Você está na página 1de 10

Perfect Competition

We now move on to study the economics of different market structures. The


spectrum of competition ranges from perfectly competitive markets where
there are many sellers who are price takers to a pure monopoly where one
single supplier dominates an industry and sets price. We start our analysis of
market structures by looking at perfect competition.

Perfect competition – a pure market

Perfect competition describes a market structure whose assumptions are


extremely strong and highly unlikely to exist in most real-time and real-world
markets. The reality is that most markets are imperfectly competitive.
Nonetheless, there is some value in understanding how price, output and
equilibrium is established in both the short and the long run in a market that
holds true to the tough assumptions of a world of perfect competition.

Economists have become more interested in pure competition partly because of


the rapid growth of e-commerce in domestic and international markets as a
means of buying and selling goods and services. And also because of the
popularity of auctions as a rationing device for allocating scarce resources
among competing ends.

Basic assumptions required for conditions of pure competition to exist

• Many small firms, each of whom produces an insignificant percentage of


total market output and thus exercises no control over the ruling market
price.

• Many individual buyers, none of whom has any control over the market
price – i.e. there is no monopsony power

• Perfect freedom of entry and exit from the industry. Firms face no
sunk costs - entry and exit from the market is feasible in the long run. This
assumption ensures all firms make normal profits in the long run

• Homogeneous products are supplied to the markets that are perfect


substitutes. This leads to each firms being passive “price takers” and
facing a perfectly elastic demand curve for their product

• Perfect knowledge – consumers have readily available information


about prices and products from competing suppliers and can access this
at zero cost – in other words, there are few transactions costs involved in
searching for the required information about prices

• No externalities arising from production and/or consumption which lie


outside the market

The real world of imperfect competition!


Clearly the assumptions of pure competition do not hold in the vast majority of
markets. Some suppliers may exert some control over market supply and seek
to exploit their monopoly power. On the demand-side, some consumers may
have monopsony power against suppliers because they purchase a high
percentage of total demand. There are nearly always some barriers to the
contestability of the market (see revision notes on barriers to entry) and far
from being homogeneous, most markets are full of heterogeneous products
due to product differentiation.

Consumers nearly always have imperfect information (for example


information gaps) and their preferences and choices can be influenced by the
effects of persuasive marketing and advertising. In every industry there is
always asymmetric information where the seller knows more about quality of
good than buyer. The real world is one in which negative and positive
externalities from both production and consumption are numerous – both of
which can lead to a divergence between private and social costs and benefits.
Finally there may be imperfect competition in related markets such as the
market for essential raw materials, labour and capital goods.

We can come fairly close to a world of perfect competition but in practice there
are nearly always barriers to pure competition.

Currency markets - taking us closer to perfect competition

“As perfect competition is a theoretical absolute, there are no pure examples of


a perfectly competitive market.” (Source: Wikipedia)

It is often said that the most competitive market possible is at best rare and
probably does not exist at all in its purest form. Perhaps the vast market in
global currencies takes us as close as we might reasonably get to a world of
perfect competition?

Brief background on currency dealing

The foreign exchange market is where all buying and selling of world currencies
takes place.
There is 24-hour trading, 5 days a week (about 9pm London Sunday to 10pm
London Friday.
Trade volume in the Forex market is around $1.2 trillion per day. This compares
with to the New York Stock Exchange which trades ‘only’ $25 billion per day.
31% of global currency trading takes place in London.
Well over ninety per cent of trading in currencies around the world is speculative
rather than the buying and selling of currencies to enable people and firms to
conduct business in the real economy.

The main players in the currency markets are as follows:

Banks both as “market makers” dealing in currencies and also as end users
demanding currency for their own operations). These banks include investment
banks and commercial “high street” banks
Hedge funds and other institutions (e.g. funds invested by asset managers,
pension funds)
Central Banks (including occasional currency intervention in the market)
Corporations (mostly defensive hedging of exposures to risk)
Private investors / market speculators / tourists

Why does a currency market come close to perfect competition?

Homogenous output: The "goods" traded in the foreign exchange markets are
homogenous - a US dollar is a dollar whether someone is trading it in London,
New York or Tokyo.

Many buyers and sellers meet openly to determine prices: There are large
numbers of buyers and sellers - each of the major banks has a foreign exchange
trading floor which helps to "make the market". Indeed there are so many sellers
operating around the world that the global currency exchanges are open for
business twenty-four hours a day. No one agent in the currency market can
influence the price on a persistent basis - all are ‘price takers’.

Currency values are determined solely by demand and supply factors.

High quality information: Most participants in the market - be they buyers or


sellers - are well informed, in most cases with access to real time information
and also plenty of background analysis on the factors driving the prices of each
individual national currency. Technological progress has made much more
information more immediately available at a fraction of the cost of just a few
years ago. This is not to say that information is cheap - an annual subscription to
a Bloomberg or a Reuter’s news terminal will normally cost several thousand
dollars. But the market is rich with information and transactions costs for each
batch of currency bought and sold have come down.

Seeking the best price: The buyers and sellers in foreign exchange only deal with
those who offer the best prices.

What are the limitations of currency trading as an example of a near-perfectly


competitive market?

Firstly the market can be influenced by official intervention via buying and
selling of currencies by governments or central banks operating on their behalf.
There is a huge debate about the actual impact of intervention by policy-makers
in the currency markets.

Those who are sceptical about the effects of intervention buying and selling to
move currencies in anything other than the short term talk of governments not
being able to "buck the market". Others conceded that intervention does change
the ruling price for a currency especially if there is concerted and coordinated
intervention by a number of countries acting in unison.

Secondly there are costs involved in a bank or other financial institution when
establishing a new trading platform for currencies. They need the capital
equipment to trade effectively; the skilled labour to employ as currency traders
and researchers.

Despite these limitations, the foreign currency markets take us close to a world
of perfect competition. Much the same can be said for trading in the equities and
bond markets and also the ever expanding range of future markets for financial
investments and internationally traded commodities.

Establishing price and output in the short run under perfect


competition
The previous diagram shows the short run equilibrium for perfect competition. In
the short run, the twin forces of market demand and market supply determine
the equilibrium “market-clearing” price for the industry. In the diagram
below, a market price P1 is established and output Q1 is produced. This price is
taken by each of the firms. The average revenue curve (AR) is their individual
demand curve. Since the market price is constant for each unit sold, the AR
curve also becomes the Marginal Revenue curve (MR).

For the firm, the profit maximising output is at Q2 where MC=MR. This output
generates a total revenue (P1 x Q2). The total cost of producing this output can
be calculated by multiplying the average cost of a unit of output (AC1) and the
output produced. Since total revenue exceeds total cost, the firm in this example
is making abnormal (economic) profits. This is not necessarily the case for all
firms. It depends on their short run cost curves. Some firms may be experiencing
sub-normal profits if average costs exceed the market price. For these firms,
total costs will be greater than total revenue.

Short run losses


The adjustment to the long-run equilibrium

If most firms are making abnormal (or supernormal) profits, this encourages
the entry of new firms into the industry, which if it happens will cause an
outward shift in market supply forcing down the ruling market price.

The increase in supply will eventually reduce the market price until price =
long run average cost. At this point, each firm in the industry is making
normal profit. Other things remaining the same, there is no further incentive for
movement of firms in and out of the industry and a long-run equilibrium has
been established. This is shown in the next diagram.
We are assuming in the diagram above that there has been no shift in market
demand, i.e. we are considering an outward shift in market supply brought about
by the entry of new competing firms each of whom is supplying a homogeneous
product to the market. The effect of increased supply is to force down the
market price and cause an expansion along the market demand curve. But for
each supplier, the price they “take” is now lower and it is this that drives down
the level of profit made towards the normal profit equilibrium.

In an exam you may be asked to trace and analyse what might happen if

• There was a change in market demand (e.g. arising from changes in


the relative prices of substitute products or complements)

• There was a cost-reducing innovation affecting all firms in the market


or an external shock that increases the variable costs of all producers.

Effects of a change in market demand

We now consider how a competitive market adjusts to a change in market


demand in both the short and the long run. In the short run, businesses are
operating with at least one fixed factor. Therefore the elasticity of the supply
curve depends on the amount of spare capacity, the level of existing stocks and
also the time scale of the production process – in other words how fast and at
what cost the industry can expand supply when demand changes.

In the long run, because of freedom of entry and exit into and out of the
industry, we expect the market supply curve to be more elastic in response to a
change in demand. The diagram below shows an outward shift of demand with
short run market supply deemed to be relatively inelastic (in which case the
short run adjustment in the market drives prices higher) but where long run
market supply is elastic, putting downward pressure on price as market output
increases.

Pure competition and economic efficiency


Perfect competition can be used as a yardstick to compare with other market
structures because it displays high levels of economic efficiency.

1. Allocative efficiency: In both the short and long run in perfect


competition we find that price is equal to marginal cost (P=MC) and thus
allocative efficiency is achieved. At the ruling market price, consumer and
producer surplus are maximised. No one can be made better off without
making some other agent at least as worse off – i.e. the conditions are in
place for a Pareto optimum allocation of resources.

2. Productive efficiency: Productive efficiency occurs when the


equilibrium output is produced with average cost at a minimum. This is
not achieved in the short run, but is attained in the long run equilibrium
for a perfectly competitive market.

3. Dynamic efficiency: We assume that a perfectly competitive market


produces homogeneous products – in other words, there is little scope for
innovation designed purely to make products differentiated from each
other and thereby allow a supplier to develop and then exploit a
competitive advantage in the market to establish some monopoly power.

Some economists claim that perfect competition is not an optimal market


structure for high levels of research and development spending and the resulting
product and process innovations. Indeed it may be the case that monopolistic or
oligopolistic markets are more effective in creating the environment for research
and innovation to flourish. A cost-reducing innovation from one producer will,
under the assumption of perfect information, be immediately and without cost
transferred to all of the other suppliers.

That said, a “competitive market” (i.e. a contestable market) provides the


discipline on firms to keep their costs under control, to seek to minimise wastage
of scarce resources and to refrain from exploiting the consumer by setting high
prices and enjoying high profit margins. In this sense, a more competitive
market can stimulate improvements in both static and dynamic efficiency over
time. It is certainly one of the main themes running through the recent
toughening-up of UK and European competition policy as this introductory
passage to a competition white paper demonstrates:

Gains from competition


Competitive markets provide the best means of ensuring that the economy's
resources are put to their best use by encouraging enterprise and efficiency, and
widening choice. Where markets work well, they provide strong incentives for
good performance - encouraging firms to improve productivity, to reduce prices
and to innovate; whilst rewarding consumers with lower prices, higher quality,
and wider choice. By encouraging efficiency, competition in the domestic market
- whether between domestic firms alone or between those and overseas firms -
also contributes to our international competitiveness.
Source: www.dti.gov.uk
The long run of perfect competition, therefore, exhibits optimal levels of
economic efficiency. But for this to be achieved all of the conditions of perfect
competition must hold – including in related markets. When the assumptions are
dropped, we move into a world of imperfect competition with all of the potential
that exists for various forms of market failure.

The next diagram shows how when price and output is not at the competitive
equilibrium, the result is a deadweight loss of economic welfare. The competitive
price and output is P1 and Q1 respectively.

Você também pode gostar