If pre-
of old-style protectionist interests and new- sent UN-style trends continue, the WTO will
WTO will become style nongovernmental organizations (NGOs), simply be unable to function as an effective mul-
a marginalized talk- the latter mainly comprising well-funded, high- tilateral forum for trade negotiations. It will
profile groups in the West purporting to repre- become a marginalized talking shop, and atten-
ing shop, and atten- sent causes (such as protection of the environ- tion will shift elsewhere, particularly to bilateral
tion will shift else- ment, food safety and other consumer issues, and regional negotiating settings. If indeed the
where, particularly working conditions, human rights, and animal WTO comes to resemble a UN agency, one
welfare). The arcana of trade policy, previously should pose the question: will the Geneva circus
to bilateral and handled through low-key diplomacy and nego- (the Secretariat and national delegations) be
regional negotiating tiation, now seem to be the crucible for global worth the candle?
settings. controversies, with their fair share of adver- The combination of these three structural
sarial sloganeering and point scoring. shifts post-Uruguay Round—regulatory over-
As important—perhaps even more so—are load and standards harmonization, excessive
the deeper internal, intergovernmental divi- legalism, and politicization—has polluted the
sions within the WTO. These are many and atmosphere above the shores of Lac Léman.
crosscutting, by no means restricted to tradi- Taken together, they put the squeeze on the
tional and new developed-developing country traditional virtue of the GATT: its ability to
cleavages—though the latter are perhaps the deliver results, that is, stronger rules for pro-
most attention grabbing. The hyperinflation of gressively more open international trade,
the GATT/WTO, that is, the accession of so through effective diplomacy and negotiation.
many developing and transitional countries This is not to say that the WTO should
during and especially after the Uruguay return to a golden yesterday. Far from it; the
Round, has added new sets of interests and pressure for a wider agenda with domestic reg-
preferences to the organization’s ongoing busi- ulatory content has to be accommodated, espe-
ness. Decisionmaking has become even more cially if it enhances transparency and facilitates
unwieldy and snail-like, more often than not market access; legalism is to some extent wel-
distracted by windy rhetoric and political come as it makes the system more rules based
grandstanding in the WTO General Council, for smaller and weaker players; and politiciza-
on the one hand, and the Geneva trade offi- tion is simply a fact of modern trade policy. Put
cials’ obsession with procedural minutiae, on another way, it would be both pie-in-the-sky
the other. As worrying, it appears that an and wrong to rely unduly on GATT-style
increasing number of recent appointments to diplomacy. However, the latter has been
the WTO Secretariat have been made more on squeezed too tightly. It needs to be revived, for
the basis of appeasing developing-country without it the WTO will not get out of its rut
pressure for more representation within the and advance.
Secretariat than on the basis of merit. The WTO, in short, needs to find a new
All the above—empty windbag speechifying, balance—for dealing with domestic regulation
political point scoring, running around in proce- so that it becomes more transparent and does
dural circles, appointments made according to not lead to regulatory overload and standards
informal developing-country quotas and not on harmonization, for dispute settlement so that
merit—are vexing signs of the UN-ization (or legal procedures do not result in judicial policy-
UNCTAD-ization, after the UN Conference making, for accommodating an increasing and
on Trade and Development) of the WTO. The overwhelming developing-country majority
GATT escaped the pitfalls and egregious fail- without a headlong descent into UN-ization.
ures of other international organizations, partic- Reviving the WTO’s diplomatic and negoti-
ularly within the UN system, because it had a ating mechanism is really in the hands of the
reasonably clear purpose, a well-framed negoti- developed-country majors (the United States and

8
the European Union in the first instance), other momentarily less noisy, but more important,
developed countries, and the key developing- the immediate post–September 11 environ-
country governments (India, Brazil, China, South ment—international political crisis and a world
Africa, and not more than a score of others) who economy heading toward recession—concen-
are in a position to be effective in the WTO. The trated minds wonderfully. A rejuvenated
focus of their efforts must be the Doha Round, WTO, with a fresh round of negotiations to
whose success or failure will, alongside unilateral, liberalize and regulate international trade, was
bilateral, and regional initiatives, determine the seen as a much-needed confidence booster for
medium-term future of the world trading system. the global economy, with the prospect of deliv-
To the Doha Round and its prospects I now turn. ering substantial gains in terms of economic
growth and poverty reduction. Hence the
political will to compromise, with attendant
The New Round: State of Play negotiating flexibility, from mid-September.
These and other factors combined to produce
After much political brinkmanship and an atmosphere of civility and cooperation in
down-to-the-wire haggling, members of the Doha, in stark contrast to the crotchety and
WTO successfully concluded their ministerial sometimes explosive mood in Seattle.
conference in Doha, Qatar, in November 2001 What was agreed in Doha? Not least,
Without the events
with an agreement to launch “broad and bal- China and Taiwan were welcomed into the of September 11,
anced” negotiations, which started in January club. The other key decisions were 16 2001, there would
2002. The Doha Round, the successor to the
Uruguay Round, puts the WTO show back on • Market access: Continued but upgraded be no new round:
the road after the disastrous failure of the negotiations to liberalize agriculture and great tragedy has
Seattle ministerial conference in 1999. services markets, and new negotiations to
The post-Seattle period witnessed drift and reduce tariff and nontariff barriers to
created a wholly
deadlock in the WTO, with bitter and entrenched industrial goods. unexpected oppor-
disagreements among member governments and • Rule making: Clarifying and improving tunity for the
an anti-globalization backlash outside. It took care- WTO rules on antidumping procedures,
ful, painstaking preparation by the WTO subsidies and countervailing measures, WTO to get back
Secretariat and member delegations to dig the regional trade agreements, and dispute on track.
WTO out of its post-Seattle ditch and bring about settlement.
success at Doha. Here credit is due above all to • Developing–country issues: Longer transi-
Stuart Harbinson, Hong Kong’s outstanding per- tion periods, improved technical assistance,
manent representative to the WTO, chairman of and other forms of “capacity building” to
the General Council through 2001, and, since help with implementation of Uruguay
September 2002, chef de cabinet to the new WTO Round agreements. Special and differential
director-general, Supachai Panitchpakdi. treatment for developing countries is rec-
Harbinson’s role was pivotal in orchestrating rea- ognized in practically every aspect of the
sonably transparent and inclusive consultations in new round. WTO members also commit
the long lead-up to Doha, thereby gradually build- themselves to the objective of ensuring
ing up the trust and confidence that had been lost duty-free and quota-free access to goods
before and after Seattle. originating in least-developed countries.
Last, it appears that developing countries
September 11 Concentrated Minds Wonderfully will be able to interpret WTO rules on
Frankly, however, without the events of patent protection more flexibly in order to
September 11, 2001, there would be no new promote access to essential medicines and
round: great tragedy has indeed created a whol- safeguard public health. In particular, they
ly unexpected opportunity for the WTO to get will have considerable leeway to override
back on track. Anti-globalization forces were patents and issue compulsory licenses for

9
generic products in emergency situations forced other WTO members to dilute the
such as an HIV/AIDS pandemic. commitment to abolish agricultural export
• “Singapore issues” and other new issues: subsidies and extracted new commitments to
Preparatory work on investment and com- negotiate on environmental and the Singapore
petition rules, with a presumption of starting issues (competition, investment, trade facilita-
ambitious negotiations after the next WTO tion, and transparency in public procurement).
ministerial conference, to take place in A Trade Negotiations Committee, chaired
Cancun, Mexico, in September 2003. New by the director-general, was set up in January
negotiations on trade facilitation and trans- 2002. It comprises eight separate negotiating
parency in government procurement, also to groups (on agriculture, services, nonagricultur-
start after the next ministerial meeting. al market access, rules, trade and environment,
(Those four items are called the Singapore TRIPS, dispute settlement, and trade and
issues because they were first placed on the development), each chaired by a permanent
WTO agenda at the 1996 ministerial meet- representative (ambassador) to the WTO.
ing in Singapore.) New negotiations to start
immediately on trade and environment to Slow Progress since Doha
clarify the relationship between the WTO The good news is that agreement at Doha
and multilateral environmental agreements, provided a short-term psychological boost to a
and to liberalize trade in environmental demoralized and weakened post-Seattle WTO,
goods and services. Finally, preparatory work and to the wider process of globalization. Failure
will be done on eco-labeling and other at Doha would have crippled the WTO, per-
WTO environment-related rules, with the haps fatally, and speeded up regional bloc for-
possibility of negotiations after the next mation, leaving poor and weak countries
ministerial meeting. exposed to the protectionist whims of their rich
and powerful counterparts.
Following Uruguay Round practice, the The bad news is that very little progress has
results of all the negotiations (with the excep- been made in Geneva since the round started.
tion of that on dispute settlement) will be There are several reasons for this state of
treated as parts of a Single Undertaking, that is, affairs, some short term, others more worry-
members will have to sign on to the whole ingly long term.
package rather than accept or reject individual First, the key to moving ahead in WTO
The good news is elements of it. The round has a three-year time negotiations is the close involvement of minis-
frame, with all negotiations to be completed ters and senior officials in national capitals.
that agreement at “not later than” January 1, 2005. Their attention waned in 2002 as the
Doha provided a This is a large, complex, and ambitious post–September 11 crisis abated, leaving the
short-term psycho- agenda, with 21 subjects listed, reflecting the business of the new round in the hands of
post–September 11 mood of all-round com- Geneva negotiators. A firm rule of thumb in
logical boost to a promise. There is a market access core to the the WTO is that there is little forward move-
demoralized and new round, that is, negotiations on further ment without clear direction and strong
trade liberalization, as demanded by the engagement from national capitals. It is to be
weakened post- United States, the Cairns Group (of leading hoped that, as the Cancun ministerial confer-
Seattle WTO. The developed- and developing-country agricultur- ence approaches, minds in key national capitals
bad news is that al exporters), Hong Kong, and Singapore. will be concentrated.
Developing countries have successfully flexed Second, business support for the new round
very little progress collective muscle with major concessions on has been conspicuously lacking in fervor.
has been made in the “implementation agenda” (flexibility and Historically, rounds have succeeded only with
assistance in implementing Uruguay Round strong lobbying by large export and FDI-ori-
Geneva since the agreements) and flexibility in interpreting ented firms in the major developed countries.
round started. WTO rules on patent protection. The EU has They are not as yet lobbying nearly as hard for

10
further multilateral liberalization as they did in eye-catching target of abolishing tariffs world- The Bush adminis-
the Uruguay Round. wide by 2015, at last gives a potential focal point tration, while all
Third, the political climate has been stormy for the round as a whole.
due to problems within the United States and the In sum, the past year has witnessed tangible too willing to cave
EU, sometimes spilling over into bilateral spats. U.S. leadership in the trading system for the first in to protectionist
In the United States, President Bush has time since the Uruguay Round. To Zoellick, this
finally got the trade promotion authority with- is part of an overall strategy to build coalitions,
interests for short-
out which no WTO round would be taken step by step, for more open markets across the term political
seriously, but only at the cost of protectionist world. Moreover, as he makes clear in his recent advantage, never-
side deals, particularly in agriculture and steel. essay in The Economist magazine, leadership in
The 2002 Farm Security and Rural Investment trade policy, especially post–September 11, folds theless has power-
Act reverses the brief liberalizing trend in U.S. into more vigorous U.S. leadership in foreign ful insiders com-
agriculture in the 1990s and dramatically policy more generally.17 mitted to freer
increases domestic subsidies, with potentially Over in the EU, the core problem remains
grave trade-distorting effects. The massive tar- the Common Agricultural Policy. The com- trade and willing to
iffs imposed to “safeguard” (i.e., protect) ineffi- mission came out with proposals for CAP exercise active,
cient U.S. steel producers have been almost as reform that, while not proposing big cuts in
damaging, particularly in souring U.S.-EU overall levels of agricultural spending, would
robust leadership in
relations and distracting the attention of the nevertheless sever the link between subsidies the WTO.
two major powers from making headway in the and production over time, thereby diminishing
new round. the trade-distorting effect of government
Notwithstanding blemishes in U.S. domes- intervention. If implemented, this would help
tic trade politics, it is important to highlight a to unblock the agricultural negotiations in
not insignificant shift in U.S. trade policy from Geneva. Unfortunately, the prospects for radi-
the Clinton to the Bush administration—with cal surgery on the CAP were dealt a blow by
potentially vital and beneficial consequences the recent EU Council of Ministers decision to
for the WTO and the wider trading system maintain overall levels of CAP spending from
down the line. The Clinton years were charac- 2006 to 2013. This diplomatic coup for the
terized by vacillation and drift in trade policy, French government means that EU produc-
as in foreign policy more generally. Often, tion-related domestic subsidies and export sub-
especially in the twilight of the second Clinton sidies will continue to massively distort world
administration, it seemed that U.S. trade poli- agricultural markets for some time to come.
cy was held hostage by labor unions and envi- EU foot-dragging on agricultural reform was
ronmental NGOs. reflected in the commission’s delayed and
This has changed. The Bush administration, defensive set of proposals for the negotiations
while all too willing to cave in to protectionist on agriculture in the Doha Round.
interests for short-term political advantage, nev- In general, the EU’s record on trade policy,
ertheless has powerful insiders committed to freer particularly in the crucial area of agricultural
trade and willing to exercise active, robust leader- protection, reinforces the point made above:
ship in the WTO. This is especially the case with there is no substitute for U.S. leadership to
U.S. Trade Representative Robert Zoellick, who, achieve progressively freer trade.
from the free trader’s standpoint, is as sound a Fourth, the sense of disgruntlement among
front man for U.S. trade policy as one can realis- most developing countries has increased, with
tically expect. He led the effort to launch the correspondingly decreasing readiness to com-
Doha Round and displayed clear, strong leader- promise. They have a litany of complaints: the
ship with three ambitious market access propos- unwillingness of the EU and the United States
als in the WTO during 2002 (on agriculture, ser- to contemplate serious liberalization of agricul-
vices, and industrial goods). The bold and imagi- ture and textiles any time soon, the EU’s over-
native U.S. proposal on industrial goods, with its aggressive stance on the Singapore issues and

11
trade and environment, and no real progress on sensus” to mean that it or any other member
special and differential treatment and the can veto the launch of new negotiations on
implementation agenda. one, several, or all of the Singapore issues.
The July 2002 deadline for “clear recom- On trade and environment, the wording of the
mendations” on special and differential treat- ministerial declaration is looser. Members instruct
ment, for instance, first had to be postponed to the Committee on Trade and Environment to give
the end of December 2002, and even this attention to relevant WTO rules, report to the Fifth
deadline has passed without agreement. Ministerial Conference, “and make recommenda-
Another deadline—this time to agree to a tions, where appropriate, with respect to future
TRIPS waiver so that developing countries action, including the desirability of negotiations.”19
without domestic production capacity can This two-stage procedure, while necessary to
import generic drugs to deal with public health prevent failure in Doha, stores up potentially
emergencies—has also been missed due to U.S. serious problems for the next ministerial meet-
blockage. It is increasingly likely that other ing. Indeed, there is a grave risk that long-stand-
important Doha Round deadlines on agricul- ing policy differences and negotiating stalemate
ture, industrial goods, and services, set for the in 2002–03 will be followed by crisis and col-
end of March 2003, will come and go without lapse in Mexico. Several or all of the factors
There is a grave risk substantive agreement. mentioned above could conspire to bring this
that long-standing about. The Latin American members of the
policy differences coalition of farm-exporting countries known as
Opportunities and Dangers Ahead the Cairns Group, led by Brazil, have walked out
and negotiating of GATT ministerial sessions before due to EU
stalemate in Looking ahead to the negotiations to take intransigence on agriculture; they could do so
place in the run-up to Cancun and beyond, again. India, perhaps in coalition with others,
2002–03 will be fol- there is much to play for, with vast opportuni- could veto the launch of new negotiations on
lowed by crisis and ty and great danger in equal measure. Three environmental and the Singapore issues. If this
collapse in Mexico. factors deserve to be highlighted: happens, the Mexico ministerial meeting will
turn into a replay of the failed ministerial meet-
Two-Stage Round ings of 1982, 1990, and 1999. Above all, it
First, this is planned to be a two-stage would raise the specter of Seattle all over again,
round. A core of politically hypersensitive something that could easily derail the new
issues—competition, investment, and bits and round for many years and thereby cripple the
pieces of the environment—have been pushed WTO system. No one should be complacent on
back to the September ministerial meeting in this score.
Mexico, when decisions will have to be taken
to launch new negotiations. Avoid a Rush to Agreement
On the Singapore issues, the Doha ministe- Second, this is going to be a long haul, last-
rial declaration states that “negotiations will ing perhaps five to six years, or even as long as
take place after the Fifth Session of the minis- the Uruguay Round (six to seven years), with
terial conference on the basis of a decision to be plenty of ups and downs, not to mention inter-
taken, by explicit consensus, at that Session on mittent crises, en route. The stated objective of
modalities of negotiations.”18 The EU and the concluding the round in three years appears
United States sometimes seem to regard these hopelessly optimistic. This is partly because the
negotiations as preprogrammed, but that is not agenda is big and messy, especially with environ-
the impression of India and perhaps other mental and the Singapore issues to be negotiat-
developing countries. India, with the help of an ed after the Fifth Ministerial Conference (and
“interpretative note” extracted from other to be supposedly completed in just over a year
WTO members in the twilight hours of the afterwards). Furthermore, the WTO’s expand-
Doha ministerial meeting, takes “explicit con- ing membership means that an ever-wider array

12
of divergent interests has to be accommodated. ance, one that furnishes a lowest common
WTO decisionmaking, therefore, is bound to be denominator of rules and obligations applica-
more difficult and dilatory. ble to all WTO members—a level playing field
Playing the long game, moreover, may be no for international trade, but still one that allows
bad thing. There is much to be said for what plenty of leeway for different countries to have
Lord Bryce called “government by discussion,” different sets of economic policies with differ-
by which he meant the thorough and delibera- ent institutional mixes of state and market, all
tive search for solutions to difficult problems, the way from European-style social democracy
rather than rushed, unreflective action based on to Anglo-Saxon economic liberalism, Hong
scant knowledge and eventuating in botched Kong-style classical liberalism, and Chinese-
solutions. The latter, not the former, spirit char- style economic liberalization combined with
acterized the endgame of the Uruguay Round: political authoritarianism. Above all, this sce-
the United States and the EU bounced most nario would be sufficiently open-ended to
developing countries into agreements (especial- encourage bottom-up unilateral experimenta-
ly TRIPS) they did not understand and had lit- tion in economic policy by national govern-
tle hope of implementing effectively afterwards. ments in response to local circumstances and
This must be avoided at all costs; developing challenges. This would in turn promote a
countries must have time to get their domestic decentralized, market-like competitive emula-
acts together, participate actively in multilateral tion among governments in search of better
negotiations, and understand the implications of policy and institutional practice. 21
the potential deals on the table. All this argues in This constitutional package for open markets
favor of a longish round. has a proven record of success, for growth and
prosperity in developed and developing coun-
Alternative Scenarios for the Negotiations tries alike. The Bush administration’s trade pol-
Third, the Doha Round presents WTO icy team, led by Robert Zoellick, has partial
members with a major opportunity to shape sight of this market access goal, but protection-
the future of the multilateral trading system. ist interests in U.S. domestic politics, channeled
There are three scenarios in view: through Congress, make it very difficult to
Scenario One would rediscover the raison achieve. A small core of other developed and
d’être of the GATT: the progressive reduction developing countries (such as Australia, New
and removal of barriers to trade, underpinned Zealand, Hong Kong, Singapore, Chile, and
by simple, transparent, nondiscriminatory Mexico) have an even stronger stake in this kind
rules, as embodied in the national treatment of WTO. They and the U.S. administration
and most favored nation principles. must forge effective alliances, in individual The Doha Round
Admittedly, the GATT had lots of loopholes negotiating areas and across the board, to ensure
and a restricted agenda of tackling border bar- that the WTO heads in the right direction. The
presents WTO
riers on (most) industrial goods. Now a much problem is that this market access constituency members with a
expanded market access agenda subsumes agri- in the WTO is far too narrow for comfort. It is major opportunity
culture, textiles and clothing, and services, as also far from coherent and unified, with differ-
well as dealing with nonborder trade barriers. ent dividing lines on different issues. to shape the future
This scenario is traditionalist in the sense Scenario Two is an EU-style future for the of the multilateral
that it restores a GATT-like compass to the WTO, which is why the EU, arguably, presents
WTO. But it is also reformist in that it ranges the WTO with its major headache. It has
trading system.
wider (broader sectoral coverage than the imposed a cordon sanitaire around a scandalous-
GATT) and ventures deeper (procedural disci- ly protectionist and massively harmful agricul-
plines to make trade-related domestic regula- tural regime. Moreover, it seems to want to
tions more transparent, as covered by GATT turn the WTO into a lumbering regulatory
Article X and GATS Articles III and VI).20 It agency in its own image. It proposes to add
is also a scenario of political and economic bal- complex and intrusive regulation to the WTO

13
The implicit stan- agenda, some of which would impose burden- ma, however, is that this is going to be very dif-
dards harmoniza- some environmental and other standards on ficult given the narrow and fractured market
developing countries. This implicit standards access constituency within the WTO. Drift
tion agenda, aimed harmonization agenda, aimed at raising devel- and then gridlock might halt movement in any
at raising develop- oping-country standards to developed-country direction. Also possible is a dog’s-breakfast
levels, is now the most insidious force in the compromise that would attempt a synthesis of
ing-country stan- WTO. The door was opened with the TRIPS all three scenarios. The likely result is that mar-
dards to developed- agreement in the Uruguay Round; the environ- ket access gains would be gutted by a combina-
country levels, is mental aspects of the Doha Round threaten to tion of regulatory protectionism and politically
open the door much wider. The result could be correct giveaways and exemptions for develop-
now the most insid- an extra layer of developed–country regulatory ing countries. How can this be avoided? How
ious force in the barriers that would shut out cheap develop- to deliver Scenario One politically? That, more
WTO. ing–country exports. than anything, is the fundamental question
Other WTO members must make sure the facing the WTO.
EU does not steer the new round by stealth in the
wrong direction. On political, legal, economic, and
moral grounds (set out earlier), WTO rules, Specific Issues for
focused on market access, should provide the nec-
essary minimum for fair play in international com- the Doha Round
merce while respecting the diversity of policies and
institutions among countries at very different Let us move now from the broad picture to
stages of development (not to mention different the individual elements of the new round.
histories and preferences).
Scenario Three is a UN-style future for the Market Access
WTO, the prospects for which have sadly Market access—the reduction and removal
increased with the accession of so many develop- of trade barriers in agriculture, services, and
ing countries to the organization. There is much industrial goods—is (or should be) the bread
pressure to reopen Uruguay Round agreements and butter of the new round. Direct border bar-
and grant blanket exemptions to developing riers to trade remain high in both developed and
countries on the grounds of special and differen- developing countries. Although the EU and the
tial treatment. There is also a clamor for technical United States have low average tariffs, they
assistance (i.e., aid), and demands to boost devel- retain high to very high tariffs in agriculture and
oping-country representation in the WTO textiles and clothing—sectors of major export
Secretariat (overriding meritocratic selection cri- potential for developing countries. Indeed, levels
teria). At the same time, the WTO is becoming of developed-country protection in these two
more a forum for adversarial political grandstand- sectors are more than 10 times the average on
ing and procedural nitpicking than one for effec- other merchandise. Developed-country tariffs
tive decisionmaking. The danger is that a more on imports from developing countries are four
politicized WTO would look more like a useless times as high as tariffs on imports from other
and wasteful UN development agency than the OECD countries.22 Nontariff barriers are also
pre-1995 GATT. It would dole out lots of aid to significant, especially in the form of widespread
poor countries and return to old-style special and and unreasonably onerous food safety, technical,
differential treatment, but would be too crippled and other standards that have a chilling effect on
to do much else. developing-country exports.
It is all very well to say that the Doha Developing countries have noticeably higher
Round should be used to realize Scenario One average tariffs, tariff peaks, and tariff escalation
while avoiding Scenarios Two and Three, as (higher tariffs on processed goods), as well as high-
might be the inclination of the politically igno- er nontariff barriers than developed countries, not
rant free-trade economist. The political dilem- to mention proliferating antidumping actions.

14
Much of this developing-country protection is distort trade). The EU, and France in particular,
aimed at imports from other developing coun- objected strongly to language on “phasing out”
tries.23 Rich-country protection is damaging pre- export subsidies right to the last minute of nego-
cisely because it provides developing countries with tiations at Doha. The price of EU approval of
a pretext not to reduce their own trade barriers; it the text was the prefatory insertion of “without
seriously undermines political efforts to accelerate prejudging the outcome of the negotiations.”
pro-market reforms in the developing world.24 This arguably dilutes the commitment to abol-
The World Bank estimates an annual gain ish export subsidies, but was necessary in order
of $2.8 trillion by 2015 from the elimination of to avert outright failure in Doha.
trade barriers and trade-related reforms on all In addition, developing countries are to have
goods and services. Developing countries special and differential treatment, which will take
would gain to the tune of $1.5 trillion, which account of food security and rural development
would lift 320 million people out of poverty. needs. “Non-trade concerns will be taken into
Two-thirds of the gain from cutting tariffs on account in the negotiations”—which assuages
industrial goods (about $300 billion) would go EU sensibilities on animal welfare, consumer pro-
to developing countries, and they would gain a tection, and rural development but without men-
roughly equivalent amount from the abolition tioning “multifunctionality,” the buzzword for the
of trade-distorting agricultural subsidies in the alleged social benefits of farming.27 Any mention
Rich-country pro-
OECD. However, the biggest gains by far for of the latter in the text would have precipitated a tection is damaging
developing countries (estimated at about $900 walkout by the Cairns Group. precisely because it
billion, two to three times the gain from liber- Finally, negotiations proper started in April
alizing goods trade) would come from radical 2002, with an evaluation of comprehensive draft provides develop-
services liberalization in both developed and schedules to be met by the time of the Mexico ing countries with a
developing countries.25 ministerial meeting.28 The highlight of negotia-
tions so far has been the radical U.S. proposal to
pretext not to
Agriculture. Agricultural protection in high- reduce trade-distorting domestic subsidies (by reduce their own
income countries remains almost as high as it $100 billion to 5 percent of agricultural produc- trade barriers; it
was at the end of the Uruguay Round, and seri- tion), bring down average tariffs from 62 percent
ous distortions continue to plague agriculture to 15 percent, and abolish export subsidies by seriously under-
in developing countries. The “built-in” WTO 2010. The Cairns Group came up with a similar- mines political
negotiations on agriculture, which started in ly radical proposal. The EU, however, shows no efforts to accelerate
early 2000, made some progress in clearing up signs of significant movement. Its long-delayed
outstanding technical and procedural issues proposal, finally put on the table in December pro-market reforms
and generated a large number of negotiating 2002, contains much more limited cuts on tariffs in the developing
proposals. However, in the absence of a larger (by 36 percent), domestic production-linked sub-
round of multilateral negotiations, govern- sidies (by 55 percent), and export subsidies (by 45
world.
ments did not get to the stage of hard bargain- percent). The EU stance, combining arch-con-
ing over market access. servatism on market access with a strong accent
The Doha ministerial declaration states that on nontrade concerns like environmental protec-
“without prejudging the outcome of the negoti- tion and animal welfare, is supported by its fellow
ations we commit ourselves to comprehensive Friends of Multifunctionality, a coalition of
negotiations aimed at: substantial improvements WTO members that includes Japan, Korea,
in market access; reductions of, with a view to Norway, and Switzerland.
phasing out, all forms of export subsidies; and Thus there remains a yawning gap between
substantial reductions in trade-distorting the United States and the Cairns Group, on the
domestic support.”26 Market access negotiations one hand, and the EU and its allies, on the other,
now revolve around tariffs and tariff quotas, and with plenty of other developing countries (such
negotiations on domestic subsidies focus on as India) highly ambivalent about their own
those that are linked to production (and hence agricultural liberalization. Alas, the prospects for

15
a political breakthrough in the agricultural is the one key area in which developing coun-
negotiations, upon which the future of the tries have an export advantage in services.
whole round hinges, appear depressingly However, mode four commitments are very
remote. As things stand, it is almost a racing cer- weak and largely restricted to the movement of
tainty that the March 31, 2003, deadline for intracorporate transferees. Finally, both devel-
establishing “modalities” for the next (more seri- oped and developing countries need to make
ous) phase of agricultural negotiations will be commitments to improve the transparency of
honored in the breach. This threatens to become domestic regulations covering services (covered
the one major round-stopper, either pre-Cancun by GATS Article VI:4 in particular). Opaque
or in Cancun itself. domestic regulations rather than border barriers
are the main hindrance to market access and
Services. The General Agreement on Trade in greater competition in services.
Services is complicated and messy, and so far has The post–September 11 environment com-
delivered only modest market access commit- plicates matters somewhat. It is going to be even
ments. The built-in GATS negotiations, like the more difficult to get developed countries to
parallel mandated agricultural negotiations, gen- accept more developing-country workers on
erated a large number of negotiating proposals short-term contracts, especially those who are
but did not get to the stage of hard bargaining semi- or unskilled (e.g., in catering and con-
over market access. Nevertheless, they have clar- struction services). Developing countries would
ified procedural issues and brought about a bet- also gain substantially from the liberalization of
ter understanding of the legal texts. In addition, hitherto protected developed-country markets
the process may have marginally improved the in (air, land, and maritime) transport and energy
medium-term prospects for net liberalization, in services. Again, the post–September 11 environ-
contrast to GATS commitments at the end of ment may make this more difficult because of
the Uruguay Round, which mostly did not go concerns about border security.
beyond the status quo in national policies. Other subjects for the GATS negotiations
Perhaps most important, developing countries include subsidies and emergency safeguards
have noticeably stepped up their participation in aimed at preventing import surges, both tech-
the services negotiations and have put several nically complicated and politically tricky. The
negotiating proposals on the table. Doha ministerial declaration stipulates that
The broad outlines of eventual agreement “participants shall submit initial requests for
are not difficult to discern. All parties need to specific commitments by June 30th 2002 and
make more commitments on national treat- initial offers by March 31st 2003”—a very
Real progress in the ment for services and investment and market tight time frame.29
access (Articles XVI and XVII GATS), with So far negotiations have made some low-key
services negotia- fewer exemptions in their schedules. progress, helped by the fact that they are not as
tions will not occur Developing countries need to make substantial- politicized as other negotiating areas such as agri-
unless there are ly more commitments in “mode three” of sup- culture and the implementation agenda. The
ply (“commercial presence,” which effectively United States’ ambitious proposal in mid–2002
breakthroughs in concerns inward investment). This would in puts transparency in domestic regulation (not sur-
other negotiating any case complement autonomous liberaliza- prisingly drawing on U.S. practice) at the heart of
tion of inward investment by the host country, GATS deliberations and future commitments.
areas, agriculture in particularly in financial and telecom services Nevertheless, real progress in the services negotia-
particular. (both key infrastructural inputs with potential- tions will not occur unless there are breakthroughs
ly big economy-wide gains). Developed coun- in other negotiating areas, agriculture in particular.
tries need to reciprocate with meaningful com-
mitments in “mode four” of supply (“movement Industrial Goods. Developed-country peak
of natural persons,” that is, cross-border move- tariffs and tariff escalation hinder developing-
ment of workers on temporary contracts). This country exports in textiles and clothing, food-

16
stuffs, steel, energy products, leather goods, and 2010 as the intermediary target date for elimi- Developing coun-
footwear. In addition, trade among developing nating all tariffs under 5 percent and bringing tries will expect
countries is severely hampered by their own maximum tariffs down to 8 percent. Arguably,
high and differentiated tariffs, not to mention this is the most important proposal to date in developed coun-
a plethora of nontariff barriers. the Doha Round, and the most visible sign of tries—the United
To begin with, developing countries will resurgent U.S. activism in international trade
expect developed countries—the United States policy. If it could generate sufficient support
States in particular—
in particular—to live up to commitments to from other WTO members, and providing to live up to commit-
phase out bilateral quotas on textiles and cloth- movement occurred on other fronts (especially ments to phase out
ing by the beginning of 2005, as set out in the agriculture), it could give real focus to negotia-
Uruguay Round Agreement on Textiles and tions and set the round on its feet. bilateral quotas on
Clothing. So far not much has been done (least Predictably, the U.S. proposal immediately textiles and clothing
of all in the United States), and the phaseout of ran into controversy. It is supported by New by the beginning of
quotas is back-loaded to the last year. There is Zealand, Hong Kong, and Singapore; the EU
also the worry that high tariffs and a cascade of and Japan are skeptical. The real opposition, 2005.
antidumping actions will follow in 2005 and however, comes from most developing coun-
beyond—even more so with China’s entry to tries. Given higher average tariffs, greater inci-
the WTO. Hence there is a good chance that dence of peak tariffs and tariff escalation, and,
the new round will be derailed if developed not least, asymmetrical dependence on customs
countries do not live up to their ATC commit- duties for government revenue, they would
ments by the 2005 deadline. bear the brunt of adjustment en route to zero
The ministerial declaration proclaims new tariffs. The other side of the coin is that they
negotiations “to reduce or as appropriate elimi- stand to benefit most: through efficiency gains
nate tariffs, including the reduction or elimina- from opening their own markets to imports,
tion of tariff peaks, high tariffs, and tariff escala- the opening of other developing-country mar-
tion, as well as non-tariff barriers, in particular on kets to their exports, and, finally, the opening of
products of export interest to developing coun- developed-country markets to their exports,
tries. Product coverage shall be comprehensive particularly in textiles and clothing.
and without a priori exclusions.” Developing and There is a tight deadline of end March
least-developed countries will have special treat- 2003 to establish modalities and formulas for
ment, “including through less than full reciproci- actual tariff-cutting negotiations. Given the
ty in reduction commitments.”30 lack of consensus so far, the odds are that this
One key to progress in these negotiations deadline will not be met.
will probably be a formula approach to tariff
harmonization akin to the “Swiss formula” fol- Rule Making: Antidumping, Subsidies,
lowed during the Tokyo Round. This would and RTAs
entail higher cuts in tariff peaks and tariffs on Market access negotiations are not enough:
processed goods. Request-offer negotiations, they need to be buttressed by improvements to the
uniform tariff cuts, “zero-for-zero” cuts, and WTO rule base. This is the essential machinery
the like, on their own, would not tackle the tar- that greases the wheels of multilateral market
iff peaks and tariff escalation that hinder devel- access on a day-to-day basis. It also tends to be
oping-country exports. neglected whenever the WTO becomes fixated on
The really radical proposals to date have launching and then negotiating a new round.
come first from New Zealand and then from The gaping hole in WTO rules is Article
the United States. Both have the abolition of VI GATT, which governs antidumping and
tariffs worldwide as the ultimate objective. The countervailing duties. It sets out the basic rules
U.S. proposal, drawing on that of the U.S. under which countries are permitted to impose
National Foreign Trade Council, has 2015 as duties on “dumped” foreign products, that is,
the target date for scrapping all tariffs, with pricing exports below comparable price in the

17
exporting country. These rules, however, are tape. Without further multilateral (nondis-
very weak, doing little to arrest selective and criminatory) liberalization and stronger WTO
open-ended antidumping actions to restrict disciplines on RTAs, this trend will make trade
imports—all too often the protectionist’s policy across the world even more unequal,
weapon of choice. Small firms and new opaque, and discriminatory. If unchecked, it
entrants from developing countries are espe- will marginalize the WTO and subject inter-
cially vulnerable; indeed, the majority of national trade and investment more decisively
antidumping actions are aimed at developing to the political whims of the major powers
country exports. Since the 1990s, developing (notably the United States and the EU) around
countries have increasingly resorted to their which RTA blocs are forming.34
own antidumping actions, especially against The U.S. proposal to abolish tariffs on
other developing countries. They would gain nonagricultural goods is of major relevance
most from strengthened Article VI provisions. here. The multilateral abolition of industrial
In the ministerial declaration, WTO mem- tariffs would remove much of the trade diver-
bers agree to negotiations “aimed at clarifying sion, rules of origin complications, and assort-
and improving disciplines under the ed red tape that are associated with RTAs.
Agreements on Implementation of Article VI of However, much discrimination would continue
The fact remains the GATT 1994 and on Subsidies and due to remaining nontariff barriers and, not
that stronger Countervailing Measures.” This was a major least, the persistence of agricultural tariffs.
WTO rules on concession by Robert Zoellick, overcoming
domestic opposition in the United States and Developing-Country Issues
antidumping winning him much respect among the WTO The preamble to the ministerial declaration
actions will face for- membership. Nevertheless, the scope of negoti- places the “needs and interests [of developing
ations is hedged about with the caveat that they countries] at the heart of the Work Program. . . .
midable opposition, should preserve “the basic concepts, principles In this context, enhanced market access, balanced
particularly in the and effectiveness of these Agreements and their rules, and well targeted, sustainably financed
U.S. Congress. instruments and objectives.”31 The fact remains technical assistance and capacity building pro-
that stronger WTO rules on antidumping grammes have important roles to play. . . . We are
actions will face formidable opposition, particu- committed to addressing the marginalization of
larly in the U.S. Congress.32 least developed countries in international trade
In addition, WTO members agree to “clar- and to improving their effective participation in
ifying and improving” disciplines on fisheries the multilateral trading system.”35
subsidies (another developing-country con- Issues specific to developing countries in
cern) and regional trade agreements, and to the new round relate, inter alia, to the imple-
“improvements and clarifications” of the mentation agenda, special and differential
Dispute Settlement Understanding. 33 treatment, technical cooperation and capacity
There is the danger that these negotiations building, the TRIPS agreement, and least-
may suffer from neglect. For example, it will be developed and small economies.
difficult to strengthen disciplines on regional
trade agreements (in GATT Article XXIV, The Implementation Agenda. Most develop-
GATS Article V, and on preferential rules of ing countries, particularly the least developed
origin) when nearly all WTO members are among them, face severe constraints in imple-
involved in one or several of them. This is menting Uruguay Round agreements, particu-
alarming. RTAs are spreading like wildfire, larly those on intellectual property protection
splicing up world markets into unequal chunks (TRIPS), trade-related investment measures
benefiting some at the expense of others. Most (TRIMS), sanitary and phytosanitary stan-
RTAs also have highly complicated, overlap- dards (SPS), technical barriers to trade (TBT),
ping, and contradictory rules of origin that tie customs valuation, and import licensing. As J.
up trade in knots of costly and burdensome red Michael Finger of the American Enterprise

18
Institute points out, there are real and substan- ods, technical assistance, and the like built into
tial costs involved in implementing these trade new commitments on a flexible, case-by-case,
procedures domestically—much more so than needs-oriented basis. This has to be treated in an
is the case with the removal of tariffs and quo- issue-specific and country-specific manner and is
tas at the border.36 This “implementation agen- inevitably going to be complicated and drawn
da” has risen to the top of the WTO priority out—another argument for a longer rather than
list in the past two years but evinced no real shorter round. Above all, the Uruguay Round
progress until fairly recently. folly of rushing developing countries into agree-
Considerable progress, however, was made ments with blithe disregard for implementation
after July–August 2001, and by the time of the effects must not be repeated.
Doha ministerial conference about half of the
approximately 100 implementation issues were Special and Differential Treatment. “Old-
resolved. These are contained in a separate style” special and differential treatment (SDT),
ministerial decision issued at the end of the as expressed in Part IV of the GATT and the
Doha ministerial conference. Inter alia, they Enabling Clause of the Tokyo Round, largely
address the Agreement on Agriculture (e.g., exempted developing countries from GATT
exercising restraint in challenging developing- rules and obligations. They were granted sweep-
country subsidies for food security and rural ing carve-outs from GATT disciplines, and they
development purposes), the SPS and TBT received developed-country preferences but
agreements, the ATC (e.g., restraint in initiat- were not obliged to reciprocate. The whole
ing antidumping investigations on developing- process caused much self-inflicted damage in
country textiles and clothing exports), TRIMS developing countries and marginalized them in
(extension of transition periods), GATT the GATT. That changed during the Uruguay
Article VI (on antidumping measures), the Round when some (but still a minority of)
Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing developing countries, on the back of unilateral
Measures (e.g., restraint in challenging certain liberalization and a sharper appreciation of their
developing-country subsidies, exempting least- trading interests, began to play a more active
developed countries from the prohibition on part in the GATT. They realized the impor-
export subsidies, and extending transition peri- tance of reciprocal obligations in order to be at
ods for the phaseout of export subsidies in the bargaining table, and they developed a bet-
other developing countries).37 ter appreciation of nondiscriminatory rules—to
This leaves another 50 or so implementa- shield them from the protectionism of other,
tion issues outstanding, which are to be dealt more powerful players and to provide very nec-
with in the new round and form part of the essary economic policy discipline domestically. Above all, the
eventual Single Undertaking. The main minis- References to special and differential treat-
terial declaration states that these issues “shall ment are sprinkled liberally throughout the
Uruguay Round
be addressed as a matter of priority by the rel- ministerial declaration and reaffirmed as “an folly of rushing
evant WTO bodies, which shall report to the integral part of the WTO Agreements.” They developing countries
Trade Negotiations Committee . . . by the end appear to encompass a grab bag of non- (or
of 2002 for appropriate action.” 38 Very little less-) reciprocal, preferential concessions; into agreements
progress has been made so far, and the end longer transition periods; technical assistance with blithe disregard
2002 deadline has been missed. and related capacity-building exercises; and
Fresh implementation issues are bound to (extra) special provisions for least-developed
for implementation
arise in the course of negotiations on market countries. The declaration also states that “all effects must not be
access, rules, and new issues in the new round. special and differential treatment provisions repeated.
These will be handled in the separate negotiating shall be reviewed with a view to strengthening
mandates.39 It is vital that the implementation them and making them more precise, effective
dimension of each and every negotiating man- and operational.”40 The separate decision on
date be carefully considered, with transition peri- implementation issues refers to “converting

19
It is in developing [nonbinding] special and differential treatment oping world. The countries concerned should
countries’ interests to measures into mandatory provisions . . . with have flexible (i.e., longer) transition periods;
clear recommendations for a decision by July substantially increased, perhaps mandatory,
subscribe to the reci- 2002.”41 This deadline had to be shifted back to technical assistance; and associated capacity-
procity principle and the end of December 2002 due to lack of building measures aimed at helping less-devel-
agreement, and even this second deadline has oped countries implement their WTO com-
adhere to basic, passed without agreement. mitments. As mentioned before, this needs to
common, nondis- It would be a grave mistake if the reviews of be done in differentiated, bottom-up fashion
criminatory rules in SDT resulted in a return to the old-style non- congruent with national circumstances and
reciprocity that did such damage to developing capacities. For this the WTO needs to set up
order to extract max- countries pre-Uruguay Round. Unfortunately, an appropriate mechanism to assess individual
imum benefit from this looks like the position of one bloc of devel- countries’ implementation problems, appropri-
the WTO system. oping countries, particularly the Like-Minded ate transition periods, and resource needs as
Group led by India, Pakistan, and Egypt, well as to monitor and review subsequent
whose focus is the implementation agenda. progress. To be avoided are open-ended opt-
The hardliners seem to want to reopen existing outs and automatic extensions of transition
Uruguay Round agreements in order to grant periods for whole classes of countries. 42
blanket carve-outs to developing countries—a
nonstarter for developed countries and the Technical Cooperation and Capacity Building.
more advanced, sensible developing countries References to technical cooperation and capacity
in the WTO. This would only exacerbate the building are spattered throughout the ministerial
begging-bowl, dependency mentality of so declaration, as well as occupying a four-paragraph
many developing-country governments. They separate section in it. The wording is mostly
would become even more dependent on uncer- vague and exhortatory, even though there is refer-
tain and insubstantial preferential market ence to “firm commitments” in the declaration.
access to developed countries, and exposed to The WTO Secretariat is instructed “to support
the vagaries of the latter’s power politics. domestic efforts for mainstreaming trade into
On the contrary, it is in developing countries’ national plans for economic development and
interests to subscribe to the reciprocity principle strategies for poverty reduction. The delivery of
and adhere to basic, common, nondiscriminatory WTO technical assistance shall be designed to
rules in order to extract maximum benefit from assist developing and least-developed countries
the WTO system. It is true that some low- and low-income countries in transition to adjust
income and all least-developed countries have to WTO rules and disciplines, implement oblig-
legitimate implementation issues to address, ations and exercise the rights of membership. . . .
given the complexity of the Uruguay Round Priority shall also be accorded to small, vulnera-
agreements and their limited capacity to give ble, and transition economies, as well as to
effect to them domestically; and they need a help- Members and Observers without representation
ing hand to participate more effectively in the in Geneva.” Technical assistance is supposed to be
WTO. But it is equally true that the score or so coordinated effectively with bilateral donors and
of more-advanced middle-income developing- other international organizations.43
country members of the WTO have few, rela- The most specific reference is to the need for
tively minor implementation problems. Even “secure and predictable funding” for technical
those faced by India are somewhat overblown (by assistance and capacity building. Accordingly,
the Indian government) and pale in comparison the director-general is instructed “to report to
with the situation in sub-Saharan Africa. the Fifth Session of the Ministerial
Hence “new-style” SDT, especially on Conference, with an interim report to the
implementation issues, should focus on the General Council in December 2002 on the
least-developed countries where problems are implementation and adequacy of these com-
real and pressing, not on the rest of the devel- mitments in the identified paragraphs.”44

20
Very little technical assistance from devel- Most controversial, developing countries are
oped-country coffers has been forthcoming concerned that TRIPS could inhibit cheap and
since the Uruguay Round. It remains to be seen plentiful access to essential medicines, such as
whether this will change substantially, even drugs to combat HIV/AIDS.
though the sums required are actually very TRIPS was one of the most sensitive issues
modest and a drop in the ocean compared with that had to be resolved by ministers at the Doha
overall aid transfers. The demand, however, is ministerial conference itself. The pharmaceutical
huge: up to 120 developing countries (existing multinationals and developed-country govern-
WTO members and about 30 accession candi- ments have had to concede greater flexibility in
dates) are in need of technical assistance for interpreting parts of TRIPS, especially sections
trade-related capacity building. So far govern- related to pharmaceutical patents, after a series
ments have pledged $10 million as part of a of public relations disasters in 2000 and 2001.
Global Trust Fund for technical assistance in The question was whether such flexibility was to
the new round. 45 be narrowly defined, essentially limited to over-
riding patents and issuing compulsory licenses
Least-Developed Countries. Again, there is for generic production in public health emer-
much exhortatory language in the ministerial gencies, such as an HIV/AIDS pandemic, or
declaration. WTO members endorse the whether it was to be more open-ended. In the
Developing coun-
Integrated Framework for Trade-Related end, in an agreement brokered by Brazil, devel- tries are concerned
Technical Assistance to least Developed oping countries seem to have won a major vic- that TRIPS could
Countries, and urge all involved to “explore the tory in procuring a rather flexible interpretation
enhancement of the [Integrated Framework].” of TRIPS insofar as it concerns public health. inhibit cheap and
The director-general and other heads of agencies A separate ministerial declaration on TRIPS plentiful access to
are requested to provide an interim report to the states that, “while reiterating our commitment
General Council at the end of 2002, and a full to the TRIPS Agreement, we affirm that the
essential medicines,
report at the Mexico ministerial meeting, on all Agreement can and should be interpreted and such as drugs to
issues affecting the least-developed countries.46 implemented in a manner supportive of WTO combat HIV/AIDS.
More specifically, WTO members commit Members’ right to protect public health and, in
themselves “to the objective of duty-free, quota- particular, to promote access to medicines for all.
free market access for products originating from . . . In this connection, we reaffirm the right of
LDCs. . . . We further commit ourselves to con- WTO Members to use, to the full, the provi-
sider additional measures for progressive sions in the TRIPS Agreement, which provide
improvements in market access for LDCs.”47 flexibility for this purpose.” These flexibilities are
explained: “Each Member has the right to grant
TRIPS. The TRIPS Agreement has been a compulsory licenses and the freedom to deter-
lightning rod for developing-country com- mine the grounds upon which such licenses are
plaints. Its short-term effect is to increase prices granted. . . . Each Member has the right to
and transfer monopoly profits from the poorer determine what constitutes a national emer-
developing countries to multinational enterpris- gency or other circumstances of extreme
es headquartered in the West, especially in the urgency, it being understood that public health
pharmaceuticals sector. The proponents of crises, including those related to HIV/AIDS,
TRIPS argue that longer-term dynamic gains, tuberculosis, malaria and other epidemics, can
that is, from foreign investment and associated represent a national emergency or other circum-
technology transfer, will outweigh short-term stances of extreme urgency.” Each member is
losses; but this is uncertain and probably applies also free to establish its own regime for the
in the main to the more-advanced developing exhaustion of intellectual property rights with-
countries. TRIPS is also regulation heavy, out challenge, subject to most favored nation
requiring much time and resources to put and national treatment provisions in TRIPS.48
domestic enforcement mechanisms in place. The same declaration instructs the TRIPS

21
Council to “find an expeditious solution” to the waiver is open-ended and goes too far in weak-
problem of WTO members who find it diffi- ening patent protection. Its preferred solution
cult to take advantage of compulsory licensing is to restrict the waiver to cover generic imports
due to lack of domestic manufacturing capaci- destined for less-developed countries, and only
ty, and to report to the General Council before for certain epidemics such as HIV/AIDS,
the end of 2002. In addition, the transition tuberculosis, and malaria.
period for least-developed countries to imple- The lone U.S. veto means another deadline
ment large sections of TRIPS is extended by 10 has been missed and throws the TRIPS nego-
years to 2016.49 tiations into turmoil. It adds to the general
The main ministerial declaration agrees to gloom in the run-up to Cancun.
new negotiations to establish a system of noti-
fication and registration of “geographical indi- Other Developing-Country Issues. A new work
cations” for wines and spirits by the Mexico program will examine issues relating to the trade
ministerial meeting. The extension of geo- of small, vulnerable economies. Two new work-
graphical indications (place names used to ing groups are also to be set up: one to examine
identify products with characteristics associat- the relationship between trade, debt, and finance
ed with specific locations) to products other and the other to examine the relationship
The lone U.S. veto than wines and spirits will also be addressed by between trade and technology transfer. 51 It is
means another the TRIPS Council. Finally, the TRIPS difficult to imagine anything substantial coming
deadline has been Council is instructed to examine, inter alia, the out of these working groups in the near future.
relationship between the TRIPS Agreement
missed and throws and the Convention on Biological Diversity
the TRIPS negotia- and the protection of “traditional knowledge Singapore Issues
and folklore” in less-developed countries.50 All Of the four Singapore issues, two—invest-
tions into turmoil. these issues for negotiation and examination ment and competition—are controversial. That is
It adds to the gen- are important for developing countries but less the case with trade facilitation and trans-
eral gloom in the have not received the publicity and attention parency in public procurement. The EU succeed-
devoted to overriding drug patents during pub- ed in getting all four issues onto the negotiating
run-up to Cancun. lic health emergencies. agenda in a two-step procedure: preparatory work
The main roadblock in the TRIPS negotia- commenced at the beginning of the round; actu-
tions at the moment is compulsory licensing al negotiations will only start after the Mexico
provisions for developing countries without ministerial meeting, “on the basis of a decision to
domestic production capacity. This concerns be taken, by explicit consensus, at that Session on
the vast majority of developing countries in the the modalities of the negotiations.”52
WTO. TRIPS rules restrict their ability to The outcomes of all four sets of negotiations
import generic drugs from other developing will fold into the Single Undertaking at the end
countries; but this is their preferred course of of the round.53 This is unfortunate. There are rea-
action in order to provide essential medicines, sonable arguments pro and contra these issues as
at affordable cost, to deal with public health negotiating items in the new round. Nevertheless,
emergencies. A compromise deal, involving a they are of secondary importance, well below the
waiver to relevant TRIPS provisions, was priority, big-ticket market access items identified
thrashed out at a mini-ministerial meeting in earlier. Furthermore, as mentioned before, there is
Australia in November 2002. The EU, other the possibility of India and perhaps other devel-
developed countries, and the developing coun- oping countries vetoing negotiations on the
tries en bloc were supportive. However, a final Singapore issues at the Mexico ministerial meet-
agreement was blocked by the U.S. administra- ing if they feel aggrieved with lack of progress in
tion, which came under heavy pressure from the new round during the course of 2002–03.
U.S. pharmaceutical multinationals. The This could, in the worst scenario, turn into a
United States argues that the proposed TRIPS replay of Seattle.

22
It would have been better to keep these ment provisions; exceptions and balance-of-
issues out of the Single Undertaking. The payments safeguards; consultation and the set-
alternative would have been opt-ins and opt- tlement of disputes between Members.”54
outs for WTO members—more along the
lines of “plurilateral” codes (as exist for public Trade and Competition Policy. The argu-
procurement and civil aircraft) that members ments in favor of bringing competition
can decide to accept or reject rather than (antitrust) rules into the WTO are not as
GATT- and TRIPS-type obligations binding strong as those in favor of investment rules in
on all. This would have allowed enthusiastic the WTO. There are disagreements about the
subsets of members to proceed with negotia- importance of so-called private barriers to
tions, while allowing others, especially skeptical trade, such as cartels; and the latter are arguably
developing-country members, to stand aside. It not as important as the public (government-
would have been a useful safety valve for the imposed) tariff and nontariff barriers to trade,
Mexico ministerial meeting. whose reduction and removal should be the
The way out of the morass in the run-up to WTO’s core mission. Furthermore, new WTO
Cancun may be to build consensus around light, competition regulations would impose an
evolutionary agreements that would be de minimis implementation burden on developing coun-
to begin with, that is, with opt-ins or opt-outs and tries on top of their post–Uruguay Round
not necessarily subject to dispute settlement. obligations. The last thing they need right now
However, they could be strengthened gradually is a WTO obligation to set up complex com-
and incrementally given sufficient consensus in the petition authorities, for which most of them
future. The overriding imperative is to prevent the simply do not have the resources.
Singapore issues from becoming a round-stopper. Even the EU recognizes that eventual
WTO agreement on competition rules in this
Trade and Investment. Given stronger link- round will have to be loose and minimalist. In
ages between trade and foreign direct invest- this vein, and before negotiations start, the
ment (FDI), there is a long-term rationale for ministerial declaration charges the Working
bringing investment rules into the WTO. A Group on the Interaction between Trade and
strong investment agreement in the WTO Competition Policy to focus on “core princi-
would create multilateral, nondiscriminatory ples; including transparency, non-discrimina-
disciplines for a liberal investment climate. tion and procedural fairness, and provisions on
Nevertheless, there is continuing momentum hardcore cartels; modalities for voluntary co-
behind unilateral liberalization of FDI in operation; and support for progressive rein-
developing countries, complemented by bilat- forcement of competition institutions in devel- New WTO com-
eral investment treaties and investment provi- oping countries through capacity building.”55
sions in regional trade agreements. Finally,
petition regulations
investment rules are already built into the Transparency in Public Procurement. A pluri- would impose an
WTO: strongly in GATS through “commer- lateral code, the Government Procurement implementation
cial presence” (mode three of supply), also in Agreement, covers public procurement in
TRIPS, and weakly on the goods side in the goods. A limited number of mainly developed burden on develop-
agreements on TRIMS and Subsidies and countries belong to it. They extend most ing countries on
Countervailing Measures. favored nation and national treatment to each
Before negotiations start, the ministerial other but not to nonsignatories, which is why
top of their
declaration charges the Working Group on the the GPA falls outside GATT disciplines. In post–Uruguay
Relationship between Trade and Investment to addition, as a result of an initiative taken at the Round obligations.
focus on issues of “scope and definition; trans- Singapore ministerial meeting in 1996, a mul-
parency; non-discrimination; modalities for tilateral working group was set up to improve
pre-establishment commitments based on a transparency in government procurement
GATS-type, positive list approach; develop- practices. Very little progress has been made to

23
Environmental date on this front. Finally, while the GATS Environmental Hazards. The relationship
standards are defi- excludes coverage of public procurement in between trade and the environment is more
services, further negotiations are mandated. complicated than that between trade and labor
nitely on the nego- Again, there is next to no progress to report. standards. Parts of the former are also already
tiating agenda for The ministerial declaration states that new built into the WTO, especially in the SPS and
negotiations “shall be limited to the trans- TBT agreements. The EU, the lead demandeur
the new round; parency aspects and therefore will not restrict on this issue, got what it wanted into the new
labor standards are the scope for countries to give preferences to round, and perhaps more than it dreamed of
definitely excluded domestic supplies and suppliers.”56 achieving. If WTO members, and developing
countries in particular, are not careful, the envi-
from it. Trade Facilitation. Arbitrary, corrupt, and ronmental bits of the negotiating agenda could
time-consuming customs administration, exces- turn out to be the Trojan horse in the new
sive trade documentation, and assorted red tape round, just as TRIPS was the Trojan horse in
often do more harm than tariffs to trade in goods the last round. This chunk of the new round
and services, particularly in developing countries. will be the EU’s chief vehicle for bringing new,
Small and medium-sized firms are hit especially complex, and mostly dubious regulation into
hard. Hence the ministerial declaration recog- the WTO.
nizes “the case for further expediting the move- The ministerial declaration contains a wordy
ment, release and clearance of goods, including paragraph in its preamble, in which WTO
goods in transit, and the need for enhanced tech- members “strongly reaffirm [their] commitment
nical assistance and capacity building in this area.” to the objective of sustainable development.” It
Before negotiations start, the Council for Trade in goes on: “We recognize that under WTO rules
Goods “shall review and as appropriate, clarify no country should be prevented from taking
and improve relevant aspects of Articles V, VII measures for the protection of human, animal or
and X of the GATT 1994.”57 plant life or health, or of the environment at the
levels it considers appropriate, subject to the
Labor, Environmental, and Other Issues requirement that they are not applied in a man-
Environmental standards are definitely on ner which would constitute a means of arbitrary
the negotiating agenda for the new round; or unjustifiable discrimination between coun-
labor standards are definitely excluded from it. tries where the same conditions prevail, or a dis-
Developing countries clearly recognize that guised restriction on international trade, and are
bringing labor standards into the WTO, in what- otherwise in accordance with the provisions of
ever form, could be the thin end of the wedge. the WTO Agreements.”58
Developed countries would in due course press The section on trade and environment in the
for obligations to comply with “minimum” or work program is split into two parts. The first
“core” labor standards, which could easily be part launches immediate negotiations, “without
abused (much like antidumping actions) in order prejudging their outcome,” on (1) “the relation-
to shut the door on cheap, labor-intensive devel- ship between existing WTO rules and specific
oping-country exports. Hence their understand- trade obligations set out in multilateral environ-
able inflexibility on the issue. mental agreements (MEAs). . . . The negotia-
The preamble to the ministerial declaration tions shall not prejudice the WTO rights of any
curtly reconfirms existing policy: “We reaffirm our Member that is not a party to the MEA in
declaration made at the Singapore ministerial con- question”; (2) “procedures for regular informa-
ference regarding internationally recognized core tion exchange between MEA Secretariats and
labor standards. We take note of work underway in the relevant WTO committees, and the criteria
the International Labor Organization (ILO) on for the granting of observer status”; and (3) “the
the social dimension of globalization.” Labor stan- reduction or, as appropriate, elimination of tariff
dards are staying off the WTO agenda—at least and non-tariff barriers to environmental goods
until this round is over. and services.”59

24
Liberalizing trade in environmental goods This prevents developed countries from “export-
and services is welcome. Clarifying the rela- ing” (or imposing) their environmental stan-
tionship between the WTO and individual dards on developing countries. The forthcoming
MEAs is probably necessary, but developing work on eco-labeling could be a useful middle
countries should proceed with a very watchful way to reconcile developed- and developing-
eye. If they do not watch out, WTO general or country concerns, but it could equally be abused
specific waivers could open the floodgates to an to impose costly and inappropriate standards on
increasing number of badly designed and developing-country exports.
administratively unwieldy MEAs that take lit- The second danger zone concerns the EU’s
tle account of developing-country concerns. attempts to get its version of the “precautionary
Trade sanctions could then be used to enforce principle” recognized in the WTO. This failed
compliance with MEAs. This may make sense outright before and in Doha. All WTO mem-
for some MEAs, but not for others. bers agree that precautionary measures, such as
The second part of the ministerial declara- temporary import bans, can be applied if there
tion on trade and environment instructs the is a danger to human, animal, or plant life or
Committee on Trade and Environment to health, but existing GATT rules, and especial-
work on the following: (1) “the effect of envi- ly the SPS Agreement, insist that these mea-
ronmental measures on market access, espe- sures should be based on scientific evidence
The forthcoming
cially in relation to developing countries, in and should not constitute disguised restrictions work on eco-label-
particular the least developed among them, and on trade. The EU, however, takes a much more ing could be a use-
those situations in which the elimination or conservative view of risk assessment than other
reduction of trade restrictions and distortions WTO members, especially where food safety ful middle way to
would benefit trade, the environment and standards are concerned. The EU stance on reconcile devel-
development”; (2) “the relevant provisions of precaution is much less based on what existing
the Agreement on Trade-Related Intellectual scientific evidence would consider as “accept-
oped- and develop-
Property Rights”; and (3) “labelling require- able” risk and wishes to take consumer and ing-country con-
ments for environmental purposes.”60 other views into account. Hence its strong cerns, but it could
It goes on: “Work on these issues should preference to “clarify” relevant SPS provisions
include the identification of any need to clarify (especially the preamble, and Articles 3.3 and equally be abused
relevant WTO rules. The Committee shall 5.7 of the agreement). Other WTO members to impose costly
report to the Fifth Session of the Ministerial consider this position to be an open invitation and inappropriate
Conference, and make recommendations, where to restrict imports on all sorts of spurious
appropriate, with respect to future action, grounds. It is nevertheless a politically sensitive standards on devel-
including the desirability of negotiations.” and high-order issue for the EU, so it would oping-country
Developing countries should again be not be surprising if the EU tried to introduce it
watchful that the EU does not use the upgrad- by stealth into the new round.
exports.
ed work of the Committee on Trade and At first glance, the wording on trade and
Environment, and possible future negotiations, environment in the work program of the minis-
to insert into the round what it was not able to terial declaration is sufficiently tight to prevent
insert explicitly into the ministerial declaration. EU skullduggery. It refers to the “effect of envi-
There are two danger zones. ronmental measures on market access” (my
The first concerns national environmental emphasis), not the other way around. And it
regulations that differentiate between products adds that the outcome of work and negotiations
on the basis of how they are produced or “shall not add to or diminish the rights and
processed. The conventional interpretation of obligations of Members under existing WTO
GATT Article III stipulates national treatment agreements, in particular the Agreement on the
for “like products”; it does not allow govern- Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary
ments to discriminate between goods according Measures, nor alter the balance of these rights
to production and processing methods (PPMs). and obligations, and will take into account the

25
needs of developing and least developed coun- remains the towering obstacle to meaningful
tries.”61 Nevertheless, the preambular references CAP reform. In the United States, President
to the environment, and the nontrade concerns Bush has to contain protectionist elements, par-
taken into account in the agricultural negotia- ticularly in the textiles and clothing lobbies, but
tions,62 provide the EU with worrying wiggle also in agriculture and steel. Both sides must
room. Hence the need for other WTO mem- exercise restraint in taking cases to WTO dis-
bers to be alert and cautious in this part of the pute settlement and relying excessively on
new round. adversarial litigation.
The twist to the tale is the more vigorous
Miscellaneous Issues. The work program on exertion of U.S. leadership in trade policy dur-
electronic commerce, which has achieved very ing the course of 2002, in contrast to the EU’s
little, will continue, as will the current practice continued defensiveness on agricultural
of not imposing customs duties on electronic reform. This cannot be divorced from the
transmissions. This will be reviewed at the broader strategic picture of an increasingly
Mexico ministerial meeting.63 The preamble confident and assertive U.S. superpower on the
contains references to “work with the Bretton international stage, compared with an internal-
Woods institutions for greater coherence in ly sclerotic and externally pusillanimous EU.
global economic policy-making”; “concluding Since the Tokyo Round, the United States and
accession proceedings as quickly as possible . . . the EU have shared leadership in the
[and] accelerating the accession of least devel- GATT/WTO. To be sure, it will still take two
oped countries”; and “making the WTO’s to tango, but is the United States about to lead
operations more transparent, including the dance for the first time since the 1960s? It
through more effective and prompt dissemina- is too early to tell.
tion of information, and to improve dialogue Second, following Uruguay Round prece-
with the public.”64 dent, success in the new round will require the
effective participation of a core of about 25
developed and developing countries who are
The Politics of the New Round already active in the WTO. Canada, Japan,
Australia, and New Zealand from the OECD
To date there is little to report regarding the pol- come to mind. In the developing-country
itics of the new round considering that it has made camp, Brazil, India, and now China stand out,
next to no progress. Politics will have to change if but this group also includes other Latin
the new round is to pick up speed. Three old and American countries (notably Mexico and
The necessary but three new features deserve to be highlighted. Chile) and many East Asian countries (notably
Thailand, Malaysia, Singapore, Hong Kong,
not sufficient con- Old Features and Korea).
dition for success is First, as in the Uruguay Round, the necessary Third, multicountry coalitions will be
for the major play- but not sufficient condition for success is for the important to give the round a kick in the right
major players, the United States and the EU, to direction. Broad-based, informal, developed-
ers, the United contain domestic political difficulties, defuse developing country coalitions will be useful to
States and the EU, bilateral conflicts, and cooperate intensively. In share information and act as sounding boards
the case of the EU, putting the domestic house for ideas (the “chat group” phenomenon), and
to contain domestic in order means doing something serious about even to resolve crises or give fresh impetus at
political difficulties, the Common Agricultural Policy and contain- strategic junctures, as was the case with the
defuse bilateral con- ing France, the eternal spoiler of international Swiss-Colombian coalition and the De La
economic policy. France’s perverse but entirely Paix Group during the Uruguay Round.65 The
flicts, and cooperate predictable bloody-mindedness on the issue of drawback of these groups (such as Friends of
intensively. agricultural export subsidies nearly caused the the New Round, Friends of GATS, G77, the
Doha ministerial conference to collapse. It African Group, and the LDC Group recently)

26
is that they are too big and heterogeneous to weak to sustain effective participation on their China is now the
forge common positions. own in the new round, so they will have to cre- most important
Perhaps more important will be small, dis- ate like-minded coalitions for this purpose.
crete, issue-based developed-developing coun- However, there are distinct limits to the developing country
try coalitions. The Cairns Group and the active participation of the second- and third- in the WTO and is
International Bureau on Textiles and Clothing division developing countries with limited or
are the pathfinders in this respect, although very limited trade policy capacity, even in coali-
bound to play a
one cannot expect such formal and relatively tion formation. During the long haul of com- major role in the
tight-knit coalitions in other negotiating areas. plex and multiple negotiations, they are likely new round. If it
More probable are looser, informal coalitions in to remain passive followers, not initiators and
areas like services, industrial goods, rules, proactive players. This applies particularly to flouts WTO rules,
implementation, and others, with membership the less-developed countries but, albeit to a others will follow,
fluid and varying across negotiating areas. lesser extent, also to large low-income coun- with potentially
Embryonic “friends” groups already exist in tries such as Pakistan, Bangladesh, Egypt, and
services (Really Good Friends of GATS), Nigeria. All may have more “negative” bargain- devastating conse-
antidumping, subsidies (Friends of Fish), trade ing power than before, that is, the ability and quences for the
facilitation (Colorado Group), dispute settlement willingness to block agreement, but they will
and implementation (G15 and the Like-Minded not have significant “positive” bargaining
WTO system.
Group). These need to be more coherent and power for the foreseeable future.
proactive if the round is to advance. Not least, The third factor is the entry of China and
they are an important counter to the UN-ization Taiwan (“Chinese Taipei”) into the WTO and
of the WTO that threatens to stop all effective their participation in the forthcoming negotia-
decisionmaking in its tracks. tions. Russia too may join while the round is
ongoing, although Russian unwillingness to
New Features initiate WTO-compatible reforms may drag
The first novel element in the potential pol- out the accession process for some time.
itics of the new round is that the active, first- Taiwan, with a track record of relative openness
division developing countries will be negotiat- to the world economy, and having liberalized
ing with each other and other developing further in order to join the WTO, is in a good
countries, especially on the tariff and nontariff position to play an active and constructive role
barriers that throttle South-South trade in in the new round.
industrial goods. During the Uruguay Round, What about China? That is the $64,000
the active developing countries tended to go question, as China is now the most important
head to head with developed countries but not developing country in the WTO and is bound
with each other. The present situation is but a to play a major role in the new round. China
reflection of the increasing differentiation faces the monumental task of implementing
within the developing world and the porous- WTO rules domestically; it is still far from
ness of the North-South divide. having a rule of law compatible with a market
The second novel element will be the more economy. If it flouts WTO rules, others will
active participation of many more developing follow, with potentially devastating conse-
countries, including some traditionally weaker quences for the WTO system.
developing countries and even some less-devel- This may be too melodramatic a scenario,
oped countries, than was the case in previous for there are positive signs, too. After a 15-year
rounds. This was certainly in evidence during WTO accession negotiation, China has capa-
the consultations in the WTO before Doha, and ble, savvy trade negotiators who will want to
in Doha itself. Of particular note was the proac- extract maximum benefit from the WTO and
tive participation of the African Group—for the use it to further bolster domestic reform—not
first time at a GATT/WTO ministerial meet- to destroy the WTO system. One year into its
ing. The countries concerned are too small and WTO membership, the Chinese government

27
is roughly on track with the staged implemen- coalitions where much of the deal making is
tation of its WTO obligations. There are also done. Finally, they have reasonably well
welcome indications that China will adopt a resourced trade policy operations back in
Brazilian rather than an Indian strategy in the national capitals.
WTO. If it acts like Brazil, it will shape differ- The last aspect—adequate trade policy
entiated interests and adopt a mixture of offen- resources at home—is now crucial to effective
sive and defensive positions in the WTO, WTO participation. In the past, including the
forming overlapping coalitions with other Uruguay Round, national participation in
WTO members along the way. If it acts like GATT negotiations involved the Geneva mis-
India, it will be negative and block on several sion and the lead ministry on trade policy at
fronts, as India tried to do (unsuccessfully) in home. Now, as trade policy and trade agree-
the Uruguay Round and in Doha. Let the ments become more complex, especially in their
United States hope China turns out to be the domestic regulatory detail, trade negotiations are
Asian equivalent of Brazil. more domestic, or national capital-centered,
than before and involve ministries and regulato-
ry agencies across government as well as private-
It is the first divi- Building Trade Policy Capacity sector consultation.

sion of developing in Developing Countries Distrust and Frustration among the Poorest
countries that has Members
Developing countries account for a four- Below the first-division bracket is a motley
on the whole bene- fifths (and increasing) majority in the WTO. 66 crew of second-division poorer countries, some
fited from the As mentioned above, there are encouraging quite large (such as Egypt, Pakistan, Morocco,
signs of more developing countries who are Nigeria, and Bangladesh) with vocal ambassadors.
WTO system; the willing and able to make their participation However, their influence in the WTO is hampered
vast majority of the count. Nevertheless, it is one thing for a devel- by a serious lack of administrative capacity at
rest have been oping country to organize itself for a minister- home. Finally, there is a very large residual group—
ial conference; it is quite another to sustain the third division as it were—amounting to half or
unable to partici- effective participation over the long, difficult more of the WTO membership (80–plus coun-
pate effectively. haul of multi-issue, simultaneous negotiations tries) with huge trade policy deficits. Many less-
in a new round. To do that, the focus must developed countries and small island-states do not
shift, in the first instance, from Geneva to the even have a Geneva mission. Most of the others
domestic setting of national trade policymak- have perhaps one or two representatives in Geneva
ing, against the extended background of to cover all international organizations in town.
national economic policy. Here there are wide It is the first division of developing coun-
and glaring divergences between developing tries that has on the whole benefited from the
countries (and countries in transition, too). WTO system; the vast majority of the rest
This feeds through to divergences in WTO have been unable to participate effectively.
participation. Thus it can be said that credible and sus-
The score or so of really active, first-division tainable trade policy outcomes, including
developing countries are in the middle-income effective participation in a WTO round,
bracket (China and India being the significant require an efficient delivery mechanism, that is,
exceptions), with rising shares of international good trade policy decisionmaking, at home.
trade and investment. Most have also under- The main objectives of trade policy manage-
taken radical and sustained unilateral liberal- ment are threefold: (1) clear, precise definition
ization. They have well-staffed missions in of national interests in policy formulation, with a
Geneva with high-profile ambassadors, many strong sense of how trade policy fits into the
of whom chair important WTO committees. overall national economic strategy; (2) effective
They are active in the formal and informal negotiating capacity at bilateral, regional, and

28
multilateral levels, with a good appreciation of meetings in the WTO; and officials in nation-
the dynamic interaction between these levels; al capitals simply do not have the time and
and (3) effective domestic implementation of resources to analyze issues and formulate nego-
unilateral measures and international agree- tiating positions. The size and complexity of
ments. Achieving these objectives requires, the new round make a bad situation worse.
inter alia, an effective lead ministry on trade This time, the weaker developing countries do
policy, good interagency coordination, substan- not wish to fall into the Uruguay Round trap of
tial nongovernmental input, and a strong being rushed into agreements they cannot
WTO mission. fathom and find very hard to implement. This
Most developing countries, in the second and accounts in some measure for their present
third divisions previously mentioned, fare badly on defensive attitude.
all these counts. Quite apart from political and eco- Given these seemingly intractable problems
nomic instability, corruption, low civil service pay, with trade policy capacity, it is not surprising
lack of qualified personnel, policy reliance on the that most developing countries’ positions in
whims of a few powerful (and mostly incompetent WTO negotiations tend to be conservative,
and venal) personalities, and a host of other insti- passive, and reactive, only making concessions
tutional, economy-wide gaping holes, there are if under extreme pressure from more powerful
specific trade policy weaknesses. They include lack players. Their domestic disarray and conse-
of competent staff to analyze and monitor the costs quent lack of negotiating preparedness also
and benefits of existing and proposed trade poli- make them easier targets for the major powers
cies, at home and abroad; lack of legal expertise; to pick off and bully, as happened in the latter
lack of able and experienced officials to participate stages of the Uruguay Round.
seriously in multiple international trade negotia-
tions; policy blockage from regulatory agencies that Good Trade Policy Begins at Home
are poorly integrated into the trade policy process Nonetheless, there are examples of good
and with protectionist interests to defend; and lit- trade policy management across the developing
tle input from business organizations. world. Trade policy capacity can be improved
All these problems in trade (and wider eco- gradually, but only in bottom-up fashion with
nomic) policy operations prevent most devel- domestic political will and in the context of
oping countries from making a systematic credible domestic policies and institutions. To
assessment of national trade policy priorities, to reiterate, the key is to have clear and sensible The weaker devel-
be implemented unilaterally and pursued trade policies, within a coherent overall national oping countries do
through regional and multilateral negotiations. economic policy framework, developed “from
Even capable heads of mission and negotiators below.” This is the precondition for successful not wish to fall into
in Geneva (not invariably the case with devel- participation in the WTO as well as in regional the Uruguay
oping-country delegations to the WTO) are trade negotiating forums. Well-targeted external Round trap of
not of much use without strong backup from technical assistance and capacity building can
national capitals. The increasing complexity of then help at the margin. On the other hand, it is being rushed into
the WTO in the wake of the Uruguay Round misleading and counterproductive to think of agreements they
imposes many more demands on trade policy trade policy capacity building in top-down
capacity at home, but the latter has not terms, as a global Cartesian construct in which cannot fathom and
improved in most developing countries, and in international organizations and donors are the find very hard to
some cases has even worsened. central actors. This misses the point: good trade implement. This
Hence the feeling of distrust and frustra- policy, like charity, begins at home, not in the
tion, the sense of being overwhelmed and International Monetary Fund and the World accounts in some
unable to cope, among developing-country Bank, nor indeed in the WTO. measure for their
officials. Small national missions in Geneva do Building trade policy capacity from the ground
not have the staff to attend, let alone keep pace up, with a central focus on putting the domestic
present defensive
with, the huge number of formal and informal house in order, is inevitably going to be a long, attitude.

29
Good trade policy, drawn out affair. It can by degrees translate into on economic and moral grounds, and progress in
like charity, begins effective WTO participation for an increasing that direction, however gradual and piecemeal,
number of developing countries. As far as the new should be integral to modern globalization. This is
at home, not in the round is concerned, a smallish and manageable first and foremost a task for national governments,
International negotiating agenda would have suited developing but the WTO, with the right sort of rules to but-
Monetary Fund countries with scarce administrative and policy tress the protection of private property rights and
resources much better. Unfortunately, the large and the enforcement of contracts in cross-border trans-
and the World messy agenda at hand, while not an insuperable actions, can be a helpful external prop. This, then,
Bank, nor indeed in problem for first-division developing countries, would be the WTO’s circumscribed but vital con-
presents a daunting challenge to most of the rest, tribution to the liberty of individuals and the pros-
the WTO. If the and an impossible burden for many. If the EU and perity of nations.
EU and other other developed countries really had developing- On the other hand, politics is a messy, prac-
developed countries country interests at heart, they would have kept the tical affair. Sensible political economy has to
agenda small and focused. factor that into the equation. Following
really had develop- Oakeshott, the seas of real-world international
ing-country inter- trade policy are indeed boundless, bottomless,
ests at heart, they Conclusion and turbulent; and the enterprise, for national
governments and the WTO, must be to keep
would have kept the Beginning with David Hume and afloat on an even keel, “using resources of a tra-
agenda small and Adam Smith, the emphasis on free ditional manner of behaviour to make a friend
trade has been not just one of the pos- of every hostile occasion.” A compass is need-
focused. tulates, but the very heart or essence, ed to chart the right course ahead, something
of economic liberalism. the WTO clearly lacks today; but the seaman-
—Jan Tumlir ship should match ambitions to prevailing
weather conditions and the tools at hand.
In political activity, then, men sail a It is this liberal-conservative compass, mix-
boundless and bottomless sea; there is ing the ideal of progressively freer trade with
neither harbour for shelter nor floor pragmatic politics, that is sorely needed for the
for anchorage, neither starting place Doha Round in order to take the WTO, and
nor appointed destination. The enter- with it the wider trading system, into the right
prise is to keep afloat on an even keel; middle-distance future. The task ahead is to set
the sea is both friend and enemy; and the objective, flesh out the policy detail, and
the seamanship consists in using build the requisite political constituency. The
resources of a traditional manner of latter in particular will be a steep uphill struggle.
behaviour to make a friend of every
hostile occasion.
—Michael Oakeshott Notes
1. On trade policy and wider economic policy
It is perhaps instructive to juxtapose the trends, see David Henderson, The Changing Fortunes
classical-liberal free-trade ideals of Jan Tumlir of Economic Liberalism: Yesterday, Today and Tomorrow
with the pragmatic conservatism expressed in (London: Institute of Economic Affairs, 1998); and
Constantine Michalopolous, Developing Countries
one of Michael Oakeshott’s most quoted pas- and the WTO (London: Palgrave, 2001), pp. 45–88.
sages. The balance between the two captures, I
hope, the tone of this extended policy essay on 2. There is the theoretical possibility of (usually
large) countries being able to exercise long-run mar-
the state of play and future of the world trad- ket power in international demand for certain
ing system, and in particular the role of the goods, thereby placing them in a position to shift
WTO within it. the terms of trade in their favor by means of an opti-
On the one hand, there is the enduring classi- mal tariff. The counterargument is that these coun-
cal-liberal message that free trade is a desirable goal tries should lower tariffs only if others reciprocate, in
order to avoid worsening terms of trade. However, in

30
reality very few countries have such market power 10. Jagdish Bhagwati, Free Trade Today (Princeton,
under long-run conditions. In addition, retaliatory N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002), pp. 51–52, 67.
tariffs by other countries would tend to nullify
terms-of-trade gains. Thus, a beautiful idea on the 11. On the dangers of regulatory overload and stan-
Olympian heights of theory (not for the first time!) dards harmonization, see Bernard Hoekman,
turns out to have limited practical relevance. This “Strengthening the Global Trade Architecture for
returns policy, as a practical proposition, to a presump- Development: The Post-Doha Agenda,” World Trade
tion in favor of unilateral free trade. On the terms of Review 1, no. 1 (2002): 32, 40; Thomas Hertel,
trade/reciprocity debate, see Lionel Robbins, Robert Bernard Hoekman, and Will Martin, “Developing
Torrens and the Evolution of Classical Economics Countries and a New Round of WTO
(London: Macmillan, 1958), pp. 182–231; and Negotiations,” The World Bank Research Observer 17,
Douglas A. Irwin, Against the Tide: An Intellectual no. 1 (Spring 2002): 136; and J. Michael Finger,
History of Free Trade (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton “Implementing the Uruguay Round Agreements,”
University Press, 1996), pp. 106–15. The World Economy 24, no. 9 (September 2001): 1098.

3. On the role of crisis in policy reform, see Stephen 12. J. Michael Finger and Julio Nogues, “The
Haggard and John Williamson, “The Political Unbalanced Uruguay Round Outcome: the New
Preconditions for Economic Reform,” in The Political Areas in Future WTO Negotiations,” The World
Economy of Policy Reform, ed. John Williamson Economy 25, no. 3 (March 2002): 321–40.
(Washington: Institute for International Economics,
1995), pp. 527–96. 13. John H. Jackson, “Dispute Settlement and the
WTO: Emerging Problems,” Journal of International
4. Paul Krugman, “What Should Trade Economic Law 1, no. 3 (1998): 344; Marco C. E. J.
Negotiators Negotiate about?” Journal of Economic Bronckers, “Better Rules for a New Millennium: A
Literature 35, no. 1 (March 1997): 13–20; and Warning against Undemocratic Developments in
Bernard Hoekman and Michel Kostecki, The the WTO,” Journal of International Economic Law 2,
Political Economy of the World Trading System: From no. 4 (1999): 551, 554, 562–64; and Arthur Dunkel,
GATT to WTO (Oxford: Oxford University Press, Peter Sutherland, and Renato Ruggiero, “Joint
1995), pp. 20–33. Statement on the Multilateral Trading System,”
WTO News, February 1, 2001, p. 2, www.wto.
5. World Trade Organization, Overview of org/english/news_e/news01_e/jointstatdavos
Developments in the International Trading _jan01_e.htm.
Environment: Annual Report by the Director-General
(Geneva: WTO, 2001), p. 86. 14. Gilbert Winham, “The World Trade
Organization: Institution-Building in the Multilateral
6. World Trade Organization, Regionalism and the Trading System,” The World Economy 21, no. 3 (May
World Trade System (Geneva: WTO, 1995). 1998): 349–68; Debra P. Steger and Susan M.
Hainsworth, “World Trade Organization Dispute
7. On the Uruguay Round agreements and the Settlement: The First Three Years,” Journal of
implications of the transition from GATT to International Economic Law 1, no. 2 (1998): 209; and
WTO, see World Trade Organization, The Legal Bronckers, pp. 554, 556.
Texts: The Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral
Trade Negotiations (Cambridge: WTO/Cambridge 15. Syliva Ostry, "WTO: Institutional Design for
University Press, 1999); Hoekman and Kostecki; Better Governance," in Efficiency, Equity and
John Croome, Reshaping the World Trading System: A Legitimacy: The Multilateral Trading System at the
History of the Uruguay Round (Geneva: Millennium, ed. Roger B. Porter et al. (Washington:
WTO/Kluwer, 1999); and John Jackson, The World Brookings Institution Press, 2001), p. 9.
Trade Organization: Constitution and Jurisprudence
(London: Pinter/Royal Institute of International 16. See “Ministerial Declaration,” WT/MIN(01)/
Affairs, 1998). DEC/W/1, November 14, 2001; “Declaration on the
TRIPS Agreement and Public Health,” WT/MIN(01)
8. On TRIPS, see Hoekman and Kostecki, chap. 6. /DEC/W/2, November 14, 2001; and “Implemen-
tation-Related Issues and Concerns,” WT/MIN(01)/
9. Simple, transparent, negative, and nondiscrim- W/10, November 14, 2001, all available at
inatory rules of conduct have a long classical-lib- www.wto.org.
eral pedigree. They are David Hume’s “general
and inflexible rules of justice.” In Hayekian termi- 17. Robert Zoellick, “Unleashing the Trade
nology, they are nomos, not thesis. See David Winds,” The Economist, December 7, 2002.
Hume, A Treatise of Human Nature, Book III, Part II
(1740; Oxford: Clarendon, 1978), pp. 520, 526, 18. “Ministerial Declaration,” paras. 20, 23, 26, 27.
567–69; and F. A. Hayek, The Constitution of Liberty
(London: Routledge, 1960), pp. 19, 162ff., 529. 19. Ibid., para. 32.

31
20. I owe this form of words, “traditionalist” and Extensions under Article 27.4 for Certain
“reformist,” to my former student Joakim Reiter, Developing Country Members,” Communication
now dealing with trade policy at the Swedish from the chairman of the General Council,
Ministry of Foreign Affairs. Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing
Measures, G/SCM/W/471/Rev.1, November 13,
21. It is the classical-liberal tradition, from Hume 2001.
and Smith to Hayek, which highlights the merits
of national (unilateral) freedom of action and 38. “Ministerial Declaration,” para. 12.
intergovernmental institutional competition, all
in search of better practice in a complex world of 39. Ibid.
uncertainty and flux. See Razeen Sally, Classical
Liberalism and International Economic Order: Studies 40. Ibid., para. 44. Also see para. 50.
in Theory and Intellectual History (London:
41. “Implementation-Related Issues and Concerns,”
Routledge, 1998), pp. 198–203.
para. 12.1(I).
22. Kym Anderson, "The future agenda of the 42. Finger, pp. 1104–5, 1107; and Hoekman, pp.
WTO", in From GATT to the WTO: The Multilateral 34–35.
Trading System in the New Millennium (Geneva: WTO
Secretariat, 2000), p. 22. 43. “Ministerial Declaration,” paras. 38–41.
23. See Michalopolous, pp. 45–128. 44. Ibid., paras. 40, 41.
24. Jagdish Bhagwati, “Trading for Development,” 45. WTO News, March 7, 2002, www.wto.org/english
The Economist, June 22, 2002, p. 28. /news_e/pres02_/pr277_e.htm, and March 11, 2002,
www.wto.org/english/news_e/pres02_/pr279_e.htm.
25. Globalization, Growth and Poverty: An Inclusive
Agenda for the World Economy (Washington and 46. “Ministerial Declaration,” paras. 3, 43.
Oxford: World Bank/Oxford University Press, 2002).
47. Ibid., para. 42.
26. “Ministerial Declaration,” para. 13.
48. “Declaration on the TRIPS Agreement and
27. Ibid. Public Health,” paras. 4, 5.
28. Ibid., para 14. 49. Ibid., paras. 6, 7.
29. Ibid., para. 15. 50. “Ministerial Declaration,” paras. 18, 19.
30. Ibid., para. 16. 51. Ibid., paras. 35–37.
31. Ibid., para. 28. 52. Ibid., paras. 20, 23, 26, 27.
32. On U.S. antidumping legislation and proposals 53. Ibid., para. 47.
for antidumping negotiations in the WTO, see
Brink Lindsey and Dan Ikenson, “Antidumping 54. Ibid., para. 22.
101: The Devilish Details of ‘Unfair Trade’ Law,”
Cato Trade Policy Analysis no. 20, November 26, 55. Ibid., para. 25.
2002; Brink Lindsey and Dan Ikenson, “Reforming
the Antidumping Agreement: A Road Map for 56. Ibid., para. 26.
WTO Negotiations,” Cato Trade Policy Analysis
no. 21, December 11, 2002. 57. Ibid., para. 27.

33. “Ministerial Declaration,” paras. 28–30. 58. Ibid., para. 6.

34. Peter Tulloch, “Regionalism and the WTO,” 59. Ibid., para. 31.
The World Trade Brief, Fourth WTO Ministerial 60. Ibid., para. 32.
Conference, November 9–13, 2001 (London:
Agenda Publishing), pp. 43–44. 61. Ibid.
35. “Ministerial Declaration,” paras. 2, 3. 62. Ibid., paras. 6, 13.
36. Finger. 63. Ibid., para. 34.
37. “Implementation-Related Issues and 64. Ibid., paras. 5, 9, 10.
Concerns.” Also see “Proposed Procedures for

32
65. On formal and informal coalitions in the Countries in GATT/WTO Negotiations,” Working
Uruguay Round, see Croome. paper no. 20, Overseas Development Institute,
February 2002; Finger and Nogues, pp. 333, 338;
66. This section draws on Razeen Sally, “Effective Hoekman, pp. 30, 32; and Richard Blackhurst, Bill
Participation in the WTO: Building Trade Policy Lyakurwa, and A. Oyejide, “Options for Improving
Capacity in Developing Countries,” The World Trade Africa’s Participation in the WTO,” The World
Brief, pp. 48–50. Also see Sheila Page, “Developing Economy 23 no. 4 (April 2000): 491–510.

33
Trade Briefing Papers from the Cato Institute
“Rethinking the Export-Import Bank” by Aaron Lukas and Ian Vásquez (no. 15, March 12, 2002)

“Steel Trap: How Subsidies and Protectionism Weaken the U.S. Steel Industry” by Dan Ikenson, (no. 14, March 1, 2002)

“America’s Bittersweet Sugar Policy” by Mark A. Groombridge (no. 13, December 4, 2001)

“Missing the Target: The Failure of the Helms-Burton Act” by Mark A. Groombridge (no. 12, June 5, 2001)

“The Case for Open Capital Markets” by Robert Krol (no. 11, March 15, 2001)

“WTO Report Card III: Globalization and Developing Countries” by Aaron Lukas (no. 10, June 20, 2000)

“WTO Report Card II: An Exercise or Surrender of U.S. Sovereignty?” by William H. Lash III and Daniel T. Griswold (no.
9, May 4, 2000)

“WTO Report Card: America’s Economic Stake in Open Trade” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 8, April 3, 2000)

“The H-1B Straitjacket: Why Congress Should Repeal the Cap on Foreign-Born Highly Skilled Workers” by Suzette Brooks
Masters and Ted Ruthizer (no. 7, March 3, 2000)

“Trade, Jobs, and Manufacturing: Why (Almost All) U.S. Workers Should Welcome Imports” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 6,
September 30, 1999)

“Trade and the Transformation of China: The Case for Normal Trade Relations” by Daniel T. Griswold, Ned Graham, Robert
Kapp, and Nicholas Lardy (no. 5, July 19, 1999)

“The Steel ‘Crisis’ and the Costs of Protectionism” by Brink Lindsey, Daniel T. Griswold, and Aaron Lukas (no. 4, April 16,
1999)

“State and Local Sanctions Fail Constitutional Test” by David R. Schmahmann and James S. Finch (no. 3, August 6, 1998)

“Free Trade and Human Rights: The Moral Case for Engagement” by Robert A. Sirico (no. 2, July 17, 1998)

“The Blessings of Free Trade” by James K. Glassman (no. 1, May 1, 1998)

From the Cato Institute Briefing Papers Series


“The Myth of Superiority of American Encryption Products” by Henry B. Wolfe (no. 42, November 12, 1998)

“The Fast Track to Freer Trade” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 34, October 30, 1997)

“Anti-Dumping Laws Trash Supercomputer Competition” by Christopher M. Dumler (no. 32, October 14, 1997)

34
Trade Policy Analysis Papers from the Cato Institute
“Free Trade, Free Markets: Rating the 107th Congress” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 22, January 30, 2003)

“Reforming the Antidumping Agreement: A Road Map for WTO Negotiations” by Brink Lindsey and Dan Ikenson (no. 21,
December 11, 2002)

“Antidumping 101: The Devilish Details of ‘Unfair Trade’ Law” by Brink Lindsey and Dan Ikenson (no. 20, November 21, 2002)

“Willing Workers: Fixing the Problem of Illegal Mexican Migration to the United States” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 19, October 15,
2002)

“The Looming Trade War over Plant Biotechnology” by Ronald Bailey (no. 18, August 1, 2002)

“Safety Valve or Flash Point? The Worsening Conflict between U.S. Trade Laws and WTO Rules” by Lewis E. Leibowitz (no. 17,
November 6, 2001)

“Safe Harbor or Stormy Waters? Living with the EU Data Protection Directive” by Aaron Lukas (no. 16, October 30, 2001)

“Trade, Labor, and the Environment: How Blue and Green Sanctions Threaten Higher Standards” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 15,
August 2, 2001)

“Coming Home to Roost: Proliferating Antidumping Laws and the Growing Threat to U.S. Exports” by Brink Lindsey and Dan
Ikenson (no. 14, July 30, 2001)

“Free Trade, Free Markets: Rating the 106th Congress” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 13, March 26, 2001)

“America’s Record Trade Deficit: A Symbol of Economic Strength” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 12, February 9, 2001)

“Nailing the Homeowner: The Economic Impact of Trade Protection of the Softwood Lumber Insudstry” by Brink Linsey,
Mark A. Groombridge, and Prakash Loungani (no. 11, July 6, 2000)

“China’s Long March to a Market Economy: The Case for Permanent Normal Trade Relations with the People’s Republic of
China” by Mark A. Groombridge (no. 10, April 24, 2000)

“Tax Bytes: A Primer on the Taxation of Electronic Commerce” by Aaron Lukas (no. 9, December 17, 1999)

“Seattle and Beyond: A WTO Agenda for the New Millennium” by Brink Lindsey, Daniel T. Griswold, Mark A.
Groombridge and Aaron Lukas (no. 8, November 4, 1999)

“The U.S. Antidumping Law: Rhetoric versus Reality” by Brink Lindsey (no. 7, August 16, 1999)

“Free Trade, Free Markets: Rating the 105th Congress” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 6, February 3, 1999)

“Opening U.S. Skies to Global Airline Competition” by Kenneth J. Button (no. 5, November 24, 1998)

“A New Track for U.S. Trade Policy” by Brink Lindsey (no. 4, September 11, 1998)

“Revisiting the ‘Revisionists’: The Rise and Fall of the Japanese Economic Model” by Brink Lindsey and Aaron Lukas (no. 3,
July 31, 1998)

35
Board of Advisers CENTER FOR TRADE POLICY STUDIES
James K. Glassman
American Enterprise
Institute T he mission of the Cato Institute’s Center for Trade Policy Studies is to increase public
understanding of the benefits of free trade and the costs of protectionism. The center
publishes briefing papers, policy analyses, and books and hosts frequent policy forums and
Douglas A. Irwin conferences on the full range of trade policy issues.
Dartmouth College Scholars at the Cato trade policy center recognize that open markets mean wider choices
and lower prices for businesses and consumers, as well as more vigorous competition that
Lawrence Kudlow encourages greater productivity and innovation. Those benefits are available to any country
Kudlow & Co. that adopts free-trade policies; they are not contingent upon “fair trade” or a “level playing
field” in other countries. Moreover, the case for free trade goes beyond economic efficiency.
José Piñera The freedom to trade is a basic human liberty, and its exercise across political borders unites
International Center for people in peaceful cooperation and mutual prosperity.
Pension Reform
The center is part of the Cato Institute, an independent policy research organization in
Razeen Sally
Washington, D.C. The Cato Institute pursues a broad-based research program rooted in the
London School of traditional American principles of individual liberty and limited government.
Economics
For more information on the Center for Trade Policy Studies,
George P. Shultz visit www.freetrade.org.
Hoover Institution

Walter B. Wriston Other Trade Studies from the Cato Institute


Former Chairman and
CEO, Citicorp/Citibank
“Free Trade, Free Markets: Rating the 107th Congress” by Daniel T. Griswold, Trade Policy
Clayton Yeutter Analysis no. 22 (January 30, 2003)
Former U.S. Trade
Representative “Reforming the Antidumping Agreement: A Road Map for WTO Negotiations” by Brink
Lindsey and Dan Ikenson, Trade Policy Analysis no. 21 (December 11, 2002)

“Antidumping 101: The Devilish Details of ‘Unfair Trade’ Law” by Brink Lindsey and Dan
Ikenson, Trade Policy Analysis no. 20 (November 21, 2002)

“Willing Workers: Fixing the Problem of Illegal Mexican Migration to the United States” by
Daniel T. Griswold, Trade Policy Analysis no. 19 (October 15, 2002)

“The Looming Trade War over Plant Biotechnology” by Ronald Bailey, Trade Policy Analysis
no. 18 (August 1, 2002)

“Rethinking the Export-Import Bank” by Aaron Lukas and Ian Vásquez, Trade Briefing
Paper no. 15 (March 12, 2002)

Nothing in Trade Policy Analysis should be construed as necessarily reflecting the views of the
Center for Trade Policy Studies or the Cato Institute or as an attempt to aid or hinder the pas-
sage of any bill before Congress. Contact the Cato Institute for reprint permission. Additional
copies of Trade Policy Analysis studies are $6 each ($3 for five or more). To order, contact the
Cato Institute, 1000 Massachusetts Avenue, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20001. (202) 842-
0200, fax (202) 842-3490, www.cato.org.

Você também pode gostar