Você está na página 1de 81

PUBLIC ECONOMICS AND PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION Public administration has always overlapped economics.

Efficiency was the holy grail of the progressive officials and academics who created the modern discipline of public administration. They sought to place public affairs "on a strict business basis," directed "not by partisans, either Republican or Democrat, but by men ... skilled in business management and economics." Consequently, they created a professional bureaucracy to manage "the increased importance of the public functions of the twentieth century city. Streets had to be paved for newly developed motor vehicles; harbors had to be deepened for big, new freighters. In addition, electric lighting systems, street railways, sewage disposal plants, water supplies, and fire departments had to be installed or drastically improved to meet the needs of inhabitants, human and commercial, of hundreds of rapidly growing industrial centers" [Weinstein, 1968: 93-95; see also Rubin, 1993]. Moreover, establishing a professional bureaucracy at the municipal level did lead directly to higher levels of investment in infrastructure and, thereby, to significant increases in economic growth [Rauch, 1994; see also Mauro, 1995]. Organizational efficiency once meant the Weberian bureaucratic paradigm, which was codified for the public sector in the Taft, Brownlow, and Hoover Commission reports [Barzelay, 1992; see, for example, Blau & Meyer, 1971]. In the years following publication of the first Hoover Commission report, public administration did not abandon the bureaucratic paradigm, but it drifted away from economics. Public administrationists discovered organizational psychology and behavior. Many in the field rejected the distinction between politics and administration, with its stress on neutral competence. Some were intimidated by the mathematics used by the rational choice disciplines. And a few rejected the traditional goals of economy and efficiency on ideological grounds Public administration's drift away from economics was not entirely one-sided. Fifty years ago, most English speaking economists accepted Pigouvian welfare economics and Keynesian macroeconomics. They generally believed that government should set goals and objectives for the economy as a whole. Many admired the system of detailed centralized planning and control used by Gosplan in the Soviet Union to implement its long-term policies and strategic plans, an adaption of the Kriegwirtschaftsplan, the planning and control system used to mobilize Germany's resources during World War I -- i.e., Weberian bureaucracy carried to its ultimate conclusion. Indeed, Gosplan's approach was not unlike the planning and control mechanisms used in the United States and the United Kingdom to fight World War II. Gradually, however, most economists came to appreciate the dysfunctions produced by state allocation of productive assets and central planning and control and to recognize the impossibility of a Pigouvian social welfare function. For many this

appreciation was reflected in a commitment to markets over almost any system of hierarchy or command. It is hardly surprising that this commitment was inimical to the idea and practice of bureaucracy -- or almost any other kind of organization or regulation, for that matter. Public Administration's drift away from economics was interrupted temporarily by the flurry of excitement generated during the 1960s and early 1970s by program budgeting and systems analysis, the former grounded primarily in applied economics and the latter in operations research and management science, both rational choice disciplines. This period witnessed the publication of the work of Charles Hitch and Roland McKean [Hitch & McKean, 1960; Hitch, 1965; McKean, 1968], Jesse Burkhead and Jerry Miner's landmark text, Public Expenditure [1971], which focused on the supply and demand for governmentally provided goods and services, and other significant works concerned primarily with questions of resource allocation in the public sector -- mostly defense [Novick, 1965; Enke, 1967; Niskanen, 1967; Quade & Boucher, 1968; Fisher, 1970], but other areas as well [Schultze, 1968; Haveman & Margolis, 1970; Hirsch, 1970; Margolis, 1970; Williamson, 1970; Merewitz & Sosnick, 1971; Rivlin, 1971 & 1972; Quade, 1975]. This body of literature represents a mother lode of scholarship that still has not been adequately incorporated into public administration. At the same time, the topics raised by Hitch and McKean and their contemporaries have since been largely abandoned by economists and now find only occasional mention in standard textbooks in public finance/economics. Arguably, the defining moment for the relationship between public administration and economics came at the Minnowbrook conference in 1970. The conference proceedings, which announced the New Public Administration [Marini, 1971], included a respectful comment on PPBS [Planning Programming Budgeting Systems - an arrangement combining program budgeting and systems analysis (Parker, 1971)], but the rational choice theorists in attendance were roughly treated by the assembly and some claim virtually expelled from it. Their comments and Steven Bram's invited paper were subsequently deleted from the conference proceedings [Marini, 1971: 5]. Ultimately, the gulf between public administration and economics created a niche that two distinct intellectual hybrids vied to fill. The first of these hybrids involved the creation in 1965 of what has since come to be known as the Public Choice Society. The participants at its first two meetings included James Buchanan, Gordon Tullock, John Rawls, William Riker, Vincent Ostrom, Toby Davis, James Coleman, and Charles Plott. Public choice involves the application of economic logic -methodological individualism and rational, self-interested decision making -- to questions and issues that had traditionally been the concern of political scientists and public administrationists; it has been one the great success stories of modern social and economic science.

The second of these hybrids involved the establishment of schools of public policy at some America most prestigious universities: Harvard, Chicago, UC Berkeley, Duke, Carnegie-Mellon, etc. These schools placed the rational choice disciplines of economics and operations research/management science at the center of their curricula. They continue to benefit from the halo effect produced by their location at elite universities, but most now acknowledge that their defining mission -- training policy analysts -- was fundamentally misconceived. On balance, they have not been intellectual successes and their faculty members have generally sought intellectual refuge in their home disciplines. Given this history of continental drift, it is surprising, indeed, to find Zhiyong Lan and David Rosenbloom asserting in a recent editorial published in Public Administration Review[1992] that the discipline of public administration is undergoing a paradigm shift and that a rational-choice, economics-based paradigm has emerged preeminent. PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION IS NOT ECONOMICS Of course, Lan and Rosenbloom are wrong. The discipline of public administration may be undergoing a paradigm shift, but a rational-choice, economics-based paradigm has not emerged preeminent, at least not so far. There are at least three reasons why public administration cannot be economics [Zorn, 1989]. Public Administration is Prescriptive First, there is the basic difference between engineering and science [Behn, 1996]. Public administration is concerned with prescription -- the identification of normative rules for decision makers that would lead them to make decisions that are optimal from the standpoint of the citizenry as a whole. Economics is concerned with prediction -- the identification of rules decision makers are likely to follow, given their incentives. Bluntly put, public administrators solve problems; economists explain choices. Economic theory is useful to public administrators when it provides them with concepts they can use to diagnose problems accurately and to prescribe effective solutions to those problems -- i.e., concepts like opportunity costs, incentives, or capitalization that can be profitably applied to an array of problems frequently encountered by public administrators. But real-world problem solving also frequently raises questions of value and of right and wrong. Economic logic recognizes no good but efficiency, no evil aside from inefficiency [Box, 1992; Hood, 1995]. Morality ought to play an important role in the conduct of the public's business; economists often have trouble accounting for this simple fact.

Public Administration Is Realistic, Empirically Grounded, and Practical Second, economics is an a priori, theoretical discipline; public administration is concerned with "pragmatic reform." Economists build elegant, logically consistent deductive models; public administrators deal with messy, real-world problems. Indeed, it can be argued that economists prefer rational choice theories to models that incorporate bounded rationality primarily because they are conclusive, not because they are right. Decision makers can be approximately rational in a nearly infinite number of ways; they can be rational in only one. This difference between economists and public administrators is illustrated by the way they deal with the problem of voluntary provision of collective goods. Economists define a collective [or public] good in terms of two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. This means that once a collective good is supplied by some of the members of a group, it may be enjoyed by all. From this premise they deduce that the decision of some of the members of a group to provide the good or some quantity of it for themselves presents each of the other members with an opportunity for strategic behavior. Since the other members of the group can profitably engage in strategic behavior, economists conclude that they will. If the other members of the group can share in the good regardless of their contributions, economists predict that they will withhold or reduce their own contributions to its provision. Hence, the decision by some of the members of a group to supply a quantity of a collective good leads other members to "free-ride" on their contributions -- which is to say that, if contributions are voluntary, collective goods will be under provided or, in the extreme, not be provided at all [see Breton, 1989]. Crime control aptly illustrates this situation. Citizens can affect the level of crime in their community in two ways: by limiting their exposure to risk and protecting their property, and by helping the police fight crime. If their possessions or personal security matter enough to them, individuals may see a direct material benefit from investing in locks, guns, guard dogs, or security systems. They may even see the benefit from participating in volunteer citizen block-watches or banding together to patrol their own streets or financing a private security force to do so. The authorities can encourage these kinds of activities by providing guidance and technical assistance, by passing out police whistles, by urging people to mark their property so that it can be more easily identified when stolen, by helping to organize block watches, by setting up emergency call systems tied to rapid response, and by positioning themselves to provide back-up to private efforts. However, self-defense alone will not control crime. Criminals must be identified, apprehended, and convicted. The police necessarily depend upon the citizenry to alert them to crime and to aid them in the conviction of criminals. Unfortunately, only

where their safety or that of their loved ones is at risk or where their property is threatened will private citizens realize a direct benefit from intervening to stop in crimes in progress. And even where they have been personally victimized, citizens rarely individually benefit from helping the police identify, apprehend, and convict their assailants, since the harm has already been done and the criminal justice system seldom provides restitution. In these instances, the behavior expected of citizens, though of great value to their community, is not personally rewarding in an obvious way. Hence, individuals often shirk these onerous civic responsibilities, trying to freeride on the efforts of their neighbors. Many economists insist that, in the presence of collective goods, citizens must be coerced to perform their civic responsibilities [Breton, 1989]; otherwise jointly provided services will necessarily be undersupplied. This mind set reflects, in part, the propensity of economists to confuse a perfectly useful analytic construct, economic man, with living, breathing humans. Economic man is a rational fool. Given the opportunity to ride free, he will. Since economic man will not voluntarily cooperate with his neighbors to provide public or collective goods, he must be forced to do so. This mind set also reflects a propensity to overlook the vitality of human ingenuity in designing social arrangements and to ignore the availability of motivational alternatives to coercion. In contrast, public administrators recognize that citizens often free-ride on the efforts of their neighbors, but they interpret this as problem to be solved rather than a necessary fact of life. Beekeeping provides the classic example of the failure to distinguish between economic theory and reality. Once upon a time, economists taught that beekeeping is a collective good and that, since fruit growers can rely on their neighbors' bees to pollinate their blossoms, most growers will. Hence, beekeeping must be undersupplied. S.N.S. Cheung, then an assistant professor of economics at the University of Washington, did something that was rather extraordinary: he left his armchair to find out whether beekeeping is actually undersupplied [Cheung, 1983]. As the result of a careful study of beekeeping and apple-growing practices in Washington State, Cheung found a long history of contractual relationships between apple growers and beekeepers. These contracts provided for beekeepers to be compensated for their contribution to the growers' apple crops. He also found that apple growers implicitly covenanted with their neighbors to keep the same ratio of bees to trees. Apple growers who did not abide by the covenant were ostracized and treated to inconveniences by those who did. Consequently, Cheung concluded that free riding may not be a serious problem among real apple growers and beekeepers [see also Ostrom. 1990; Ostrom, et al., 1994, Breton, 1989].

The primary point that Cheung was trying to make is that real people are not rational fools. They often do contribute voluntarily to the provision of collective goods [Ostrom. 1990]. Furthermore, social conventions or group norms can discourage freeriding and reduce shirking. These conventions can take the form of ethical precepts, regularities imposed by institutions, or simply fixed rules of thumb for individual behavior. Moreover, group norms can be collectively enforced through the ostracism of those who fail to contribute and praise for those who do. A second lesson to be drawn from the fable of the bees is that neither community norms nor the collective enforcement of those norms just happened. Knowledge of what to do and how to do it was provided by field agents of the United States Department of Agriculture's [USDA] Extension Service. This information gave apple growers a solid technical basis for group norms governing the behavior of individual growers. The field agents determined how many hives were needed and fairly apportioned responsibility for their provision. They also played a role in monitoring compliance with group norms and in passing that information along to growers. In so doing, the field agents could identify shirkers and the subsequent shortfall in the provision of bees that had to be made good by the rest of the community. Moreover, the USDA provided growers with a powerful collective sanction against free riders in the form of marketing orders and quota. Free riders were not merely subject to social ostracism; the other growers could have actually denied them access to the most lucrative markets. The point is that voluntary contributions to the provision of public goods don't just spontaneously occur; opportunities for collectively beneficial action must be identified, individual contributions established, performance monitored, and defectors sanctioned [see Heckathorn and Maser, 1989; Maser, 1986]. This is, of course, the last and most important lesson of the fable of the bees: voluntary provision can be organized and must be managed. Because management implies a manager, it follows that someone, usually a public official, must be charged with mobilizing the community on the behalf of the public good, organizing provision of the good, creating incentives, and supervising enforcement of community norms [Powers & Thompson, 1994]. Public Administrators are Preoccupied with Technical Efficiency There is a third reason why public administration is not economics. As a normative discipline, public administration is preoccupied with identifying decision rules that citizens would unanimously support. In practice this means that, just as economists don't like to make value judgments, public administrators are usually more comfortable condemning technical than allocative efficiency. Technical inefficiency means that managers fail to minimize cost or maximize output because they aren't

using the best available technology. Technology means not only plant and equipment, but also the methods used to coordinate activities and to motivate performance. Best available, means in practice, not merely in theory. A comparison of how Ford Motor Co. accounts for its purchases with how the Navy handles accounts payable illustrates technical inefficiency. Not so long ago, Ford cut the required number of manual accounting transactions to pay for goods from nine to three, permitting a 75 percent staff reduction in its accounts payable department [Hammer, 1990: 104, 107]. In contrast, it takes the Navy twenty-six manual accounting transactions and nine reconciliations -- thirty-five steps in all -- to process and pay for things [Hemingway, 1993: 8-12]. This system is not only time consuming, it often leads to bad service and excessive investment in inventories. According to the National Performance Review, it causes delays in obtaining repair parts that keep a high proportion of the Navy's cars and trucks out of commission and forces the taxpayer to fund ten percent more vehicles than the Navy really needs [Gore 1993: 12]. Computerization could eliminate more than half of the steps in the Navy's accounts payable process [Hemingway, 1993: 25]. But why are fourteen, let alone thirty-five, accounting records needed where Ford gets by with three? One answer is that Navy fails to capture information once and at the source. Instead, each step in the supply process -- requisition, receipt, certification of invoice, reconciliation, and revision -- is repeated at every level of the organization. Moreover, the people who produce information do not process it. Processing is handled by financial management specialists from the bottom of the organization at the top. Finally, the Navy does not build financial control into its job designs. Naval officers have little discretion as to the mix or quantity of resources used by their commands. Even in peacetime their effectiveness in managing resources often has little or no bearing on the evaluation of their performance. Until recently, most economists assumed that technical efficiency was someone else's concern: engineers, maybe accountants, organization theorists, or even public administrationists. Nowadays they understand that technical inefficiency is often far more important than allocative inefficiency, but they tend to explain it in terms of structural or other factors [e.g., lack of competitive pressure] that are beyond the control of managers. While the efforts of economists to understand managerial failure has in recent years produced some powerful new theories and concepts that can that can help public administrators deal with a variety of problems [see below], economists still tend to overlook the most common cause of technical inefficiency: ignorance. Ignorance is Protean. As they say in the Navy, there are only a few ways to do right, there are an infinite number of ways to screw up. For example, the Navy's Byzantine system of accounting is arguably an unintended consequence of the Anti-

Deficiency Act [33 U.S.C. 1214, 1257 (1905)]. The system was designed to insure that neither local commanders nor higher level authorities exceeded the obligational authority granted them by Congress. That authority is now divided into fifty separate accounts, 557 management codes, and 1,769 accounting lines. At the same time it should, perhaps, be acknowledged that a preoccupation with technical efficiency leads public administration to slight allocative efficiency. Allocative efficiency has to do with matching supply to demand. It is of special concern to economists, who object to private monopolies, for example, not because their prices are too high, but because they produce less than they would under competition. Why is this is bad? It is bad, even where production is technically efficient, because consumers would willingly pay more for the things that aren't being produced than it would cost to make them. Hence, net benefits are forfeit [net benefits = willingness and ability to pay - cost > 0]. Economists refer to foregone net benefits as "deadweight loss." It is not hard to find instances of allocative inefficiency in government or to identify some fairly common pathologies that induce it. Economics teaches, for example, that, in the presence of a capital market where funds can be obtained at a price, the welfare of the citizenry will be maximized by the implementation of all projects offering positive net present values. This means that the timing of benefit/cost flows usually does not matter so long as future benefits and costs are properly discounted. But governments often appear to be obsessed with the timing of outlays. They give too much weight to current costs and benefits and too little to future ones. Consequently, they often put off investment programs that would produce net benefits or they stretch out programs, thereby increasing their costs, in order to comply with arbitrary spending constraints. For example, over the past two decades, the Department of Defense has reduced production rates for a variety of weapons systems below minimum optimal scale. In several instances this has had the result of increasing the present value costs of the total production run by more than 100 percent. Why? To reduce the annual deficit. In this case, the federal government was willing to trade huge future liabilities for small current reductions in the growth of the national debt, the interest upon which is now running about six percent per year. Government's propensity to disregard questions of feasibility, especially administrative and economic feasibility, also often results in allocative inefficiency. For example, John Mendeloff [1988] has shown how this propensity leads OSHA to over-regulate and how overregulation leads to underregulation. Both over- and underregulation are examples of allocative inefficiency. According to Mendeloff, OSHA overregulates exposures to harmful chemicals in the workplace because it

often sets standards without regard to the benefits and costs of reducing hazards to those levels [pp. 155-185]. John F. Morrall III [1986] estimates that as a consequence OSHA's proposed standards impose costs on industry that typically exceed benefits by a factor of ten. In the case of its proposed formaldehyde standard, costs were 25,000 times greater than benefits. Not surprisingly, these costs have inspired industry to embrace every legal, administrative, or political measure that might conceivably prevent, delay, or overturn promulgation of new standards. Consequently, nearly all of OSHA's discretionary resources have been absorbed defending standards that govern a mere handful of hazardous substances. The opportunity cost of overregulation can, therefore, be seen in the workers who are exposed to hundreds of underregulated substances because the resources needed to revise standards are simply not available. Government also has a propensity to disregard the incentive effects of the prices it sets. This necessarily results in allocative inefficiency. Fortunately, this propensity seems to be waning. Nevertheless, some people still have trouble seeing a relationship between low grazing fees on BLM land and overgrazing, between low prices for agricultural water and wasteful farm irrigation practices or urban water scarcity, between low timber harvest fees and overlogging, between the low landing fees charged private planes and airport overcrowding, or between agricultural price supports and food surpluses. Public administrators ignore allocative efficiency at their peril. A preoccupation with technical efficiency, like poverty, may be "no sin, but it is no great honor either." THE RENEWAL OF INTEREST IN ECONOMICS Of course, observers as perceptive as Lan and Rosenbloom could not have concluded that economics has emerged as public administration's preeminent paradigm unless their claim held a kernel of truth. A paradigm shift seems to be in the works; at least, many in the field now reject the traditional bureaucratic paradigm. Moreover, economics seems much more directly relevant to the concerns of public administration than in the recent past. There are three not entirely unrelated reasons for these changes: changing styles in political science, changes in the environment of public administration, and advances in economic science. I will deal with the first of these two issues briefly. The remainder of this essay will focus on the last. Political Science It is, perhaps, not too strong to say that a rational-choice, economics-based paradigm has emerged preeminent in American political science, including bureaucracy and public policy, subfields that are closely related to public administration. In my opinion this is a healthy turn of events. An unbiased observer would have to acknowledge,

however, that political science, like most of the humanities and social sciences, is prone to academic fads. They come and they go, often leaving little or nothing behind in the way of accumulated knowledge. It is natural that we think of ourselves as the tip of progress's arrow, but intellectual history demands a more humble interpretation. Just as academics of past generations usually seem wrong-headed to us, so too are we likely to appear to the next. Nevertheless, for good or ill, when political science sneezes, public administration more often than not catches a cold. Political science has sneezed. Changes in the Environment of Public Administration Public administration in the United States has also been influenced by the "new public management" [Gore, 1993]. The new public management emphasizes "performance appraisal and efficiency; the disaggregation of public bureaucracies into agencies which deal with each other on a user-pay basis; the use of quasi-markets and contracting out to foster competition; cost-cutting; and a style of management which emphasizes amongst other things, output targets, limited term contracts, monetary targets and incentives, and freedom to manage" [Rhodes, 1991: 11; Dunleavy & Hood, 1994]. The new public management is a worldwide movement [Rhodes, 1991; see also Hood, 1991; Schedler, 1995; Osborne and Gaebler, 1992; Barzelay, 1992]. Arguably, it represents a paradigm shift in public administration. Herman Schwartz [1994], for example, claims that government is undergoing "a profound shift toward a new kind of regime .... not simply a shift towards less state, but also a shift to a different kind of state." He attributes this shift to international market pressures. He stresses that many of the governments that have embraced the new public management are or were dominated by social democrats. New Zealand, which under Labour governments has gone further than any other country in its embrace of the new public management, is a prominent example [see below]. The driving force behind the new public management is technological change. Reductions in information costs brought about by computers and computer networks and our increased capacity to use them have caused four major shifts in the comparative advantage of governance mechanisms and institutional arrangements. These are [see Reschenthaler and Thompson, forthcoming]: 1. The efficacy of the market has increased relative to government provision and control; 2. The efficacy of the market and other self-organizing systems has increased relative to hierarchically coordinated systems; 3. The efficacy of decentralized allocation of resources and after-the-fact control has

increased relative to centralized allocation and before-the-fact control; and 4. The efficacy of process-oriented structures has increased relative to functional structures. These changes are hardly surprising. As will be explained below, the comparative advantage of any institutional arrangement boils down to a question of information or transaction costs. Changes in information costs should and have dramatically altered the relative advantage of governance mechanisms and institutional arrangements. Large organizations, for example, were once justified by economies of scale and scope. Economies of scale are produced by spreading fixed expenses, especially investments in plant and equipment and the organization of production lines, over larger volumes of output, thereby reducing unit costs. Economies of scope are produced by exploiting the division of labor -- sequentially combining highly specialized functional units in multifarious ways to produce a variety of products. Economies of scale and scope were made possible by hierarchy and bureaucracy, which broke tasks down into their simplest component parts and recombined them to produce complex goods and services, allocated scarce resources to administrative units, and established product-market strategies. In turn, hierarchy and bureaucracy were made possible by innovations in organizational design, administrative controls, and operational engineering [Chandler, 1962]. As Nathan Rosenberg and L.E. Birdsall [1986: 235-37] explain, most of the entrepreneurs of the Industrial Revolution were merchants and financiers -- they knew little or nothing about production. Business did not learn how to organize and supervise large numbers of workers until the mid 19th century. As late as 1892, for example, Carnegie Steel avoided the problem of organizing and managing the work of its production employees. "The organization of the work of large numbers of employees was a new management function, and direct employment could not have become a general practice until recruiting, organizing, and supervising factory workers been sorted out and fitted into a hierarchical scheme." Of course, only very large organizations could take full advantage of the bureaucratic revolution. Only they could be completely vertically integrated or afford to devote substantial amounts of resources to gathering and processing quantities of data for top management to use to coordinate activities, allocate resources, and set strategy -- these are, after all, fixed costs; they contribute nothing directly to output. The computer is rapidly eroding economies of scale in administration, production, and marketing and, thereby, the comparative advantage of hierarchy and bureaucracy. Today, any organization that can afford a computer workstation and software [about $20,000] can have first-class administrative systems, ranging from purchasing and inventory control to human resources management to financial planning and capital

budgeting to marketing and logistics. Twenty years ago these systems were available only to giant organizations. Moreover, computerized production [which consists of machine tools or other equipment for fabrication, assembly or treatment, linked by a materials handling system to move parts from one work station to another, and operating as an integrated system under full programmable control] now permits organizations to produce customized services at mass-production prices. In computerized production facilities, overheads are more important than production volume. In these facilities, direct manufacturing labor often accounts for less than 5 percent of costs; materials and purchased components typically account for thirty to forty percent more. This leaves at least fifty-five percent for overheads. Most overheads are transaction or information costs. They involve activities like purchasing, materials handling, marketing, accounting, and asset utilization. They are driven by an organization's policies, its operating and administrative procedures, and its customer relationships -- not output volume, rate, or even mix. To control overheads, including the costs of holding materials, parts, and finished goods inventories, many organizations have adopted techniques like lean manufacturing and just-in-time delivery of parts and materials. They have also modified their managerial cost accounting systems to focus the attention of responsibility center managers, marketing and manufacturing teams, and especially product designers and engineers on controlling overheads. Two tools have been critical to this effort: cycle-time burdening and transaction cost accounting [activitybased costing]. Again, not surprisingly, this is feasible because technology generates information about underlying productive processes. Computer-assisted-design programs also produce cycle-time and transactions costs estimates. Universal product codes and optical scanning devices permit continuous monitoring and, therefore, realtime reprogramming of the production process. As a result of the declining importance of economies of scale in production, the average size of the workplace has been falling throughout the industrialized world for the last twenty years [Economist, June 24, 1995: 4-6 Survey]. Large companies are "mimicking their smaller competitors by shrinking their head offices, removing layers of bureaucracy and breaking themselves up into constellations of profit centers, ... they are 'sticking to their knitting' -- concentrating on their core businesses and contracting everything else out, ... [and] they are putting a computer on every desk and giving power to front-line workers." As Shoshana Zuboff explains [1988: 204], efficient operations in the modern workplace call for a more equal distribution of knowledge, authority, and responsibility. To create value from information, members of the organization must be given the opportunity to know more and do more. This means "dismantling the very same managerial hierarchy that once brought greatness."

All of this looks like economics to many noneconomists, but it is really not. The intellectual justification for these changes comes primarily from management thinkers such as Peter Drucker, Theodore Levitt, Thomas Peters, Joseph Bower, Robert Anthony, Robert Kaplan and Robin Cooper, Henry Mintzberg, Alfred Chandler, Kenichi Ohmae, C.K. Prahaladad and Gary Hamel, and Peter M. Senge. The informational and organizational tools used in making these changes are described in the Harvard Business Review, Sloan Management Review, and Management Accounting, not the American Economic Review or even the Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. Many public administrators now read these journals and have tried to use the new tools in their organizations -- hence the new public management. Borrowing from the business-management literature is an old custom, as well as a recent phenomenon for the discipline of public administration. Business administration and public administration are both prescriptive, pragmatic disciplines [Hammond, 1990; Fitch, 1990]. Moreover, business schools and schools of public administration once shared the same proverbs of administration, just as we shared the Weberian bureaucratic paradigm and a common intellectual foundation in the works of Chester Barnard, Henri Fayol, Mary Parker Follett, Luther Gulick, Phillip Selznick, Frederick Taylor, and others. We both taught that bureaucracy is the solution to the "problem of maximizing organizational efficiency," that bigger is better, that organizations should be functionally differentiated and vertically integrated, and that top management always knows best. Besides, large organizations in both the public and the private sectors were fundamentally alike. Most were hierarchies; most distinguished between high-level management tasks [planning, organizing, staffing, and developing] and low level management tasks [controlling, operating, reporting, and budgeting]; and most centralized resource allocation and staff services. Now changes are taking place in what managers do and how organizations are put together -- even in what they are. The new public managers are interested in the way business does things, not because it is better than government, but because they face similar problems and the business-management literature is full of ideas that seem relevant to meeting these new challenges. Advances in Economics While the business-management literature is central to the new public management, two bodies of economic literature have also profoundly influenced its reception and its implementation: public choice theory and the new economics of organization. Public choice theory has changed the way we think about government and how it works. Moreover, in explaining the rules that voters, elected officials, and bureaucrats are likely to follow given their incentives, public choice theory has given public

administrators some useful new normative information. After all, in many cases, a good normative model is merely a good positive model run backwards. Nevertheless, when public administrators look to advances in economic science for help, it is not primarily to the public choice literature that they turn to, but the new economics of organization. The new economics of organization focuses on incentive and control structures and on the allocation of property rights and the ownership so as to minimize intraorganizational externalities or spillovers. It comprehends concepts like the Coase Theorem, transaction costs, externality, asymmetric information -- including agency theory, moral hazard, and adverse selection, contract theory, incomplete contracts, implicit contracts, incentive contracts, search and signaling theory, team theory, and incentive compatibility that are directly relevant to managerial problems. It is the legacy of economists like Kenneth Arrow, William Baumol, Albert Breton, Ron Wintrobe, Harold Demsetz, Victor Goldberg, Michael Jensen, Paul Milgrom, William Niskanen, Gordon Tullock and especially Ronald Coase and Oliver Williamson. It provides the new public management with the solid analytical foundation needed to understand how, when, and where to delegate authority, replace rules and regulations with incentives, develop budgets based upon results, expose operations to competition, search for market rather than administrative solutions, or use quasimarkets and contracting out to foster competition. The economics of organization has already influenced the design of a variety of institutional arrangements [ranging from emissions trading and "bubbles" to outright deregulation of the airlines and interstate trucking] in the United States and the privatization and securitization of an astonishing array of government-owned assets [and some liabilities] in Europe. Moreover, the evidence is accumulating that these arrangements work. It is partly because of this evidence that the ideas of the new public managers command the attention they do. PUBLIC CHOICE THEORY Public choice theory, like the older normative theory of public finance from which it evolved, starts with the demand for and the supply of collectively provided goods and services. With two exceptions, the theory of demand for a collectively provided good is identical to the theory of consumer demand for a private good. In both instances, demand reflects individual willingness and ability to pay to consume a good or service. Total demand for the service is, therefore, assumed to be a decreasing function of the price of the good, an increasing function of consumer income, and the size of the market for the good. The two differences between the theory of demand for a collectively provided good and the theory of consumer demand for a private good are that the quantity of service provided within a jurisdiction is determined by a

political process, usually assumed to be some form of majority rule, and is necessarily uniform throughout the jurisdiction. Hence, the quantity demanded of a collectively provided service will depend upon its price [P], the permanent income of the citizenry [Y], and population size [C], i.e.: Di = f [Pe, Ya, Cb] where: e = the price elasticity of demand for good i; a = the income elasticity of demand for good i; and b = a value from 0 to 1, representing the degree of publicness of good i. [This formulation is outlined in Borcherding, 1977; see also Bergstrom & Goodman, 1972]. The functional relationship that would obtain in any particular case would, of course, reflect existing political institutions as well as culturally mediated tastes and preferences [Breton, 1989]. There is a fair amount of evidence that this model of voter demand for collectively provided goods works reasonably well in practice. Literally hundreds of studies have demonstrated that family/per capita income, tax price, community size, and population served better explain cross-sectional variations in collectively supplied service levels that any other set of "determinants" [Oates, 1994; e.g., Duncombe, 1991; Romer, 1992]. Of course these variables work best where service levels are determined by direct referenda [Holcombe, 1977, 1986, & 1989; Inman, 1978; Romer & Rosenthal, 1982]. The one bug in the ointment is the "flypaper effect," so called because intergovernmental transfers tend to stick where they land [Oates, 1994; Rubinfeld, 1994; Ladd, 1994]. That is: intergovernmental grants appear to produce far larger increases in the output of government services than predicted by the income and price elasticities of the basic demand model. The Median Voter and Bowen Equilibrium In democracy, Di should reflect the tastes and elasticities of the median voter [Bowen, 1943] and would be in equilibrium where: Vm = Tm where: Vm = the marginal benefit of good or service i to the median voter m Tm = the marginal cost of good or service i to the median voter m

Then, where the cost of the good is equally shared by all voters [n], it follows that the marginal cost of the good to all voters is:

Since the Samuelsonian efficiency condition [1954, 1955], where the sum of the marginal costs of providing the collective good equals the sum of marginal benefits to all contributors, is:

it follows, that, for a Bowen equilibrium to be efficient, the marginal cost/benefit to the average voter would have to be equal to the marginal benefit/cost to the median voter, i.e., the following condition would have to be satisfied:

Consequently a Bowen equilibrium will be efficient if and only if marginal net benefits sum to zero at the output or supply level preferred by the median voter. This is of course something of a "knife-edged condition," except where the tastes, willingness, and ability to pay of all the voters in a jurisdiction are practically identical. One mechanism that might lead to the satisfaction of this condition is Tiebout sorting [named after the late Charles M. Tiebout, 1956] in which voters move to the communities whose governments best satisfy their preferences for collectively provided goods and services [Zax, 1989; Deller, 1990a, 1990b; Taylor, 1991; see, however, Hoyt, 1990]. While most economists grant that Tiebout sorting takes place, there is little consensus as to its significance. William Fishel [1992], for example, claims that the evidence from zoning and voting demonstrates that it is fairly complete; John Yinger, Howard S. Bloom, Axel Borsch-Supan, and Helen F. Ladd [1988], however, claim that the evidence from tax-capitalization is equivocal. This is a significant claim, because, at the local level, to the extant that service and tax levels are capitalized in real property values, reliance on the property tax reduces differences between the mean and the median voter even in the absence of Tiebout sorting. Reliance on proportional or progressive income taxes probably has a similar effect at state and, perhaps, federal levels of government. The key point to be stressed here is, as Bowen explained [his conclusion was later popularized by Downs, 195960], the average voter's demand for collectively provided goods will normally exceed the preferred consumption level of the median voter. This means that in a democracy, where costs are equally shared or, perhaps, even where taxes are proportional to income, collectively provided goods will tend to be undersupplied.

There is evidence that Bowen/Downs undersupply does occur. For, example, Fabio Silva and Jon Sonstelie [1995] recently tested William Fischel's [1989, 1995] hypothesis that, by requiring equal spending per pupil across all school districts in the state and, thereby, reducing Tiebout sorting and widening the gap between the preferences of the average and the median voter, the California Supreme Court in Serrano v. Priest caused a reduction in public spending to support elementary and secondary education. Before Serrano, California ranked 11th among states in public school spending per pupil, 13 percent above the average of all other states. By 1990, California had fallen to 30th, ten percent below the average. Silva and Sonstelie found that one-half of this decline could be attributed to Serrano. They attributed the remainder to rapid enrollment growth during the 1980s. Lindahl Equilibrium There is a second condition whereby the knife-edged condition described earlier might obtain, at least in theory: where decisions about collective provision are made unanimously. Unanimity can be satisfied under Lindahl equilibrium [Feldman, l980], a special case of the Samuelsonian efficiency condition. Formally, Lindahl equilibrium is defined as a vector of expenditure shares [S1,S2,...,Sn] and a level of provision [D*] such that for all i, where i's expenditure share is Si, the quantity of the good desired is D* [i.e., because i's expenditure or Ti is SiD*, Si = 1]. Furthermore:

Under this formulation, demand for all i is presumed to be normal, i.e., the higher i's share Si, the lower the D, i will want. Hence, if the Lindahl equilibrium were D1 and one i reduced their contribution to the provision of the good, the share of all other i would increase and D1 > D2. This voting rule is seldom used, however, because of the transactions costs associated with finding Lindahl equilibrium -- search, bargaining, and monitoring costs [Heckathorn & Maser, 1989; Maser, 1986]. Because of this fact, James Buchanan and Gordon Tullock [1962] suggest that an optimal constitution would minimize the sum of the costs imposed upon dissatisfied minorities, a decreasing function of the size of required majorities, and transactions costs, an increasing of function. Indeed, Americans have tried to design a constitutional order with this goal, albeit not this formulation, in mind. The founding fathers designed the federal Constitution to protect lives, liberties, and property from the overweening ambitions of a reckless and extravagant executive, the passions of minorities, and the interests of narrow or temporary majorities. This structure was intended to insure that the United States would have a government of law and that the law would change slowly and incrementally and only when the direction of change was endorsed by a large majority

of the citizenry. The founding fathers relied upon partisanship, jealousy between the two chambers of Congress, and the particularities of committee interests to make the federal government an agent of negotiation and compromise that would reach its decisions through the discovery of a lowest common denominator [Thompson, 1979]. Legislative Decision Making Representation promotes efficiency in two other ways. First of all it minimizes the transactions costs of political participation [economists see participation as cost, not a benefit]. Second, it transforms some public goods, where each individual voter's preferences are known only to himself or herself and costs are shared, into private goods, where benefits and costs are denominated in dollars and knowledge of the netbenefit schedule of each voter/legislator is equally available to all [Shepsle & Weingast, 1984]. Once the public goods problem is laid to rest, efficiency should be easy to arrive at. According to the Coase Theorem [Coase, 1960], where we are dealing with private goods and decisions are made one good at a time, any decision rule will produce an efficient outcome -- except where prevented by restrictions on side payments, transactions costs, or just plain ignorance [Dahlman, 1979]. Consider, for example, the following problem: there are three legislators: X, M, and N. Each represents a smog producing district; however, X's constituents export all of their smog to M's; M's export all theirs to N's; and N's keep all the smog they produce, plus that which they import from X's and M's constituents. The problem that X, M, & N must deal with is underinvestment in maintenance of automotive smog control devices. This is a real market failure: smog control devices work properly only when they are properly maintained; the cost of maintaining this equipment is very low, at least compared to other equally effective means of abating pollution. Unfortunately, since individuals bear the cost of maintenance, but the benefit thereby produced accrues primarily to others; they have no incentive to do so. The result is underinvestment. Compulsory inspection and maintenance [I&M;] is one way to deal with this market failure. It is an attractive example for our purposes for a number of reasons, one of which is that it can be assumed to impose roughly equal costs on voters in each constituency. Figure 1 illustrates the political calculus associated with a typical compulsory I&M; option. In this example the efficient solution is at xopt, where the vertical sum of Vx, Vm and Vn equals MC. But since each legislator prefers the I&M; option that equates T and V for the median voter in their constituencies: zero for X, xmed for M, and xhi for N. This example also clearly illustrates the typical gap between xmed and xopt -- although, in this case, xmed is closer in xopt than zero [see also Nelson, 1990; Bell, 1989].

[Figure 1 goes about here]

What happens when this problem is approached in a Coasian manner, searching at the margin for Pareto superior moves? For example, I&M; does not have to be compulsory to be effective. Automobile operators could be bribed to have their vehicles inspected and to achieve high maintenance scores at inspection. These bribes could be financed by a property tax levied on N's district. Under these circumstances, the situation outlined in Figure 2 would obtain. [Figure 3 shows the same circumstances in preference space and demonstrates that the efficient solution obtained in Figure 2 is also the Bowen Equilibrium.]

[Figures 2 and 3 about here]

Note that this solution has the attractive quality of making all three legislators better off than they would have been under the solution shown in Figure 1, but it is only one of possibly many Coasian solutions to the problem of underinvestment in the maintenance of smog control equipment. The Coase theorem merely states that, where decision makers are not constrained in their search for a solution, the solution they choose will be efficient. Of course, real legislators do not always behave like Coasian paragons. Simple human fallibility goes a long way toward explaining this fact. Information on the incidence of benefits and costs of a proposal may be equally available to all, but it may also be available to none. It is easy to conceptualize a Coasian solution to a problem of market failure; it is frequently far harder to design a practical program to implement one [e.g., Hahn and Noll, 1982]. Hence, it is not surprising that legislators fail to behave like Coasian paragons. Like the rest of us, individually and, consequently, collectively, they make mistakes. Explaining Oversupply The basic model for a collectively provided good implies the likelihood of undersupply. To many public choice theorists this likelihood appears to fly in the face of reality. What they want to do is explain what they observe: an excess of

government [Coughlin, 1991]. Two serious attempts to explain government excess have been mounted and, while neither entirely succeeds, both have taught us something about government. These are the interest-group theory of politics and William Niskanen's theory of spending coalitions, which introduced the notions of structurally induced equilibrium and agency theory to the study of politics and bureaucracy. The economic theory of interest-group politics is largely the creation of the "Chicago school" of regulatory theorists: George Stigler [1971], Richard Posner [1971, 1974], and Sam Peltzman [1976]. They argued that a variety of government programs [agricultural subsidies, military procurement, tariffs and import quotas, most regulation of business, and the structure of the tax system] are the product of an exchange between elected officials, who receive votes and campaign contributions, and members of groups, who reap higher incomes from their political investment. The theory predicts that politicians will use their power to transfer income from those with less political power to those with more: from the rich and the poor to the middle class and from disorganized, diffuse interests to well-organized concentrated interests [e.g., geographically-targeted benefits and predominantly federally-financed costs (Ferejohn, 1974; Shepsle & Weingast, 1981; Hird, 1991)]. Who gets what depends upon the costs and benefits to individual group members of participating in political processes and the ability of groups to influence policy makers. Of course, political scientists have known about interest groups for generations. What was new about the economic theory of interest-group politics? First, economists better understood the costs and benefits of government actions and their distributional consequences, which focused attention on the size of individual payoffs rather than the wealth of the player. Second, economists brought Mancur Olson's theory of collective action to bear upon the question of interest group influence on the public policy process. Olson demonstrated [Olson, 1965; Olson & Zeckhauser, 1966] that political participation [interest-group activity, voting, etc.] imposed private costs upon the participant but tended to create benefits that were nonexclusive, which in turn led to free-riding and the "exploitation of great by the small." This focused attention on public policies that could deny benefits to nonparticipants, the concentration of benefits produced by those policies, and the support thresholds required to claim those benefits. Third, economists based their theory on an assumption that is often wrong, but still might be of considerable utility in partial equilibrium analysis, that elected official are exclusively concerned with maximizing the probability of their reelection, which is an increasing function of interest group support [since citizens won't even vote unless they are persuaded to do so by campaign advertising and workers].

The biggest problem with the economic theory of interest-group politics is that, while it often tells a plausible story about existing public policies, empirical tests of its basic assumptions and predictions seldom work very well, compared say to the presumption that legislators pursue their own notions of the common good [Peltzman, 1984 & 1990; Kalt & Zupan, 1990; Mayer, 1991; Graddy, 1991a&b;]. And, of course, one should be mindful that the economic theory of interest-group politics was created primarily to explain government regulation of prices and entry in industries like trucking and airlines. Both of which have been subsequently deregulated. The one central claim of the economic theory of interest-group politics that has gone unchallenged is that many of the benefits of government action: tariffs, agricultural marketing orders, import quota, various types of price and entry control regulation, tariffs, pork barrel spending, and the like, do not accrue to their nominal recipients [Buchanan, Tollison, and Tullock, 198]. Instead, the rents created by government action are capitalized in asset prices, especially real property values, or competed away. Government created rents are often competed away because their existence leads to rent-seeking -- behavior aimed at getting or keeping rents. Most of these activities are directly unproductive and are, beyond some point, entirely wasteful. Gordon Tullock [1967] was probably the first scholar to think systematically about the consequences of rent-seeking. He argued that, if everyone could freely participate in the rush for the spoils, each rent-seeker would expend the full amount of the potential transfer in its pursuit. In which case, the rents created by government would be dissipated by the directly unproductive activities incurred to capture them. Indeed, in an implicit analogy to the effect of product differentiation in the economics of imperfect competition, Tullock hypothesized that the waste involved in capturing rents could actually exceed the rent to be captured. In a related vein, Mancur Olson [1982] argued that, if rents are extensive and efforts to retain them pervasive, the inevitable result is a kind of policy gridlock, which devours ever more resources in defense of the economic status quo, stultify change, and, by diverting investment away from productive activities and inhibiting the process of creative destruction, reduces the rate of economic growth. Indeed, an outsider cannot help but notice the amounts of money spent on campaigns for public office in this country or the resources employed to influence the legislative, administrative, and judicial processes. What seems remarkable about the American political system is not that it produces more rents than in other countries -- that doesn't seem to be the case [see Krueger 1974] -- but that the creation, maintenance, and distribution of rents attracts [or the gestation and implementation of any policy initiative, for that matter, requires] so much more effort here than elsewhere. William Niskanen and the Budget Maximizing Bureaucrat

In a second attempt to explain government excess, William Niskanen, Chairman of the Cato Institute and former head of the President's Council of Economic Advisors, [1971; Blais & Dion, 1991] showed that a revenue-maximizing, single-product bureau with absolute monopoly and agenda-setting powers would be technically efficient but produce up to two times the optimal quantity of output. While there are, perhaps [see Carroll, 1989, 1990], too many monopoly bureaus, their agenda-setting powers are often limited, most use a variety of technologies to provide an array of services, and technical inefficiency is widespread. Hence, anyone who leaps from the presumed monopoly power of bureaus to the allocative efficiency of government is undoubtedly over-reaching. Having said that, one must still recognize the remarkable scientific contribution made by Niskanen. First of all he, more than anyone else, demonstrated that the behavior of government officials, like corporate bureaucrats, could be deduced from their tastes and opportunities and that this approach is more effective than assuming that they are merely well trained robots. Second, Niskanen showed how the ability to control agendas presented to median voters could shift outcomes from their preferred positions. For example, confronted with a choice between nothing and a higher than preferred spending level [i.e. Vm < Tm ], the median voter should prefer the higher spending level as long as total benefits exceeded total costs [ Vm > Tm]. Of course, this same mechanism in the hands of a different agenda setter could lead to undersupply, but Niskanen argued that in the American congressional system, committees and subcommittees, the effective legislative and budget agenda setters, are likely to be dominated by program advocates [for evidence on this point, see Shepsle, 1976, 1979, 1986; Munger, 1984]. Finally, Niskanen adapted the structure-conductperformance paradigm from the industrial organization theory to the behavior of government bureaus, demonstrating, among other things, that monopoly supply is a necessary, but insufficient condition for allocative inefficiency. Niskanen's strictures against bureaucratic monopoly have probably had more influence on the theory and practice of public administration than any other idea drawn from the public choice literature [Ezzamel, 1993; Ferris & Graddy, 1991; Mayston, 1993; Miranda, 1994 & 1995; Rogerson, 1990]. Political scientists have embraced Niskanen's notion of structurally induced equilibrium, primarily I think because it appeals to their concern with political institutions and their fascination with games of strategy. There is now an extensive literature on structurally induced equilibrium [see Bendor, 1990; McKelvey, 1976; Shepsle, 1979]. One conclusion that can be drawn from this literature is that, if referenda are not carefully restricted to a single issue dimension, the drafter can manipulate them to produce almost any outcome desired. Another widely-accepted conclusion is that an inability on the part of the legislature to achieve a stable

collective choice could be a source of considerable bureaucratic discretion -- even were there no problems measuring bureaucratic performance or designing incentive mechanisms [Hill, 1985; Knott & Miller, 1987]. Of course, could is not the same as is [Langbein, 1996; McCubbins & Schwartz, 1984; McFadden, 1976, 1977]. Both economists and political scientists have also recognized the decisive role played by individually motivated agents in the determination of bureaucratic outcomes. Most, however, question Niskanen's assumption that bureaucrats are revenue maximizers [Blais & Dion, 1991]. In the meantime new theories have been developed that rely on a more careful or perhaps more imaginative description of bureaucratic tastes and opportunities. Contemporary models of bureaucracy stress the informational endowments of bureaucrats, the implicit and explicit contracts that link their actions to rewards, and their discretionary powers. The presumption that individuals within the State's administrative apparatus are single-mindedly driven to expand and protect existing programs and develop new programs of intervention has given way to the presumption that their utility functions might include some or more of the following arguments: effort and risk aversion, perquisite consumption, control benefits and other nonpecuniary benefits, and reputation [Laffont & Tirole, 1993; Gonzalez & Mehay, 1985; Mehay, 1986; Migue & Belanger, 1974; Schleifer, 1994; see also Antoci, 1995; De Fraja, 1993; Gemmell, 1990; Santerre, 1990; Whynes, 1993; McFadden, 1976, 1977]. Moreover, the dichotomy between competitors and monopolists proposed by the structure-conduct-performance paradigm: price takers versus price setters, has been largely superseded in the industrial-organization literature by a new technology of games under incomplete information [Tirole, 1988]. The newer models of bureaucratic behavior often seem inherently plausible. But like the economic theory of interest-group politics, they generally fail to yield successful empirical predictions beyond the ones for which they were custom tailored [see Conybeare, 1984]. For example, a while back L.R. Jones and I [Thompson & Jones, 1986] proposed a bilateral monopoly model of the budget process, with the central control office on one side and agencies on the other. We assumed that budgeters were primarily interested in cutting budgets -- that is after all what they are paid to do -and that agency officials were motivated by a variety of considerations -- task accomplishment, perquisite consumption, control benefits and other nonpecuniary benefits, and reputation [see Thompson & Williams, 1979]. The typical outcomes of this model were less than optimal budgets and outputs and higher than minimum unit costs. If this model were generally valid, however, both budgeteers and agency heads would consistently oppose competition whenever it raised its ugly head. That does not always seem to be the case, however. In both New Zealand and Australia, for examples, officials in central control agencies have taken the lead in promoting competition within government.

Another example is due to Terry M. Moe [1990: 140, 1989; see also Tabellini & Alesina, 1990; Cooley & Smith, 1989], who argues that political authorities, especially legislators, favor administrative controls that are ineffective by design. He claims that legislators shun serious policy control and, instead, seek "particularized" control because they "want to be able to intervene quickly, inexpensively, and in ad hoc ways to protect or advance the interests of particular clients in particular matters." Detailed rules that impose rigid limits on an agency's discretion and its procedures help to satisfy this appetite. Consequently, detailed object-of-expenditure budgets are the norm, for example, not for historical reasons, but because they are suited to the needs of temporary governing coalitions, which are likely to be far more concerned with who gets public monies and where it goes, than with what it buys for the public at large. Furthermore, Moe argues that the rigidity characteristic of the American administrative process is largely the product of the efforts of temporary ruling coalitions to prevent future majorities from interfering with their handiwork [see also McCubbins, Noll, & Weingast, 1989]. Summing up Public choice theorists are often cynical about politics and pessimistic about the workings of government. They disallow any role for what Steve Kelman [1987] calls "public" or "civic" spirit, except to the extent that self interest is defined to include an interest in the welfare of others [a tactic which has the effect of denying to public choice any Popperian bite whatsoever]. Moreover, as Michael Trebilcock [1994] explains, public choice theorists implicitly reject the notion that ideas have power [which, if true, would render public choice an exercise in futility], although the recent trend to privatization, deregulation, and to tax reform can hardly be explained any other way. As Trebilcock puts it, these policies show that ideas have force and that "... politics, to an important extent, is partly about what are thought to be good ideas as well as what are thought to be politically salient interests." These problems aside, and clearly they are not small problems, what public choice theorists say about coalition formation, free riding, agenda setting, and bureaucracy is important, if for no other reason than because it has been useful in promoting a healthy skepticism [not cynicism] about government and interest group demands. It is not a bad thing to look beneath the packaging [see Stanbury, 1993]. Individuals and groups do often turn to government to obtain or preserve economic rents that would otherwise be unavailable to them. Government activities often are designed to interfere with efficient market solutions to resource allocation problems. Society has several common pools of wealth: [1] personal and business net assets; [2] government's net real and financial assets, not including natural resources; [3] publicly owned natural resources; [4] the stock human capital; [5] an environment pool that reflects the overall "quality" of the environment; and [6] the wealth of the

future generations. The wealth of future generations is, of course, largely dependent upon the expansion of the first five pools. Politics, at its worst, is merely a means by which stakeholder groups use the collective, coercive power of government to tilt these pools in their direction. This produces a lot of sloshing about and considerable leakage. Moreover some groups are especially vulnerable to losses -- the young and a fortiori the unborn, for instance, must bear the consequences of the failure of current generations to expand these resource pools, but are largely excluded from political processes. Consumers and taxpayers, individually and collectively, are similarly although not so completely disadvantaged in political arenas. It seems likely that increased skepticism about existing institutional arrangements and governance mechanisms has encouraged experimentation with alternatives and increased receptivity to the lessons of the new economics of organizations and institutions. THE NEW ECONOMICS OF ORGANIZATION In a recent article, Robert D. Behn [1995] observed that public administration needs to focus on big questions, such as how public managers can break the micromanagement cycle of procedural rules and how they can measure the achievements of their agencies in ways that will help to increase those achievements. The new economics of organization focuses on these vital questions. Its basic idea is that the comparative advantage of any institutional mechanism or governance arrangement boils down to a question of information or transaction costs "and to the ability and willingness of those affected by information costs to recognize and bear them" [Arrow, 1969; see also Alchian & Demsetz, 1972; and Barzel, 1982]. Hence, the circumstances that create market failures: public goods, natural monopolies, externalities, moral hazard and adverse selection, etc., the problems that justify government action in a capitalist economy, are fundamentally information failures. Markets could deliver public goods, for example -- if information technology existed that would permit free-riders to be profitably excluded from enjoying them. Monopolies could be compensated to behave like competitors -- if information costs were lower. And, externalities could be eliminated by bargaining between self-interested individuals, without the intervention of government -- if transactions costs were zero. Much the same logic applies to the choice between organizations and markets and the kinds of governance mechanisms used within organizations. The problem with the elegant, logically consistent deductive models created by the practitioners of the economics of organization is that many are neither empirically grounded nor very practical. Until very recently the economics of organization was a classic example of theory without data. Ten years ago, for example, when John Conybeare [1984] surveyed the literature on economic structure and performance in the public sector, he found a single empirical study to cite. This situation is changing [e.g., Frant, 1993; forthcoming], but not very rapidly. One reason for this state of

affairs is that tinkering is required to make a satisfactory positive theory of public sector supply arrangements. One cannot, for example, simply presume that arrangements have been selected because they minimize the sum of operating and transactions costs [Moe, 1984; although it is best to be agnostic on this point, see Ferris & Graddy, 1991, 1994; De Groot, 1988] or that the arrangements one observes are optimal; careful, comparative, best-practice research is needed. Second, the new economics of organization can be impractical, in part because its practitioners are often more interested in saying what cannot be done, than what should be, and in demonstrating that circumstances give rise to inefficiencies, than how one might go about minimizing them. Consider the typical approach to asymmetric information -- agency, moral hazard, and adverse selection problems. Economists seem to fix on problems in which there is high degree of conflict between principal and agent, which usually leads to a substantial gap between what principals get and what they could get if they were better informed [Persky, 1994]. But intellectual interest ought not obscure reality. Many, perhaps most, asymmetric information problems have reasonably satisfactory solutions [Tirole, 1994]. Evidence that a potential problem is a real one requires information about magnitudes, and not just an existence proof. Agency, moral hazard, and adverse selection problems are common in corporate governance, since the interests of corporate managers are also not necessarily identical to those of the stockholders [see, for example, Williamson, 1988]. Yet many businesses survive and prosper nonetheless. Furthermore, these conflicts do not undermine completely the value of theories that ignore them. Moreover, when economists look closely at agency problems, they often shrink in size, when they cannot be made to disappear altogether [Baker, 1992; Baker, Gibbons, & Murphy, 1994; Campbell, Chan, & Marino, 1989; Hemmer, 1993; Itoh, 1993; Bates, 1993; De Groot, 1988; De Fraja, 1993; Good, 1992; Mayston, 1993; Wallis, 1991]. The difference between potential and real agency problem is demonstrated by James Buchanan's conjecture that risk-averse public officials will exploit their superior understanding of the production of government services to extract higher budgets from the public [1969:98-102]. Buchanan's argument goes something like this: from the public official's standpoint, it may be more costly to finance public spending with taxes than with debt. In which case, borrowing would lead to higher than optimal levels of government spending and services. Consequently, Buchanan concludes that pay-as-you go financing serves as a check on public officials, bringing their actions into line with the tastes of the citizenry. Pay-as-you go financing has much to recommend, but as it turns out, the risk-aversion problem that is at the heart of Buchanan's conjecture is strictly incentive compatible -- either it is not a problem or is easily soluble [Choate and Thompson, 1989, 1990; see also Wittman, 1989].

In the remainder of this essay I assume that agency problems are not completely intractable and can usually be mitigated if not completely overcome. Given this assumption, what can one take from new economics of organization that is both useful and valid? The Control Problem The propensity to devise inflexible and comprehensive rules is, perhaps, nowhere more irresistible than where government procurement is concerned. Consider the fruitcake, 250 tons of which are purchased by the Army each year. To preclude abuses on the part of unscrupulous bakers, to make sure there really are some candied fruits and nuts in the fruitcake, to guarantee adequate shelf-life and resistance to handling, and to insure palatability in all the far-flung places of the world where the American soldiers celebrate Christmas, the specifications for the MIL-F-1499 [Fruitcake] are eighteen pages long. Plastic whistles take sixteen pages, olives seventeen, chewing gum fifteen, condoms thirteen, and so on. The late Frederick C. Mosher [1980: 545-47] not so long ago observed that government has experienced a sea change in its responsibilities and its tactics and concluded that these massive changes have rendered obsolete the traditional administrative controls we inherited from our forebears. In a similar vein, Allen Schick [1978: 518] has noted with concern that recent changes in the reach and scale of government have been accompanied by massive growth in the scope and content of rule-bound governance mechanisms: reporting requirements have multiplied; auditors scrutinize more closely the accounts of federal agencies and contractors; and direct controls in the form of rules and regulations have proliferated. Schick concluded that we cannot afford to go on imposing direct controls over an ever widening sphere of activities -- that new solutions to the problem of administrative governance must be sought. He finished with a reminder that in many cases individuals can be more effectively influenced to serve the public interest "by inducements which allow them to pursue their own interests than by constraints which try to bar them from behaving as they want." Perhaps the most useful contribution of the economics of organization is that it has made us cognizant of the alternative governance mechanisms that are available for influencing people to advance the policies and purposes of the institutions they serve: [1] outlay budgets, [2] responsibility budgets, [3] fixed-price contracts, and [4] flexible-price contracts, of the circumstances under which each has a comparative advantage, and the criteria to be used in choosing between them. Governance in General

All governance system designers face the same key choices: what, where, when, and, whom to control. The choice of what and where to control is reasonably self-evident. Management control should be primarily addressed to the behavior of service suppliers [i.e., departments and agencies, contractors, etc.], the efficiency with which they produce goods and services, and ultimately the efficiency with which they use the assets at their disposal. The choice of whom to subject to controls and when to execute those controls is less self-evident. In the abstract, a governance system designer has four sets of options, comprised of two choices of subject and two of timing. [1] The subject may be either an organization or an individual; and [2] Controls may be executed either before or after the subject acts. Before-the-fact controls are intended to prevent subjects from doing undesirable things or to compel them to do desirable thing. These controls necessarily take the form of authoritative mandates, rules, or regulations that specify what the subject must do, may do, or must not do. The subjects of before-the-fact controls are held responsible for complying with these commands and the controller attempts to monitor and enforce compliance with them. After-the-fact controls are executed after the subject, either an organization or an individual, decides on and carries out a course of action and, therefore, after some of the consequences of the subject's decisions are known. Because bad decisions cannot be undone after they are carried out, after-the-fact controls are intended to motivate subjects to make good decisions. Hence subjects are made responsible for the consequences of their decisions, and the controller attempts to monitor those consequences and to see that subjects are rewarded or sanctioned accordingly. Combining the choice of subject with that of timing, we find that the governance system designer must choose among four distinct institutional alternatives: individual responsibility, before-the-fact or after-the-fact, and organizational responsibility, before-the-fact or after-the-fact. Privatization The significance of these alternative designs is partially reflected in debates over the merits of privatizing the delivery of public services. Proponents of privatization imply that the choice is between rule-governed, often over-regulated, monopolistic public bureaucracies and freely competing private firms [Hanke, 1987; Savas, 1982; see, however, Donahue, 1989]. Were that the choice, it is difficult to see how privatization could be wrong, since it resolves to a simple question of monopoly or competition. Other things equal, provision by competing private firms will usually be more efficient than provision by a public monopoly. But other things are not equal. Consequently, the distinction often drawn by proponents of privatization between public and private production is often overly simplistic. It is simplistic because many proponents of privatization implicitly assume

that governments are flawed but markets are perfect: that market participants are perfectly informed, that market transactions are costless, and that they involve the exchange of a discrete product for cash. However, when the choice of governance arrangements is at hand, that is precisely what we must not do. In the real world, where the production of a good or service may be characterized by increasing returns to scale or scope, a high degree of lumpiness in production [or consumption], asset specificities, or the absence of close substitutes, the purchaser must expend resources shopping and bargaining over prices and terms. If the item or service is to be made available at a later date, the purchaser must expend resources to insure that the supplier adheres to the terms of the bargain or contract. That is, to avoid costly mistakes, the purchaser must incur search, bargaining, monitoring, and enforcement costs. These transaction or control costs are part of the cost of acquiring a a good or service. It does not matter whether they occur inside of government or out; ultimately the public pays. Consequently, the distinction between provision by a public agency and provision by a private entity fails to capture the full range of choices available to the governance system designer. It also fails to reflect all of the factors that are relevant to the choice. First, although most goods and services are produced by organizations and not individuals, effective control ultimately presumes individual accountability. The distinction drawn by the proponents of privatization between public and private provision ignores the capacity of controllers to hold managers of public organizations under their jurisdictions individually responsible for their behavior and, thereby, their capacity to influence directly the rewards and sanctions that accrue to those individuals, such as salary and opportunities for advancement. Controllers cannot possibly hold managers personally responsible where their relationship to the supplying organization is at arm's length and the structure of individual responsibility is veiled by the organizational form. The only way an organization can be rewarded [or punished] is by increasing [or reducing] its revenues. An organization's revenues can affect an individual manager's welfare, but only indirectly. The difference between holding individuals and organizations accountable or between direct, personal influence and indirect influence is quite straightforward. Take the following example: if the quality of services supplied by an agency, the Defense Logistics Agency for example, is grossly unsatisfactory, the controller can recommend the dismissal of the agency director. Where the Department of Defense has an arm's length relationship with a service supplier, McDonnell-Douglas for example, and the relationship is unsatisfactory, all that the controller can do is recommend termination of the relationship. The controller can punish the supplying organization, but cannot punish the managers responsible for the failure -- although their actions might very well lead the organization's board of directors to to so. Unfortunately, punishing a monopoly [that is, any sole-source supplier] is like cutting

off your nose to spite your face; rewarding one is like eating an eclair to celebrate staying on a diet. Consequently, where the supplying organization is a monopoly, the capacity to influence managers directly will have considerable utility, particularly where controllers can stimulate and exploit competition between alternative management teams. This claim can be verified by reference to the private sector. In the private sector, most real natural monopolies make intermediate products, i.e., goods that are used to produce consumer goods or services. Natural monopoly [decreasing costs as output increases] can usually be attributed to spreading large, lumpy investments in specialized resources -- technological know-how, product specific research and development, equipment. -- over additional output. Investment in specialized resources often inspires a process called vertical integration ["backward" if initiated by the consumer goods producer, "forward" if initiated by the intermediate goods producer] [Joskow, 1988; Colbert & Spicer, 1995]. The new economics of organization tells us that vertical integration occurs because it permits transaction or control costs to be minimized, in part through the substitution of direct supervision for indirect influence [see Williamson, 1985; on the relevance of transaction cost economics to public administration, see Maser, 1986; Vining and Weimer, 1990; and Ferris and Graddy, 1991, 1994; see also Friedman, 1981 and Borcherding, 1983, 1988]. In the language of transaction-cost economics, investment in specialized resources is called asset specificity. An asset is said to be specific if it makes a necessary contribution to the provision of a good or service and has a much lower value in alternative uses. The corollary of asset specificity is bilateral monopoly, a circumstance that provides an ideal environment for opportunistic behavior on the part of both supplier and customer. For example, once intermediate product producers have acquired specialized assets, their customers may threaten to switch suppliers to extract discounts from them. In that case, suppliers may find it necessary to write off large parts of their specialized investment. Or, if demand for the final good increases greatly, the intermediate product supplier may be able to use its monopoly power to extort exorbitant prices from customers. Hence, where the relationship between the intermediate product supplier and his customer is at arm's length, the threat of opportunistic behavior may be sufficient to eliminate the incentive to make what would otherwise be cost-effective investments. Vertical integration can eliminate this threat. Indeed, where the intermediate product producer provides homogeneous goods or services [i.e., outputs that are easily monitored], total production volume is specified, and technologies are mature, vertical integration permits a bilateral monopoly to be governed satisfactorily by unbalanced or two-part transfer prices [Masten, 1993; Young, 1991; Schroeder, 1993; Prusa, 1990]. Vertical integration is, of course, only one way to deal with asset specificity [Walker & Poppo, 1991]. Some organizations invest in specialized resources and own design-

specific assets, which they provide to their suppliers. This is called quasi-vertical integration. It is common in both the automobile and the aerospace industries, and, of course, it is standard procedure for the Department of Defense to provide and own the equipment, dies, and designs that defense firms use to supply it with weapons systems and the like [see Monteverde and Teece,1982]. Other organizations that rely on a small number of suppliers or a small number of distributors write contracts that constrain the opportunistic behavior of those with whom they deal. A well-executed contract can approximate the outcome from vertical integration [although such contracts are often very hard to write and, where one of the parties is inclined to exploit the other, prohibitively costly to enforce] without incurring the very real costs of vertical integration. In other cases, desired outcomes can be realized through alliances based on the exchange of hostages [e.g., surety bonds, exchange of debt or equity positions] or just plain old-fashioned trust based on long-term mutual dependence. In Japan, for example, buyer-seller relationships tend to be based on mutual confidence [Ravenscroft, 1993]. Toyota relies on a few suppliers that it nurtures and supports. It maintains tight working links between its manufacturing and engineering departments and its suppliers and explicitly eschews opportunistic behavior in the interest of maintaining long-term relationships. Nevertheless, in one study of vertical integration in the U.S. aerospace industry, Scott Masten [1984] unambiguously demonstrated that asset specificity and, therefore, decreasing cost is basic to the make-or-buy decision. Where intermediate products were both complex and highly specialized [used only by the buyer], there was a 92 percent probability that it would be made internally; even 31 percent of all simple, specialized components were made internally. The probability dropped to less than 2 percent if the component was not specialized, regardless of its complexity. The proponents of privatization also err in their implicit claim that responsibility can be vested in organizations if and only if the organization is private, and in individuals if and only if the organization is part of the public sector. The absurdity of this claim becomes clear as soon as it is explicitly stated; it is consistent with neither theory nor practice. For example, many state legislatures base their relationships with public entities such as universities or hospitals on arm's length relationships that are guaranteed by self-denying ordinances, which exempt the managers of these public entities from detailed oversight and direct control. The Department of Defense's decisions about base closure and realignment, for example, are exempted from direct congressional control by just such a self-denying ordinance [Twight, 1990]; public authorities are another good example [Frant, forthcoming]. Similarly, the recurring procurement fraud cases show that managers of private entities that supply services to the government can be held directly and personally responsible for their behavior when it violates federal law. Finally, most of the proponents of privatization implicitly presume that the services provided to or for government are homogeneous or fungible, which implies that the

problem of identifying the most efficient supplying organization or management team resolves to a simple question of price search, an elementary control mechanism that reveals information about the "customer's" demand for the service. In fact, many of the organizations supplying goods or services to or for government supply bundles of more or less heterogeneous products -- many of these products are hard to measure and costly to evaluate, some prohibitively so. Choosing between Alternatives Proponents of privatization do make one significant, unexceptionable claim: the choice of institutional design should depend on the cost and production behavior of the good or service in question. However, they frequently fail to carry this claim to its logical conclusion. This choice should depend upon minimizing the sum of production costs and transactions costs [Williamson, 1985]. At least two factors are relevant from a transactions-cost standpoint: the ease with which the consequences of operating decisions can be monitored and the desirability of inter-organizational competition. Most management control theorists believe that where consequences [that is, an organization or responsibility center's outputs] are easily monitored, control should focus on the consequences of the subject's decisions; where they are not, control should focus on their content [inputs]. Because consequences are easily monitored where entities produce homogeneous outputs or where a responsibility center within an entity performs fungible activities, it follows that controllers should rely on after-the-fact controls where homogeneous outputs are supplied. In contrast, it follows that they should rely on before-the-fact controls where each item supplied is, from the "customer's" perspective, intrinsically unique. Furthermore, this view has been reinforced by recent findings in organizational economics and agency theory [Mayston, 1993; Ezzamel, 1993; Macintosh, 1993; Whynes, 1993; Good, 1992; Brown, Thornton, Buede, & Miller, 1992]. At the same time, industrial organization theory tells us that inter-organizational competition is desirable only where costs are constant or increasing as quantity of output [rate or volume] increases [Tirole, 1988; Carlton & Perloff, 1990]. Where economies of scale or scope cause costs to decrease when output is increased, monopoly supply is usually appropriate [Barzelay (1992) refers to entities that have this characteristic as "utilities"; see also Kettl (1993)]. Because responsibility can be effectively vested in organizations only where customers or their agents are ultimately indifferent to the survival of one or more of the supplying organizations, the implication of this line of reasoning is that controllers should vest responsibility in organizations only where inter-organizational rivalry is practical and likely to be effective -- and in individuals, where it is not [Willig & Jatar, 1993; Aertsen, 1992]. These normative prescriptions are summarized in Figure 4. FIGURE 4 GOES ABOUT HERE

Execution of Alternative Governance System Designs These four basic sets of controls are all employed by government. But is each appropriately employed? Before this question can be answered, I must first show how these designs are used and explain the practical logic of their implementation. My discussion will concentrate on the use of before-the-fact controls. This does not mean that I particularly like them. On the contrary, I believe that controllers should resort to before-the-fact control designs only where production and transaction costs clearly renders their use the least objectionable alternative [Reid, 1990]. I concentrate on the use of before-the-fact controls because it seems to me that their implementation is not well understood, especially by those who most rely on them. Many participants in the policy process seem to believe that before-the-fact controls not only safeguard against abuse, but also, by reducing costs, improve performance. If failure occurs nevertheless, they tend to believe the solution lies in still more or better rules. One possible explanation for the persistent faith in the efficacy of before-the-fact controls is that its devotees just don't understand how hard it is to execute them efficiently. For example, they appear to believe that the subjects of before-the-fact controls will comply with them simply because they are morally obligated to do so. Obviously, however, not everyone is inclined to respect moral authority, to respect the law, or to obey rules. It is necessary to monitor and enforce compliance with rules and to ferret out and punish noncompliance. It is also necessary to specify the content of before-the-fact controls -- to tell subjects what to do and what not to do in such a way as to find and enforce efficiency, which is no easy matter. Moreover, many of those who believe in the potency of before-the-fact controls fail to understand that moral authority is all too easily eroded by an oversupply of rules. Moral authority, respect for the law, the inclination to obey rules are of critical importance to the stability and the efficacy of social arrangements. In reality, that they are far too important to be frittered away where other mechanisms of social control will suffice. Rather they ought to be carefully husbanded so that they will be available when and where they are really needed [see Tyler, 1990]. Before-the-fact controls are like after-the-fact controls in that they ultimately rely on incentives and sanctions for their effectiveness. The difference is that after-the-fact management controls are incentive or demand-revealing mechanisms, while beforethe-fact management controls are incentive or demand-concealing mechanisms. This means that opacity is an essential characteristic of before-the-fact controls. The incentive aspects of before-the-fact controls are thus less clear than the incentive aspects of after-the-fact controls. This also means that their effectiveness is hostage to the skill with which they are executed, which explains why their incentive aspects are easily overlooked and, perhaps, why they are not better understood. In order to show how demand-concealing mechanisms work, I will first try to show how demandrevealing mechanisms work or, at least, what they are.

After-the-Fact Governance System Designs By demand-revealing mechanisms, I mean those in which customers [or their agents] declare their willingness to pay for various quantities of goods, services, or activities. Customers transparently reveal a demand schedule that fully expresses their wants and preferences to their suppliers. Then they let suppliers figure out how best to satisfy those wants and preferences. The classic demand-revealing mechanism is the competitive spot market, where customers buy from any number of anonymous firms. When many suppliers are disposed to satisfy customer wants, customers simply choose the best price and quantity combinations offered -- those that moves them farthest down their demand schedules. In so doing customers reward the suppliers that are willing to do the most to satisfy their tastes and implicitly punish the rest. For example, they might order wheat from a broker, at the market price payable on delivery. In that case, there would be no formal contract. Customers would put no restrictions on producers. In fact, customers probably won't even know who grew their grain. But wheat farmers are nevertheless rewarded for their contributions. Government relies on these kinds of spot markets when, for example, it purchases electrical components off the shelf. After-the-Fact Controls Transparently Reward Measured Performance or Results The spot market is by no means the only demand-revealing mechanism used to govern transactions between buyers and sellers. There many variations on the basic theme of reliance on transparent rewards. But all of these variations have one common attribute: rewards are provided after operating decisions have been made by the producer, after assets have been acquired and used and outputs monitored. Because they are executed after asset acquisition and use decisions have been made, we refer to them as ex-post or after-the-fact controls. A close analog to a spot market is seen where government uses prospective price mechanisms to reimburse free-standing service providers. The system used by the Health Care Financing Administration to pay hospitals for treating patients is an example. The enrollment-driven funding formulas used by some states to compensate post-secondary institutions for teaching students is another [Jones, Thompson, and Zumeta, 1986]. In both of these instances the subject is a freestanding organization, and the structure of authority and responsibility within the supplying organization is purely an internal matter. The government or its agent announces a price schedule and specifies minimum service quality standards [or a process whereby these standards are to be determined] and the time period in which the price schedule will be in effect. Under prospective pricing, all qualified organizations will be paid a stipulated per-unit price each time they perform a specified service, such as enrolling a full-time equivalent student or treating a heart attack. This means, among other things, that the government's financial liability is somewhat open ended. It depends on the price offered and the quantity of service actually provided [Liability = Price Quantity], although not directly on the costs incurred by the suppliers.

Another close relative of the spot market is the fixed-price contract. Again, under fixed-price contracts, prices are fixed before hand and aren't affected by the supplier's subsequent costs. In contrast, under flexible-price contracts those costs are shared with the customer. The limit under flexible-price contracts is reached in the case of a cost-plus fixed-fee contract, where the customer assumes full responsibility for all legitimate, measured costs. In a pure fixed-price contract government usually buys from numerous suppliers held at arm's length. Frequent bidding contests are held and orders are shifted among suppliers chosen simply on price. These price schedules can entail all sorts of complex arrangements, including rate, volume, and mix adjustments as well as inflation adjustments and sometimes default penalties. Fixed-price contracts also comprehend franchises to provide a specified services, perhaps at specified locations, for a fixed periods of time -- garbage collection at a military base, for example. Under all of these demand-revealing mechanisms, government relies upon interorganizational competition, along with the profit motive, to motivate service suppliers to make wise asset acquisition and use decisions and to produce efficiently. If interorganizational competition is effective, organizations that don't make wise asset acquisition and use decisions fall by the wayside. Demand-Revealing Mechanisms in Vertically Integrated Organizations In some cases, even where the cost behavior of the service in question renders vertical integration and therefore monopoly supply appropriate, after-the-fact, demandrevealing mechanisms can still be effectively employed. This is done in businesses and businesslike public sector organizations by holding managers responsible for optimizing a single criterion value, usually a measure of financial performance, subject to a set of specified constraints. This control mechanism is, therefore, usually known as responsibility budgeting [Anthony and Young, 1988: 365-386; Thompson, 1991], sometimes as performance contracting [Islam, 1993]. The fundamental construct of responsibility budgeting is an account [or control] structure that is oriented toward administrative units that have purposes or objectives and use inputs [resources] to produce outputs [goods or services]. Ideally a responsibility budget contains a single number or financial performance target [e.g. a unit cost standard, or a profit or return-on-investment target] for each administrative unit. Responsibility centers are classified according to two dimensions: [1] The integration dimension &endash; i.e., the relationship between the responsibility center's objectives and the overall purposes and policies of the organization; [2] The decentralization dimension &endash; i.e., the amount of authority delegated to the responsibility manager, measured in terms of the discretion to acquire and use assets. On the first dimension, a responsibility center can be either a mission center or a support center. The output of a mission center contributes directly to the organization's objectives. The output of a support center is an input to another responsibility center in the organization, either another support center or a mission

center. On the decentralization dimension, discretionary expense centers, which mimic the governmental norm, are found at one extreme and profit and investment centers at the other. A support center may be either an expense center or a profit center. If the latter, its profit is the differences between its expenses and "revenue" from "selling" its services to other responsibility centers [Halal, 1994]. Both profit and investment centers are usually free to borrow, and investment centers are also free to make decisions about plant and equipment, new products, and other issues that are significant to the long-run performance of the organization. Responsibility budgeting is largely concerned with setting targets, monitoring performance in terms of the targets specified, and rewarding managers accordingly. Responsibility centers coordinate their activities via a process of exchange and mutual accommodation. This is often possible now, where it wasn't really before, because the design of responsibility structures [the allocation of property rights and the ownership so as to minimize intraorganizational externalities or spillovers] and management information systems [performance measures, transfer prices, and costing procedures] are now more sophisticated. The increased sophistication of performance measures, transfer prices, and costing procedures is largely due to improvements in computer speed and software [Lapsey, 1994]. Where bilateral relationships are concerned, it is usually possible to set up some kind of transactional arrangement to eliminate or internalize spillovers [Ronan, 1992; Ronan & Balachandran, 1988; Balachandran & Ronan, 1989; Dorkey & Jarrell, 1991]. In most cases, these relationships can be governed via buyer-seller arrangements and, where they occur within the organization, by appropriate transfer prices. Where monopoly supply is appropriate, two-part tariffs [e.g., hook-up plus usage charges for telephone services, see Tirole, 1988; Cohen, Loeb, Stark, 1992] or unbalanced transfer prices can be used to manage relationships and to provide the supplier with an incentive to make long term investments in plant, equipment, or know-how. [Unbalanced transfer prices are often easier to use than cost-based twopart tariffs, since the latter must be very carefully calibrated to produce an efficient solution, but accountants don't like them very much] In other cases, support units can be made to compete within the context of a quasi-market dynamic with others supplying similar services inside and outside the organization and permitted to charge whatever the market will bear. Such an account structure would look something like the following: 1. All administrative units are be classified as either mission or support centers. 2. All costs accrued by support centers -- including charges for the use of capital assets and inventory depletion -- are charged to the mission centers they serve. 3. Mission centers are funded to cover their expected expenses -- including support center charges. 4. A working capital fund provides short-term financing for support units. 5. A capital asset fund provides long-term financing of capital assets and encourages

efficient management of their acquisition, use, and disposition. The principal formal device by which transactions are currently accomplished within government is the revolving fund. These funds involve buyer-seller arrangements internal to federal government. The Navy had a revolving fund as early as 1878. Modern day revolving funds date to the 1947 National Security Act and, under the Defense Business Operating Fund, have grown to $40 billion a year. Two kinds of funds have been established under this authority: stock and industrial funds. Stock funds are used to purchase supplies in bulk from commercial sources and hold them in inventory until they are supplied to the customer -- usually a military unit or facility. Industrial funds are used to purchase industrial or commercial services [e.g., depot maintenance, transportation, etc.] from production units within the government. Both kinds of funds are supposed to be financed by reimbursements from customers' appropriations [Juola, 1993: 43]. Modern transfer pricing could expand the scope of this device and enhance its effectiveness by establishing rules for setting prices prospectively rather than retrospectively and my emphasizing the notational nature of the exchange. Transfer prices encourage efficient choice on the part of support centers and the units that use their services, only [1] if prices are set ahead of time, [2] if support centers nominally charge all of their expenses against revenues earned delivering services, and [3] if support centers are treated as responsibility centers -- their managers are authorized to incur expenses to deliver services and are held responsible for meeting the stated financial targets of their centers: the more highly capital intensive ones, as investment centers, most others either as cost or income centers [although in most cases their performance could be evaluated in terms of quasi-profitability -- i.e., benchmark cost/price less actual cost][Bailey, 1967: 343]. Under responsibility budgeting/performance contracting, the structure of authority and responsibility within the organization is of crucial interest to the controller. The effectiveness of responsibility budgets depends on the elaboration of well-defined objectives, accurate and timely reporting of performance in terms of those objectives, and careful matching of spending authority and responsibility. Their effectiveness also depends on the clarity and transparency with which individual reward schedules are communicated to responsibility-center managers and the degree of competition between alternative management teams [Govindarajan, 1988; Goold, 1991; Chia, 1995]. Examples of governments that have experimented with responsibility budgeting and accounting include New Zealand, Australia, Great Britain, Switzerland, Finland, the Province of Alberta, Canada, and many others [Schick, 1990; Cothran, 1993; Ezzamel. 1993; Schedler, 1994]. These governments have rapidly downsized their public bureaucracies to more efficient types of organizations and replaced reliance on monopolistic agencies with policies favoring competition and contracting out on the assumption that competition, both of advice and delivery systems, is essential to

efficient service provision. As noted above, New Zealand has carried these reforms furthest. Most of the attention given to public administration in New Zealand has focused on its efforts to improve the quality of its financial reports and its performance measures. It is the first country to publish a rational set of general purpose financial statements: including a balance sheet showing assets and liabilities and an accrual-based statement of income and expenses. However, the changes made in the structure of its government are perhaps even more noteworthy [Scott, Bushnell, & Sallee, 1990; Ball, 1994]. First, Parliament privatized everything that was not part of the "core public sector." The residual "core" includes a mix of policy, regulatory and operational functions. Second, Parliament redefined its relationship with department heads. Departmental heads are appointed for fixed terms, with the possibility of reappointment. Each works to a specific contract, negotiated with the State Services Commission, which also monitors and assesses performance [hence, performance contacting, see World Bank, 1995; Islam, 1993]. Third, Parliament changed the way it appropriates funds. The basis of appropriation now depends on the department's ability to supply adequate information about its performance. All departments started out in Mode A; the majority have now progressed either to Mode B or C. Under Mode A, departments are treated as discretionary cost centers and Parliament appropriates funds for the acquisition of inputs. Under Mode B, departments are treated like quasi-profit or expense centers. Under Mode C, departments are treated like investment centers. Appropriations pay for the outputs produced by the department and for any changes in the department's net assets. Under both Modes B and C, managers are free to make decisions [under C most] about investments in plant and equipment. Parliament relies on the fact that managers' financial performance is one of the main bases upon which their performance is assessed to insure that their decisions will be sound [Gul, 1994; Halal, 1994; see, however, Burke, 1990]. Before-the-Fact Governance System Designs Before-the-fact management controls are demand-concealing mechanisms. Their distinguishing attribute is that they are executed before public money is spent. That is, they govern a service supplier's acquisition and use of both short-term and long-term assets, which means that the controller retains the authority to preview these decisions. Examples of before-the-fact management control include object-ofexpenditure appropriations and encumbrance accounts -- these govern the kind of assets that can be acquired by governmental departments and agencies; apportionments, position controls, and the fund and account controls that regulate the rate, timing, and purpose of public spending [Pitsvada, 1983; Schick, 1964, 1978], and the similar rules and regulations that govern the behavior of private contractors [Goldberg, 1976; Kovacic, 1990]. Readers will recognize the combination of before-the-fact controls and individual responsibility in traditional government budgets. Most will also recognize the

combination of before-the-fact controls and organizational responsibility in the socalled cost-plus contract -- the most notorious member of the administered or flexibleprice contract family. I generally prefer the term "flexible-price contract" to "cost-plus contract," because I am concerned primarily with distinguishing these contracts from fixed-price contracts. Flexible-price contracts comprehend a variety of incentive and cost-sharing contract designs other than the classic cost-plus contract. In turn, flexible-price contracts are included in the broader category of administered contracts [see Goldberg, 1976]. Most governmental budgets are spending plans. To distinguish them from responsibility budgets, I use the term "outlay budgets." Under outlay budgets, supplying organizations are guaranteed an allotment of funds in return for providing a service for a stipulated period. They usually receive the allotment regardless of the actual quantity or quality of services provided [which has the effect of treating every government department, agency, or bureau as a discretionary cost center]. Flexible-price contracts are basically production plans. They fully specify product or service characteristics and a usually a delivery schedule. Under flexible-price contracts, supplying organizations are guaranteed reimbursement [complete or partial] for any legitimate expense incurred providing the service. Hence, the prices they are paid for providing services are determined retrospectively according to settled costaccounting standards and the specifics of their contracts. To say that controllers focus their attention primarily on a supplier's asset-acquisition decisions does not mean that they ignore performance in executing outlay budgets or price in executing flexible-contracts. Controllers usually take account of information about the future consequences of a supplier's decisions as well as information on its current and past behavior. Their attention to performance may be tacit, as in the execution of traditional line-item budgets, rather than express, as in the execution of performance, program, or zero-base budgets. But the consequences of asset acquisition decisions usually matter a great deal to controllers. What is crucial is that, under these control systems designs, attention to the performance consequences of spending decisions is necessarily prospective in nature. Controllers will not reveal a demand schedule that fully expresses customer wants and preferences to suppliers or leave it to suppliers to figure out how best to satisfy those wants and preferences. Even under these control systems designs, the service provider, whether a department or an outside contractor, must assume some responsibility for managing output levels and delivery schedules, service quality, or price. Nevertheless, as I shall demonstrate, the logic of demand-concealing oversight requires supplier discretion to be carefully restricted. This means that suppliers must be subjected to fairly extensive, fairly detailed before-the-fact controls. An agency's outlay budget, for example, should identify all the asset acquisitions that it is to execute during the year, specify their magnitudes, and make it clear who is responsible for implementing each acquisition. Of course, constraining managerial discretion is not the only function that before-the-

fact controls perform. If it were, it would be hard to claim that they ever represented a least-objectionable alternative, let alone explain their widespread use. Rather, constraining managerial discretion is chiefly a means to an end, not an end in itself [Lewis & Sappington, 1989; Baron & Besanko, 1988; Reichelstein, 1992; Keren, 1989]. To show how subjects can be told what to do in such a way as to enforce efficiency, I will outline in detail the logic of employing the two basic before-the-fact governance system designs: flexible-price contracts and outlay budgets. Flexible Price Contracts There is a difference in the role that competition plays under fixed and flexible-price contracts. The difference is not that it takes place before the production of the service in question. [Economists refer to such a competitive regime as competition for the market, to distinguish it from competition in the market.] The recipients of fixed-price contracts often receive exclusive franchises prior to the delivery of services. The difference between the role played by competition under fixed and flexible-price contracts can be summarized by the expression "moral hazard." Under flexible-price contracts, competition cannot be relied upon to keep prices low, let alone to enforce efficiency [Cohen & Loeb, 1990]. Once a flexible-price contract has been signed, the supplier is free to dip his hand into the customer's pocket. Because the supplier is spending somebody else's money, the normal incentives to cost effectiveness largely disappear. Decisions that affect cost, service quality, or price [i.e., asset acquisition and use decisions] must be made during performance of a contract, but once a contract is signed, the supplier can no longer be fully trusted to make them [Thomas & Tung, 1992]. This conclusion holds especially where the customer ignores information regarding the performance of suppliers on earlier contracts or cannot [will not] award future contracts based on good performance. Even where fixed-price contracts are concerned, the refusal to take past performance into account discourages supplier loyalty and eliminates incentives to improve the quality of the product delivered [see Kelman, 1990; von Ungern-Sternberg, 1994]. Why, then, would a customer ever sign a flexible-price contract? Why not simply write fixed price contracts? The answer is that a fixed-price contract is the mechanism of choice where controllers know precisely what their principals want and there are several potential service suppliers who know how to meet those preferences. Under those circumstances, service quality attributes offered, promised delivery schedules, and bid price allow the customer to evaluate proposals satisfactorily. Regrettably, all of these conditions are likely only where the service in question is fairly simple and relatively standard -- garbage collection, for example [von Ungern-Sternberg, 1994]. Technological Uncertainty and Financial Risk In other cases, neither the controller nor the service supplier may have enough knowledge of the value of product attributes or production processes prior to performance of the contract to employ a fixed-price contract [Macintosh, 1993]. It is a simple fact of life that considerable experience is usually required to manage to a

narrow range of outcomes; where specialized or unique services are involved, no organization is likely to have the required experience. Consequently, any organization that agreed to produce a unique service, according to a specified schedule, at a fixed price would incur a large financial risk. This risk can be shifted, but it cannot be eliminated. Government, especially the federal government, can often bear financial risks better than supplying organizations. This is the case because of the size of the assets government commands and its ability to pool risk. Consequently, the cost to government will often be lower if it assumes a portion of the risk associated with acquisition of the service. Flexible or retrospective pricing is one way for the government to assume this risk. Moreover, the preferences of the government may change during performance of a contract. Under a fixed-price contract, it might not be possible to secure desired changes in service attributes if they involve increased costs for the vendor. Of course, the indifference of the government to financial risk is easily exaggerated. Government is not immune to financial risk, otherwise it would never make economic sense for it to rely on outlay budgets [Carlton and Perloff, 1990: 503]. Moreover, while it may be true that doing business with government is risky, the risk is mostly unsystematic, and may, therefore, be diversified away. Nevertheless. my point remains: customers should prefer flexible-price contracts to fixed-price contracts where it is cheaper for the customer to deal with uncertainty than it is for the contractor to do so or where the customer is more concerned with the ability of the contractor to provide a product that works than with price [see, however, Cohen & Loeb, 1989]. The question is: can before-the-fact controls be used to insure that the seller retains an interest in cost effectiveness? Using Before-the-Fact Controls to Enforce Efficiency under Flexible-Price Contracts Execution of a flexible-price contract must begin with a fully specified project spending plan detailing work to be performed, personnel, material, and equipment to be used, input quality standards, and scheduled milestones. This plan provides a basis for the enforcement of efficiency through bargaining and negotiations carried on during the performance of the contract [Reichelstein, 1992; Kathawala, 1990; Lewis & Sappington, 1989]. This process can be compared to a repeated prisoner's dilemma game, in which both parties have a common interest in reaching agreement but also have antagonistic interests with respect to the content of agreements. In this game, the customers try to get as much of what they want as they can at a given price, and the supplier tries to get the highest possible price for providing the service [Hofstede, 1967; see also Breton, 1989]. Bargaining power in a prisoner's dilemma game depends on the information available to each party. In particular, the customer's power is greatest where the customer [or his agent] knows the supplier's true cost schedule, but can withhold full information as to his preference or demand schedule [Morgan, 1949].

This is simply a more formal way of saying that strategic advantage accrues to the party that can best look ahead and reason back. To do so, one must be able to put oneself squarely in the other party's shoes [i.e., one must know the other party's costs under a variety of contingencies]. This is one purpose of "should-cost" models. It is also one of the purposes behind selecting agents who have walked in the other party's shoes [promoting trust is another] -- purchasing agents in manufacturing plants, for example, are usually recruited from the ranks of industrial salesmen and process engineers and vice versa. [The federal government's revolving-door laws enjoin this kind of personnel exchange, however. These laws probably increase the government's power to set an agenda but undoubtedly reduce its ability to understand or use the information that that power confers.] In a repeated game the information available to the customer [or his agent] will depend upon his ability to control the sequence of moves and countermoves that comprise the game. Public choice theorists refer to this condition as agenda control [Hammond, 1986]. Given comprehensive before-the-fact controls, under which changes can be made only with the prior approval of the other party or his agent, the party suggesting or initiating a change must necessarily reveal valuable information to the other. This can work to the advantage of the customer or the supplier, or both. For example, consider the following situation: ". . . contracts and specifications are drawn for . . . a ship and agreed to. . . . The contractor discovers he can do the welding of some plates less expensively by another means. About that time the client decides that some room on the ship should be larger.... The contractor can plead that he cannot easily change the room size: however, if the client will permit the altered welding maybe a deal can be struck" [Stark and Varley, 1983: 132]. But when flexible-price contracts are appropriately employed, there is every reason to believe that most change proposals will be initiated by the service supplier. Competition for the market provides an incentive to potential service suppliers to promise more than they can deliver, since contracts are usually awarded to the service suppliers who promise the most. Consequently, very few contract winners can make good on all their promises, especially where their managerial discretion is severely restricted by a full set of before-the-fact controls. This fact will usually become evident to the service supplier during performance of the contract. The service supplier will also learn of the tradeoffs between cost, service quality, and delivery schedule available to it and will eventually want to [or in some cases have to] change its promises or its plans. Under a full set of before-the-fact controls, such changes are contingent upon prior approval. To secure approval service suppliers must reveal information about their capabilities and trade-off possibilities. As a result, power to enforce the preferences of the government passed to purchasing officers -- but only if they know what they are doing and how to make it happen [Brown, Thorton, Buede, & Miller, 1992; Reichelstein, 1992; Lewis & Sappington, 1989]. A practical example of this process can be seen in the development and production of the Army's multiple launch rocket

system, where the relative expertise of the program manager permitted not only a confident source-selection decision but also highly effective contract management [Kennedy School, 1987]. Outlay Budgets A similar logic [Wildavsky and Hammond, 1965] applies where outlay budgets have a comparative advantage -- under decreasing costs to scale over an array of specialized or unique services [the following is based on Thompson, 1993]. Outlay budgets can help to keep prices low and to encourage efficiency where large, lumpy investments in specialized resources are needed in order to provide services, where each problem, client, or task performed is in some sense unique, and where the most serious problems are supposed to be dealt with first. Many organizational units in the government have these attributes. They supply outputs that are heterogeneous, hard to define, and nearly impossible to measure. As a consequence, "such bureaus seem always to be near the beginning or end of a comprehensive dismantling and restructuring since there is usually a sense that performance is not all that it might be. The performance of such bureaus can only be improved by budget augmentation. And, of course there are no guarantees in budget augmentation alone." Under outlay budgets, controllers retain authority to screen [or preaudit] all significant operating decisions. Presumably, they would like to know as much as possible about alternative choices and their consequences before managers of administrative units decide or acts. That is, they would like service suppliers to reveal comprehensive menus of all possible actions and price lists identifying the minimum cost of performing each action under every possible contingency. But wishes are not horses. There is no way to compel managers within an organization to reveal their units' true production functions -- even if they know what they are [and in most cases, they won't][Brown, Thorton, Buede, & Miller, 1992]. Consequently, controllers must usually settle for a practical approximation of this ideal. Here too, their authority provides a basis for the enforcement of efficiency through bargaining carried on during the execution of the budget. If controllers are skillful, if they play their cards right, their principals' preferences may be approximated, if not fully satisfied. That is, over time, they may be able to compel supplying organizations to address the "most important" problems and to address these problems at a reasonable cost. The more pressured the unit, the faster its movement. But, here too as with flexiblecontracts, the impetus for change must come from the operating manager. That is, responsibility center managers must have an interest in increasing their budgets. Otherwise they will be indifferent to circumstances in which low priority problems drain resources from problems that are of greater importance to their superiors or legislative sponsors. And here too, a full set of before-the-fact controls must be in place. At a minimum this means that controllers must specify when, how, and where

assets are to be employed and how much the subordinate can pay for them. In addition, money saved during the budget period from substituting less costly or more productive assets for more costly or less productive assets must revert to the treasury. Money lost in failed attempts to improve operations must be found elsewhere, and new initiatives requiring the acquisition of additional assets or reallocation of existing assets must be justified accordingly. These constraints are necessary because they prevent the operating manager from overstating asset requirements in high priority areas to get resources for use elsewhere, thereby creating a precedent for higher levels of support in the lower priority area. They are also necessary to force the operating manager to seek authorization to make changes in spending plans and, therefore, to reveal hidden preferences, capabilities, and trade-off possibilities. Where these conditions obtain, where a budget maximizer is subject to tight beforethe-fact controls, the controller can enforce efficiency during the budget period by requiring affirmative answers to the following questions: Will a proposed change permit the same activity to be carried out at lower cost? Will higher priority activities be carried out at the same cost? Will the proposed asset acquisitions or reallocations of savings support activities that have lower priority than those presently carried out? When operating managers know and understand these criteria, controllers will approve most changes in spending plans that the managers propose -- because managers will propose only mutually advantageous changes. Paradoxically, to say that before-the-fact controls are needed to reinforce the controller's bargaining power where outlay budgets are called for, does not mean that the controller must administer before-the-fact controls directly. Under certain conditions, trust can be substituted for bargaining and enforcement costs and authority to spend money, transfer funds, and fill positions can be safely delegated to operating managers. The threat that direct controls might be reimposed can be sufficient to insure that the operating managers ask the right questions of themselves and get the right answers to those questions before they take action -- which should go a long way toward insuring that managerial behavior corresponds to the customer preferences. This is obviously also the case where flexible-price contracts are appropriate. For example, the Department of Defense has a program that designates exemplary contractors and exempts them from direct oversight. The necessary conditions for relying on trust are: reimposition of controls must be a credible threat; the gain to the operating manager from delegation must more than offset the associated sacrifice in bargaining power [the manager of an aging agency in the stable backwaters of public policy, for example, may have nothing to gain from relief from before-the-fact controls, if the price of such relief is a change in business as usual]; and the controllers must be confident that their monitoring procedures, including post-audit, will identify violations of trust. As A. Breton and R. Wintrobe [1982; see also Gormley, 1989; McMaster, 1994]

explain, the sufficient condition is simply that the controller and the operating manager trust each other. Trust requires mutual respect and understanding and a common sense of commitment to a joint enterprise. In this context, its corollary is a willingness on the part of both the controller and the operating manager to eschew opportunistic behavior that would be costly to the long-term well-being of either the operating unit or the organization as a whole, including a willingness to forego opportunities to exploit events for personal advantage. Trust in a bargaining relationship can be poisoned by a single lapse of honesty or fair dealing, by contempt on the part of one of the parties for the abilities, judgment, or ethical standards of the other, by an excess of zeal or an overtly adversarial or confrontational approach, or by a simple lack of communication. In other words, the kind of trust that is needed to realize the best possible outcomes under a spending budget, or under a flexible-price contract for that matter, can be threatened by the very same conditions that threaten a business partnership -- or, more familiarly, a marriage. Of course, these conditions also apply where contractual relationships are concerned. According the original manager of Lockheed's Skunk Works, Kelly Johnson, there are fourteen rules for running a successful systems-development project, including complete control of the program, small military project offices, specifications agreed to in advance, timely funding, and minimal inspections and reports, but the most important is: "mutual trust between the ... project officer and the contractor" [Kitfield, 1989: 28]. All long-term buyer-seller relationships ultimately rely on incentives, even those governed by outlay budgets and flexible-price contracts. As we have seen, the difference is that when these governance system designs are employed, the incentives are deeply embedded in the process of budget or contract execution. Consequently, they are often overlooked. External observers fail to understand how they work; they also fail to understand how hard it is to make them work well. Effective execution of demand-concealing governance system designs -- flexible-price contracts as well as outlay budgets -- requires a great deal of savvy on the part of the controller. The skills required to execute demand-concealing governance system designs properly are certainly far rarer than are those needed to design and execute after-the-fact controls, for which a modicum of technical expertise will suffice. It usually takes years of training and practical experience, combined with a lot of common sense, to manage the complexities of bargaining in this context. The Costs of Over-Control All long-term buyer-seller relationships rely to a degree on standards and rules. Even where the government uses prospective price mechanisms to reimburse free-standing service providers, quality standards must often be specified and enforced. But demand-concealing governance system designs require considerably higher levels of reliance on before-the-fact controls and also on monitoring and enforcing compliance with them than do demand-revealing designs. At the very least, adoption of one of these governance system designs means that controllers must take steps to ensure that

suppliers fairly and accurately recognize, record, and report their expenses. This, in turn, requires careful definition of costs and specification of appropriate account structures, bookkeeping practices and internal controls, direct costing procedures, and the criteria to be used in handling overheads. But accurate accounts will not guarantee efficiency. Even if -- as is unlikely to be the case [Sourwine 1993; 1994]-- the service supplier's financial and operational accounts completely and accurately present every relevant fact about the operating decisions made by its managers, they will not provide a basis for evaluating the soundness of those decisions. This is because cost accounts can show only what happened, not what might have happened. They cannot show the range of asset acquisition choices and tradeoffs the supplier considered, let alone those that should have been considered but were not [Cohen & Loeb, 1990, 1989]. As I have noted, under outlay budgets and flexible-price contracts, asset acquisition decisions must be made, but the supplier cannot be trusted to make them efficiently. Consequently, suppliers must be denied some discretion to make managerial decisions. Hence, the federal acquisition regulations state: "Although the government does not expect to participate in every management decision, it may reserve the right to review the contractor's management efforts" In fact, where government decides which costs are allowable under the terms of a contract and which are not, it has the power to determine which activities and what items of expenditure the source will undertake. Furthermore, federal contracts typically assign to government the right to review make-or-buy decisions, to approve subcontractors and suppliers, to specify internal financial reporting, operational, cost accounting, and planning systems, wage rates, etc. A fundamental question is how far should this participation go. To what extent should the government replace or duplicate the supplier's managerial efforts? It is necessary to pose this question because before-the-fact controls are costly, both in terms of outof-pocket monitoring and reporting costs and in terms of benefits lost owing to the customer's inability to exploit fully the supplier's managerial expertise. Government or its agents will very seldom be more competent to make asset acquisition decisions than suppliers. The answer to this fundamental question is obvious: the minimum necessary, given the motivations of service suppliers and the incentives confronting them. Sometimes, "the minimum necessary" is a great deal indeed. How much depends on circumstance and the controller's skill in exploiting the opportunities that are created by the supplier's response to institutional constraints. The problem of figuring out how much constraint is necessary is, perhaps, best expressed in terms of minimizing the sum of the costs that arise out of opportunistic behavior on the part of suppliers [that is, to use the language of public discourse, waste, fraud, and abuse] and the costs of control, both direct and indirect. Economic theory tells us that this optimum is to be found where the marginal costs of controls equal their marginal benefits, as shown in Figure 5. [from Breton and Wintrobe, 1975;

see also Williamson, 1985 -- Williamson largely ignores, however, the particular institutional designs, including those outlined here, that actually drive costs -- Masten, 1993; Masten, Meehan, and Snyder, 1991; Harr, 1990; Harr and Godfrey, 1991, Reid, 1990]. The benefits produced by administrative controls are characterized by diminishing marginal returns. This is simply an abstract way of saying that controls that produce the greatest payoffs in terms of waste, fraud, and abuse avoided should be executed first. In contrast, the costs of control [the sum of direct and indirect cost of their execution] are characterized by increasing marginal costs. This assertion is, of course, debatable. To the extent that we are talking about the direct cost of controls -- the outof-pocket search, bargaining, monitoring, and enforcement costs that they impose on buyer and seller alike -- it might be more reasonable to presume constant marginal costs. However, it seems to me that the indirect costs of control -- stifled initiative, dulled incentives, and duplicative effort [Marcus, 1988], do increase at an increasing rate as the quantity of controls is increased. Hence, the total cost of controls is depicted by the triangle marked with diagonal lines in 5. The lightly shaded triangle represents the total benefits from controls. These consist of avoided waste, fraud, and abuse. The darker triangle shows the waste remaining. FIGURE 5 GOES ABOUT HERE The figure indicates that it almost never makes sense to try to eliminate abuse altogether. If the sum of the costs of opportunistic behavior on the part of suppliers plus the direct and indirect costs of controlling their behavior is minimized, some abuse must remain simply because it would be dreadfully uneconomical to eliminate it. Controls contribute nothing of positive value; their singular purpose lies in helping us to avoid waste. To the extent that they do what they are supposed to do, they can generate substantial savings. But it must be recognized that controls are themselves very costly [e.g., see Vena, 1994]. WHAT DIFFERENCE DOES IT MAKE? How much more efficient would the government be if governance system designs were carefully tailored to circumstances? Unfortunately, I don't have an unambiguous answer for this question. The theory outlined here states that both the ease with which the consequences of operating decisions can be monitored and the desirability of interorganizational competition matter. But most empirical studies overlook the distinction between the subject and the timing of controls. Hence, most don't show how the choice of mechanism affects costs. Moreover, I would like to distinguish the costs of mismatching controls from the costs of over-control or micromanagement. The consequences of micromanagement are far more frequently denounced than measured. Nevertheless, my reading of the evidence suggests that mismatched controls may add

five to twenty percent to the real cost of supplying services; over-control can add far more. Some of this evidence goes to the efficiency of privatizing various services, including custodial services and building maintenance, the operation of day-care centers, fire protection services, hospitals and health care services, housing, postal services, refuse collection, security services, ship and aircraft maintenance, waste water treatment, water supply, and weather forecasting. Because these are common, homogeneous services that do not require large, lumpy investments in extraordinary assets -- indeed, most have direct commercial counterparts -- they are appropriate candidates for a combination of organizational responsibility and after-the-fact control. Not surprisingly, the evidence shows that shifting from individual responsibility and before-the-fact controls to organizational responsibility and after-the-fact controls does reduce the cost of deliveringtheseservices [Domberger & Li, 1995; Szymanski & Wilkins, 1992; Haskel & Szymanski, 1993; see also Parker & Martin, 1995; Ehrlich, Gallais-Hamonno, Liu, & Lutter, 1994]. In his evaluation of the navy's commercial activities program, Paul Carrick [1988] of the Naval Postgraduate School, for example, found that the introduction of competition reduced service cost in eighty percent of the cases studied, with average savings of nearly forty percent -- the greater the number of competitors, the greater the average savings. Carrick also found that navy teams won over one third of the competitions carried out under OMB Circular A-76, achieving productivity improvements of thirteen percent on average. In these latter instances, the only significant change in governance relations was the shift from a demand-concealing to a demand-revealing governance system design, since most winning in-house teams were the incumbent suppliers. In another relevant study, which was carried out under the auspices of the Defense Enterprise Program, Scott Masten, James Meehan, and Edward Snyder [1991] carefully analyzed the determinants of control/transaction costs, holding production costs constant, in the construction of the SSN-21 Seawolf. Looking at 74 components -- 41 "make" items and 31 "buy" items, classified using benchmarks similar to those outlined here -- they determined that intraorganizational control costs represented about fourteen percent of total costs -- about thirteen percent for make components and seventeen percent for buy components. They also determined that the proper choice of governance mechanism permitted control costs to be substantially reduced. Making the right decisions resulted in control costs that were a third less than if all components had been made internally and half what they would have been if all components had been contracted out. Several analysts have found that, where appropriate, the substitution of after-the-fact for before-the-fact controls produces similar productivity gains. David J. Harr, for example, reports that replacing standard outlay budgets with responsibility budgets in Defense Logistics Agency depots was associated with efficiency increases of ten to 25 percent [Harr, 1990: 36; Harr and Godfrey, 1991: 68-9]. Other analysts who have

looked at the issue outside the defense arena make even stronger claims about the significance of the nature and timing of controls. Gordon Chase, for example, asserts that "wherever the product of a public organization has not been monitored in a way that ties performance to reward, the introduction of an effective monitoring system will yield a fifty percent improvement in the product in the short run" [Allison, 1982: 16]. Productivity increases of this size are not, in fact, unheard of. One frequently cited example of such an increase is the central repair garage of the New York Sanitation Department, which replaced its standard municipal outlay budget with a well designed responsibility budget. Robert Anthony claims that this reform increased productivity by nearly seventy percent -- from a high of 143 percent in the machine repair center to a low of nineteen percent in the motor room [Anthony and Young, 1988: 356-7]. William Turcotte's classic matched comparison of two state liquor agencies reports even larger productivity differences caused by the substitution of after-the-fact for before-the-fact controls [Turcotte, 1974]. The organizations studied by Turcotte ran sizable statewide programs featuring large numbers of local retail sales outlets. Furthermore, both defined their missions in identical terms -- maximization of profits from the sale of alcoholic beverages to the public. According to the theory outlined here, this situation called for the use of a rather simple, straightforward responsibility budget to govern local retail sales outlets. One of the states [Turcotte refers to it as state B] did in fact adopt this approach to governance -- treating outlets as a profit centers, holding outlet's mangers responsible for meeting profit targets, and granting them the operational discretion needed to meet those targets. The other state [Turcotte refers to it as state A] relied on outlay budgets and a comprehensive set of before-thefact controls. Turcotte reports that one consequence of the difference in the control strategies used by the two states is that direct control costs were twenty times higher in state A than in state B. The indirect costs of control were somewhat less disproportionate, but absolutely far greater in state A than in state B. Furthermore, individual stores in state B were twice as productive as stores in state A. Operating expenses for each dollar of sales in state A were 150 percent higher than in state B, administrative expenses were 300 percent higher, and inventory costs 400 percent higher. However, both Anthony and Turcotte appear to conflate the choice of governance designs with their intensity. New York's garages and State A's liquor stores were subject not only to the wrong kinds of controls but probably also to an excess of controls. One of the more melancholy properties of before-the-fact controls is their propensity to proliferate -- excess controls cause failures, which leads to more controls, and then more failure. I would not be surprised if two-thirds of the productivity differences reported here were due to over-control. Unworthy Candidates for After-the-Fact Controls The evidence also shows that instances in which a single supplier could more

efficiently supply the entire market are unworthy candidates for after-the-fact controls. The case that has been given the greatest amount of attention by industrialorganization economists is where customers artificially maintain rival suppliers [Anton and Yao, 1990]. There is, however, a more interesting case -- where design error produces a search failure [the technical term for this phenomenon is adverse selection]. Consider what can happen when rival companies are invited to bid on a fixed-price, sole-source contract to supply an advanced and, therefore, highly risky or uncertain technology. They will likely respond to such an invitation in one of two ways: 1. If they bid at all, they will bid high to protect themselves against the risk of failure; this means that the price of the service to the customer will be excessively high; or, even worse, 2. One or more of the bidders will underestimate the difficulty of the contract [or overestimate his capacity to meet its terms]. It will often be the low bidder, of course, and win the contract. If it is not very lucky, it will then be cursed by its victory. When it fails to deliver, as it mostly will, or threatens to slide into bankruptcy, the customer may have to step in to rescue the project and, in some cases, the company as well. Alas, open-bidding contests tend to select suppliers for their optimism [or their desperation], since the bidder with the most optimistic view of a project's feasibility will usually win the contract. Unfortunately, the most optimistic [or most desperate] bidder is unlikely to best understand the contract's technical feasibility. Indeed, it may overestimate its feasibility precisely because of its incompetence to carry it out. This likelihood probably doesn't matter very much where all of the bidders have the experience needed to manage to a narrow range of outcomes [i.e., there are a number of firms already supplying the market]. In that case, either comparative advantage will trump optimism or, if not, the advantage will usually be borderline. But this likelihood is crucial where bidders lack the experience needed to manage to a narrow range of outcomes -- as will usually be the case where advanced and, therefore, highly risky technologies are concerned. It is generally acknowledged that the worst defense procurement fiasco in recent memory, Lockheed's default on the C-5A program and the subsequent Department of Defense bailout, occurred because Lockheed misread the difficulty of designing and building the C-5A. Consequently, Lockheed submitted a bid on a fixed-price, total package procurement contract to design and deliver 150 C-5s that was fifty percent less than Boeing's, the next highest bid. Evidently, even if Lockheed had known what it was doing, which as it turned out it didn't, its bid would have been half-again too low. By the time the Department of Defense and Lockheed discovered magnitude of their error, they were in too deep to get out. The same thing happened more recently with the Navy's A-12 medium bomber program. Fortunately, when the A-12 development team got into trouble, Department of Defense decided the A-12 was expendable and canceled the contract, thereby

avoiding the worst aspects of the C-5A case. Nevertheless, this was evidently a near run thing. In the mid-1980s, Boeing took a bath on a series of fixed-price contracts that it sought and won despite lack of expertise. Again, fortunately for Boeing and ultimately for the taxpayer, Boeing's civilian profits were sufficient to make good its military losses. The point is that, where a unique product or service is involved, a single organization will often be uniquely qualified to supply it. Identifying the right supplier is, therefore, the key to getting the best product, on time, and at a reasonable price. In the private sector the search process is often fairly informal. Firms tend to rely on experience and reputation to pick suppliers. A decision to invite a proposal is usually tantamount to an offer to do business. Proposals are more often than not jointly developed. In the public sector, the process is more formal. Potential suppliers must appear on a list of qualified vendors. Customers must usually request proposals from more than one organization. Requests for proposals [RFP] are supposed to provide detailed explanations of what proposals should include and how they will be evaluated. Evaluations tend to be highly ritualized, with each section of a proposal assigned an explicit numerical score and its overall evaluation based upon the weighted sum of these scores. Only after evaluators have identified the best proposal will the government's representatives engage in ex parte conversations with the vendor to work out contractual details and nail down a best and final offer. Nevertheless, these search processes have similar aims and, I believe, more often than not produce similar outcomes. Where the program manager is authorized to issue an RFP rather than an invitation to bid, the formality described here is probably more apparent than real. Indeed, where a single supplier has an acknowledged technological lead, the law permits the request of a single proposal and a sole-source contract. Even where that is not the case, purchasing officers probably have a pretty good idea of the identity of the most qualified suppliers. RFPs cannot but reflect purchasing officers' subjective judgments about the importance of various product attributes and the competence of alternative vendors to deliver on their promises. The formality with which proposals are evaluated also serves to insulate them from the consequences of choice and, therefore, to protect them from the complaints of rebuffed vendors. This is especially important when, as happens in the best of circumstance, things go wrong. One must sympathize with procedures that work to minimize unjust criticism and keep hard-working contract officers out of trouble. Unfortunately, there is a tendency for RFPs to swell out of control, particularly where major projects are concerned. These RFPs tend to be very detailed; in response, proposals expand to carload size, and armies of evaluators are needed to score them. This is clearly wasteful, although probably less wasteful than when the contract is awarded solely on the basis of price and the winning contractor turns out to be incompetent. One lesson suggested by the example of the C5-A is that the costs arising from mismatched controls are asymmetrical in their composition: if other things were

equal, it would be far more prohibitive to rely on after-the-fact controls where beforethe-fact controls are called for than vice versa -- evidently because moral hazard is easier to fix than adverse selection. This lesson is reinforced by Masten, Meehan, and Snyder's [1991] finding that, although making "buy" components would have caused internal control costs to be about seventy percent higher than they actually were, contracting out "make" items would have caused control costs to increase even more - nearly two hundred percent, from thirteen percent of the total value of the items to over thirty percent. But other things are not all equal. Not only are after-the-fact controls easier to use, they are also self-limiting. Where the purchaser relies on demand-revealing controls, over-control produces negative feedback in the form of higher prices or reduced output that causes controls to be cut back. Before-the-fact controls often produce positive feedback that leads to their multiplication. Carrying Legitimate and Necessary Controls to Self-Defeating Extremes Organization theorists have long understood that failure induces certain predictable responses -- and that these responses, in turn, produce certain equally predictable consequences. Pradip N. Khandwalla [1978], for example, observes that threatening situations always generate pressures for direct controls: standardization of procedures, institution of rules and regulations, and centralization of authority. Michael Crozier [1964] argues that failures to meet expectations almost inevitably produce a cycle of rule-making, more failure, and then more rules. Anthony and Young [1988: 562] claim that detailed rules result from encrustation: an abuse occurs, someone decides that "there ought to be a law," and a rule is promulgated to avoid the abuse in the future; but such rules often continue after the need for them has passed. No one who has the power to rescind the rule may ever consider "whether the likelihood and seriousness of error is great enough to warrant continuation of the rule." Jack H. Knott and Gary J. Miller [1987: 108, 257, 262-5] observe that stricter rules and tighter oversight often produces positive short-term results, but that they also exacerbate the factors that cause organizational failure. Furthermore, extra supervisors giving more orders and monitoring effort more closely may make subordinates "even more resentful of their status than before, which may make subordinates even more unwilling to trust or cooperate with management. Which leads to more stringent rules, greater reliance on hierarchy, and more hostility on the part of subordinates and on and on." Robert Merton [1957; see also Marcus, 1988] concludes that reliance on rules and regulations reflects a concern with error prevention and that an emphasis on error prevention, rather than measured performance, tends to result in organizational rigidity and ultimately total ineffectiveness. In other words, the inclination to respond to abuses with calls for more and better rules is normal, as is responding to failure with ever more inflexible and comprehensive rules, greater oversight and closer supervision. William Kovacic [1990: 112] provides an example here of the cyclical process by which before-the-fact

controls induce failure and thereby additional controls in the Department of Defense. "Because DOD's contracting personnel are overmatched by their industry counterparts, Congress and DOD have sought to rebalance the playing field by mandating layers of procedural safeguards and intricate review processes. By having large numbers of less talented eyes look long enough at a given problem, it is assumed that DOD can prevent Contractors from picking its pocket." In other words, asymmetries in human capital between government and its suppliers help to explain the size and content of the existing control regime. Kovacic [1990: 112-13] further observes that: "[t]his strategy has enormous costs. Programs proceed at a glacial pace as contractors and government purchasing personnel carry out required review and auditing procedures. Authority is dispersed so widely among a large collection of program managers, contract officers, senior [government] executives, auditors, and inspectors that accountability vanishes. Government payrolls expand, and contractors hire legions of contract administrators to respond to the requirements of large multitiered ... procurement organizations." Excess Controls One critical piece of evidence on the burden of procurement controls in the United States was provided recently by a study described in the Economist [Anon. 1993]. This study was conducted by Software Productivity Research of Burlington, Massachusetts, and used a method called function-point analysis to estimate the productivity and cost-effectiveness of three kinds of software projects: small management-information systems, large-scale systems, and military systems. Function-point analysis is widely used in the software business because it can be applied to any piece of software written in any computer language. Both Texas Instruments and Unysis sell computer-aided engineering programs that automatically compute five things in terms of a measure called "function points": inputs, outputs, inquiries, files, and interfaces, weighted according to the complexity of the codes needed to provide them. Once a software project's function points have been measured, it is a simple matter to calculate its cost per function point, the standard measure of cost effectiveness used in the industry, and the number of function points produced per systems engineer, a standard measure of productivity. Applying function-point analysis to thousands of software projects selected from around the world, Software Productivity Research found that American military software productivity lags behind France, Israel, Korea, the United Kingdom, Germany, Sweden, and even Italy. The problem is not that American software engineers are inherently unproductive. On the contrary. The same study showed that the United States is in first place in the production of management-information systems and runs a strong second to Japan in large-scale systems software projects. Software Productivity Research also discovered that differences in cost per function point are due primarily to the amount of paperwork generated per point. Preparation of this paperwork takes a lot of engineering time, but contributes no function points to

the finished product. American military projects generate five times as much paper and cost twelve times as much per point as management-information systems projects. They are six times as costly per function point as big systems software projects, which are arguably comparable to military software projects. This comparison is particularly telling. Software production is mostly overhead -- product development, design, documentation, and administrative support; no production labor, no capital, no materials. Once codes have been written and documentation prepared, software can be reproduced innumerable times at almost no cost. What this comparison suggests is that, for activities like software engineering, federal procurement procedures may account for more than half their cost. There is a second reason for emphasizing this evidence. This one of a very small number of studies that that directly estimates the cost burden imposed by federal acquisition procedures. There are other estimates, of course. One was provided by the Grace Commission [President's Private Sector Survey on Cost Control [Grace Commission], 1983: 146; see also MacManus, 1991; Lamm, 1988]. The Grace Commission estimated that complying with procurement regulations accounted for at least ten percent of the cost of the Pentagon's purchases, about $12 billion a year. The Grace Commission based its estimate on the observation that oil companies give substantial discounts to most bulk purchasers -- up to fifteen percent in some cases. However, because of the costs of complying with cumbersome procurement regulations, many suppliers refuse to offer similar discounts to the Department of Defense. Consequently, the Department of Defense pays market prices for about eighty percent of the gas and oil that it buys. Petroleum products are at one end of the spectrum and software engineering the other. Raw materials and processing costs account for nearly all oil company expenses; overheads for nearly all software company expenses. Based on a survey of 206 firms, Gansler [1995: 123-124] found that the typical defense plant spends about four times as much to administer contracts as its commercial counterpart and employs four times as many administrators, and that on average defense goods cost 30 to 50 percent more than their commercial equivalents. But for high-tech products, costs are typically 200 to 500 percent higher. These studies also show why it is that good estimates of the costs of before-the-fact controls are lacking: the accounting standards established by the federal government that tell contractors how to measure costs simply do not provide this information. Indeed, the main objective of these procedures is not cost finding, but the identification of allowable/disallowable costs. Accounting for Transaction Costs In the typical defense plant, direct manufacturing labor accounts for only ten to twenty percent of costs; materials and purchased components typically account for thirty to forty percent more. This leaves at least fifty percent for overheads. And that's the typical defense firm; as we noted earlier, direct labor costs are practically irrelevant in

the increasing number of firms that rely on flexible computer-aided design and manufacturing. Figuring out what drives overheads, identifying cost drivers that do not add value to end products, and changing them, ought to be the purpose of cost analysis. The software productivity study is useful precisely because it took this approach -paperwork was identified as a cost driver as well as a source of unproductive expense. The studies reported by Gansler all took this approach as well. Unfortunately, this is not government's typical approach to cost measurement. Its accounting standards require suppliers to focus on direct labor and materials costs and to treat most other costs as fixed. They call for overheads to be assigned to products on the basis of standard labor hours or machine time. While this approach may have made sense thirty years ago, when efficient use of direct labor was the key to manufacturing productivity, it is unrealistic today and has probably always had the effect of diverting attention from costs that arise out of the procurement process. Until government accounting standards are changed to focus on overhead and transaction costs, we won't know how much federal controls really increase costs. For example, everyone believes that procurement regulation increases paperwork burdens -- that's the gist of both the Software Productivity Research study and the Grace Commission's opportunity-cost analysis. But increased red tape is just the tip of the iceberg. Most of the cost of procurement controls result from their effect on operating processes and the use of assets. This was forcefully brought home to me by an experience working with a firm that makes trailers for the Army. Trailers are technologically unsophisticated and their manufacture appears to be a pretty straightforward exercise in metal bashing. The company in question established a second production line at a new location for its military business, because that was the easiest way to comply with federal costaccounting standards and other government reporting requirements. Of course, duplication of facilities increases the average cost of the firm's trailers -- an increase that should properly be attributed to the policies that caused it and not to the trailers themselves. This firm tries to practice the principles of lean management and just-in-time inventory control. On its commercial side, it has succeeded fairly well. Its inventories have been cut to the bone, and manufacturing-cycle time -- the time from the start of production to shipment of the finished product -- is usually less than thirty-six hours. Products are shipped to customers as soon as they are finished, which allows the firm to apply just-in-time inventory control to the production of finished goods as well as to raw materials, components purchased elsewhere, and work-in-progress inventories. On its military side, total inventories were once twenty-five times higher. This doubled the company's working capital requirements and increased rents, insurance, utilities, and depreciation, since they also varied directly with inventory size. Inventory size was higher on the military-production line because cycle time was

higher; cycle time was higher because the Army required inspection at each stage of manufacture and because the Army preferred to take delivery in large batches. Increased cycle time also meant less intensive use of the firm's plant and equipment, which increased each trailer's capital cost. The same thing happened with management time. Consequently, although direct labor costs per trailer were not significantly higher, overhead costs per trailer were more than twice as high on the military line as on the commercial line. What about Benefits? To say that controls have high costs does not necessarily mean that they cost too much. Evidence of over-control requires information on the benefits as well as the costs of control. For example, earlier I used fruitcakes to illustrate the ludicrous extent of federal procurement controls, I must nevertheless acknowledge that the Department of Defense pays only $1.50 a pound for its fruitcake -- about half the price in civilian markets. Are the benefits of control generally proportionate to their costs? One agency, as an example, the Defense Contract Audit Agency proudly claims that it saved the American taxpayer about $7 billion in 1988 and cost only $1 billion. Its criminal investigations generated an additional $300 million in fines and penalties and cost only $84 million . This sounds like a pretty good deal, even if one allows for the source of the claims. However, the rule of thumb is that monitoring and enforcing regulations imposes private costs of about $10 for every dollar spent by the government [Weidenbaum and DeFina, 1978]. Since these costs are ultimately borne primarily by the firm's customers and since in this instance the customer is the government, this multiplier implies that Defense Contract Audit Agency regulation imposed costs of $10 billion to save $7 billion, in the first instance, and $1 billion to save $300 million in the second -- in other words, it cost on average more than $1 to save $1, which is consistent with marginal costs of $2 and $4. Evidence that marginal costs are greater than marginal benefits, let alone four times greater, is prima facie evidence of over-control. Looking beyond government, it is not hard to find evidence that the marginal benefits produced by some before-the-fact controls are actually negative. Alfred A. Marcus, for example, shows that increasing the number of safety rules governing the operation of nuclear power plants, together with greater oversight and closer supervision, actually had the effect of degrading reactor safety [Marcus, 1988]. Anecdotal evidence suggests that this is often the case where defense procurement is concerned, especially where demand-concealing governance mechanisms are called for, but where a plethora of rules deny the program managers the authority to trade off costs, schedules, and performance. Finally, excessive reliance on rules often produces organizations that are simultaneously over controlled and out of control. Turcotte [1974: 69], for example, found that the managers of retail stores in state A were subject to more rules and far stricter executive and legislative oversight than their counterparts in state B, but, even

so, were far less responsive to the wishes of their political masters. Evidently the managers of retail stores in state A were subject to so many rules that none of them mattered very much. Consequently, over-control led straightaway to loss of control. How Well Are Designs Matched to Circumstances? The match between the governance mechanisms used by government and the cost behavior of the goods and services it produces and acquires is frequently imperfect. Yet the mismatches are, perhaps, not as pervasive as one might fear. Among the services that the Government now contracts out, there are very few it should perform for itself. And while there are many minor services that the Government performs for itself that should probably be let to contract, there are fewer critical ones. At the same time, there are clear opportunities for subjecting many of the common, everyday services used and/or produced by government to competition. Many of these services do not require large, lumpy investments in extraordinary assets and some already have direct commercial counterparts. For example, only 58,000 Department of Defense employees are subject to A-76 competitions under the government's commercial activities program, about one-tenth of the 540,000 currently performing activities with private sector counterparts [Carrick, 1988: 521]. Congress has formally exempted 250,000 Department of Defense employees from the commercial activities program. Most of the rest of the Department of Defense's employees are effectively exempted from competitive challenge by the absence of cost information. In many cases, the Department of Defense simply doesn't have the unit cost information it needs to implement the A-76 program. Government policy currently restricts the use of flexible-price contracts to situations characterized by considerable procurement risk. In other contracts, the degree of incentive is supposed to be calibrated to the project's riskiness. The first ship in a multi-ship construction program, for example, is supposed to be constructed under a cost-plus contract, while later editions are required to be built under under incentive and eventually fixed-price contracts, on the assumption that experience permits the service supplier to manage to a narrower range of cost outcomes and, therefore, to assume a greater share of the risk burden. Where production volume is sufficient, government policy calls for the maintenance of long-term contractual relations with two or more producers, as second sourcing permits renewed competition at each renegotiation of production contracts. On the face of it, these look like sound policies. Moreover, it seems that the government generally makes the proper transition from cost-plus to award-fee contracts as it moves from design to prototype development. During the mid to late 1980s, however, the federal government was under excessive pressure to sign to fixed-price contracts awarded by competitive bidding on major systems development projects -- the big ticket projects that account for eighty percent of federal procurement spending. much of this pressure it was a consequence of the

Competition in Contracting Act. Its intensity was reflected in the decline in flexibleprice contracts from sixty percent of the Department of Defense's major purchases in 1978 to twenty percent in 1988 [Pilling, 1989: 3-7]. This was excessive. Some of the adverse effects of favoring fixed-price contracts and competitive bidding regardless of circumstances have been mitigated by governmentsponsored changes in production technology and by its imaginative use of quasivertical integration. They have not been eliminated altogether [Pilling, 1989]. Besides, multiple sources are required to exploit competition and that runs counter to the current need for a drastic culling of defense firms. One of the biggest needs of government is a modern activity-based costing system. Obviously, better cost information is necessary to carry out make-or-buy decisions, but that is not the most important use for such a system. Rather, adequate cost accounts are needed to implement a sound responsibility budgeting system, and the lack of a sound responsibility budgeting system is by far the greatest mismatch between governance system design and circumstances in government. It is not unlikely that such a system would show that many of the activities performed by government, especially overhead and supply activities, are essentially unproductive and could be eliminated. CONCLUSION Steven Kelman [1991: 196] argues that one reason for government's excessive reliance on before-the-fact controls is an intellectual failure to understand their high costs, especially the cost they exact in terms of mission performance. If Kelman is correct, then the situation is happy indeed. Intellectual failures are fairly easy to fix. But Kelman's diagnosis is also an indictment of many in public administration. It implies that, in our research, our literature, and our teaching, we have failed to show the need for alternative institutional designs and governance mechanisms. And the simple fact is that governance mechanisms have not been developed -- especially innovative administrative controls -- to match contemporary government's tactics and responsibilities. Many do not even understand that this task should be central to the enterprise of public administration. Fortunately, the field is changing. Public administration has accepted Mosher's challenge to look outward more, inward less -- to understand a wide variety of institutional arrangements: regulation, incentives in the form of loans and taxes, contracting, and quasi-governmental enterprises. Despite their efforts, however, many remain equivocal. Why? Since the new economics of organization provides a satisfactory framework for analysis, the answer must lie in an inability to look beyond superficial institutional dissimilarities to common structural elements -- an inability to

see that the entire spectrum of institutional arrangements is put together from a common set of materials [the allocation of property rights and accounting for the ownership and use of assets] and that, to design effective institutions, the materials used must fit together harmoniously to minimize the sum of production and transaction costs. This essay neither promises nor provides a complete answer to the question of how institutions are should be put together, how property rights should be allocated within and between organizations or accounted for. It is, I hope, a step in the right direction. BIBLIOGRAPHY
Admati, A., Pfleiderer, and J. Zechner. "Shareholder Activism, Risk Sharing and Financial Market Equilibrium," Journal of Political Economy. 102/6 [1994], 1097-1130. Aertsen, F. "Contracting Out the Physical Distribution Function: A Trade-off between Asset Specificity and Performance Measurement," International Journal of Physical Distribution & Logistics Management. 23/1 [1993], 23-29. Ahlbrandt, R. "Efficiency in the Provision of Fire Services," Public Choice. 16 [fall 1973], 1-15. Alchian, A.A. and Demsetz, H. "Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization," American Economic Review. 62/5 [Dec. 1972], 777-795. Allison, Graham T., Jr.. "Public and Private Management: Are They Fundamentally Alike in all Unimportant Particulars?" in Robert T. Golembiewski and Frank Gibson, eds., Readings in Public Administration, 4th ed. Boston: Houghton Mifflin [1983], 1-19. Anon. "A Guide to Better Buying," The Economist. [October 18, 1986], 71. Anon. "Software Engineering: Made to Measure," The Economist. [January 23, 1993], 79. Antoci, Angelo. "A Public Contracting Evolutionary Game with Corruption," Zeitschrift Fuer Nationaloekonomie. 61/2 [1995], 89-122. Anton, J.J. and Dennis A. Yao. "Measuring the Effectiveness of Competition in Defense Procurement," Journal of Policy Analysis and Management. 9/1 [Fall 1990], 60-79. Anthony, R. N. Planning and Control Systems: A Framework for Analysis. Boston MA: Graduate School of Business Administration, Harvard University [1965]. Anthony, R.N. "New Frontiers in Defense Financial Management," The Federal Accountant. XI [June 1962], 13-32. Anthony, R.N. and Govindarajan, Vijay. Management Control Systems, 8th edition. Chicago: Irwin [1995]. Anthony, R. N. and Young D. Management Control in Nonprofit Organizations., 4th edition. Homewood IL: Irwin [1988].

Arrow, K. "The Organization of Economic Activity: Issues Pertinent to the Choice of Market versus Non-market Allocation," in The Analysis and Evaluation of Public Expenditure: The PPB System. US Congress, Joint Economic Committee, Washington DC: US Govt. Printing Office [1969]. Bailey, M.J. "Defense Decentralization through Internal Prices," in S. Enke ed. Defense Management. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall [1967], 337-352. Baker, George P. "Incentive Contracts and Performance Measurement," Journal of Political Economy. 100/3 [June 1992], 598-614. Baker, George., Gibbons, Robert , and Murphy, Kevin J. "Subjective Performance Measures in Optimal Incentive Contracts," Quarterly Journal of Economics. 109/4 [Nov. 1994], 1125-1156. Balachandran, Kashi R., and Ronen, Joshua. "Incentive Contracts When Production Is Subcontracted," European Journal of Operational Research. 40/2 [May 25, 1989], 169-185. Balachandran, Kashi R., and Srinidhi, Bin. "On the Control of Public Service," Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance. 9/1 [New Series] [Winter 1994], 21-39. Ball, Ian. "Reinventing Government: Lessons Learned from the New Zealand Treasury," Government Accountants Journal. 43/3 [Fall 1994], 19-28. Baron, David P., and Besanko, D. "Monitoring of Performance in Organizational Contracting: The Case of Defense Procurement," Scandinavian Journal of Economics. 90/3 [1988], 329-356. Barzel, Y. "Measurement Costs and the Organization of Markets," Journal of Law and Economics. 25/1 [Jan. 1982], 27-48. Barzelay, M., with Armajani, B.J. Breaking through Bureaucracy: A New Vision for Managing in Government. Berkeley: University of California Press [1992]. Bates, Laurie J. "Property Tax Collector Performance and Pay," National Tax Journal. 46/1 [March 1993], 23-31. Becker, G. "Public Policies, Pressure Groups, and Dead Weight Costs," Journal of Public Economics. 28/2 [1985], 371-400. Becker, S. W., and Neuhauser, D. The Efficient Organization. Elsevier-North Holland Publishing Company [1975]. Behn, R. "Public Management: Should it Strive to Be Art , Science, or Engineering," J ournal of Public Administration Research and Theory." 6/1 [1996], 91-193. Behn, R.D. "The Big Questions of Public Management," Public Administration Review. 55/4 [1995], 313-324. Bell, Christopher R. "Between Anarchy and Leviathan: A Note on the Design of Federal States," Journal of Public Economics. 39/2 [Jul. 1989], 207-221. Bellamy, Christine, and Taylor, John A. "Reinventing Government in the Information Age," Public Money & Management. 14/3 [July-September 1994], 59-62. Belman, Dale, and Heywood, John S. "Public Wage Differentials and the Public Administration 'Industry'," Industrial Relations. 27/3 [Fall 1988], 385-393.

Bendor, J. "Formal Models of Bureaucracy: A Review," in Naomi B. Lynn and Aaron Wildavsky, eds., Public Administration: The State of the Discipline. Chatham, NJ: Chatham House Publishers [1990], 373-417. Bendor, J., and Hammond, Thomas H. "Rethinking Allison's Models," American Political Science Review. 86/2 [June 1992], 301-322. Beniger, James R. The Control Revolution:: Technological an Economic Origins of the Information Society. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press [1986]. Bergstrom, T., and Goodman, R. "Private Demands for Public Goods," American Economic Review. 63/3 [1972], 280-296. Bish, R. L., and Nourse. H. O. Urban Economics and Policy Analysis. New York, McGraw-Hill Book Company [1975]. Blais, Andr and Dion, Stphane, eds. The Budget-Maximizing Bureaucrat: The Empirical Evidence. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press [1991]. Blau, Peter M., and, Meyer, Marshall W. Bureaucracy in Modern Society, second edition. Random House [1971]. Borcherding, T.E. "Some Revisionist Thoughts on the Theory of Public Bureaucracy." European Journal of Political Economy. 4/1 [1988], 47-64. Borcherding, T.E. "Toward a Positive Theory of Public Sector Supply Arrangements," in J.R.S. Prichard, ed., Crown Corporations in Canada: The Calculus of Instrument Choice. Toronto: Butterworths [1983]. Borcherding, T.E. "The Sources of Growth of Public Expenditures in the United States, 1902-1970," in Borcherding, ed. Budgets and Bureaucrats. Duke [1977], 46-70. Borcherding, T.E. Budgets and Bureaucrats: The Sources of Government Growth. Durham, NC: Duke University Press [1977]. Bos, Dieter, and Peters, Wolfgang. "Privatization, Internal Control, and Internal Regulation," Journal of Public Economics. 36/2 [July 1988], 231-258. Bowen, H. R. "The Interpretation of Voting in the Allocation of Resources," Quarterly Journal of Economics. 58/1 [1943], 27-48. Bower, Joseph. The Resource Allocation Process. Boston: Harvard Business School Division of Research [1970]. Box, Richard. "Public Choice and Public Administration," Public Administration Review. 52/3 [May 1992], 303304. Breit, W. "Income Redistribution and Efficiency Norms." In Hochman and Peterson, eds. Redistribution through Public Choice. New York: Columbia University Press [1974], 3-21. Breton, Albert. "The Growth of Competitive Governments," Canadian Journal of Economics. 22/4 [Nov. 1989], 717-750. Breton, A. and Wintrobe, R. "The Equilibrium Size of a Budget-Maximizing Bureau." Journal of Political Economy. 83/2 [1975], 195-207.

Breton, A. and Wintrobe, R. The Logic of Bureaucratic Conduct. New York: Cambridge University Press [1982]. Brock, W.A. and S.P. Magee. "The Economics of Special Interest Politics," American Economic Review. 68/2 [May 1978], 246-50. Brown, Pamela C., Thornton, James R., Buede, Dennis M., and Miller, Jeffrey B. "A Revelation Scheme for Allocating Organizational Resources," Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 18/2 [July 1992], 201-214. Buchanan, James M. "An Economic Theory of Clubs," Economica. 32/1 [February 1965], 1-14. Buchanan, James M. The Demand and Supply of Public Goods. Chicago: Rand McNally [1968]. Buchanan, J. M. Cost and Choice: An Inquiry into Economic Theory. Chicago, Illinois, The University of Chicago Press [1969]. Buchanan, James M., and Tullock, G. The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press [1962]. Buchanan, J. M., Tollison, R.D., and Tullock, G., eds. Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press [1980]. Burke, Chris. "Internal Markets: The Road to Inefficiency? Public Administration. 68/3 [Autumn 1990], 389-396. Burkhead, Jesse, and Miner, J. Public Expenditure. Chicago, Aldine, Atherton [1971]. Button, Kenneth and Swann, Dennis, eds. The Age of Regulatory Reform. New York: Oxford University Press [1989]. Campbell, Tim S., Chan, Yuk-Shee, and Marino, Anthony M. "Incentive Contracts for Managers Who Discover and Manage Investment Projects," Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 12/3 [Dec. 1989], 353-364. Carlton, D. W. and Perloff, J. M. Modern Industrial Organization. Glenview, IL: Scott, Foresman-Little, Brown Higher Education [1990]. Carrick, P.M. "New Evidence on Government Efficiency." Journal of Policy Analysis and Management. 7/3 [Spring 1988], 518-28. Carroll, Kathleen A. "Bureau Competition and Inefficiency: A Reevaluation of Theory and Evidence," Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 13/1 [Jan. 1990], 21-40 Carroll, Kathleen A. "Industrial Structure and Monopoly Power in the Federal Bureaucracy: An Empirical Analysis," Economic Inquiry. 27/4 [Oct. 1989], 683-703. Caves, D.W., Christensen, Laurits R., Swanson, Joseph and Tretheway, Michael "Economic Performance of U.S. and Canadian Railways: The Significance of Ownership and the Regulatory Environment," in W.T. Stanbury and F. Thompson, eds., Managing Public Enterprises. New York: Praeger [1982], 123-151. Chandler, A. Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of Industrial Enterprise. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press [1962]. Cheung, S.N.S. "The Fable of the Bees," Journal of Law & Economics. 16 [April 1973], 11-33.

Chia, Yew Ming. "Decentralization, Management Accounting System Information Characteristics and Their Interaction Effects on Managerial Performance: A Singapore Study," Journal of Business Finance & Accounting. 22/6 [Sept. 1995], 811-830. Choate, G. M. and Thompson, F. "Biased Budgets," Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 14/3 [Fall 1990], 425-434. Choate, G. M. and Thompson, F. "Budget Makers as Agents: An Investigation of Discretionary Behavior under State-Contingent Rewards," Public Choice. 58/1 [1988], 3-20. Chubb, J.E., and Moe, T.M. "Politics, Markets, and the Organization of Schools," American Political Science Review. 82/4 [December 1988], 1065-1087. Coase, R. "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics. 3/1 [1960], 1-44. Coase, R. "The Lighthouse in Economics," Journal of Law and Economics. 17/2 [October 1974], 357-76. Cohen, Susan I., and Loeb, Martin P. "On the Optimality of Incentive Contracts in the Presence of Joint Costs," International Journal of Industrial Organization. 8/3 [Sept. 1990], 405-416. Cohen, Susan I., and Loeb, Martin P. "The Demand for Cost Allocations: The Case of Incentive Contracts Versus Fixed-Price Contracts," Journal of Accounting & Public Policy. 8/3 [Fall 1989], 165-180. Cohen, Susan I., Loeb, Martin P., and Stark, Andrew W. "Separating Controllable Performance from NonControllable Performance: The Case of Optimal Procurement Contracting," Management Accounting Research. 3/4 [Dec. 1992], 291-306. Colbert, Gary J. "A Multi-Case Investigation of a Theory of the Transfer Pricing Process," Accounting, Organizations & Society. 20/6 [Aug. 1995], 423-456. Conybeare, John A.C. "Bureaucracy, Monopoly and Competition: A Critical Analysis of the Budget-Maximizing Model of Bureaucracy," American Journal of Political Science. 28/3 [August 1984], 479-502. Cooley, Thomas F., and Smith, Bruce D. "Dynamic Coalition Formation and Equilibrium Policy Selection," Journal of Monetary Economics. 24/2 [Sept. 1989], 211-233. Cooper, Robin and Turney, Peter B. "Internally Focused Activity-Based Cost Systems," in R.S. Kaplan, ed., Measures for Manufacturing Excellence. Boston: Harvard Business School Press [1990], 291-308. Corbett, Charles J. "Decentralization of Responsibility for Site Decontamination Projects: A Budget Allocation Approach," European Journal of Operational Research. 86/1 [Oct. 1995], 5, 103-119. Cornes, R. and Sandler, Todd The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club Goods. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press [1986]. Cothran, Dan A. "Entrepreneurial Budgeting: An Emerging Reform?" Public Administration Review. 53/5 [Sep/Oct 1993], 445-454. Coughlin, Peter J. "Electoral Politics, Interest Groups, and the Size of Government," Economic Inquiry. 28/4 [Oct 1990], 682-705. Cowan, Tyler, ed. The Theory of Market Failure. Fairfax, VA: George Mason University Press [1988].

Crozier, Michael. The Bureaucratic Phenomenon. Chicago: University of Chicago Press [1964]. Dalhman, C. "The Problem of Externality," Journal of law and Economics. 23/2 [1979], 140-62. Davidow, W.H., and Malone, M.S. The Virtual Corporation: Structuring and Revitalizing the Corporation for the 21st Century. New York: Harper-Collins [1992]. Davis, O.A., and A.B. Whinston. "On the Distinction between Public and Private Goods," American Economic Review. 57/2 [May 1967], 360-73. De Fraja, Giovanni. "Productive efficiency in Public and Private Firms," Journal of Public Economics. 50/1 [Jan. 1993], 15-30. De Groot, Hans. "Decentralization Decisions in Bureaucracies as a Principal-Agent Problem," Journal of Public Economics. 36/3 [Aug. 1988], 323-337. Deller, Steven C. "An Application of a Test for Allocative Efficiency in the Local Public Sector," Regional Science & Urban Economics. 20/3 [Nov. 1990], 395-406. Deller, Steven C. "Pareto-Efficiency and the Provision of Public Goods within a Rural Setting," Growth & Change. 21/1 [Winter 1990], 30-39. Demski, J. and Feltham, G. Cost Determination. Ames: Iowa State University Press [1976]. Denzau, A.T. and R.J. Mackay. "Benefit Shares and Majority Voting," American Economic Review. 66/1 [March 1976], 69-76. Dixon, Warren A. The Demand and Supply of Collective Goods: From a Market Exchange to the Political Process. Unpublished dissertation, University of Oregon, 1970. Dixit, A. and Pindyk, R. Investment Under Uncertainty. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press [1994]. Domberger, Simon, and Li, Eric Ah Lik. "An Ordered-Probit Analysis of Price and Performance in Competitively Tendered Contracts," Australian Economic Review. 110 [Second Quarter 1995], 14-22. Donahue, John D. The Privatization Decision: Public Ends, Private Means. New York: Basic Books, 1989. Dorkey, Frank C., and Jarrell, Gregg A. "Calculating Proper Transfer Prices," Public Utilities Fortnightly. 127/1 [Jan 1, 1991], 25-27. Douglas, Evan J., and Santerre, Rexford E. "Incentive Contracts and Stockholder Monitoring: Substitute Sources of Executive Compliance," Quarterly Review of Economics & Business. 30/2 [Summer 1990],\ 24-31. Downs, A. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row [1957]. Downs, A. "Why the Government Budget is Too Small in a Democracy," World Politics. 12/4 [winter 1959/60], 541-563. Downs, G. W. and Larkey, P. D. The Search for Government Efficiency. New York: Random House [1986]. Drucker, Peter. Management: Tasks, Resaponsibilities, Practices. New York: Harper & Row [1973].

Duncombe, William D. "Costs and Factor Substitution in the Provision of Local Fire Services," Review of Economics & Statistics. 74/1 [Feb. 1992], 180-184. Duncombe, William D. "Demand for Local Public Services Revisited: The Case of Fire Protection," Public Finance Quarterly. 19/4 [Oct. 1991], 412-436. Dunleavy, Patrick. Democracy, Bureaucracy, and Public Choice: Economic Explanations in Political Science. New York: Harvester/Wheatsheaf [1991]. Dunleavy, Patrick, and Christopher Hood. "From Old Public Administration to New Public Management," Public Money & Management. 1/3 [July-Sept. 1994], 9-16. Eberts, Randall W. "School Reform, School Size, and Student Achievement," Economic Review [Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland]. 26/2 [Second Quarter 1990a], 2-15. Eberts, Randall W. "Structure, Conduct, and Performance in the Local Public Sector," National Tax Journal. 43/2 [June 1990b], 165-173. Ehrlich, Isaac, Gallais-Hamonno, Georges, Liu, Zhiqiang, and Lutter, Randall. "Productivity Growth and Firm Ownership: An Analytical and Empirical Investigation," Journal of Political Economy. 102/5 [Oct. 1994], 10061038. Enke, S., ed. Defense Management. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall [1967]. Ezzamel, Mahmoud. "Corporate Governance and Financial Accountability: Recent Reforms in the UK Public Sector," Accounting Auditing & Accountability Journal. 6/3 [1993], 109-132. Feldman, A.M. Welfare Economics and Social Choice Theory. Boston: Martinus Nijhoff [1980]. Ferejohn, John A. Pork Barrel Politics: Rivers and Harbors Legislation, 1947-1968. Stanford CA: Stanford University Press [1974]. Ferris, James "Coprovision: Citizen Time and Money Donations in Public Service Provision," Public Administration Review. 44/4 [July/Aug. 1984]. Ferris, J.M. and Graddy, E. "Organizational Choices for Public Service Supply," Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization. 10/1 [1994], 126-141. Ferris, J.M. and Graddy, E. "Production Costs, Transaction Costs, and Local Government Contractor Choice." Economic Inquiry. 19/3 [Summer 1991], 541-554. Fisher, Gene H. Cost Considerations in Systems Analysis. Rand Report R-490-ASD [December 1970]. Fischel, William A. "Property Taxes and Tax Revolts: The Legacy of Proposition 13," Journal of Economic Literature. 33/1 [March 1995], 239-240. Fischel, William A. "Property Taxation and the Tiebout Model: Evidence for the Benefit View from Zoning and Voting," Journal of Economic Literature. 30/1 [March 1992], 171-177. Fischel, William A. "Did Serrano Cause Proposition 13?" National Tax Journal. 42/4 [Dec. 1989], 465-473. Fitch, Lyle C. "Luther Gulick," Public Administration Review. 50/6 [Nov. 1990], 604-608.

Frant, Howard. "Politics and Effectiveness in the Design of Public Organizations," Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory. forthcoming. Frant, Howard. "Rules and Governance in the Public Sector: The Case of Civil Service," American Journal of Political Science. 37/4 [Nov. 1993], 990-1007. Friedman, L.S. Microeconomic Policy Analysis. New York: McGraw-Hill [1984]. Friedman, L.S. "Public Institutional Structure and Resource Allocation: The Analysis of Adjustment," Research in Public Policy Analysis and Management. 2 [1981], 303-25. Ganley, J. A. , and Cubbin, J. S. Public Sector Efficiency Measurements: Applications of Data Envelopment Analysis. New York: Elsevier Science Publishers, 1992. Gansler, Jacques S. Defense Conversion: Transforming the Arsenal of Democracy. Cambridge. MA: The MIT Press [1995]. Gemmell, Norman. "Public Employees' Preferences and the Size of the Public Sector," Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 14/3 [Dec. 1990], 393-402. Goldberg, V. "Regulation and Administered Contracts." Bell Journal of Economics. 7/2 [Fall 1976], 426-448. Gonzalez, R.A., and Mehay, S.L. "Bureaucracy and the Divisibility of Local Public Output," Public Choice. 45/1 [1984], 89-102. Good, David H. "Productive Efficiency and Contract Management: Some Evidence from Public Transit Agencies," Public Finance Quarterly. 20/2 [April 1992], 195-215. Goold, Michael. "Strategic Control in the Decentralized Firm," Sloan Management Review. 32/2 [1991], Winter 6981. Gore, Al From Red Tape to Results: Creating a Government that Works Better and Costs Less, Report of the National Performance Review. New York: Times Books/Random House [1993]. Gormley, W.T. Taming the Bureaucracy: Muscles, Prayers, and other Strategies. Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press [1989]. Govindarajan, Vijay. "A Contingency Approach to Strategy Implementation at the Business-Unit Level: Integrating Administrative Mechanism with Strategy," Academy of Management Journal. 31/4 [Dec. 1988], 828-853. Graddy, E. "Toward a General Theory of Occupational Regulation," Social Science Quarterly. 72/4 [December 1991a], 676-695. Graddy, E. "Interest Groups or the Public Interest -- Why Do We Regulate Health Occupations?" Journal of Health Politics, Policy, and Law. 16/1 [Spring 1991], 25-49. Gradstein, Mark. "Rent Seeking and the Provision of Public Goods," Economic Journal. 103/420 [Sept. 1993], 12361243. Gramlich, E.M. Benefit&endash;Cost Analysis of Government Programs, 2nd ed. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall [1990].

Grosskopf, Shawna. "Economies of Scope in the Provision of Local Public Services," National Tax Journal. 43/1 [March 1990], 61-74. Gul, Ferdinand A. "The Effects of Management Accounting Systems, Perceived Environmental Uncertainty and Decentralization on Managerial Performance: A test of 3-Way Interaction," Accounting, Organizations & Society. 19/4,5 [May-July 1994], 413-426. Hahn, R. and Hird, J. "The Costs and Benefits of Regulation." Yale Journal on Regulation. 5/2 [Winter 1991], 17191761. Hahn, R. and Noll, R. "Design for an Emissions Permit Market," in L. Graymer & F. Thompson, eds., Reforming Social Regulation. Los Angeles: Sage [1982], 37-54. Halal, William E. "From Hierarchy to Enterprise: Internal Markets Are the New Foundation of Management," Academy of Management Executive. 8/4 [Nov. 1994], 69-82. Hamel, Gary, and Prahalad, C.K. Competing for the Future. Boston: Harvard Business School Press [1994]. Hammer, M. "Reengineering Work: Don't Automate, Obliterate." Harvard Business Review. [July-August 1990], 104-112. Hammond, T.H. "In Defence of Luther Gulick's 'Notes on the Theory of Organization'," Public Administration. 68/2 [Summer 1990], 143-173. Hammond, T.H. "Agenda Control, Organizational Structure, and Bureaucratic Politics." American Journal of Political Science. 30/2 [May 1986], 379-420. Hammond, T.H., and Miller, G.J. "A Social Choice Perspective on Authority and Expertise in Bureaucracy," American Journal of Political Science. 29/1 [1985], 1-28. Hanke, Steve H. Prospects for Privatization. New York: Proceedings of the Academy of Political Science; 36, no. 3 [1987]. Hardin, R. "Collective Action as an Agreeable N-prisoners' Dilemma," Behavioral Scientist. 16 [Sept.-Oct. 1971], 472-481. Harr, D.J. and Godfrey, J.T. Private Sector Financial Performance Measures and Their Applicability to Government Operations. Montvale, NJ: National Association of Accountants [1991].\ Harr, David J. "How Activity Accounting Works in Government," Management Accounting. 72 [September 1990], 36-40. Harr, David J. "Productive Unit Resourcing: A Business Perspective on Government Financial Management," Government Accountants Journal. [Summer 1989], 51-57. Hartman, Robert W. "One Thousand Points of Light Seeking a Number: A Case Study of CBO's Search for a Discount Rate Policy," Journal of Environmental Economics & Management. 18/2[Part 2] [March 1990], S3-S7. Haskel, Jonathan, and Szymanski, Stefan. "Privatization, Liberalization, Wages and Employment: Theory and Evidence for the UK," Economica. 60/238 [May 1993], 161-181. Haveman, Robert H., and Julius Margolis, eds. Public Expenditures and Policy Analysis. Chicago: Rand McNally [1970].

Heaver, T.D., and Waters II, W.G. "Public Enterprise under Competition," in W.T. Stanbury and F. Thompson, eds., Managing Public Enterprises. New York: Praeger [1982], 152-160. Heckathorn, D., and Maser, S.M. "The Contractual Architecture of Public Policy: A Critical Reconstruction of Lowi's Typology," Journal of Politics. [November 1990]. Heckathorn, D., and Maser, S.M. "Bargaining and the Sources of Transaction Costs: The Case of Government Regulation," Journal of Law, Economics and Organization. 3/2 [1987a]. Heckathorn, D., and Maser, S.M. "Bargaining and Constitutional Contracts," American Journal of Political Science. 3/2 [1987b]. Hemingway, A.W. "Cost Center Financial Management: Training OPTAR Managers." Navy Comptroller. 3/3 [April 1993], 2-26. Hemmer, Thomas. "Risk-Free Incentive Contracts: Eliminating Agency Cost Using Option-Based Compensation Schemes," Journal of Accounting & Economics. 16/4 [Oct. 1993], 447-473. Hill, J. "Why so Much Stability?" Public Choice. 46 [1985], 275-287. Hird, J.A. "The Political Economy of Pork: Project Selection in the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers," American Political Science Review. 85/2 [1991], 429-456. Hirsch, Werner Z. The Economics of State and Local Government. New York: McGraw-Hill [1970]. Hirschleifer, Jack. "Transfer Pricing and Decentralized Decisions," in C. P. Bonini, R. Jaedicke, and H. M. Wagner, eds., Management Controls: New Directions for Basic Research. New York: McGraw-Hill [1964], 49-75. Hitch, C. J. Decision Making for Defense. Berkeley: University of California Press [1965]. Hitch, C.J. and McKean, R. The Economics of Defense in the Nuclear Age. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press [1960]. Hochman, H.M. and Rodgers, J. D. "Pareto Optimal Redistribution," American Economic Review. 58/4 [September 1969], 542-547. Hochman, H.M. "Individual Preferences and Distributional Adjustments," American Economic Review. 61/2 [May 1972], 353-360. Hochman, H.M. and Peterson, G. E., eds. Redistribution through Public Choice. New York: Columbia University Press [1974]. Hochschild, J.L. What's Fair? American Beliefs about Distributive Justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press [1981]. Hofstede, G.H. The Game of Budget Control. Amsterdam: Van Gorcum & Co [1967]. Holcombe, R.G. "The Florida System: A Bowen Equilibrium Referendum Process," National Tax Journal. 30/1 [March 1977], 77-84. Hood, Christopher. "Emerging Issues in Public administration," Public Administration. 73/1 [Spring 1995], 165183.

Hood, C. "A Public Management for all Seasons." Public Administration. 69/1 [Spring 1991], 3-20. Hood, C. The Limits of Government. London: John Wiley & Sons [1976]. Hopkins, T.D. "The Costs of Federal Regulation." Journal of Regulation and Social Costs. 2/1 [March 1992], 5&endash;31. Horn, Murray The Political Economy of Public Administration: Institutional Choice in the Public Sector. New York: Cambridge University Press [1995]. House, R., Prichard, R., and Trebilcock, M. "Smaller or Smarter Government?" University of Toronto Law Journal. 40/2 [1990], 498-541. Hoyt, William H. "Local Government Inefficiency and the Tiebout Hypothesis: Does Competition Among Municipalities Limit Local Government Inefficiency?" Southern Economic Journal. 57/2 [Oct. 1990], 481-496. Hunt, Lester C., and Lynk, Edward L. "Privatisation and Efficiency in the UK Water Industry: An Empirical Analysis," Oxford Bulletin of Economics & Statistics. 57/3 [Aug 1995], 371-388. Islam, Nasir. "Performance Contract: Contractualization of the Government-Public Enterprise Interface," Optimum. 23/4 [Spring 1993], 53-59. Itoh, H. "Coalitions, Incentives, and Risk Sharing," Journal of Economic Theory. 60/2 [Aug. 1993], 410-427. Jasay, Anthony de Social Contract, Free Ride: A Study of the Public Goods Problem. Oxford UK: Clarendon Press [1989]. Johnson, Ronald N.. and Libecap, Gary D. "Agency Growth, Salaries and the Protected Bureaucrat," Economic Inquiry. 27/3 [July 1989], 431-451. Johnson, H. Thomas and Kaplan, Robert S. Relevance Lost: The Rise and Fall of Management Accounting. Boston: Harvard Business School Press [1991]. Jones, L. R., Thompson, F., and Zumeta, W.M. "The Logic of Budget Execution," Economics of Education Review. 6 [Spring 1986], 44-53. Joskow, P. "Asset Specificity and the Structure of Vertical Relationships: Empirical Evidence," Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization. 4/1 [Spring 1988], 95-118. Kalt, J. and Zupan, M. "The Apparent Ideological Behavior of Legislators," Journal of Law and Economics. 33/1 [1990], 103-132. Kaplan, Robert S. "The Topic of Quality in Business School Education and Research," Selections. [Autumn 1991], 13-21. Kaplan, Robert S., ed. Measures for Manufacturing Excellence. Boston,: Harvard Business School Press [1990]. Kathawala, Yunus. "Organisational Structure Considerations in the Next Decade: Implications for Operations Management," International Journal of Operations & Production Management. 10/8 [1990], 53-60. Kelman, S. "The Prescriptive Message," Public Administration Review. 51/3 [May/June 1991], 21-23.

Kelman, S. Procurement and Public Management: The Fear of Discretion and the Quality of Government Performance. Washington: The AEI Press [1990]. Kelman, S. Making Public Policy a Hopeful View of American Government. New York: Basic Books [1987]. Kennedy School. "The Multiple Launch Rocket System: On Time and Under Budget," C16-87-773.0. Case Program, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, Cambridge MS [1987]. Keren, Michael. "Decentralization, Aggregation, Control Loss and Costs in a Hierarchical Model of the Firm," Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 11/2 [March 1989], 213-236. Kettl, Donald F. Sharing Power: Public Governance and Private Markets. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 1993. Khandwalla, P.N. "Crisis Responses of Competing versus Noncompeting Organizations," in C. Smart and W.T. Stanbury, eds., Studies on Crisis Management. Montreal: Institute for Research on Public Policy [1987]. Kiewiet, D. Roderick "Bureaucrats and Budgetary Outcomes: Quantitative Analyses," in Blais and Dion, eds. The Budget-Maximizing Bureaucrat. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press [1991]. Kitfield, James. "Black Programs: Too Big to Hide?" Military Forum. 26. [April 1989], 21-28. Knott, Jack H., and Miller, Gary J. Reforming Bureaucracy: The Politics of Institutional Choice. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, [1987]. Koford, Kenneth. "On Dimensionalizing Roll Call Votes in the U.S. Congress," American Political Science Review. 85/3 [Sept. 1991], 956-976. Kovacic, William E. "The Sorcerer's Apprentice: Public Regulation of the Acquisitions Process," in Robert Higgs, ed., Arms, Politics, and the Economy. New York: Holmes & Meier Publishers Inc. [1990], 104-131. Krueger, A.O. "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society." American Economic Review. 64/2 [June 1974], 291-303; reprinted in Buchanan, Tollison, and Tullock [1980], 51-70. Ladd, Helen F. "Comments on Chapter 5," in Quigley and Smolensky, eds., Modern Public Finance. [1994], 152156. Laffont, Jean-Jacques, and Tirole, Jean. A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press [1993]. Lamm, David. "Why Firms Refuse DOD Business," National Contract Management Journal. 21 [Winter 1988], 4555. Lan, Zhiyong and Rosenbloom, D. "Public Administration in Transition?" Public Administration Review. 52/6 [Nov.-Dec. 1992], 535-537. Langbein, Laura. The Causes and Consequences of Bureaucratic Discretion. Unpublished manuscript, Public Administration, American University, 1996. Lapsley, I. "Responsibility Accounting Revived? Market Reforms and Budgetary Control," Management Accounting Research. 5/3,4 [Sept.-Dec. 1994], 337-352.

Larkey, Patrick D. Evaluating Public Programs: The Impact of General Revenue Sharing on Municipal Government. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press [1979]. Larkey, P.D., Stolp, Chandler, and Winer, Mark "Theorizing about the Growth of Government: A Research Assessment," Journal of Public Policy. [May 1981], 157-220. Leibenstein, H.J. Beyond Economic Man. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press [1976]. Lewis, Tracy R, and Sappington, David E. M. "Inflexible Rules in Incentive Problems," American Economic Review. 79/1 [March 1989], 69-84. Littlechild, S.C., with Thompson, F. "Aircraft Landing Fees: A Game Theory Approach," The Bell Journal of Economics. 8/1 [Spring 1977], 186-204. Lovell, C. and Tobin, C. "The Mandate Issue." Public Administration Review. 41/3 [May/June 1981], 318-330. Lozier, John "Volunteer Fire Fighters and Community Mobilization," Human Organization. 35/4 [1976], 19-46. Mackintosh, Maureen. "Economic Behaviour and the Contracting Outcome under the NHS Reforms: Theory and the Example of Community Nursing," Accounting Auditing & Accountability Journal. 6/3 [1993], 133-155. MacManus, Susan A. "Why Businesses are Reluctant to Sell to Governments," Public Administration Review. 51/4 [July/August 1991], 328-44. Marcus, Alfred A. "Responses to Externally Induced Innovation: Their Effects on Organizational Performance," Strategic Management Journal. 9 [Winter 1988], 387-402. Margolis, Julius, ed., The Analysis of Public Output. New York: Columbia University Press, for the National Bureau of Economic Research, 1970. Marini, Frank, ed. Toward a New Public Administration: The Minnowbrook Perspective. New York: Chandler [1971]. Maser, Steven M. "Transaction Costs in Public Administration," in Donald Calista, ed., Bureaucratic and Governmental Reform. Greenwich, CN: JAI Press Inc. [1986], 55-72. Masten, Scott E. "Transaction Costs, Mistakes, and Performance: Assessing the Importance of Governance," Managerial & Decision Economics. 14/2 [Mar/April 1993], 119-129. Masten, S.E. "The Organization of Production," The Journal of Law and Economics. 27/3 [1984], 403-417. Masten, S.E., Meehan, J.W., and Snyder, E.A. "The Costs of Organization," The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization. 7 /1 [1991], 1-25. Mauro, Paolo. "Corruption and Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110/3 [Aug. 1995], 681-712. Mayer, Kenneth R. The Political Economy of Defense Contracting. New Haven CN: Yale University Press [1991]. Mayston, David. "Principals, Agents and the Economics of Accountability in the New Public Sector," Accounting Auditing & Accountability Journal. 6/3 [1993], 68-96.

McCubbins, Matthew, and Schwartz, Thomas "Congressional Oversight Overlooked: Police Patrols versus Fire Alarms," American Journal of Political Science. 28/2 [1984], 165-179. McCubbins, Matthew D., Noll, Roger G., and Weingast, Barry R. "Structure and Process, Politics and Policy: Administrative Arrangements and the Political Control of Agencies," Virginia Law Review. 75/2 [Mar 1989], 431508. McDavid, James "Part-time Firefighters in Canadian Municipalities," Canadian Public Administration. 29/3 [1986], 377-387. McFadden, D. "Revealed Preferences of a Government Bureaucracy, Parts I and II," Bell Journal of Economics. 6/2 [autumn 1976], 401-416; 7/2 [spring 1977], 52-72. McKean, Roland N. Public Spending. New York: McGraw-Hill [1968]. McKelvey, Richard "Intransitivities in Multidimensional Voting Models and Some Implications for Agenda Control," Journal of Economic Theory. 12 [1976], 427-482. McLure, C.E. and Zodrow, G.R. "The Study and Practice of Income Tax Policy," in Quigley and Smolensky, eds., Modern Public Finance. [1994], 165-212. McMaster, Robert. "The Contract State: X-Efficiency and Trust," Management Research News: MRN. 17/7 [1994],8,9, 47-49. McVay, Barry "Caution! Slippery Fixed-Price Incentive Contracts Ahead," National Contract Management Journal. 26/1 [1995], 15-22. Mehay, S.L. "Economic Incentives under Contract Supply of Local Government Services," Public Choice. 46/1 [1986], 79-86. Mendeloff, J.M. The Dilemma of Toxic Substance Regulation: How Overregulation Causes Underregulation. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press [1988]. Merewitz, Leonard, and Sosnick, Stephen H. The Budget's New Clothes: A Critique of Planning-ProgrammingBudgeting and Benefit-Cost Analysis. Chicago: Markham [1971]. Merton, Robert. Social Theory and Social Structure. New York: The Free Press [1957]. Migue, J.-L., and Belanger, G. "Toward a General Theory of Managerial Discretion." Public Choice. 17 [Spring 1974], 27-42. Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J. Economics, Organization and Management . New Jersey: Prentice-Hall [1992]. Miller, Gary J. Cities by Contract. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press [1981]. Miller, Gary J. Managerial Dilemmas: The Political Economy of Hierarchy. Cambridge UK: New York: Cambridge University Press [1992]. Milward, H. B. "Nonprofit Contracting and the Hollow State," Public Administration Review. 54/1 [Jan.-Feb. 1994], 73-77.

Minasian, J. "Land Utilization for Defense," in S. Enke, ed. Defense Management. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: PrenticeHall, Inc. [1967], 234-56. Miranda, Rowan. "Bureaucracy, Organizational Redundancy, and the Privatization of Public Services," Public Administration Review. 55/2 [Mar/Apr 1995],193-200. Miranda, Rowan. "Privatization and the Budget-Maximizing Bureaucrat," Public Productivity & Management Review. 17/4 [summer 1994], 17-34. Moe, T.M. "The Politics of Structural Choice: Toward a Theory of Public Bureaucracy," in Oliver E. Williamson, ed., Organization Theory: From Chester Barnard to the Present and Beyond. New York: Oxford University Press [1990]. Moe, T.M. "The Politics of Bureaucratic Structure," in John E. Chubb and Paul E. Peterson, eds. Can the Government Govern? Washington: The Brookings Institution [1989]. Moe, Terry "The New Economics of Organization," American Journal of Political Science. 28 [1984], 739-77. Monissen, H.G. "Rent&endash;Seeking in General Equilibrium: A Didactic Illustration," Public Choice. 72 [December 1991], 111&endash;130. Monteverde, K., and Teece, D.J. "Appropriable Rents and Quasi-Vertical Integration," The Journal of Law and Economics. 25 [1982], 403-418. Moores, Ken. "A Reconciliation of Market Competition, Decentralization, Size, and Financial Performance Results: An Extension Testing Moderating Effects," Human Relations. 42/1 [Jan. 1989], 67-80. Morgan, J. "Bilateral Monopoly and the Competitive Output," Quarterly Journal of Economics. 63 [1949], 370-381. Morrell, J.F. "A Review of the Record," Regulation. 10/5 [November/December 1986], 25-43. Mosher, F.C. "The Changing Responsibilities and Tactics of the Federal Government," Public Administration Review. 40/6 [November-December 1980], 540-547. Muid, C. "Information Systems and New Public Management--A View from the Centre," Public Administration. 72/1 [Spring 1994], 113-125. Mueller, D.C. Public Choice II. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press [1989]. Munger, Michael "On the Mutuality of Interests between Bureaus and High Demand Review Committees," Public Choice. 43 [1984], 211-215. Nelson, Michael A. "Decentralization of the Subnational Public Sector: An Empirical Analysis of the Determinants of Local Government Structure in Metropolitan Areas in the U.S.," Southern Economic Journal. 57/2 [Oct. 1990], 443-457. Niskanen, W.A. Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton [1971]. Niskanen, W. A. "The Defense Resource Allocation Process," in S. Enke, ed. Defense Management. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc. [1967], 3-22. Niskanen, W.A. "The Total Cost of Regulation?" Regulation. 14/2 [Summer 1991], 23-25.

Niskanen, W.A. "The Costs of Regulation (continued)," Regulation. 15/1 [Spring 1992], 25-26. Novick, D. Efficiency and Economy in Government through New Budgeting and Accounting Procedures. Santa Monica, CA: The RAND Corporation, R-254 [1954]. Novick, D. A New Approach to the Military Budget. Santa Monica, CA: The RAND Corporation, R-1759 [1956]. Oates, Wallace E. "Federalism and Government Finance," in Quigley and Smolensky, eds., Modern Public Finance. [1994], 126-151. Okun, A. Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution [1975]. Olson, M. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press [1965]. Olson, M. The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities. New Haven, CN: Yale University Press [1982]. Olson, M., and Zeckhauser, R. "An Economic Theory of Alliances," Review Economics & Statistics. 48/3 [Aug. 1966], 266-79. Osborne, D. and Gaebler, Ted Reinventing Government: How the Entrepreneurial Spirit Is Transforming the Public Sector from Schoolhouse to Statehouse, City Hall to the Pentagon. Reading, MA: Addison Wesley [1992]. Ostrom, Elinor. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press [1990]. Ostrom, Elinor, Gardner, Roy, and Walker, James; with Agrawal, Arun. Rules, Games, and Common-Pool Resources. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press [1994]. Parker, David, and Martin, D. "The Impact of UK Privatisation on Labour and Total Factor Productivity," Scottish Journal of Political Economy. 42/2 [May 1995], 201-220. Parker, David. "Comment: The Inadequacy of Traditional Theories and the Promise of PPB as a Systems Approach," in Marini, ed., Toward a New Public Administration [1971], 301-308. Parks, Roger B., et al. "Consumers as Coproducers of Public Services," Policy Studies Journal. 9 [Summer 1981], 1001-1011. Parks, Roger B. et al. "Coproduction of Public Services," in R.C. Rich, ed., Analyzing Urban-Service Distributions. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books [1982], 185-189. Peltzman, S. "How Efficient is the Voting Market?" Journal of Law and Economics. 33/1 [1990], 27-63. Peltzman, S. "Constituent Interest and Congressional Voting," Journal of Law and Economics. 27/1 [1984], 181210. Peltzman, S. "Toward a More General Theory of Regulation," Journal of Law and Economics. 14/2 [1976], 109148. Perrow, Charles A. "The Bureaucratic Paradox: The Efficient Organization Centralizes in order to Decentralize," Organization Dynamics. [Spring 1977], 3-14.

Persky, Allan. "The Expected Utility Hypothesis as Immunity against the "Legal" Utilization of the Money Pump and Underachiever Methods," Southern Economic Journal. 61/2 [Oct. 1994], 478-487. Peters, Thomas J. and Waterman, Robert H. In Search of Excellence: Lessons form America's Best-Run Companies. New York: Harper & Row [1982]. Pilling, Donald L. Competition in Procurement. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution [1989]. Pincus, J. J. Pressure Groups & Politics in Antebellum Tariffs. New York: Columbia University Press [1977]. Pinheiro, Armando C., and Schneider, Ben R. "The Fiscal Impact of Privatization in Latin America," Quarterly Review of Economics & Finance. 34 [Summer 1994], 9-42. Pitsvada, B.T. "Flexibility in Federal Budget Execution," Public Budgeting and Finance. 3/1 [Spring 1983], 17-26. Poole, Keith T. "Patterns of Congressional Voting," American Journal of Political Science. 35/1 [Feb. 1991], 228278. Poole, Keith T., and Rosenthal, Howard. "The Enduring Nineteenth-Century Battle for Economic Regulation: The Interstate Commerce Act Revisited," Journal of Law & Economics. 36/2 [Oct. 1993], 837-860. Posner, R,A. "Taxation by Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science. 2/1 [1971], 22-50. Posner, R,A. "Theories of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science. 5/2 [1974], 335-358. Powers, K.A., and Thompson, F. "Managing Coprovision: Using Expectancy Theory to Overcome the Free-Rider Problem," Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory. 4/2 [1994] 179-196. Prusa, Thomas J. "An Incentive Compatible Approach to the Transfer Pricing Problem," Journal of International Economics. 28/1,2 [Feb. 1990], 155-172. President's Private Sector Survey on Cost Control [Grace Commission]. Task Force Report on the Office of the Secretary of Defnse. Arlington VA: PPSS [July 13, 1983]. Quade, E. S. and Boucher, W. I. Systems Analysis and Policy Planning. New York: American Elsevier [1968]. Quade, E. S. Analysis for Public Decisions. New York: American Elsevier [1975]. Quiggin, John. "Does Privatisation Pay?" Australian Economic Review. 110 [Second Quarter 1995], 23-42. Quigley, John M. and Smolensky, Eugene, eds. Modern Public Finance. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press, 1994. Rauch, J. Demosclerosis: The Silent Killer of American Government. New York: Times Books [1994]. Rauch, J.E. "Bureaucracy, Infrastructure, and Economic Growth: Evidence from U.S. Cities During the Progressive Era," American Economic Review. 85/4 [Sept. 1995], 968-979. Ravenscroft, Sue Pickard. "Bargaining Behavior in a Transfer Pricing Experiment," Organizational Behavior & Human Decision Processes. 55/3 [Aug. 1993], 414-443.

Recktenwald, H.C. "Potential Welfare Losses in the Public Sector Anatomy of the Nature and Causes." in H. Hanusch, ed. Anatomy of Government Deficiencies. Berlin: Springer-Verlag [1983], 43-58. Reichelstein, Stefan "Constructing Incentive Schemes for Government Contracts: An Application of Agency Theory." Accounting Review. 67/4 [Oct. 1992], 712-731. Reid, Gary J. "Perceived Government Waste and Government Structure: An Empirical Examination of Competing Explanations," Public Finance Quarterly. 18/4 [Oct. 1990], 395-419. Reschenthaler, G.B., and Thompson, F. "The Information Revolution and the New Public Management." Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory. 6/1 [Winter 1996], 124-143. Rhodes R.A.W. "The New Public Management," Public Administration. 69/1 [Spring 1991], entire issue. Rivlin, Alice M. Systematic Thinking for Social Action. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution [1971] Rivlin, Alice M. New Approaches to Public Decision-Making. Ottawa: Information Canada, for the Economic Council of Canada [1972]. Rogerson, William P. "Quality vs. Quantity in Military Procurement," American Economic Review. 80/1 [March 1990], 83-92. Romer, Thomas and Rosenthal, Howard. "Economic Incentives and Political Institutions: Spending and Voting in School Budget Referenda," Journal of Public Economics. 49/1 [Oct. 1992], 1-33. Ronen, Joshua. "Transfer Pricing Reconsidered," Journal of Public Economics. 47/1 [Feb. 1992], 125-136. Ronen, Joshua, and Balachandran, Kashi R. "An Approach to Transfer Pricing under Uncertainty," Journal of Accounting Research. 26/2 [Autumn 1988], 300-314. Rosenthal, Howard A. "Committee Power, Structure-Induced Equilibria, and Roll Call Votes--Comment," American Journal of Political Science. 36/1 [Feb. 1992], 1-39. Rosenberg, Nathan , and Birdsall, L.E. How the West Grew Rich: The Economic Transformation of the Industrial World. New York: Basic Books [1986]. Rosenfeld, Yehiel "Cost-Plus and Incentive Contracting: Some False Benefits and Inherent Drawbacks," Construction Management & Economics. 9/5 [Sept. 1991], 481-492. Rubin, Irene S. "Who Invented Budgeting in the United States?" Public Administration Review. 53/5 [Sept.-Oct. 1993], 438-444. Sah, Raaj K. "The Quality of Managers in Centralized versus Decentralized Organizations," Quarterly Journal of Economics. 106/1 [Feb. 1991], 289-295. Samuelson, P.A. "A Diagrammatic Exposition of a Theory of Public Expenditure," Review of Economics and Statistics. 37 [Nov. 1955], 350-56. Samuelson, P.A. "The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure," Review of Economics and Statistics. 36 [Nov 1954], 387-9. Santerre, Rexford E. "A Test of Executive Behavior in the Local Public Sector," Review of Economics & Statistics. 72/3 [Aug. 1990], 546-550.

Savas, Emanuel S. Privatizing the Public Sector: How to Shrink Government. Chatham NJ: Chatham House Publishers [1982]. Schedler, K. Ansatze einer Wirkungsorientirten Verwaltungsfuhrung: Von der Idee des New Public Managements (NPM) zum konkreten Gestaltungsmodell. Bern: Verlag Paul Haupt [1995]. Schlesinger, J.R. "The Changing Environment for Systems Analysis," in S. Enke, ed. Defense Management. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall [1967], 89-112. Schlesinger, J.R. "Systems Analysis and the Political Process," in Frederick S. Lane, ed. Current Issues in Public Administration, 2nd edition. New York: St. Martin's Press [1982], 390-404. Schick, Allen. "Budgeting for Results: Recent Developments in Five Industrialized Countries," Public Administration Review. 50/1 [Jan/Feb 1990], 26-34. Schick, A.. "Contemporary Problems in Financial Control," Public Administration Review. 38/6 [NovemberDecember 1978], 513-519. Schick, Allen. "Congress and the Details of Administration," Public Administration Review. 36/6 [NovemberDecember 1976], 516-528. Schick, A. "Control Patterns in State Budget Execution," Public Administration Review. 24/2 [June 1964], 97-106. Schroeder, Douglas A. "Organizational Structure and Intrafirm Transfer Prices for Interdependent Products," Journal of Business Finance & Accounting. 20/3 [April 1993], 441-455. Schultze, Charles L. The Politics and Economics of Public Spending. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution [1968]. Schwartz, H. "Small States in Big Trouble," World Politics. 46/4 [July 1994], 527-555. Scotchmer, S. "Public Goods and the Invisible Hand," in Quigley and Smolensky, eds., Modern Public Finance. [1994], 93-119. Scott, G., Bushnell, P., and Sallee, N. "Reform of the Core Public Sector: The New Zealand Experience," Public Sector. 13/3[1990], 11-24. Shepsle, Kenneth "Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models," American Journal of Political Science. 23/1 [1979], 27-43. Shepsle, Kenneth A. The Giant Jigsaw Puzzle: Democratic Committee Assignments in the Modern House. Chicago: University of Chicago Press [1978]. Shepsle, K. and Weingast, B. "Political Solutions to Market Problems," American Political Science Review. 78 [June 1984], 417-34. Shepsle, K.A., and Weingast, B.R. "Political Preferences for the Pork Barrel: A Generalization," American Journal of Political Science. 25/1[1981], 96-111. Shleifer, Andrei. "Politicians and Firms," Quarterly Journal of Economics. 109/4 [Nov. 1994], 995-1025.

Silva, Fabio and Sonstelie, Jon "Did Serrano cause a decline in school spending?" National Tax Journal. 48/2 [Jun 1995], 199-215. Sonstelie, J. C. and Portney, P. R. "Profit-Maximizing Communities and the Theory of Local Public Expenditure," Journal of Urban Economics. 5 [1978], 263-277. Sourwine, Darrel A. "Cost accounting Standards: Myths & Misconceptions," Management Accounting. 75/7 [Jan. 1994], 42-43. Sourwine, Darrel A. "CAS Applicability, Coverage and Disclosure," Journal of Accountancy. 176/2 [Aug. 1993], 69-74. Stanbury, W.T. "A Skeptic's Guide to the Claims of So-Called Public Interest Groups," Canadian Public Administration. 36/4 [winter 1993], 580-605. Stanbury, W.T., and Thompson, F. "Toward a Political Economy of Government Waste," Public Administration Review. 55/5 [Sept/Oct 1995] 418-427. Stark, R., and Varley, T. "Bidding, Estimating, and Engineered Construction Contracting," in R. EngelbrechtWiggens, et al., eds., Auctions, Bidding, and Contracting. New York: New York University Press [1983], 121-135. Stedry, A. Budget Control and Cost Behavior. Englewood Cliffs NJ: Prentice-Hall [1960]. Szymanski, Stefan, and Wilkins, S. "Competitive Tendering: Lessons from the Public Sector," Business Strategy Review. 3/3 [Autumn 1992], 101-113. Tabellini, Guido. and Alesina, Alberto. "Voting on the Budget Deficit," American Economic Review. 80/1 [March 1990], 37-49. Taylor, Lori L. "Government Budgets and Property Value," Economic Review [Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas]. [Sept. 1991], 1-7. Thomas, Jacob K., and Tung, S. "Cost Manipulation Incentives Under Cost Reimbursement: Pension Costs for Defense Contracts," Accounting Review. 67/4 [Oct. 1992], 691-711. Thompson, F. "Matching Responsibilities with Tactics: Administrative Controls and Modern Government," Public Administration Review. 53/4 [July-August 1993], 303-318. Thompson, F. "Management Control and the Pentagon: The Strategy-Structure Mismatch," Public Administration Review. 51/1 [1991], 52-66. Thompson, F."Why America's Military Base Structure Can't be Reduced," Public Administration Review. 48/1 [1988], 557-63. Thompson, F. "Lumpy Goods and Cheap Riders: An Application of the Theory of Collective Goods," Journal of Public Policy. 7/4 [1987], 427-445. Thompson, F. "Closeness Counts in Horseshoes and Dancing . . . and Elections," Public Choice. 38/3 [1982], 30516. Thompson, F. "Utility Maximizing Behavior in Organized Anarchies," Public Choice. 36 [1981], 17-32.

Thompson, F. "American Legislative Decision Making and the Size Principle," American Political Science Review. 73/4 [1979], 1100-8. Thompson, F. and Jones, L.R. Regulatory Policy and Practices: Regulating Better and Regulating Less. Praeger: New York [1982]. Thompson, F., and Jones, L. R. "Controllership in the Public Sector," Journal of Policy Analysis and Management. 5/3 [1986], 547-571. Thompson, F., and Williams, R. "A Horse Race Around a Mobius Strip: A Review and a Test of Utility Maximizing and Organizational Process Models of Public Expenditure Decisions," Policy Sciences. 11 [1979], 119-42. Tiebout, Charles M. "A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures," Journal of Political Economy. 64/4 [October 1956], 416-424. Tirole, Jean. "The Internal Organization of Government," Oxford Economic Papers. 46/1 [Jan. 1994], 1-29. Tirole, Jean. The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press [1988]. Trebilcock, Michael J. The Prospects for Reinventing Government? Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute [1994]. Tullock, G. "The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies and Theft," Western Economic Journal. 5/2 [June 1967], 224-232; reprinted in Buchanan, Tollison, and Tullock [1980], 39-50. Tullock, G. "The Cost of Transfers," Kyklos. 4/4 [December 1971], 629-643; reprinted in Buchanan, Tollison, and Tullock [1980], 269-282. Turcotte, W.A. "Control Systems, Performance, and Satisfaction in Two State Agencies," Administrative Sciences Quarterly. 19 [March 1974], 60-73. Turnbull, G.K., and Djoundourian, S.S. "The Median Voter Hypothesis: Evidence from General Purpose Local Governments," Public choice. 81/3 [1994], 223-138. Twight, Charlotte "Department of Defense Attempts to Close Military Bases: The Political Economy of Congressional Resistance," In Arms, Politics, and the Economy. Robert Higgs ed. New York: Holmes & Meier Publishers Inc. [1990], 236-79. Tyler, Tom R. Why People Obey the Law. New Haven, CN: Yale University Press [1990]. Vancil, Richar. Decentralization: Management Ambiguity by Design. Homewood IL: Dow Jones Irwin [1979]. Vena, Carl H. "The Real World of Military Standard 1567A and Work Measurement," Industrial Engineering. 25/2 [Feb. 1993], 42-43. Vining, A.R. and Boardman, A.E. "Ownership Versus Competition: Efficiency in Public Enterprise," Public Choice. 73/2 [1992], 205-240. Vining, A.R. and Weimer, D. "Government Supply and Government Production Failure: A Framework Based on Contestability," Journal of Public Policy. 10 [March-April 1990], 54-90. von Ungern-Sternberg, Thomas "Quality Incentives in Auctions for Construction Contracts," International Journal of Industrial Organization. 12/1 [1994], 89-104.

Vroom, V. Work and Motivation. New York: Wiley [1964]. Walker, Gordon, and Poppo, Laura. "Profit Centers, Single-Source Suppliers, and Transaction Costs," Administrative Science Quarterly. 36/1 [March 1991], 66-87. Wallis, J.J. "The Political Economy of New Deal Fiscal Federalism," Economic Inquiry. 29/3 [July 1991], 510-524. Weidenbaum, M. and DeFina, R. The Cost of Federal Government Regulation of Economic Activity. Washington, DC: The American Enterprise Institute [1978]. Weimer, David Leo and Vining, Aidan R. Policy Analysis: Concepts and Practice, 2nd ed. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall [1992]. Whitaker, Gordon P. "Coproduction: Citizen Participation in Service Delivery," Public Administration Review. 40/3 [May/June 1980], 240-246. Whynes, David K. "Can Performance Monitoring Solve the Public Services' Principal-Agent Problem?" Scottish Journal of Political Economy. 40/4 [Nov. 1993], 434-446. Wildavsky, Aaron and Hammond, A. "Comprehensive vs. Incremental Budgeting in the Department of Agriculture." Administrative Sciences Quarterly. 10 [1965], 321-346. Williamson, O.E. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: The Free Press [1985]. Williamson, O.E. "Administrative Decision Making and Pricing," in Margolis,ed., The Analysis of Public Output. [1970], 115-135. Willig, Robert D., and Jatar, Ana Julia. "Public Versus Regulated Private Enterprise," World Bank Research Observer. Annual Conference on Development Economics Supplement [1993], 155-180. Wilson, J.Q. Bureaucracy. New York: Basic Books [1989]. Wittman, Donald. "Why Democracies Produce Efficient Results," Journal of Political Economy. 9/6 [Dec. 1989], 1395-1424. World Bank. Bureaucrats in Business: The Economics and Politics of Government Ownership. New York: Oxford University Press [1995]. Yinger, J., Bloom, Howard S., Borsch-Supan, A., and Ladd, Helen F. Property Taxes and House Values: The Theory and Estimation of Intrajurisdictional Property Tax Capitalization. Boston: Academic Press [1988]. Young, Allan Richard. "Transaction Costs, Two-Part Tariffs, and Collusion," Economic Inquiry. 29/3 [July 1991], 581-590 Zax, Jeffrey S. "Is There a Leviathan in Your Neighborhood? Is Leviathan a Mythical Beast? Searching for Leviathan: A Reply and Some Further Reflections," American Economic Review. 79/3 [June 1989], 560-583. Zald, Mayer N. "Decentralization: Myth vs. Reality," Personnel. 41 [July-August 1964], 19-26. Zorn, C. Kurt. "The Economic Perspective on Public Administration," Public Administration Review. 49/2 [Mar/Apr 1989], 213-214.

Zuboff, S. In the Age of the Smart Machine: The Future of Work and Power. New York: Basic Books [1988].

Você também pode gostar