Você está na página 1de 35

Working Paper

The Property and Environment Research Center is dedicated to improving environmental quality through property rights and markets.
This paper can be downloaded without charge from The Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: http://www.ssrn.com/link/PERC-PUB.html

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2229897

THE FREEDOM TO FISH:


AN OBSOLETE INSTITUTION GOVERNING HIGH SEAS FISH STOCKS

Reed Watson

Abstract The high seas are often characterized as the final and most challenging frontier of fisheries governance. Stock depletions and rent dissipation persist there despite the recovery of several fish stocks within exclusive economic zones. This article examines the legal institutions relevant to managing straddling and highly migratory fish stocks, focusing in particular on the United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea (UNCLOs) and the UN Fish Stocks Agreement. It summarizes the evolution of the freedom to fish and explains how that freedom has frustrated efforts to address excess capitalization and stock depletion on the high seas. The article then describes the conditions under which a communal property framework, of the type envisioned in the UN Fish Stocks Agreement, could function for straddling and highly migratory fish stocks. Noting that these conditions are currently absent from most regional fisheries management organizations, the article concludes by outlining the options for collective and unilateral action to close the high seas commons.

Research Fellow and Applied Programs Director, Property and Environment Research Center (PERC). This paper was first presented at the workshop Tackling the Global Fisheries Challenge, held November 14 -15, 2012 at the PERC in Bozeman, Montana. I thank the participants at the workshop for helpful comments but take full responsibility for any errors or omissions.

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2229897

TABLE OF CONTENTS
I. INTRODUCTION ..................................................................................................................................... 2 II. FISHING ON THE HIGH SEAS ............................................................................................................. 4 A. Emergence and Evolution by Custom .................................................................................................. 4 B. Formal Convention............................................................................................................................... 6 III. TURBOT: A CASE STUDY IN CONFLICT ........................................................................................ 9 IV. THE UN FISH STOCKS AGREEMENT ............................................................................................ 11 A. Compelled Cooperation, Limited Influence ....................................................................................... 13 B. Self-Enforced Exclusion .................................................................................................................... 14 C. Self-Enforced Compliance ................................................................................................................. 15 D. Evaluating the RFMO Framework ..................................................................................................... 16 V. TOWARDS EXCLUSIVITY................................................................................................................. 21 A. B. Bolstering Communal Management ............................................................................................... 23 Extending the Sovereign Control of Coastal Nations ..................................................................... 26

VI. CONCLUSIONS .................................................................................................................................. 29 REFERENCES ........................................................................................................................................... 31

I. INTRODUCTION
The depletion of open-access resources is a well understood and documented phenomenon. Garret Hardins 1968 article The Tragedy of the Commons alone has more than 19,000 citations in the academic literature. Nonetheless, numerous natural resources still languish under open-access institutional regimes. Many of these resources are global in scale, beyond the jurisdiction of any one nation. The widespread depletion of global commons reflects

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2229897

the incentive of nations to free ride on the conservation measures of others and to act in their own rational self-interest despite there being societal benefits to unanimous restraint (Walker 2009). Few institutional structures reflect this international collective action dynamic better than those governing straddling and highly migratory fish stocks. In the waters beyond the 200 mile exclusive economic zones of coastal nations, hereinafter referred to as the high seas, international law dictates that all nations enjoy a practically unfettered freedom to fish. This paradigm example of open access has coincided with numerous stock collapses, rampant overcapitalization, and widespread economic waste (McWhinnie 2009). Without the ability to limit entry or enforce management rules, and with an indeterminate number of potential participants, it is hardly surprising that some of the most challenging fisheries management problems remaining in the world arise in what is left of the high seas (Hannesson 2011, 669; Serdy 2010). The purpose of this article is to examine the legal institutions governing high seas fish stocks and, in particular, the institutional reforms needed to avoid the collapse of straddling and highly migratory stocks. Section II reviews the customary foundations of the freedom to fish on the high seas and the subsequent recognition of that freedom in the United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea. Section III provides a short case study of the tension between the freedom of high seas fishing and the sovereignty of coastal nations. Section IV analyzes the UN Fish Stocks Agreement and the powers it describes for regional fisheries management organizations (RFMOs). Section V considers whether a communal property rights structure is feasible in the context of high seas fisheries. Concluding that the characteristics of effective community management are largely absent from the current RFMO structure, the section then outlines
3

multilateral and unilateral actions to cure those deficiencies and close the high seas commons. Section VI concludes.

II. FISHING ON THE HIGH SEAS


The overexploitation of many straddling and highly migratory fish stocks is not surprising given the open access nature of the resource (Barkin 2011). Originally by custom and now by formal convention, every nation is free to fish on the high seas. Commentators routinely characterize this freedom as the natural and egalitarian outcome of international negotiations (Orrego Vicua 1999). It is not. A careful examination of the institutional history reveals that the freedom of high seas fishing originated from and was subsequently circumscribed by the unilateral actions of coastal states acting in their own self-interest (Hannesson 2011, 668).

A. Emergence and Evolution by Custom


Most scholars trace the freedom of high seas fishing to the freedom of navigation articulated by the Dutch jurist Hugo Grotius. In his 1609 treatise Mare Liberum, Grotius argued that waters beyond territorial seas, historically three nautical miles from the coast, were international and that all nations were free to use it for seafaring trade. Later in the seventeenth century, the Dutch signed bilateral treaties with other European naval powers embracing Grotius doctrine and establishing as custom the freedom of high seas transit. The freedom of the high seas expanded from navigation to include the freedom of fishing. The theory advanced was that resources of the high seas, including the sea bed and the water column, were res communis, the
4

property of all, to which no nation could be excluded (Munro 2007). The freedom of the seas as it specifically applied to fisheries rested upon the two assumptions, first, that coastal states could not effectively control fishing activities beyond their territorial waters, and, second, that high seas fish stocks were inexhaustible (Orrego Vicua 1999). Not until after late in the 19th century were either of these assumptions tested (Smith 1994). Technological advancements in navigation, fish finding equipment, refrigeration, and transportation allowed both costal and distant water fishing nations to profitably target epipelagic species such as tuna and bill fish, as well as deep water species such as toothfish and roughy (Valdermarsen 2001). Dwindling coastal stocks coupled with increasing global seafood demand during the second half of the twentieth century accelerated the spatial expansion and capitalization of high seas fisheries (Bjarndal and Munro 2003). As these developments undermined the second assumption of resource inexhaustibility, coastal states acted unilaterally to regulate fishing beyond their territorial waters, thus casting doubt on the first assumption of coastal state incapacity. With the Truman proclamations of 1945, the United States unilaterally asserted exclusive jurisdiction over portions of the continental shelf beyond the traditional territorial seas.1 A second proclamation specific to high seas fisheries stated in relevant part: In view of the pressing need for conservation and protection of fishery resources, the Government of the United States regards it as proper to establish conservation zones in those areas of the high seas contiguous to the coasts of the United States wherein fishing activities have been or in the future may be developed and maintained on a substantial scale. Where such activities have been or shall hereafter be developed and maintained by its nationals alone, the United States regards it as proper to establish explicitly bounded conservation zones in which
1

Proclamation No. 2667, "Policy of the United States with Respect to the Natural Resources of the Subsoil and SeaBed of the Continental Shelf", 28 September 1945, 10 Fed. Reg. 12303; XIII Bulletin, Dept. of State, No. 327, 30 September 1945, p. 485.

fishing activities shall be subject to the regulation and control of the United States.2

The true precursors to the existing exclusive economic zone were the unilateral actions of Chile3 and Peru,4 who by presidential proclamation claimed sovereignty out to 200 nautical miles. During the ensuing decades, coastal nations around the globe made similar declarations of sovereignty beyond traditional territorial waters. As these and the Truman proclamations were protectionist measures aimed at limiting fishing, mining, and other resource extraction by foreign nations, the freedom of navigation was preserved (Nanada 1987).

B. Formal Convention
The formal recognition of freedom on the high seas came in 1982 with the third United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea. Specifically, Article 87(1) of the Convention states the high seas are open to all states, whether coastal or land-locked, and articulates a nonexhaustive list of freedoms including navigation, over flight, the laying of submarine cables, building artificial islands, fishing, and scientific research.5 Articles 55 and 56 define the exclusive economic zone and the rights of coastal states therein, respectively. In relevant part, Article 56 states [i]n the exclusive economic zone, the coastal State has (a) sovereign rights for the purpose of exploring and exploiting, conserving and
2

Proclamation No. 2668. Policy of the United States with Respect to Coastal Fisheries in Certain Areas of the High Seas." 28 September 1945, 10 Fed. Reg. 1230. 3 Presidential Declaration Concerning Continental Shelf of 23 June 1947, El Mercurio, Santiago de Chile, 29 June 1947. 4 Presidential Decree No. 781 of 1 August 1947, El Peruano: Diario Oficial. Vol. 107, No. 1983, 11 August 1947. 5 United Nations, Third United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea,1833 U.N.T.S. 397, 10 December 1982 [hereinafter UNCLOS or Convention].

managing the natural resources; [and] (b) jurisdiction as provided for in the relevant provisions of this Convention with regard to (iii) the protection and preservation of the marine environment. Article 57 limits coastal states from defining exclusive economic zones beyond 200 nautical miles from the baseline from which the territorial sea is measured. Explicitly codifying the superiority of coastal state sovereignty within exclusive economic zones, Article 86 explains that the freedom on high seas does not entail any abridgement of the freedoms enjoyed by all States in the exclusive economic zone in accordance with article 58. The 1982 Convention also specifically addressed the management of straddling stocks and highly migratory fish stocks, though it did so in a fairly opaque manner. With respect to straddling stocks, Article 63 obligates coastal and fishing nations to seek, either directly or through appropriate subregional or regional organizations, to agree upon the measures necessary for the conservation of these stocks in the adjacent [high seas] area. Similarly, Article 64 regarding highly migratory stocks states coastal and distant water fishing nations: shall cooperate directly or through appropriate international organizations with a view to ensuring conservation and promoting the objective of optimum utilization of such species throughout the region, both within and beyond the exclusive economic zone. In regions for which no appropriate international organization exists, the coastal State and other States whose nationals harvest the species in the region shall cooperate to establish such an organization and participate in its work.

Article 116 conditions a nations right to high seas fishing on adherence to the above provisions though it does not specify any objective criteria or enforcement mechanisms by which noncooperating nations would lose their high seas fishing rights. Given the distribution of fishing effort at the timethe FAO estimated in the period leading up to the widespread establishment of EEZs, total fish catch beyond 200 nautical miles
7

from the coastline amounted to approximately five percent of the total catch (FAO 1994)it might have appeared that the tragedy of the commons had been averted in regards to ocean fisheries. Indeed, coastal states had exclusive jurisdiction and, most importantly, the ability to exclude vessels from other nations from the most productive fishing grounds. Appearances can be deceiving, however, and tensions between the rights of coastal and distant water fishing nations soon appeared. First, as Lawrence Juda explained, the fish themselves proved uncooperative, failing to recognize the sanctity of human-made delimitations adopted by diplomatic conference. For them the 200-mile limit held no particular meaning, and instead of recognizing its significance, they continued to respond to biological and physical imperatives (Juda 1997). Secondly, though some distant water fishing vessels returned to home waters, others began to expend considerable time and effort fishing waters immediately beyond the EEZs (Juda 1997). In fact, following UNCLOS passage, the portion of the total marine fish catch rapidly increased two-fold (FAO 1994). Articles 63 and 64 of UNCLOS, describing in generalities the duty of coastal and fishing nations to cooperate, not surprisingly failed to alleviate the uncertainty and conflict over straddling and highly migratory fish stocks. Indeed, by recognizing the authority of coastal states to evict distant water fishing nations from traditional coastal fishing grounds but failing to articulate a hierarchy of rights for straddling or highly migratory fish stocks, UNCLOS indirectly increased fishing pressure on the high seas (Maguire 2006) and hastened the conflicts over straddling and highly migratory fish stocks (Juda 1997).

III. TURBOT: A CASE STUDY IN CONFLICT


The Turbot War of 1995 is a well-worn but illustrative example of the legal uncertainty surrounding the management and harvest of straddling and highly migratory fish stocks. During the 1950s and 1960s, longer seasons (MacCay and Finlayson 1995) and rapid industrialization of the fishing industry off Canadas eastern coast began to deplete the regions commercially viable stocks, particularly Northern cod (DeSombre and Barkin 2002, 332). In 1992, following years of below average catch reports, Canadas federal government declared an indefinite moratorium on cod fishing in Canadian waters. By 1994, the Northwest Atlantic Fishery Organization (NAFO), the relevant regional fisheries management organization, also declared a moratorium on cod fishing in the high seas area beyond Canadas recently established exclusive economic zone. In response to the cod moratoriums, the fishing-dependent communities of Newfoundland and Nova Scotia began targeting various groundfish species on the Grand Banks including Greenland halibut, also known as turbot. After the collapse of the cod fishery, distant water fishing nations (DWFNs) also began pursuing turbot beyond Canadas EEZ. In 1994, fearing the turbot fishery would collapse as had the cod fishery, Canadas House of Commons amended the Coastal Fisheries Protection Act to prohibit foreign vessels from fishing for straddling stocks in contravention of any conservation and management measures,6 and to allow protection officers to board, inspect, and search vessels found in Canadian or the NAFO Regulatory Area.7 These amendments effectively extended Canadas exclusive economic zone beyond the 200 nautical mile limit.

6 7

Coastal Fisheries Protection Act, 1994, c. 14 s. 2 Coastal Fisheries Protection Act, R.S., 1985, c. C-33, s. 7; R.S., 1985, c. 31 (1st Supp.), s. 5; 1994, c. 14, s. 4.

Soon after these amendments, NAFO established a total allowable catch for turbot (Canadian Department of Fisheries and Oceans 1995a). The European Union, of which Spain was by then a member, invoked the RFMOs objection procedure and unilaterally set a higher quota for itself. On March 6, 1995 Canadas Prime Minister Chretien proposed a 60 -day moratorium on turbot fishing so that the parties could resolve the dispute diplomatically (Gezelius 1999). The EU rejected the proposal, and Spain threatened to send warships to protect its turbot fishing fleet. On March 9, 1995, a Canadian Department of Fisheries and Oceans (DFO) vessel, the Cape Roger, arrested the Spanish stern trawler Estai on the grounds that the vessel had been fishing turbot illegally.8 The arrest occurred approximately 245 miles from Canadas nearest coast, well into the international waters beyond Canadas 200 mile EEZ. Though specific details of the event were disputed, most versions include the Estai crew cutting their nets and fleeing as the Canadian vessels approached, then only surrendering after the Cape Roger crew fired warning shots from a .50 caliber machine gun. The resulting political imbroglio is what makes the Turbot War the paradigmatic example of the tension between the freedom of high seas fishing and the management of straddling fish stocks. Brian Tobin, then director of Canadas Department of Fisheries and Oceans, demanded withdrawal of all Spanish vessels from the Grand Banks. Tobin claimed the international laws governing straddling stocks were ineffective and that Canadas extra-jurisdictional actions were legal and justified (Blake 19998). Tobin also accused several nations of overexploiting straddling stocks in the Bering Sea and the Sea of Okhotsk.

The claim of illegal fishing was presumably based not on the EUs objection to the NAFO turbot quota but to the Estais use of an illegal drift net per NAFO regulation.

10

Spain and the EU countered that Canadas enforcement of domestic laws in international waters violated international law and, in particular, UNCLOS Article 89.9 Later in March, 1995, the EU attempted to use economic sanctions against Canada and was only unsuccessful because Britain voted against them. After much bickering, the parties agreed to a new mandatory enforcement regime to govern Canadian and EU vessels operating in the NAFO regulatory area, including independent, on-board observers, enhanced surveillance and monitoring, and gear restrictions (Canadian Department of Fisheries and Oceans 1995b). On its face, the Turbot War involved only two nations and one marginally profitable straddling stock. But in a broader sense, the conflict reflected the widespread confusion over the high seas freedom to fish vis--vis the jurisdiction of coastal nations. Perhaps fittingly then, the Turbot War significantly shaped what remains the applicable law on straddling and highly migratory fish stocks, the UN Fish Stocks Agreement. As discussed in Section V, the case study is worth reconsidering as a positive example of fisheries governance and a useful guide for future institutional reform.

IV. THE UN FISH STOCKS AGREEMENT


Following closely on the heels of the Turbot dispute, the final session of the United Nations Conference on Straddling Fish Stocks and Highly Migratory Fish Stocks produced what is officially known as the Agreement for the Implementation of the Provisions of the United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea of 10 December 1982 relating to the Conservation
9

UNCLOS entered into force on 16 November 1994, so, to the extent Article 89 of that agreement would have prescribed Canadas enforcement of domestic fishing regulations on distant water fishing nations operating beyond the 200 nautical mile boundary, the provision was untested.

11

and Management of Straddling Fish Stocks and Highly Migratory Fish Stocks, or what is more commonly called the UN Fish Stocks Agreement. The stated objective, as included in the unabbreviated title, was to ensure the long-term conservation and sustainable use of straddling fish stocks and highly migratory fish stocks.10 As evidenced by the gunboat diplomacy in the North Atlantic, the depletion of Alaskan Pollock in the Bering Strait Donut Hole, and cod on the Newfoundland Grand Banks (Crothers and Nelson 2006), UNCLOS had failed to articulate a hierarchy of rights or workable management framework with respect to straddling and highly migratory stocks. The UN Fish Stocks Agreement was to be the answer. Among the principles stated in Article 5, the Fish Stocks Agreement set out to ensure the long-term sustainability of straddling and highly migratory fish stocks and to prevent or eliminate overfishing and excess fishing capacity.11Towards these ends, the Agreement compels coastal and high seas fishing nations to agree upon the measures necessary for the conservation of straddling stocks in the high seas areas adjacent to EEZs and to cooperate with a view to ensuring the optimum utilization of highly migratory stocks throughout their migratory region. 12 Drafters of the Fish Stocks Agreement thus did not attempt to impose top-down directives for managing straddling and highly migratory stocks; they sought to compel cooperation, agreement, and collective management by all interested nations.

10

United Nations, Agreement for the Implementation of the Provisions of the United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea of 10 December 1982 relating to the Conservation and Management of Straddling Fish Stocks and Highly Migratory Fish Stocks,4 August 1995 [hereinafter Fish Stocks Agreement or Agreement]. 11 Id., at Article 5, paragraphs (a), (b), and (h). 12 Id., at Article 7, paragraph 1 (a) and (b).

12

A. Compelled Cooperation, Limited Influence


Part III of the Agreement sets out the mechanisms for international cooperation and specifies the rights and responsibilities of coastal and distant water fishing nations. Specifically, Article 8, paragraph 3 requires relevant coastal nations and those nations fishing for straddling and highly migratory stocks managed by a regional fisheries management organization (RFMO) to become members of the RFMO or to agree to apply the RFMOs conservation management measures.13 If no regional fisheries management organization exists for a particular straddling or highly migratory stock, the Agreement requires relevant coastal and distant water fishing states to establish one. Per the Agreement, RFMO membership is open to every state with a real interest in the fisheries concerned, though the term real interest is not defined and there is no deadline for entry.14 Article 10 of the Fish Stocks Agreement enumerates RFMO functions, including the collection and exchange of catch data, the use of scientific information in standard setting, and the accommodation of new members and their fishing interests.15 The relevant provisions specifically empower RFMOs to define participatory rights such as allocations of allowable catch or levels of fishing effort; and to establish appropriate cooperative mechanisms for effective monitoring, control, surveillance and enforcement.16 But what the Agreement does not do is specify RFMO procedures for passing resolutions. Member and cooperating nations are required by the Fish Stocks Agreement to consider an enumerated list of historical and biological
13

Regional fisheries management organizations and regional fisheries management arrangements are functionally equivalent and treated the same throughout the Fish Stocks Agreement. Therefore, for the remainder of this article, any discussion of organizations or RFMOs is applicable to arrangements. 14 UN Fish Stocks Agreement, at Article 8, paragraph 3. 15 Article 11 specifies the factors member states can consider when determining the nature and extent of participatory rights for new members, including the status of the fisheries under management, the fishing practices and patterns of members and participants, and the interests of coastal communities. 16 UN Fish Stocks Agreement, at Article 10 (b) and (h).

13

considerations but are otherwise free to adopt whatever rules and rule-promulgating procedures they see fit.17 While some RFMOs have developed workable procedures for enacting conservation measures, other organizations require consensus among membership and, as a result, have been unable to enact meaningful limits on catch, effort, or participation (Allen, Joseph, and Squires 2010, xiii). Moreover, because the RFMOs are often comprised of diverse nations with opposing interests, achieving any agreement can be difficult and, when it does occur, the agreements tend to be weak (Alder and Lugten 2002) and diluted from the science-based recommendations (Crothers and Nelson 2006). By and large, the cooperation-based conservation of high seas fish stocks has not emerged organically from the RFMOs, as was envisioned in the UN Fish Stocks Agreement.

B. Self-Enforced Exclusion
In perhaps the most substantive provision of the entire Fish Stocks Agreement, Article 8, paragraph 4 limits access to fishery resources governed by an RFMO to members of the organizations and those nations which agree to apply the RFMOs conservation and management measures. Similarly, Article 17 prohibits a nonmember and non-cooperating nation from authorizing vessels flying its flag to fish for straddling or highly migratory stocks managed by an RFMO. Although these provisions purport to exclude nonmember and non-cooperating nations from fishing for straddling or highly migratory fish stocks managed by an RFMO, the Fish Stocks Agreement does not expressly grant RFMO member or cooperating nations exclusion
17

UN Fish Stocks Agreement, at Article 7, paragraph 2 (a) through (f).

14

power; enforcement of the vessel exclusion is left to the vessels flag state.18 Member, participating, and cooperating states are only empowered to exchange information on vessels flagged by excluded nations and to take measures . . . to deter activities of such vessels which undermine the effectiveness of subregional and regional conservation and management measures.19 Aside from the enforcement powers, or lack thereof, the applicability of these provisions to non-signatories of the Fish Stocks Agreements is questionable under international law. Specifically, Article 34 of the Vienna Convention on the law of Treaties holds that [a] treaty does not create either obligations or rights for a third State without its consent.20 If we assume the exclusion provision of the Fish Stocks Agreement is an implementing provision of UNCLOS, it would bind all 162 UNCLOS signatories (Juda 1997). But, if on the other hand, the Fish Stocks Agreement is a separate and distinct convention, it binds only those 79 nations that signed the FSA. Under either interpretation, the lack of universal application and the expectation of selfenforcement allow for widespread for free-riding which, in turn, discourages signatories from enacting meaningful conservation measures to rebuild stocks (Crothers and Nelson 2006).

C. Self-Enforced Compliance
Much like exclusion from the fishery, enforcement of conservation rules in the fishery is effectively left to flag states (FAO 2001). The Fish Stocks Agreement specifies only weak enforcement powers for RFMO member and participating nations, as against each other (Korman

18 19

Id., at Article 17, paragraphs 1-2. Id., at Article 17, paragraph 4. 20 United Nations, Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties, 23 May 1969, vol. 1155, article 34.

15

2010). Article 20 specifies the duty of member states to cooperate in the enforcement of subregional and regional conservation and management measures, to share information on possible violations, and to immediately investigate alleged violations by vessels flagged by the member state.21 But, because member states can unilaterally opt out of adopted measures, or refuse to enforce them on their own vessels, compliance is more a matter of convenience than credible commitmenteven among member states (Munro 2007). The enforcement powers applicable to vessels of nonmember nations are even weaker. Rosemary Rayfuse explains that flag states have limited interest in or means of enforcing RFMO conservation measures, particularly against vessels flying flags of convenience (Rayfuse 2004). What few enforcement powers RFMO members can apply to nonmembers are heavily conditioned and rarely employed. For instance, Article 21 which specifies boarding and inspecting powers for RFMO member and participating states, only allows an inspecting state to seize a foreign vessel and prevent it from fishing if (1) there are clear grounds for believing the vessel committed a serious violation, (2) notice has been provided to the flag state, and (3) the flag state has failed to respond to the notice or take any enforcement action.22

D. Evaluating the RFMO Framework


Given the limited exclusion and enforcement powers described in the Fish Stocks Agreement, it is hardly surprising that RFMOs have made little progress towards ensuring the long term conservation and sustainable use of straddling and highly migratory fish stocks (Cullis-Suzuki and Pauly 2010; Rayfuse 2004). The question is whether the RFMO model of
21 22

UN Fish Stocks Agreement, at Article 20. UN Fish Stocks Agreement, at Article 21, paragraph 8, referencing paragraphs 5-7.

16

communal resource management in incurably flawed or whether it can be reformed to successfully prevent the tragedy of commons on the high seas. In her 1990 book Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, Elinor Ostrom described the common characteristics of groups that have effectively governed common pool resources. What she described as the basic design principles included: 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. Group boundaries are clearly defined. Rules governing the use of collective goods match local needs and conditions. Most individuals affected by these rules can participate in modifying the rules. The rights of community members to devise their own rules are respected by external authorities. A system for monitoring member's behavior exists and community members undertake this monitoring. A graduated system of sanctions is used. Community members have access to low-cost conflict resolution mechanisms. For common pool resources that are parts of larger systems: appropriation, provision, monitoring, enforcement, conflict resolution, and governance activities are organized in multiple layers of nested enterprises (Ostrom 1990).

Because the regional fisheries management organizations rely on the cooperation and selfgovernance of coastal and distant water fishing nations acting in their own self-interest, Ostroms basic design principles provide a useful framework for understanding why RFMOs have not been more successful at managing high seas fish stocks. The first design principle, clearly defined group boundaries, is perhaps the most important feature to prevent the exhaustion of common pool resources and, unfortunately, it is also probably the characteristic most lacking from the current RFMO structure (Munro 2007). Pursuant to Article 8, paragraph 3, RFMO membership is limited to nations with a real interest, but because that term is not defined, the provision offers no meaningful limit at all. At minimum, requiring previous participation in the fishery would limit the total number of potential participants to an ascertainable list (Ple 2000). Developing nations might object on

17

equity grounds but, according to Serdy (2010) those wanting to enter the fishery will m ost likely have made their investments already, and in any event there are few international fisheries in a healthy enough state for new investment in them to be encouraged. An alternative strategy for clearly defining the group is to require some sort of credible commitment and to set a deadline after which enrollment is closed. Making enrollment costless only encourages speculation, and not limiting enrollment perpetuates the free-rider problem and its chilling effect on meaningful conservation measures. A separate but related issue to clearly defined group membership is the exclusion of nonmembers. Though Articles 8 and 17 purport to exclude vessels flagged by nations that dont join or participate with the relevant RFMO, exclusion of these vessels has proven difficult with the Agreements reliance on flag state enforcement. Not surprisingly, this inability to exclude has discouraged cooperative management and the adoption of meaningful conservation measures by the RFMOs (Kaitala and Munro 1997). Several RFMOs have implemented closed regional vessel registers as an initial step towards defining group boundaries. Allen, Bayliff, Joseph and Squires (2010, 92) describe how the Inter-American Tropical Tuna Commission (IATTC) established a closed Regional Vessel Register (RVR) as a form of limited entry and a hybrid of international common property and individual use rights. The resolution initiating the IATTCs register requests that member parties provide and continually update a list of authorized vessels fishing for tuna and tuna like species in the Eastern Pacific Ocean (EPO) (IATTC 2000). Though touted for providing exclusivity, it is not entirely clear whether this RVR binds only participating nations or whether it grants the RFMOs ability to enforce exclusion of non-registered vehicles from high seas areas. The fact that the resolution creating the contracting parties only requests and does not
18

obligate nonmember nations with vessels fishing in the Eastern Pacific Ocean to provide the relevant vessel information suggests that the RVR does not enhance exclusion powers beyond what is described in the Fish Stocks Agreement. Moreover, because member nations can make changes to the RVR without consent of or compensation to the vessel owners, the access rights created by the RVR are insecure. With few exceptions, defining group boundaries and excluding nonmembers is costly, if not practically impossible, under the freedom of the high seas and the current RFMO framework. The second and third design principles regarding the importance of local conditions and member participation in rule modification are present, or at least available, in the current RFMO structure. Their regional scope addresses the locality issue as effectively as can be hoped given the immense range of tuna and other highly migratory species. However, regarding the participatory requirement of rule modification, the group consensus required by several RFMOs combined with the heterogeneity of group member objectives is thought to limit their ability to pass meaningful conservation measures. If the consensus requirement is a strategic choice by members seeking to limit the ability of RFMOs, other members could challenge these policies under Article 7, specifically, the requirement of signatories to cooperate and agree to measures necessary for the conservation and optimum utilization of fish stocks.

Like the first principle regarding clearly defined group boundaries, the fourth design principle regarding external authorities respecting the rights of community members to devise their own rules is incredibly important but currently lacking from high seas fisheries institutions. On the surface, the Fish Stocks Agreement appears to recognize the right of RFMOs to enact conservation measures, but it does not go the necessary distance of binding nations who are not members to the organization. In essence, nonmembers are external authorities and they are
19

expressly not required to respect an RFMOs conservation practices per the Vienna Convention. Hence, the relevant questions become whether an RFMO conservation measure that subjugates the freedom of other nations to fish on the high seas would be challenged by those nations; whether the challenge would come in the form of gun boat diplomacy demonstrated during the Turbot War or through adjudication; and, if by adjudication, how an international tribunal would decide the case.

Regarding the fifth principle, an effective monitoring system, the Fish Stocks Agreement describes fairly robust procedures for boarding and inspecting vessels flagged by RFMO members and detailed, if highly conditional, authority for RFMO-member vessels to board and inspect vessels flagged by nonmember and non-participating nations. Additionally, several RFMOs have instituted on-board observer programs and electronic vessel monitoring systems to ensure compliance with enacted conservation measures. The obvious problems, however, are that RFMOs cover enormous areas, spanning millions of square miles of open ocean, and budget constraints can reduce the impact of observer coverage and electronic tracking to insufficient levels. Monitoring for IUU fishing at the port state is a third option but not a panacea given the ability of nonmembers to transfer catch to member-flagged vessels or to land catches at distant ports not involved in the RFMO.

The use of a graduated systems of sanctions is largely absent from the 1995 Fish Stocks Agreement and the existing practices of most RFMOs. Again, the issue turns on the selfenforcement expectation. If some flag states are unwilling to regulate or sanction IUU fishing, the incentive for self-regulation by all flag states is reduced. The Nauru Agreement Concerning Cooperation in the Management of Fisheries of Common Interest, or simply the Nauru

20

Agreement, provides a good example of several nations developing a treaty-based solution to this prisoners dilemma problem. The Parties to the Nauru Agreement23 (PNA) collectively control 25-30 percent of the worlds tuna supply and approximately 60 percent of the western and central Pacific tuna supply (Lan 2011). Signatory countries agreed, among other things, not to license purse seine vessels observed fishing in certain defined high seas areas (Nauru Fisheries and Marine Resources Authority 2010). If observed fishing in a prohibited area, a vessels license to fish in a signatorys waters can be revoked. Other restrictions are included in the Implementing Arrangements, such as a prohibition on fish aggregating devices, and the sanctioning system has worked to deter noncompliance (Gagern and van den Bergh 2011).

The final design principles Ostrom describes are accessible and low-cost dispute resolution procedures and a nested organizational structure for common-pool resources that are parts of larger systems. To its credit, the Fish Stocks Agreement provides ample flexibility for RFMOs to develop these structures individually, and that flexibility is desirable given the regional and fishery-specific political dynamics.

V. TOWARDS EXCLUSIVITY
Despite the possibility for regional fishery management organizations to develop some of the characteristics Ostrom found in effective communal management regimes, it is evident that few, if any, of these characteristics are inherent in the current RFMO structure. The first design principle, clearly defined group boundaries and the exclusion of nonmembers, is antithetical to

23

The Parties to the Nauru Agreement (PNA) include Federated States of Micronesia, Kiribati, Marshall Islands, Nauru, Palau, Papua New Guinea, Solomon Islands, and Tuvalu.

21

the freedom of the high seas and yet critical to the success of communal management strategy embodied in the RFMOs. As such, a non-trivial tension exists between the freedom of high seas fishing described in UNCLOS and the objectives of long term conservation and sustainable use of high seas fish stocks articulated in the UN Fish Stocks Agreement. This section explores the various actions signatories to the Agreement can take to exclude nonmember nations from entering RFMO managed fisheries and engaging in illegal, unreported, and unregulated fishing. Assuming that a communal property framework is untenable at the international level, the final section describes the conditions under which coastal states might act unilaterally to extend their sovereign control beyond the current 200 mile boundary.

As discussed above, custom has preceded formal convention in the development of the law of the sea. Regarding UNCLOS and exclusive economic zones, the convention came after unilateral actions by coastal states expanded sovereign jurisdiction from three to 12 and eventually to 200 nautical miles, thereby diminishing the scope of the freedom of the high seas as Grotius first pronounced it. Regarding the UN Fish Stocks Agreement, the convention recognized the regional fisheries management organizations already in operation but did little to expand their exclusion, conservation, or enforcement powers. If we assume past developments are any predictor of the future, bottom-up custom rather than top-down convention is likely to drive the institutional reforms needed to support ecologically and economically sustainable management of highly migratory and straddling fish stocks. Indeed, based on the history of high seas fishing, one could argue that the existing international conventions have served little more than a positivist function, only pronouncing then-existing customs and norms.

22

A. Bolstering Communal Management


With the understanding that UNCLOS and the UN Fish Stocks Agreement are the byproducts of customnot the final word on the law of the seainstitutional reform becomes a realistic if not inevitable outcome. Nonetheless, accepting the proposition that any state can enter a high seas fishery under current international law, Hallman et al. (2010) describe various mechanisms for deterring nonmember nations from entering a transnational fishery managed by an RFMO. These measures are aimed at clarifying group boundaries through self-exclusion and voluntary compliance with RFMO conservation measures; hence they are consistent with the freedom of fishing on the high seas and more likely to be perceived as legitimate. The first approach Hallman et al. describe for deterring entry by nonmember nations24 involves the use of trade measures, a wide variety of actions nations can take by themselves or with cooperating countries to compel participation in an RFMO or to render entry by nonmember nations less profitable (Hallman et al. 2010). The two broad categories of trade measures are prohibitions on imports from nonmember fishing vessels and prohibitions on landings, port use, and transshipments from nonmember nations (Barrett 2006, DeSombre 2005). The Fur Seals Treaty provides an example of success: by prohibiting the import and processing of nonauthenticated fur seal skins, the Treaty deterred entry into the fishery by non-signatories. The import ban was particularly easy to enforce in the fur seals market because London was the only port of note at the time (Hallman et al. 2010).25 Though such a ban would be more difficult to enforce with multiple ports for landing tunas and other high seas species, the credible threat of

24

The first mechanism Hallman et al. describe, domestic compliance, is meant to deter additional fishing pressure from member nations. Though important, member compliance is a separate issue beyond the focus of this article. 25 Presumably fur seal processing capacity was not easily built in other, entrepreneurial port locations.

23

trade sanctions has and will continue to enable RFMOs to restrict market access and curtail IUU fishing (Rayfuse 2004; Ple 2000; DeSombre 2005). The second approach Hallman et al. describe for deterring entry concerns exclusion of unregistered vessels. In the context of high seas fisheries, Serdy (2010) notes that the treatybased rule of exclusion of nonmembers could have already risen to the level of custom. Joseph et al. (2009) find support for this argument in the closed regional vessel registers, such as the IATTCs, which ostensibly limit participation in the fishery to registered vessels. According to Aust (2010), however, for state action to rise to the level of customary international law there first must be evidence of substantial uniformity across states and, second, there must be general recognition by states that the action is sufficiently settled to be binding on all states. It is certainly debatable whether both of these conditions are present. The third approach, excluding nonmembers from fishing in member parties EEZs, is exemplified by the Nauru Agreement described above. Of course, the success of this approach depends on the size of the high seas area relative to the exclusive economic zones and the target species range. That is to say, excluding nonmembers from fishing in an EEZ will only deter high seas fishing if the EEZ exclusion significantly reduces the profitability of fishing on the high seas (Hannesson 2005). In areas where a larger portion of the target species is found on the high seas, exclusion from member nations EEZ will be a weaker deterrent to high seas fishing. As Hallman et al. explain, enforcement of conservation measures is more effective when it is perceived as legitimate by all nations, not just the members of the RFMO. The financial disincentives created by trade measures, limiting access to registered vessels, and EEZ exclusion are all designed to encourage self-exclusion and compliance by nonmembers, thus adding to their

24

perceived legitimacy. The question remains, however, whether the financial disincentives will be sufficient to actually deter entry into the fishery. If not, unilateral action by RFMO member nations might be necessary to exclude nonmembers and preserve the communal property model. The final method Hallman et al. describe for deterring entry into a high seas fishery is unique from the others in in that it contemplates unilateral enforcement actions by member nations. Rather than relying on financial disincentives to prompt self-exclusion and compliance, this approach contemplates the seizure of vessels from nonmember nations fishing in contravention of the RFMOs conservation measures. To enhance the perceived legitimacy, RFMOs could pass resolutions declaring the specific conditions and deadline for entry, as well as the unilateral enforcement procedures by which nonmembers would later be expelled from RFMO waters. Though such declarations and unilateral exclusion actions might seem to violate the UNCLOS Article 87, they could be justified under either UNCLOS Article 116, which conditions the freedom to high seas fishing on a nations cooperation with and adherence to conservation measures.26 Justifying the exclusion of nations from high seas areas governed by RFMOs requires that the exclusion criteria be reasonably related to the real interest language used in Article 8, Paragraph 3 of the Fish Stocks Agreement and that the exclusion be done in furtherance of an RFMO conservation measure. Authority to board and inspect non-complying vessels can be found in Article 21 of the Fish Stocks Agreement (Bederman 2000) though the seizure of those vessels and their crew would require actions not currently sanctioned by the Fish Stocks Agreement.

26

UN Fish Stocks Agreement, Articles 87 and 116.

25

In addition to clarifying group boundaries and excluding nonmembers, unilateral action could also garner external respect for RFMO conservation measures and buttress the internal sanctioning of non-compliance, the other basic design principles of communal property management most clearly missing from existing institutions. Specifically, the boarding, inspection, and seizure of vessels violating an RFMOs conservation measures is ultimately necessary if straddling and highly migratory fish stocks are to be effectively managed as communal property. Barrett et al. (2004) argue that the development of international custom may indeed require RFMO members unilaterally seize vessels of non-signatory nations. Guzman (2012), reflecting on the Estai incident, claims that unilateral action by Canada was required to drive dissenting states to the negotiating table and that similar unilateral actions is necessary to overcome the inefficient requirement of consent to establish binding international law.

B. Extending the Sovereign Control of Coastal Nations


Each of the deterrents Hallman et al. describe could reduce the incidence of illegal, unreported, and unregulated fishing on the high seas. However, none of them is likely to achieve the degree of exclusivity that is required to foster market-based management of straddling or highly migratory fish stocks. Though catch shares and other market-based schemes have prevented or reversed the collapse of numerous fish stocks within exclusive economic zones (Costello et al. 2010), their applicability on the high seas is limited. As Hannesson (2004) explains, individual transferable quotas (ITQs) only emerged after the establishment of exclusive economic zones; exclusive sovereign control is a prerequisite to setting meaningful limits on total catch, distributing catch shares among industry participants, monitoring catches, enforcing

26

rule compliance, and excluding outsiders. In only a handful of instances have multiple nations collaborated to rationalize a fishery, and in all of them, management authority eventually devolved to the national level.27 Serdy (2010) argues that international law does not preclude RFMO member nations from collaborating to create a market of tradable, multi-national catch shares, but that participating nations must first establish national quota allocations, agree on an ad hoc or continuing basis to waive objection procedures when trades disturb the initial quota allocations, and determine ex-ante how to accommodate new entrants. If RFMOs are incapable of excluding non-members, the only mechanism by which market-based management could emerge for straddling or highly migratory fish stocks is for coastal nations to extend their sovereign control into the high seas. Indeed, the incremental extension of sovereign jurisdiction into the high seas has shaped fisheries management more directly, if not more abruptly, than any formal convention or RFMO conservation measure. Since the freedom of fishing on the high seas is the remainder of coastal nations incrementally extending sovereign jurisdiction, and since UNCLOS and the UN Fish Stocks Agreement are not prohibitive barriers to further extensions, why havent coastal nations carved up the remaining high seas or, at the very least, extended their jurisdictions to encompass commercially valuable straddling and highly migratory fish stocks? At least four explanations are possible. First, most of the influential coastal nations have distant water fishing fleets that would suffer financial losses if areas of the high seas were closed. Few nations fit neatly into one of the two categories of coastal or distant water fishing nation, and the choice of coastal
27

For example, the International Halibut Commission sets the overall catch quota for the Pacific halibut that occupies both U.S. and Canadian waters; however, each country separately manages its own ITQ system. Similarly, the European Commission sets catch limits for North Sea flatfish stocks, with member states receiving their own share and determining their own management regime (Hannesson 2011).

27

nations not to catalyze the expansion of EEZs beyond 200 miles could be influenced by their own distant water fishing interests. Second, extending sovereign jurisdiction far beyond the coast entails significant monitoring and boundary enforcement costs, all with uncertain benefits. Though technological advancements have reduced the cost of detecting entry by foreign vessels, credible boundary enforcement requires boats on the water to evict intruders or an internationally recognized system of sanctions. Third, and on a related note, extending coastal state sovereign jurisdiction could precipitate armed conflict. The Canadian governments arrest of the Estai during the Turbot War nearly did. Extending coastal state sovereign control necessitates the curtailment or complete elimination of the freedom to fish on the high seas. The major distant water fishing nations, Russia, Japan, Taiwan, Korea, Poland and Spain, will undoubtedly oppose such extensions, perhaps with military force. War is perhaps the highest possible cost of boundary enforcement. The fourth and final explanation for why coastal nations have not extended exclusive sovereign control further into the high seas is that jurisdictional expansion might not solve the conflict over straddling and highly migratory fish stocks. By definition, the range of all highly migratory stocks and most straddling stocks encompasses ocean to which multiple coastal nations could claim jurisdiction. Neighboring coastal nations presumably could negotiate management agreements for straddling and highly migratory stocks, as some have done for transboundary stocks, in essence forming regional fishery management organizations that entirely exclude distant water fishing nations. The Nauru Agreement could be characterized in this light, though the replicability of this approach could be limited for the reasons noted above.

28

Until the benefits of extending coastal state jurisdiction beyond 200 miles exceed the costs of defining, monitoring, and enforcing the new boundaries; the risk of future stock collapses, continued overcapitalization, and armed conflict; as well as the foregone revenue of fishing in distant waters, coastal nations are unlikely to act unilaterally to close the high seas commons. This leaves RFMOs to solve the issue of excluding distant water fishing nations that free ride on the conservation measures of member nations. And while RFMO members have several exclusion strategies to choose fromtrade measures, vehicle registries, EEZ exclusion, and unilateral actiona more credible and comprehensive commitment to such policies is required before market-based management of straddling and highly migratory fish stocks becomes feasible.

VI. CONCLUSIONS
As the saying goes, freedom is never free. The freedom to fish on the high seas has come at the cost of stock collapses, overcapitalization, and a general squandering of ecological and economic resources as nations compete for the unowned and open-access fish stocks (World Bank 2008). The dissipation of rents flowing from straddling and highly migratory stocks persists despite the U.N. Fish Stocks Agreement and the conceptual appeal of regional fisheries management organizations. The reason is simple; regional fisheries management organizations lack the structural characteristics, the design principles, of an effective communal property regime. Until RFMO member nations take action to exclude non-member nations, or until the expected benefits outweigh the expected costs of coastal nations extending their sovereign

29

control straddling and highly migratory fish stocks, the dissipation of rents on the high seas will continue.

30

REFERENCES
Alder, Jacqueline, and Gail Lugten. Frozen Fish Block: How Committed are North Atlantic States to Accountability, Conservation and Management of Fisheries? Marine Policy 26, no. 5 (2002): 345-357. Allen, Robin Leslie, James Joseph, and Dale Squires. Conservation and Management of Transnational Tuna Fisheries. Wiley-Blackwell, 2010. Allen, Robin Leslie, William Bayliff, James Joseph, and Dale Squires. The Benefits and Costs of Transformation of Open Access on the High Seas in Conservation and Management of Transnational Tuna Fisheries. Wiley-Blackwell, 2010. Aust, Anthony. Handbook of International Law. Cambridge University Press, 2010, 2nd edition. Barkin, J. Samuel. Degradation and Cooperation on the High Seas: The Case of International Fisheries Management. Beyond Resource Wars: Scarcity, Environmental Degradation, and International Cooperation (2011): 141. Barrett, Scott. Environment and statecraft: the strategy of environmental treaty-making. Oxford University Press, 2006. Barrett, S., J. Joseph, T. Groves, and D. Squires. 2004. Design of an Effective and Implementable Plan to Limit Overfishing. Paper presented to the American Economic Association winter meetings, Philadelphia, PA, 2004. Bederman, D. J. CCLMR in Crisis: A Case Study of Marine Management in the Southern Ocean, in Scheiber HN (ed.) Law of the Sea: the Common Heritage and Emerging Challenges. The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff, 2000. Bjorndal, Tron and Gordon Munro. The Management of High Seas Fisheries Resources and the Implementation of the UN Fish Stocks Agreement of 1995, in Folmer, Henk, and Tom Tietenberg, eds. The International Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Economics 2003/2004: A Survey of Current Issues. Edward Elgar Pub, 2004. Blake, Raymond B., Water Buoys the Nation: Fish and the Re-emergence of Canadian Nationalism, Maple Sheets: Marburg Contributions to Canadian Research (1998) 12, p. 11. Canadian Department of Fisheries and Oceans, Backgrounder: Why NAFO Members Agreed Upon A Total Allowable Catch for Greenland Halibut. March News Release [B-HQ-953E] (1995a).

31

Canadian Department of Fisheries and Oceans, Canada-EU reach agreement to conserve and protect straddling stocks, April 15 News Release [NR-HQ-95-36E] (1995b). Colburn, Jamison E., Turbot Wars: Straddling Stocks, Regime Theory, and a New U.N. Agreement, Journal of Transnational Law and Policy 6 (1998): 323. Costello, Christopher, John Lynham, Sarah E. Lester, and Steven D. Gaines. Economic Incentives and Global Fisheries Sustainability. Resource 2 (2010). Crothers, G. T., and Lindie Nelson. High seas fisheries governance: a framework for the future? Marine Resource Economics 21, no. 4 (2006): 341. Cullis-Suzuki, Sarika, and Daniel Pauly. Failing the high seas: A global evaluation of regional fisheries management organizations. Marine Policy 34, no. 5 (2010): 1036-1042. DeSombre, Elizabeth R. and J. Samuel Barkin. Turbot and Tempers in the North Atlantic, in Conserving the Peace: Resources, Livelihoods and Security (Richard Matthew, Mark Halle, and Jason Switzer, eds.) Winnipeg: International Institute for Sustainable Development, 2002. DeSombre, Elizabeth R. Fishing under flags of convenience: Using market power to increase participation in international regulation. Global Environmental Politics 5, no. 4 (2005): 73-94. Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations. Some High Seas Fisheries Aspects Relating to Straddling Fish Stocks and Highly Migratory Fish Stocks, FAO Fisheries Circular No. 879 (1994): 1. Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations, Office of Director-General, FAO Legislative Study 71, Fisheries Enforcement Related Legal and Institutional Issues National, Subregional or Regional Perspectives, pt. 3 (2001). Gagern, Antonius, and Jeroen van den Bergh. A critical review of fishing agreements with tropical developing countries. Marine Policy (2012). Gezelius, Stig S. "Limits to externalisation The EU NAFO policy 19791997."Marine Policy 23, no. 2 (1999): 147-159. Guzman, Andrew T. Against Consent. Virginia Journal of International Law 52 (2012): 747. Hallman, Brian, Scott Barrett, Raymond P. Clarke, James Joseph, and Dale Squires. Limited access in transnational tuna fisheries, in Conservation and Management of Transnational Tuna Fisheries. Wiley-Blackwell, 2010: 195-211. Hannesson, Rgnvaldur, The Privatization of the Oceans. MIT Press, 2004.
32

Hannesson, Rgnvaldur, The problem of high seas fishing: is there a role for ITQs?" Paper prepared for the OECD, Revised January 2005, Bergen, Norway: The Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration. Hannesson, Rgnvaldur. Rights based fishing on the high seas: Is it possible? Marine Policy 35, no. 5 (2011): 667-674. Hardin, G. The Tragedy of the Commons, Science 162: 1243-1248 (1968). Inter-American Tropical Tuna Commission, Resolution on a Regional Vessel Register, 66th Meeting, 12-15 June 2000, C-00-06. Joseph, J., Dale Squires, W Bayliff, and T Groves. Addressing the Problem of Excess Fishing Capacity in Tuna Fisheries, in Conservation and Management of Transnational Tuna Fisheries. Wiley-Blackwell, 2010. Juda, Lawrence. The 1995 United Nations agreement on straddling fish stocks and highly migratory fish stocks: A critique. Ocean Development & International Law 28, no. 2 (1997): 147-166. Korman, Seth. International Management of a High Sea Fishery: Political and Property-Rights Solutions and the Atlantic Bluefin. Va. J. Int'l L. 51 (2010): 697. McCay, Bonnie J. and Alan Christopher Finlayson. The Political Ecology of Crisis and Institutional Change: The Case of Northern Code. Presented to the Annual Meetings of the American Anthropological Association, Washington, D.C., November 15-19, 1995, p. 3. Maguire, Jean-Jacques. The State of World Highly Migratory, Straddling and Other High Seas Fishery Resources and Associated Species. No. 495. FAO, 2006. McWhinnie, Stephanie. The Tragedy of the Commons in International Fisheries: An Empirical Examination. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 57 (2009): 321333. Munro, Gordon R. Internationally shared fish stocks, the high seas, and property rights in fisheries. Marine Resource Economics 22, no. 4 (2007): 425. Nanadan, S.N. The exclusive economic zone: A historical perspective, Food and Agriculture Organization Corporate document repository, 1987. Nauru Fisheries and Marine Resources Authority, A Third Arrangement Implementing the Nauru Agreement Setting Forth Additional Terms and Conditions of Access to the Fisheries Zones of the Parties, (2010), retrieved online October 25 at: https://sites.google.com/site/naurufisheries/home/regional-laws.
33

Orrego Vicua, Francisco. The changing international law of high seas fisheries. Vol. 9. Cambridge University Press, 1999. Ostrom, Elinor. Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press, 1990. Ple, J.P. Responding to non-member fishing in the Atlantic: the ICCAT and NAFO experiences. PUBLICATIONS ON OCEAN DEVELOPMENT (2000): 197-208. Rayfuse, Rosemary Gail. Non-flag state enforcement in high seas fisheries. Vol. 46. Martinus Nijhoff Publishers, 2004 at 48. Rayfuse, Rosemary Gail. Countermeasures and High Seas Fisheries Enforcement. Netherlands International Law Review 51 (2004): 41-76. Serdy, Andrew. International fisheries law and the transferability of quota: principles and precedents in Conservation and Management of Transnational Tuna Fisheries. WileyBlackwell, 2010: 97-125, at 97. Smith, Tim D. Scaling fisheries: the science of measuring the effects of fishing, 1855-1955. Cambridge University Press, 1994. Valdemarsen, John Willy. Technological trends in capture fisheries. Ocean & coastal management 44, no. 9 (2001): 635-651. Walker, Brian, Scott Barrett, Stephen Polasky, Victor Galaz, Carl Folke, Gustav Engstrom, Frank Ackerman, et al. Looming global-scale failures and missing institutions. Science 325, no. 5946 (2009): 1345-1346. World Bank. 2008. The sunken billions: The economic justification for fisheries reform. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

34

Você também pode gostar