Você está na página 1de 32

ADBI Working Paper Series

Paths to a Reserve Currency:


Internationalization of the
Renminbi and Its Implications

Yiping Huang, Daili Wang,
and Gang Fan
No. 482
May 2014
Asian Development Bank Institute






The Working Paper series is a continuation of the formerly named Discussion Paper series;
the numbering of the papers continued without interruption or change. ADBIs working
papers reflect initial ideas on a topic and are posted online for discussion. ADBI encourages
readers to post their comments on the main page for each working paper (given in the
citation below). Some working papers may develop into other forms of publication.

Suggested citation:
Huang. Y., D. Wang, and G. Fan. 2014. Paths to a Reserve Currency: Internationalization of
the Renminbi and Its Implications. ADBI Working Paper 482. Tokyo: Asian Development
Bank Institute. Available: http://www.adbi.org/working-
paper/2014/05/23/6268.paths.reserve.currency.renminbi/
Please contact the authors for information about this paper.
E-mail: yiping.huang@anu.edu.au, dailiwangpku@gmail.com, fangang@phbs.pku.edu.cn












Yiping Huang is a professor of economics at the National School of Development, Peking
University. Daili Wang is a research intern of Peking University. Gang Fan is a director of
the National Economic Research Institute.
The views expressed in this paper are the views of the authors and do not necessarily
reflect the views or policies of ADBI, ADB, its Board of Directors, or the governments
they represent. ADBI does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this paper
and accepts no responsibility for any consequences of their use. Terminology used may
not necessarily be consistent with ADB official terms.

Asian Development Bank Institute
Kasumigaseki Building 8F
3-2-5 Kasumigaseki, Chiyoda-ku
Tokyo 100-6008, Japan

Tel: +81-3-3593-5500
Fax: +81-3-3593-5571
URL: www.adbi.org
E-mail: info@adbi.org

2014 Asian Development Bank Institute

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
Abstract

In this paper we try to address the question of what could help make the renminbi a reserve
currency. In recent years, the authorities in the Peoples Republic of China (PRC) have
made efforts to internationalize its currency through a two-track strategy: promotion of the
use of the renminbi in the settlement of cross-border trade and investment, and liberalization
of the capital account. We find that if we use only the quantitative measures of the economy,
the predicted share of the renminbi in global reserves could reach 12%. However, if
institutional and market variables are included, the predicted share comes down to around
2%, which is a more realistic prediction. By reviewing experiences of other reserve
currencies, we propose a three-factor approach for the PRC authorities to promote the
international role of the renminbi: (i) increasing the opportunities of using renminbi in the
international community, which requires relatively rapid growth of the PRC economy and
continuous liberalization of trade and investment; (ii) improving the ease of using renminbi,
which requires depth, sophistication, and liquidity of financial markets; and (iii) strengthening
confidence of using renminbi, which requires more transparent monetary policy making, a
more independent legal system, and some political reforms. In general, we believe that the
renminbis international role should increase in the coming years, but it will take a relatively
long period before it plays the role of a global reserve currency.

JEL Classification: F30, F33, F36, F42

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
Contents


1. Introduction ................................................................................................................ 3
2. What Has Been Achieved? ........................................................................................ 3
2.1 Public Sector and Private Sector Uses ........................................................... 4
2.2 Is the Renminbi Already a De Facto Anchor for Regional Currencies? ........... 7
2.3 Summary ....................................................................................................... 9
3. What Are the Main Obstacles? .................................................................................. 9
3.1 Brief Review of International Experiences ...................................................... 9
3.2 Determinants of Currency Shares in Global Reserves ................................. 12
3.3 Summary ..................................................................................................... 16
4. What Needs to Be Done? ........................................................................................ 17
4.1 Economic Weights ....................................................................................... 18
4.2 Openness and Depth of Financial Markets................................................... 20
4.3 Credibility of Economic and Legal Systems.................................................. 22
5. What Are the Likely Implications? ............................................................................ 23
6. Summary of the Main Findings ................................................................................ 24
Appendix ............................................................................................................................. 27
References ......................................................................................................................... 28



ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
1. INTRODUCTION
Around mid-2008 at the height of the global financial crisis, the Peoples Bank of China
(PBC) made two important decisions with regard to its currency policy: one was to
significantly narrow the trading band of the renminbiUS dollar exchange rate and the
other was to promote the international use of the renminbi (RMB) in trade settlement,
especially trade with neighboring economies. The former was similar to what the PBC
did during the Asian financial crisis to stabilize investors currency expectations. The
latter, however, was likely motivated by the ambition to make the RMB an international
currency.
Many policy makers in the Peoples Republic of China (PRC) believe that the
international monetary system dominated by a national currency, the US dollar, is
logically inconsistent and unsustainable. The outbreak of the subprime crisis in the
United States (US) was evidence of the problem. A possible long-term solution is to
create a supranational currency, such as a revamped special drawing right (SDR) of
the International Monetary Fund (IMF) (see, e.g., Zhou 2009). In the short run,
however, the subprime crisis could lead to weakening demand for the US dollar and
create room for the RMB to play some kind of international role.
While policies to internationalize the RMB picked up pace in late 2008, the PBCs
planning of this effort started much earlier. In 2006, a study group of the central bank
published an article titled The Timing, Path and Strategies of RMB Internationalization,
in which it argued that the time has come for promotion of the internationalization of
the RMB (PBC Study Group 2006). The study group also suggested that
internationalization of the RMB could enhance the PRCs international status and
competitiveness and would increase the countrys influence in the world economy.
The PRCs strategy of RMB internationalization is sometimes characterized as a two-
track approach (Subacchi 2010). The first track aims at increasing the international use
of the currency, starting with regional use for trade and investment settlement and
establishment of the offshore currency market in Hong Kong, China. And the second
track tackles the capital account convertibility issue, allowing greater cross-border
capital mobility, encouraging holding of RMB assets by nonresidents, and providing
instruments for hedging currency risks. In the past 5 years, the PRC authorities have
made significant progress in all these areas and will likely move ahead more rapidly in
the coming years.
Will the RMB likely become a global reserve currency? This is the central question we
attempt to address in this paper. To shed light on this subject, we tackle four specific
issues in turn. First, what has the PRC accomplished so far in terms of RMB
internationalization? Second, what are the main obstacles for it to become an
international reserve currency? Third, what can the PRC authorities do to promote the
international role of its currency? And finally, what are the implications for the PRC and
the world if the RMB becomes a reserve currency? In the remainder of the paper we
address these questions in turn and draw together the main findings of the study in the
final section.
2. WHAT HAS BEEN ACHIEVED?
Chinn and Frankel (2005) provide a good analytical framework for organizing the
PRCs policy efforts in internationalizing its currency (Table 1). An international
currency should possess three important cross-border functions: store of value,
3

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
medium of exchange, and unit of account. Each of these functions may be further
decomposed into public and private purposes. While Gao and Yu (2012) confirm that
nonresidents have started using the RMB as a vehicle currency in trade and financial
settlement, Li and Liu (2008) sketch a promising future for it to serve as a reserve
currency.
Table 1: International Use of the Renminbi
Function Purpose Date Event
Store of Value
International reserves
(public)
Jul 2012 Indonesias central bank was allowed to invest
in the Peoples Republic of China interbank
bond market
Apr 2013 Reserve Bank of Australia plans to invest 5%
of its foreign reserves in renminbi
Currency substitution
(private)
Dec 2002 Provisional Measures on Administration of
Domestic Securities Investments of Qualified
Foreign Institutional Investors
Feb 2004 Banks in Hong Kong, China were allowed to
open renminbi deposit accounts
Jun 2007 First renminbi-denominated bond was issued
Dec 2012 Qianhai cross-border renminbi loan rules were
published by the Peoples Bank of China
Medium of
Exchange
Vehicle currency
(public)
N/A N/A
Invoicing currency
(private)
Jul 2009 Pilot program for renminbi settlement of cross-
border trade transactions
Jan 2011 Domestic enterprises were allowed to invest
renminbi overseas
Aug 2011 Cross-border trade settlement in renminbi was
extended to the whole country
Unit of Account Anchor for pegging
(public)
N/A N/A
Denominating currency
(private)
N/A N/A
Source: Chinn and Frankel (2005), updated by authors.
2.1 Public Sector and Private Sector Uses
Due to the long-existed legal and administrative barriers, the PRCs capital market
features apparent segmentation. The nonequivalence of the offshore currency (CNH)
market with the official or onshore currency (CNY) generates non-negligible benefits for
foreign investment: while offshore equivalent instruments whose payoff is equivalent in
most, if not all, states of the world, investing in the onshore market could yield returns
as much as 100150 basis points higher than the global benchmark (Maziad and Kang
2012). As a result, RMB-denominated assets greatly appeal to foreign central banks
that seek high yield yet safe investment to diversify their asset portfolio. In 2010, the
PRC began allowing foreign central banks to directly invest in its domestic interbank
bond market without going through the Qualified Foreign Institutional Investor (QFII)
program, which allows foreign investors to buy onshore stocks and bonds under a
quota system. On 23 July 2012, Bank Indonesia and the PBC announced they had
reached an agreement allowing the Indonesian central bank to invest in the PRC
interbank bond market.
Clearly, foreign central banks interest in the PRC bond market is driven at least by two
considerations. One, as most central banks with large foreign exchange reserves
4

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
struggle with the only major option of investing in the US treasury market, the PRC
bond market offers a useful option for diversification. This makes sense especially as
the PRC is on the way to becoming a dominant economic power in the world. And two,
the PRC bond market offers somewhat higher yields, compared with similar markets in
the developed world. It is also helped by the expectation that the onshore currency
market could show a longer-term trend of appreciation.
In terms of functioning as a medium of exchange, the PRC started signing currency
swap agreements with other countries under the framework of the Chiang Mai Initiative
(CMI) following the Asian financial crisis. The purpose of such agreements is to
improve future financial stability by functioning as an alternative to the individually
accumulated foreign exchange reserves, and to promote trade and investment with
these countries. As a result of the PRCs involvement in the buildup of the regional
financial architecture, the RMB is used as a vehicle currency via the swap agreements
and as a denominating currency in the issuance of Asian bonds under the Asian Bond
Fund II scheme.
The PBC has subsequently also signed other currency swap agreements beyond the
CMI framework. For instance, in December 2008, the PRC signed its first swap
agreement with the Republic of Korea. This was a serious move by the PRC in
response to the widespread financial crisis. Since then, the PRC has signed swap
agreements with central banks of 19 economies. The latest was signed between the
PBC and the Bank of England in late June 2013 for a total of 200 billion yuan. It is
possible that France may also follow the United Kingdom (UK) to sign such an
agreement with the PRC. According to our count, the total value of currency swap
agreements is more than 2.2 trillion yuan.
Table 2: Bilateral Swap Agreements Signed since 2008
Date Amount
(yuan
billion)
Date Amount
(yuan
billion)
Republic of Korea 12 Dec 2008 180 Uzbekistan 19 Apr 2011 0.7
26 Oct 2011 360 Mongolia 6 May 2011 5
Hong Kong,
China
20 Jan 2009 200 20 Mar 2012 10
22 Nov 2011 400 Kazakhstan 13 Jun 2011 7
Malaysia 8 Feb 2009 80 Thailand 22 Dec 2011 70
8 Feb 2012 180 Pakistan 23 Dec 2011 10
Belarus 11 Mar 2009 20 United Arab Emirates 17 Jan 2012 35
Indonesia 23 Mar 2009 100 Turkey 21 Feb 2012 10
Argentina 2 Apr 2009 70 Australia 22 Mar 2012 200
Iceland 9 Jun 2010 3.5 Ukraine 26 Jun 2012 15
Singapore 23 Jul 2010 150 Brazil 26 Mar 2013 190
7 Mar 2013 300 United Kingdom 22 Jun 2013 200
New Zealand 18 Apr 2011 25 Total 2,206
Source: Peoples Bank of China.
At the private level, the authorities took various steps to use the RMB for settlement of
international trade and investment in order to partially replace traditional invoicing
currencies such as the US dollar and yen. In July 2009, the PBC and other government
departments introduced the first pilot program of using RMB in the settlement of cross-
border trade. This program aims at facilitating trade and investment for 67,000
enterprises in 16 provinces. Two years later in August 2011, the authorities issued a
notice extending the geographical coverage of RMB trade settlement to the whole
country. The PBC issued the Administrative Rules on RMB-denominated Foreign
5

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
Direct Investment in October 2011 and announced in June 2012 that all PRC
companies with an import/export license can use RMB to settle cross-border trade.
RMB settlement has grown very rapidly during the past years. According to PBC data,
international trade and foreign direct investment settled in RMB amounted to 1 trillion
yuan (US$161 billion) and 85.4 billion yuan (US$13.7 billion), respectively, during the
first quarter of 2013.
1
One caveat needs to be made, which is that while RMB
settlement has increased exponentially, most cross-border activities are still invoiced in
other hard currencies such as US dollars. Therefore, the RMB is not yet being used as
a true international currency.
The development of the offshore currency market in Hong Kong, China made a unique
contribution in encouraging private nonresident holding of RMB. The offshore market
offers a useful laboratory for strengthening RMB outbound circulation and appealing to
nonresident investors. As early as 2004, the Hong Kong Monetary Authority launched
the RMB Business Scheme, allowing banks in Hong Kong, China to open RMB deposit
accounts for individuals and some enterprises. However, the offshore deposit market
did not really take off until mid-2010 when new rules were issued to relax restrictions
on RMB activities of banks in Hong Kong, China. By March 2013, the total value of
CNH deposits had reached 668 billion yuan (US$107 billion), almost 745 times the
value of when the market was first established in February 2004 (Figure 1). In addition,
the number of institutions engaging in RMB business has increased to 140 from the
original 32, quadrupling within less than 10 years.
Figure 1: Renminbi Deposits in Hong Kong, China Offshore Markets, 20042013

Source: Hong Kong Monetary Authority.
Development of an offshore market for RMB-denominated bonds began in mid-2007,
when selected mainland banks were permitted for the first time to raise funds by
issuing such bonds in Hong Kong, China. The China Development Bank was the first to
issue RMB-denominated bonds in Hong Kong, China in July 2007, while the China
Construction Bank became the first PRC bank to issue them in London (outside of
Hong Kong, China) in November 2012.
1
See
http://www.pbc.gov.cn/publish/english/955/2013/20130417083528793671703/20130417083528793671
703_.html
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
800
0
20
40
60
80
100
120
140
160
Feb-04 Aug-05 Feb-07 Aug-08 Feb-10 Aug-11 Feb-13
No. of institutions engaged in renminbi business (left axis)
Renminbi deposits (billion yuan, right axis)
6


ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
In 2010, bond issuance permission was extended to nonfinancial firms and foreign
multinationals doing business in the PRC. McDonalds, the well-known fast food chain
store, and Caterpillar, the US-based maker of construction equipment, were among the
first group of foreign companies to tap into the dim sum bond market. HSBC became
the first non-Hong Kong, China institution to issue RMB bonds in London in April 2012.
Despite its short history, the size of the offshore bond market has expanded rapidly
since 2012, with continuous relaxation of restrictions imposed by PRC regulators and
strong expectations of RMB appreciation.
Some foreign central banks have started to hold RMB as part of their foreign reserves,
as the international significance of the currency increases rapidly. This activity,
however, remains primitive, mainly because the currency is not yet convertible under
the capital account and internationally available RMB-denominated assets remain
scarce. One recent significant step was in June 2013 when the Reserve Bank of
Australia decided to invest up to 5% of its foreign reserves in RMB, which should be
equivalent to A$2 billion according to the banks current size of foreign reserves.
2.2 Is the Renminbi Already a De Facto Anchor for Regional
Currencies?
Economists have long argued that there are some fundamental factors driving implicit
or explicit regional currency arrangements in Asia (Kawai 2002). The US dollar has in
the past been the most significant anchor currency for the region, although in the last
decade of the 20th century the yen also played an important role for some regional
currencies such as the won and the NT dollar. Given the PRCs capital account
controls and inflexibility of the RMB exchange rate, there is not yet an explicit
arrangement linking foreign exchange rates to the RMB. However, Ito (2008)
suggested that, implicitly, the RMB was probably already serving as one of the anchors
for regional currencies.
To assess this possibility, especially with respect to changes over time, we conduct
some statistical analyses by applying the framework of Frankel and Wei (1994).
Specifically, the following model is estimated:

/
=
0
+
1

/
+
2

/
+
3

/
+
4

/
.
On the left is the dependent variable, which is the daily return of exchange rates of
Asian economies. At the same time, the daily return of the US dollar, the euro, the yen,
and the RMB are placed on the right side of the equation as explanatory variables. All
the exchange rates are expressed relative to the IMFs SDR, as suggested by
Fratzscher and Mehl (2011). Moreover, to ensure that all the factors are exogenous
and circumvent the potential multi-collinearity arising from the fact that the RMB is to
some extent pegged to the US dollar, the RMB factor is orthogonalized with respect to
the US dollar factor by regressing the former on the latter and taking the residuals as
the new explanatory factor.
2

All daily data are drawn from the IMF database for the period between 1 January 1999
and 10 June 2013. In the empirical estimation, we use the date of the exchange rate
policy reform on 21 July 2005 dividing the whole sample period into two subperiods.
Estimation results using pre-reform data confirm that the exchange rates of all seven
Asian currencies are significantly influenced by the US dollar (top half of Table 3).
2
The following empirical findings hold when conducting a similar auxiliary regression on the euro and yen.
The results are available upon request from the authors.
7


ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
Among them, the Hong Kong dollar and the ringgit are strict dollar pegs. The Indian
rupee, the rupiah, and the won are heavily impacted by the US dollar with a weight of
more than 0.85. The US dollars influence on the Singapore dollar and the baht,
however, is slightly smaller, with a weight of around 0.550.65. Influences of the yen
are noticeably smaller but present in a number of cases, such as the Singapore dollar
and the baht. The euro does not have a noticeable effect and the RMB asserts no
significant influence on other Asian currencies.
The story changed significantly after the July 2005 exchange rate reform (bottom half
of Table 3). The overall impacts of the US dollar, the yen, and the euro are similar to
those before July 2005. Yet, the RMB shows important influences on its neighbors
currencies. Specifically, while the US dollar seems to dominate in the case of the Hong
Kong dollar, the won, and the baht, the RMB affects the Indian rupee, the rupiah, the
ringgit, and the Singapore dollar more, though this finding is still slightly odd given that
it is not yet fully convertible and the exchange rate is not yet freely floating. It is,
nonetheless, consistent with the fact that Asian central banks pay close attention to the
movement of the RMB exchange rate.
Table 3: Asian Currency Regimes with Rise of the Renminbi

Hong
Kong
dollar Rupiah
Indian
rupee Won Ringgit
Singapore
dollar Baht
Before the Renminbi Reform (1 Jan 199920 Jul 2005)
US dollar 0.994*** 0.858*** 0.875*** 0.978*** 1.000*** 0.570*** 0.619***
(0.0162) (0.0737) (0.091) (0.235) (0.0002) (0.0954) (0.177)
Euro 0.0103 0.0309** 0.197 0.0192 3.83E-05* 0.0185 0.0133
(0.0116) (0.0144) (0.136) (0.0388) (2.32E-05) (0.0195) (0.0354)
Yen 0.00996* 0.0150* 0.243*** 0.0317 5.2E-06 0.171*** 0.164***
(0.00555) (0.00876) (0.0732) (0.0232) (1.3E-04) (0.0133) (0.0231)
Yuan 0.00555 0.00139 1.913 0.144 0.0066 1.452 1.244
(0.0348) (0.00155) (2.111) (0.515) (0.00417) (2.033) (3.888)
Constant 4.2E-04 5.06E-05 0.00128 3.03E-04 5.08E-07 0.000133 5.6E-05
(2.74E-04) (1.18E-04) (1.7E-03) (4.09E-04) (3.28E-07) (1.67E-04) (3.0E-04)
Observations 1,340 1,205 1,089 1,026 1,348 1,286 1,108
R-squared 0.951 0.738 0.131 0.4 0.99 0.502 0.368
After the Reform (20 Jul 200510 Jun 2013)
US dollar 0.966*** 0.673*** 0.714*** 0.919*** 0.717*** 0.592*** 0.836***
(0.0106) (0.0725) (0.104) (0.114) (0.0489) (0.0406) (0.0369)
Euro 0.00119 0.0677 0.0216 0.15 0.0595 0.0792** 0.0471
(0.0072) (0.0608) (0.0638) (0.117) (0.0408) (0.0342) (0.0301)
Yen 0.00215 0.205*** 0.248*** 0.0186 0.127*** 0.0593*** 0.00608
(0.00359) (0.0253) (0.0511) (0.0623) (0.018) (0.0151) (0.0149)
Yuan 0.0403** 0.749*** 0.954*** 0.526** 1.227*** 1.185*** 0.444***
(0.018) (0.163) (0.177) (0.229) (0.136) (0.111) (0.126)
Constant 4.3E-06 3.18E-04** 1.7E-04 2.9E-04 5.8E-05 1.94E-05 2.57E-05
(1.63E-05) (1.27E-04) (2.17E-04) (1.93E-04) (9.20E-05) (7.51E-05) (8.24E-05)
Observations 1,525 1,382 1,453 1,489 1,457 1,526 1,329
R-squared 0.957 0.186 0.09 0.164 0.286 0.26 0.468
Source: International Monetary Fund International Financial Statistics, CEIC.
Recently, however, Kawai and Pontines (2014) challenged the validity of the above
type of exercise by arguing that there could be a serious multi-collinearity problem
between the US dollar and RMB exchange rates (as indicated above, our analyses first
8

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
take out the influences of the US dollar exchange rate on the RMB and then use the
residual of the RMB exchange rate to estimate its influence on Asian currencies). By
proposing and applying a new two-step estimation method, they found that, while the
RMBs influence was on the rise, there was not yet a RMB bloc in East Asia (Kawai
and Pontines 2014). Therefore, this issue needs to be explored further.
2.3 Summary
To sum up, within a relatively short period, the PRC authorities have made meaningful
progress in internationalizing the countrys currency. The amount of international trade
and direct investment settled in RMB is growing very rapidly. RMB deposits have
already reached a relatively high level in Hong Kong, China and are growing quickly in
other markets. RMB-denominated assets, mainly bonds, are already on offer both in
Hong Kong, China and London. In addition to large volumes of currency swap
agreements, some foreign central banks have also started holding RMB as part of their
foreign exchange reserves. The RMB even asserts important influences on exchange
rates of some other Asian currencies.
Assessing such progress in the framework proposed by Chinn and Frankel (2005), we
find that RMB internationalization has advanced most remarkably in its use as a
medium of exchange for both the public and private sectors. International functions lag
most clearly as a unit of account for the private sector and store of value for the public
sector. The significant achievements are attributable to two important factors: one is
the relative decline of the US dollar following the global financial crisis and therefore
new demand for an alternative international currency; and the other is the PRC
governments well planned and well executed policies. Some even argue that the main
driving force behind the impressive growth of the offshore RMB market is the strongly
held view that the RMB would inevitably and substantially appreciate against other
major currencies. In other words, speculative desire has overwhelmed other
fundamental demand, such as risk hedging, in driving the growth of the offshore
currency market (Garber 2011).
3. WHAT ARE THE MAIN OBSTACLES?
Despite the progress the PRC authorities made in internationalizing the currency, the
RMB is not yet an international currency. Is it realistic for it to become an international
currency in the perceivable future? Academic assessment may lead to very different
conclusions. Some may suggest that given the PRC is already the worlds second
largest economy and one of the most important global trading partners, it is a matter of
time for the RMB to ascend to international currency status. Meanwhile, others may
argue that it is very hard for the international market to accept the RMB as a global
currency due to the PRCs primitive financial markets, unique monetary policy
mechanism, capital account controls, and underdeveloped legal system.
3.1 Brief Review of International Experiences
What are the main obstacles for the RMB to become an international currency? We try
to shed some light on this question. First, we take a brief look at the rise of the US
dollar, the deutsche mark, the yen, and the euro to global reserve currency status and
draw some simple lessons. Second, we adopt some quantitative methods to identify
key determinants of the shares of existing international currencies in global currency
reserves. The estimation results are then applied to predict the likely shares of the
9

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
RMB under different sets of assumptions. One key message appears to be clear and
consistent: size of gross domestic product (GDP) and size of trade are only a
necessary condition, but quality of markets, policies, and institutions are by far more
important for producing international currencies.
During the 20th century, three national currencies rose to international currency status:
the US dollar in the first half of the century, and the deutsche mark and the yen over
the two decades following the 19711973 collapse of the Bretton Woods system. The
first decade of the 21st century witnessed the ascendancy of a supranational currency:
the euro. By looking at the circumstances in which each of the currencies became an
international currency, we may be able to draw some useful lessons for the
internationalization of the RMB.
At the beginning of the 20th century, the pound sterling reigned supreme. Although the
US was already the largest economy of the world, its currency was still a relatively
unimportant currency in global financial markets. In retrospect, the main reason the US
dollar did not rule the world economy before World War I was its lack of a deep, liquid,
and open financial market. Another important reason was the absence of a credible
central bank, which is often considered a prerequisite for development of financial
markets and financial instruments (Frankel 2011). These reasons suggest that while
size of the economy is an important condition for creating an international currency, it is
far from a sufficient condition.
The situation changed in 1913 when President Woodrow Wilson ratified the
establishment of the Federal Reserve and the onset of World War I accelerated the US
dollars rise. Large-scale wartime lending by the US to Britain reversed the long-
established creditordebtor relationship, positioning the dollar as a strong global
currency. Even though the pound sterling made a slight comeback later in the 1930s
after the Great Depression, by 1944 the dollar had sealed its crown position through
the establishment of the Bretton Woods system. The new position of the US dollar
relative to the pound sterling was also clearly reflected in the composition of foreign-
owned liquid assets around that time. During the past decade, the dollars share in
international reserves have trended down gradually but stayed above 60% (Figure 2).
Figure 2: Currency Composition of Official Foreign Reserves

Source: International Monetary Fund Currency Composition of Official Foreign Exchange Reserves (COFER)
database.
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
0%
5%
10%
15%
20%
25%
30%
1999-Q1 2002-Q1 2005-Q1 2008-Q1 2011-Q1
Euro Yen
Swiss franc Pound sterling
US dollar (right axis)
10

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
The deutsche mark was born in Ludwig Erhards currency reform in 1948, but its
central bank, the Bundesbank, was not founded until 1957. Despite its short history, the
mark continued to gain status throughout the 1980s. The main contributor to this was
the growing size of the German economy and the impeccable reputation that the
Bundesbank established in keeping the value of the mark strong. In 1989, the deutsche
mark saw its peak performance in the international monetary system when the
currency reached almost 20% of world foreign exchange reserves. Following that peak,
the deutsche mark started a long journey of decline due to slowdown of the economy
and collapse of the Berlin Wall. The Maastricht Treaty signed in 1992 came to fruition
in January 1999 and the deutsche mark, together with the French franc and nine other
continental currencies, went out of existence in the historic creation of the euro.
The story of the rise of the yen began as Japans export-driven economic miracle
allowed its currency to meet the first criterion for internationalization: the countrys
economic weight. After the collapse of the Bretton Woods system in 1973, central
banks around the world began to hold yen as a substitute foreign exchange reserve.
Nevertheless, since Japanese financial markets remained uncompetitive, highly
regulated, and mostly closed to foreigners, the actual extent of yen internationalization
was low. International use of the yen accelerated in the late 1980s and the share of
world foreign exchange reserves denominated in yen reached its peak at 9% in 1991.
Since the bursting of the real estate and equity bubbles at the start of the 1990s, the
country slowly yet painfully fell into a long-lasting spiral recession. By the end of 2003,
it became clear that any further attempt to internationalize the yen would be futile
without a fundamental change in the economic might of Japan (Takagi 2011).

At the end of the 20th century, a supranational regional currency came into existence.
The motivation of creating the euro was mainly political: it was deemed as an
indispensable step toward realizing the ambition of a united Europe. Naturally the euro
started with two advantages: it was the home currency for a bloc that resembled the
US in terms of economic scale and it seemed likely to inherit the credibility of the
deutsche mark. As a result, it advanced quickly into the ranks of the top reserve
currencies in its first decade and was expected to pose a challenge to the long global
supremacy of the greenback.
3


Experiences of the dollar, deutsche mark, yen, and euro suggest that to assume
international status, a currency needs to be supported by at least three key factors: the
scale of the economy, which leads to the extensiveness of the issuing countrys
transactional networks (Eichengreen 2005); the stability of the currency value, which is
believed to be linked to sound macroeconomic fundamentals in the issuing country
(Chen, Peng, and Shu 2009); and the existence of well-developed and open financial
markets, which guarantees the liquidity and convertibility of the currency (Cohen 2007).
However, these may still not be sufficient. As Helleiner (2008) suggested, confidence
and power in a currency may derive not only from economic fundamentals, but also
from the social institutions. Further, as Krugman (1984) noted, there is a kind of circular
causation encouraging a leading international currency to become even more
prominent over time since people find benefits in using a currency that is used by
others.
3
Whether the euro will displace the US dollar as the main international currency is far from unambiguous.
See Kenen (2002), Chinn and Frankel (2008), and McNamara (2008) for a detailed discussion.
11


ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
3.2 Determinants of Currency Shares in Global Reserves
To verify the above suggestions and illustrate the importance of the various factors for
RMB internationalization, we apply a quantitative framework to identify the
determinants of shares of individual currencies in total global reserve holdings, using
data of existing reserve currencies. Potential explanatory variables include scale of the
economy, stability of the currency, and development of financial markets and social
institutions. After estimation of the model using data for existing international reserve
currencies, we also carry out a series of counterfactual exercises to identify some of
the main obstacles for the RMB in becoming a reserve currency.
There are several studies in the literature looking at the same question. Previous
models, such as those adopted by Chen, Peng, and Shu (2009) and Li and Liu (2008),
considered the three traditional economic fundamentals in determining currency shares
in global foreign reserve holdings. This is a reasonable exercise as they reveal the
potential that the PRC could realize by looking at only the three basic (quantitative)
variables. However, Lee (2010) showed that adding a capital account liberalization
index to the model could generate different results. By adding policy and institutional
variables to the model, we may be able to see how restrictive these variables are for
the PRCs reserve currency ambition. At the same time, empirical results including
policy and institutional variables may also shed light on where the authorities should
direct their key reform efforts.
In this study, we intend to include a series of potential determining variables for
currency shares in global foreign reserves. We start with the basic model including only
the most commonly used variables, mostly quantitative measures. We will then
estimate several additional models by including new variables, mostly qualitative or
institutional variables. The logic of doing this is simple: most studies examine the
RMBs potential share in global foreign reserves by looking only at the size of the PRC
economy. While this is useful, most economies in the world never reach their potential
because of institutional deficiencies. For instance, the currency share will not rise
alongside economic growth if the currency is not convertible. By estimating the
potentials with the policy and institutional variables, we are able to tell what is
practically achievable under the current policy and institutional setting. At the same
time, comparison of different potential estimates can also tell what can be done to
increase the RMBs share in global currency reserves.
The currencies identified in the IMF Currency Composition of Official Foreign Exchange
Reserves (COFER) database are the US dollar, euro, pound sterling, yen, Swiss franc,
and a category of all other currencies. Because some member countries choose not to
report the currency compositions of their foreign reserves, the model below takes the
currency composition of the allocated reserves (about 70% of total reserves) as the
dependent variable representing the reserve currency share.
We use quarterly data for the period 19992011 because data before January 1999 do
not cover the euro. An economys GDP and trade share in the world are included to
tackle the impact of the scale of the economy. Inflation differential (vis--vis OECD
average inflation) and exchange rate volatility (3-year monthly average, national
currency vis--vis the SDR) are added to the model to capture features of the stability
of the currency. The stock market capitalization as a share of five major financial
centers (New York, London, Tokyo, Euronext, and Zurich) combined and the ratio of
such a capitalization level to GDP are derived to reflect the development of financial
markets. Data on stock market capitalization are obtained from the World Federation of
12

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
Exchanges, while the others are obtained from the IMF International Financial Statistics
and CEIC.
We use currency appreciation to proxy market participants implicit demand for the
currency.
4
As suggested by Li and Liu (2008), long-term appreciation would also be
helpful for achieving the store of value function of an international currency. To
measure the extent of capital account liberalization, previous researchers have
proposed two distinct approaches. The de jure approach is based on legislative
restrictions (Chinn and Ito 2008), while the de facto one is often constructed as the
ratio of gross cross-border capital stock to GDP (Lane and Milesi-Ferretti 2007). Since
the quarterly data are employed, the more refined de facto index is a better fit. The
indicator introduced to describe the overall institution is adopted from Economic
Freedom of the World: 2012 Annual Report by the Fraser Institute. Economic freedom
is a composite index constructed from 42 variables in 5 broad areas: size of
government, legal system and property rights, sound money, freedom to trade
internationally, and regulation.
5

The following model specification is adopted in empirical estimation:

where GDP is the countrys share in global GDP, Trade is the countrys share in global
trade, MktCap is total market capitalization, Inf is inflation differential vis--vis the
OECD average, FXV is exchange rate volatility, FXA is currency appreciation, KALib is
capital account liberalization index, MktGDP is market capitalization relative to GDP,
and Institution is the economic freedom index. A one-period lag of the dependent
variable is also added to control for the inertia of international currency choice as
suggested by Krugman (1984).
6
Table 4 provides some statistical characteristics of the
data set.
4
Currencies used in the first-stage estimation are all from developed economies (eurozone, Japan,
Switzerland, UK, and US). The movement of the exchange rate is generally determined by market force.
5
Due to data availability, the economic freedom index ends at the end of 2010. For variables that do not
explicitly describe the eurozone, the data are derived from the GDP-weighted average of euro area
countries (EA-17).
6
Earlier work, such as Chinn and Frankel (2005), recommended the use of a nonlinear logistic
transformation model. The findings from both the linear and nonlinear models, however, are qualitatively
symmetric.
1 1 2 3 4 5
1 2 3 4 5 , 1
it it it it it it
it it it it i t it
share GDP Trade MktCap Inf FXV
FXA KALib MktGDP Institution share

= + + + + +
+ + + + + +
13


ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
Table 4: Data Description for the Major Currencies
Share GDP Trade Mkt_Cap Mkt/GDP Inf FXV FXA KA Lib. ECOF
Period Average (Q1 1999Q4 2011)
CNY 2.57% 6.57% 7.34% 47.50% 0.89% 1.38% 0.39% 79.78% 5.854
EUR 23.51% 7.62% 15.01% 14.28% 32.36% 0.42% 1.66% 0.12% 160.94% 7.452
JPY 4.05% 3.64% 5.35% 15.50% 74.06% 0.36% 2.52% 0.69% 88.88% 7.693
CHF 0.19% 0.30% 1.27% 3.41% 199.50% 0.45% 1.98% 0.63% 271.92% 8.266
GBP 3.52% 1.62% 4.14% 12.16% 130.13% 0.45% 1.72% 0.24% 246.92% 8.263
USD 66.52% 38.17% 12.66% 54.64% 97.97% 0.79% 1.39% 0.13% 125.62% 8.228
End of Period (Q4 2011)
CNY 9.30% 10.50% 19.10% 31.45% 0.74% 1.69% 2.59% 116.10% 6.180
EUR 24.70% 7.85% 11.70% 14.39% 28.08% 0.19% 2.48% 2.53% 205.45% 7.450
JPY 3.60% 4.42% 4.80% 14.95% 51.77% 0.29% 2.76% 0.29% 120.11% 7.650
CHF 0.10% 0.41% 1.20% 4.25% 160.46% 0.47% 3.24% 2.55% 311.37% 8.110
GBP 3.80% 1.50% 3.10% 12.78% 130.20% 0.28% 2.36% 0.84% 300.99% 7.930
USD 62.30% 37.41% 10.50% 53.63% 87.76% 0.70% 1.79% 1.72% 162.15% 7.760
Correlation Matrix
GDP 0.98
Trade 0.72 0.60
Mkt_Cap 0.95 0.97 0.58
Mkt/GDP 0.31 0.12 0.62 0.12
Inf 0.30 0.18 0.11 0.19 0.09
FXV 0.42 0.28 0.31 0.21 0.05 0.07
FXA 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.04 0.02 0.01 0.10
KA Lib 0.42 0.26 0.42 0.27 0.67 0.05 0.13 0.00
ECOF 0.11 0.28 0.05 0.35 0.60 0.19 0.15 0.01 0.56
Note: GDP is the countrys share in global gross domestic product; Trade is the countrys share in global
trade; Mkt_Cap is total market capitalization; Mkt/GDP is market capitalization relative to GDP; Inf is inflation
the differential vis--vis the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development average; FXV is
exchange rate volatility; FXA is currency appreciation; KA Lib is the capital account liberalization index; and
ECOF is the economic freedom index.
Sources: International Monetary Fund Currency Composition of Official Foreign Exchange Reserve,
International Financial Statistics, and Direction of Trade Statistics; World Bank World Development Indicators;
and CEIC data.
In the empirical estimation, we start with the basic model and then add additional
variables in the new estimation (Table 5). The F-statistic and Hausman test validate a
fixed-effects panel regression model. Model (1), the basic model, replicates previous
exercises, such as those by Chinn and Frankel (2005) and Chen, Peng, and Shu
(2009). It is not surprising that the size of GDP and that of the financial market are very
important in determining the currency share in global reserve holdings. However, both
inflation and exchange rate volatility are not significant, possibly a consequence of the
short sample period, as discussed in Chen, Peng, and Shu (2009). The lag-dependent
variable, as expected, has very strong explanatory power.
Model (2) considers the development of financial markets, by adding the ratio of
financial market capitalization to GDP. This variable tells something about the financial
development in a country. We should be clear, however, that it only captures the
quantity dimension of financial development, nothing about depth, liquidity, and
sophistication of financial markets. Model (3) further includes currency appreciation in
the model, which reflects implicit demand for the currency. Model (4) adds the capital
account liberalization index, which really is a prerequisite for international currency
holding. And finally, Model (5) includes the economic freedom indicator to control the
impact of a broad range of policies and institutions.
14

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
Table 5: Panel Regressions of Determination of Currency Shares
Explanatory Variables
Dependent Variable: currency share in global reserves
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
GDP share 0.145** 0.146** 0.0964* 0.0945* 0.103*

(0.0576) (0.0576) (0.0523) (0.052) (0.0523)
Trade share 0.146*** 0.156*** 0.0975** 0.100** 0.092*
(0.0491) (0.051) (0.046) (0.0464) (0.052)
Inflation 0.0664 0.0612 0.0364 0.0513 0.0133
(0.086) (0.086) (0.0778) (0.0776) (0.0871)
Exchange rate volatility 0.0856 0.0991 0.0378 0.0666 0.121
(0.0726) (0.075) (0.0657) (0.0677) (0.0811)
Mkt_Cap 0.0349* 0.0327* 0.0193 0.0248 0.0169
(0.0203) (0.0195) (0.0185) (0.0186) (0.0194)
Mkt_Cap/GDP 0.00112 0.00137 0.000802 0.000862
(0.00156) (0.0014) (0.00142) (0.0014)
Appreciation

0.0673*** 0.0672*** 0.0674***


(0.00886) (0.0088) (0.0093)
Capital account liberalization 0.00631** 0.00849**
(0.00311) (0.0036)
Economic freedom 0.0043*
(0.0025)
Lag of share 0.898*** 0.897*** 0.925*** 0.907*** 0.891***
(0.0198) (0.0198) (0.0182) (0.0202) (0.0265)
Constant 0.0151** 0.0172*** 0.0093*** 0.0141** 0.048**
(0.00355) (0.00370) (0.00166) (0.00698) (0.0226)
Observation 255 255 255 255 235
R-squared 0.948 0.948 0.958 0.959 0.958
GDP = gross domestic product, Mkt_Cap = market capitalization.
Source: Authors calculation.
The general findings are that size matters. A countrys GDP and trade shares in the
world play very important roles in determining its currency share in global currency
reserves. Currency appreciation, capital account liberalization, and economic freedom
are also quite important in affecting the currency share. However, coefficient estimates
of other variables such as inflation volatility and financial market capitalization are not
significant in the estimated models. We suspect that these are mainly results of a data
quality problem. For instance, market capitalization is probably not an accurate
representative of the actual degree of financial market development. In the appendix,
we report results from various robustness checks to validate our findings.
Having obtained the results, we then predict the likely share of the RMB in global
currency reserves. We assume the share to be zero in the first quarter of 1999 and
then apply estimated parameters and actual values of the independent variables for the
PRC to predict the RMBs share. Since the share of currency in foreign reserve
holdings is nonnegative, during the recursive process one should always choose the
maximum of zero and the predicted value. The predicted RMB shares at the end of
2011 are 10.1% under Model (1), 8.9% under Model (2), 5.3% under Model (3), 6.8%
under Model (4), and 2.2% under Model (5). In general, the more policy and
institutional variables are included in estimation, the lower the estimated share for the
RMB in global currency reserves.
15

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
Comparison of these predictions also reinforces one of our important argumentsthe
predicted potentials simply based on quantitative measures are probably too optimistic
(Figure 3). For instance, if we just look at the PRCs GDP and trade shares in the
world, the RMBs share should be around 10%. This is possible if all policy and
institutions in the PRC are similar to those in the US and other developed countries.
Yet, we know this is not true. If we take into account several important policy
considerations and institutions, such as capital account liberalization and economic
freedom, then RMBs actual potential share comes down to only around 2%. However,
we think this last number makes sense because (i) it tells us what the PRC can
realistically achieve now and (ii) what reform actions the PRC needs to undertake in
order to realize the 10% potential.
Figure 3: Counterfactual ExerciseLinear Models

Note: Models (1)(5) are consistent with those models reported in Table 2.
Source: Authors calculation.
3.3 Summary
Based on the above analyses, we propose three sets of factors that are critical for
producing an international currency: (i) economic weights, (ii) openness and depth of
financial markets, (iii) and credibility of economic and legal systems. Comparing the
PRCs situation using these criteria may suggest that while the RMBs international role
is likely to rise in the coming years, it would be difficult for it to become a global reserve
currency anytime soon.
The first factor should create more chances of using a countrys own currency in
international transactions. It is useful to note, however, that while economic weights are
important, they are perhaps not the most fundamental factors. The Swiss franc is an
international currency, although the size of the Swiss economy is relatively small.
Conversely, the US dollar did not become a global currency before World War I when
the US economy was already bigger than the economies of the United Kingdom,
Germany, and France combined. Nonetheless, the PRCs rising importance in global
GDP and trade has already generated some demand for the RMB as a settlement
currency. It is not too difficult to imagine such demand rise rapidly as the PRC
becomes the largest economy in the world over the coming decade.
The second factor determines how easily nonresidents can access the currency, make
an investment, liquidate it, and hedge the risk. The yen provides a good case. For
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
2005-Q1 2006-Q1 2007-Q1 2008-Q1 2009-Q1 2010-Q1 2011-Q1
Model (1)
Model (2)
Model (3)
Model (4)
Model (5)
16

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
decades, Japan was the worlds second largest economy and the size of its financial
markets was phenomenal. However, the role of the yen as an international currency
peaked in the late 1980s. This was partly because the Japanese economy entered a
long period of stagnation. More fundamentally, however, it was due to the fact that the
Japanese financial markets are not really open to foreign investors. With capital
account controls and primitive financial markets, the PRC lags significantly in this area
before the RMB can truly become an international currency.
And the third factor underscores investor confidence in the currency by supporting
currency, financial, economic, and even political stability. It is perhaps no coincidence
that all existing global reserve currencies are from developed economies. And the US
dollar did not rise to international currency status until after the establishment of the
Federal Reserve System. This is probably the most difficult area for the PRC to catch
up. The gaps between the PRC and those existing international currency countries in
the five categories of the economic freedom index discussed are very wide, especially
in the legal system and property rights, sound money, and regulation.
4. WHAT NEEDS TO BE DONE?
The key challenge facing the PBC and other PRC authorities now is how to raise the
RMBs potential share in global reserves from 2% identified by Model (5) to 10%
identified by Model (1) and even higher levels in the future. The main difference
between the two model specifications is a set of policy and institutional gaps.
The PBC has adopted a two-track approach in internationalizing the RMB: one is to
promote the international use of the RMB and the other is to liberalize the capital
account (PBC Study Group 2006). We may regard the first track as facilitating
nonresidents to use and hold RMB and the second as creating demand for RMB by
nonresidents. The first-track strategies are important because a currency becomes an
international currency only if nonresidents use it, but the second-track strategies are
more criticalthe US dollar has been the global currency mainly because of the strong
US economy, its efficient and liquid market, and its sound legal system.
Most of the authorities recent policy actions are related to the first track. These include
use of the RMB in trade and investment settlement, setting up of offshore markets,
issuance of RMB-denominated securities products overseas, and holding of RMB as
part of foreign central banks currency reserves, etc. These efforts should continue.
The authorities may even take further steps to encourage nonresidents to hold RMB.
One such possible step is to add RMB to the IMFs SDR basket and another is to
promote intraregional cross-holding of reserve currencies as proposed by Fan, Wang,
and Huang (2013).
The SDR was first established in 1969 as a supplement to the US dollar as a source of
international liquidity (Williamson 2009), but it is only an imperfect reserve asset since it
does not allow accomplishment of functions such as market intervention and liquidity
provision (IMF 2011). The SDR basket currently consists of four major global
currencies only (Table 6). Adding the RMB to the basket would not only make it a part
of the global reserve assets but also significantly increase its global profile. The IMF
was initially reluctant about the idea of including the RMB in the SDR basket but now
suggests that recent reforms that allow nonresidents, including central banks, to hold
RMB-denominated deposits could contribute, over time, to resolving some of the
technical difficulties in hedging RMB exposure (IMF 2011, 20).
17

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
Table 6: Official Special Drawing Right Weights (%)
1990 1995 1998 2000 2005 2010
US dollar 40 39 39 45 44 41.9
Deutsche mark 21 21
French franc 11 11
Euro 32 29 34 37.4
Yen 17 18 18 15 11 9.4
Pound sterling 11 11 11 11 11 11.3
Total 100 100 100 100 100 100
Source: International Monetary Fund Special Drawing Right Statistics.
Fan and his collaborators made a proposal in 2010 to establish an intraregional
mechanism for cross-holding of reserve currencies (see Fan, Wang, and Huang
2013).
7
The key idea is for governments in Asia to reach bilateral agreements in
holding each others currencies as part of their foreign reserves. Weights of such
currency holdings may be determined by shares of their bilateral trade in total trade.
This arrangement has some similarities to currency swap agreements, which are
mainly a crisis response mechanism (although sometimes also used as a means to
promote trade and investment), while cross-reserve holdings are part of regular
operations. It immediately makes regional currencies available as reserve currencies,
opens government bond markets to each other, and also encourages parties involved
to monitor others macroeconomic and policy development.
Our view, however, is that whether or not the RMB can become an international
currency will fundamentally be determined by the broadly defined second track of the
PBC. The PRC can encourage nonresidents to hold RMB, but it will not last if it does
not possess the essential qualities of an international currency. For instance, the
amount of offshore RMB deposits often fluctuates alongside changes in currency
expectation. We now discuss some of the important reforms that could underscore
these three factors.
4.1 Economic Weights
So far the hope for the RMB to become an international currency is mainly driven by
the rapid rise of the economy. During the first 30 years of economic reform, the PRC
maintained an average GDP growth rate of 10%. By the end of 2010, it had already
surpassed Japan to become the worlds second largest economy. The general
expectation is that, if the strong growth momentum continues, the PRC will likely
overtake the US to become the largest economy in the world within the next 10 years.
Growth sustainability should be one of the fundamental factors supporting a rising
RMB. The declining international role of the yen in the 1990s as its economy fell into
stagnation offers an important lesson for the PRC.
However, the sustainability of the countrys growth could be a big question mark.
Despite its strong growth performance, economists and officials have long been
worried about its growth model. Former Premier Wen Jiabao once pointed out that the
PRC growth model is unstable, unbalanced, uncoordinated and unsustainable.
8

Some of the key structural problems frequently discussed include unusually high
7
This paper was first completed in 2010 as a project report for the PRC Center for International Economic
Exchange (CCIEE). It was presented at the ADBI/CCIEE joint workshop on regional currency
cooperation in November 2010.
8
See http://news.xinhuanet.com/english/2007-03/16/content_5856569.htm
18


ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
investment share of GDP, heavy dependency on resource consumption, large current
account surplus, unequal income distribution, and serious pollution. The IMFs latest
report on Article IV consultation also confirmed the international communitys worry
about the PRCs structural problems (IMF 2013).
So what lies behind the PRCs unique growth model with strong economic growth but
serious structural imbalances? One explanation is the so-called asymmetric
liberalization of the market. On the one hand, product markets have almost been
completely liberalized; on the other, distortions in factor markets have remained broad
and serious. In general, such policy distortions depressed costs of labor, land, energy,
capital, and water, subsidized owners of the endowments (e.g., producers, investors,
and exporters), and literally functioned at the cost of households. This special
mechanism redistributing income from households to enterprises was the key reason
economic growth was unusually strong but the economic structure became increasingly
imbalanced (Huang 2010; Huang and Tao 2010; Huang and Wang 2010).
The good news is that rebalancing of the PRC economy is already under way. There
are at least three pieces of evidence supporting this claim (Huang et al. 2013): One,
the current account surplus has already narrowed from 10.8% of GDP in 2007 to below
3.0% in recent years. This is the reason some officials argue that the RMB exchange
rate is now close to equilibrium. Two, recent studies suggest that shares of total and
household consumption in GDP started to pick up after 2007 and 2008 (Huang et al.
2013). And three, official estimates of the Gini coefficient point to continued
improvement in income distribution among households after 2008.
So far, improvements have been mainly triggered by the rapid rise of wages as a result
of the emerging labor shortage problem in the PRC (Figure 4). Rapidly growing wages
squeeze corporate profits and therefore slow production, investment, and export
activities. At the same time, they also redistribute income back to households from
corporations and therefore contribute to faster growth of consumption. However,
change of the growth model is only in its nascence and further reforms are necessary
to push the PRCs growth model onto a more sustainable path.
Figure 4: Monthly Wages of Migrant Workers in the Peoples Republic of China
(yuan, 1978 price)

Source: Lu Feng. 2011. Employment Expansion and Wage Growth (20012010). PRC Macroeconomic
Research Center, Peking University, Beijing, 12 June. The original data set ended in 2010 and was updated
by the authors up to 2012.
50
100
150
200
250
300
350
400
1980 1988 1996 2004 2012
Real salary Polynominal trend
19

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
Economic policies under the Li Keqiang-led government, the so-called Likonomics, are
moving in the right direction. Likonomics is popularly regarded as supported by three
pillars: no major stimulus, deleveraging, and structural reforms (Huang 2013). Since
late 2012, the government has shown an unusual tolerance for slowing growth, as GDP
growth stayed constantly below 8%. Although the policy makers are still mindful about
downside risks, they take a relatively more relaxed approach toward the growth
slowdown as long as it stays close to the new and lower growth potential, evidenced by
the robust labor market.
The success or failure of Likonomics will be determined by the outcome of the
structural reforms. Policy makers and policy advisors are currently working on
proposals for an extended reform agenda, including the financial sector, fiscal policy,
land use, factor price, income distribution, administrative controls, and household
registration system. These are all very important, but the following three will dictate the
sustainability of the PRCs growth: (i) change of local government behavior from direct
involvement in economic activities to public goods provision; (ii) restructuring of the
state-owned enterprises to reduce monopoly power and implicit government support;
and (iii) liberalization of factor markets, especially that of capital. These reforms should
support the continuous rise of the countrys economy in the global system and further
increase the importance of the currency.
In the meantime, it is equally important for the PRC to participate or even lead global
liberalization efforts, including the Group of Twenty process and other international
initiatives. It is hard to imagine the RMB as a global currency if the PRC is absent from
or even resists such global initiatives.
4.2 Openness and Depth of Financial Markets
An international currency should be supported by well-developed financial markets that
are freely accessible by nonresidents, sufficiently liquid, reasonably stable, and
equipped with effective hedging instruments. To achieve these goals, the PRC needs
to liberalize its capital account to allow free flow of capital across the border. That
alone, however, is not enough. The lack of capital account restrictions does not
necessarily mean that the capital market is open. Here, again, Japan provides another
important reference. While Japans capital markets are large, they are not very liquid
and foreign investment remains limited.
The PRC appears to have accelerated its efforts of capital account liberalization after
the new government took office in March 2013. One expectation is that the PBC plans
to achieve basic convertibility of the RMB under the capital account by 2015 and full
convertibility by 2020. Such an expectation is certainly consistent with the monetary
authoritys plans of introducing market-based interest rates, adopting the deposit
insurance system, strengthening market disciplines for financial institutions, and
allowing residents to access overseas capital markets.
It is important to point out that capital account liberalization did not just start. It has
been going on for more than 30 years in the PRC. We can use some quantitative
measures of capital account control to illustrate this point (Figure 5). The literature
provides two types of measures for the PRCs capital account controls: one de jure
indicator, such as the ChinnIto index (Chinn and Ito 2008) and Quinns longitudinal
data (Quinn and Toyoda 2008); and the other de facto indicator such as the TOTAL
Index by Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2007). The former often has too broad a category
coverage and fails to capture important changes over time, while the latter cannot
distinguish impacts of capital account liberalization from those of other macroeconomic
changes. The measure depicted in Figure 5 is a de jure index constructed by Huang et
20

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
al. (2012) by going through thousands of policy documents issued by the State
Administration of Foreign Exchange (SAFE) during the past three decades.
Huang et al. (2012) assumed complete control of the capital account for 1977, the year
before the leaders officially launched the economic reform. They then adopted the
classifications used by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
and SAFE, i.e., 11 categories of capital account transactions. For each item, a score of
3 denotes full control, 2 strong control, 1 slight control, and 0 liberalized. By updating
the index in response to legislation issued, an index ranging from January 1978 to
December 2010 is constructed to describe the extensiveness of the PRCs capital
control. The results clearly show that capital account liberalization has been going on
for some time in the PRC. In fact, the authorities adopted a well-established strategy
for liberalizationinflows first, outflows later; long-term first, short-term later; and direct
investment first, portfolio investment later. If the index was 100 at the start of the
economic reform, it has already come down to close to 50 in recent years.
Figure 5: Capital Account Restriction Index

Source: Huang et al. (2012).
Yet, several areas are still under strict regulation (Table 7). In opening the securities
markets to foreign investors, the government pursued a strategy of segmenting the
markets with different investors. Foreign investors can participate in the transaction of
foreign currencydenominated shares and debt instruments, such as the B shares, H
shares, and red chips stocks. However, the RMB-denominated A shares, bonds, or
other money market instruments are not open to the nonresident investors unless they
have a QFII quota. Restrictions on PRC residents are even stricter. Generally,
residents cannot buy, sell, or issue capital or money market instruments in the
overseas markets outside the Qualified Domestic Institutional Investor (QDII) scheme.
There is currently a huge debate in the PRC about planned capital account
liberalization, especially about its sequencing and timing. While most economists
concur that achieving free capital account is beneficial for the economy by bringing
about efficiency improvement, the critical question is about associated financial risk.
Are the financial institutions and markets sound enough to withstand volatile capital
flows? As suggested by McKinnon (1991), domestic reforms should be pushed forward
along with the opening of the capital account. These reforms consist of reduction of
state intervention in the operation of major financial institutions, introduction of market-
based interest rates, greater flexibility of the exchange rate, and improvement in the
50
55
60
65
70
75
80
85
90
95
100
Sep-77 Sep-81 Sep-85 Sep-89 Sep-93 Sep-97 Sep-01 Sep-05 Sep-09
21

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
independence of the central banks monetary policy making (Dobson and Masson
2009).
Table 7: Capital Account Management in the Peoples Republic of China
Non
Convertible
Partially
Convertible
Mostly
Convertible
Fully
Convertible
Total
Capital and money market instrument 2 10 4 16
Derivatives and other instruments 2 2 4
Credit operation 1 5 6
Direct investment 1 1 2
Liquidation of direct investment 1 1
Real estate transaction 2 1 3
Personal capital transaction 6 2 8
Total 4 22 14 40
Sources: Peoples Bank of China; International Monetary Fund Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements
and Exchange Restrictions Report.
4.3 Credibility of Economic and Legal Systems
An international currency is one that nonresidents would use not only in normal times
but also depend on at crisis times. Therefore, just having a strong economy and an
open market is not sufficient. The US dollar served as a global currency during much of
the 20th century because of the well-established legal system in the US and the
Federal Reserve System, as well as its efficient market and strong economy. This is
perhaps the highest hurdle that the PRC will need to overcome in order to make the
RMB an international currency. If the PRC succeeds, it would be historical because it
would be the first time in centuries that a developing countrys currency becomes a
global currencyand developing economies by definition are unstable, volatile
(although often with stronger growth), and vulnerable in the face of shocks.
We are unable to provide a complete list of the tasks for improving the credibility of the
PRCs economic and legal system, but we can start with at least the following three.
One, the PRC needs an independent central bank. While there are many reasons the
PBC is not independentand perhaps there are many good reasons why that is the
casethis could seriously affect the achievement of monetary policy objectives in an
open economy. Of course, independent monetary policy making does not mean
complete lack of coordination with the government. It should possess the following
characteristics. First, monetary policies should have clearly defined policy objectives,
such as growth or inflation. Supporting state-owned enterprises (SOEs) or local
governments, however, should not be a part of the PBCs obligation. Second, the PBC
should use monetary policy instruments such as interest rates and liquidity measures,
abandoning administrative tools such as credit quota and window guidance. And finally,
the PBC should also improve quality and timeliness of its monetary policies.
Two, the PRC needs a fair and transparent legal system to protect property rights and
to enforce bankruptcy. An economy with many loss-making SOEs and monopoly state-
owned financial institutions could never support an international currency. Nonresidents
will have confidence in holding RMB assets only if they know that their property rights
are effectively protected and they will be fairly treated even if they are involved in
economic disputes with PRC SOEs.
And three, political reforms may also be needed to improve the transparency and
representativeness of the political system. While we do not have a fixed idea about
specific forms of needed political reform, to become a global economic leader, the PRC
22

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
needs to adopt a political system that the rest of the world trusts. Here, again,
important changes are necessary to systemically crack down on corruption, reduce
social tension, and build a harmonious society.
5. WHAT ARE THE LIKELY IMPLICATIONS?
Internationalization of the RMB will likely be an ongoing process and making it an
international reserve currency should also be a long-term goal. Before that, however,
the RMBs international role may grow gradually over time. Some PRC scholars
speculated that it would take three decades for it to be internationalized: in the
neighboring areas during the first decade, within the region during the second decade,
and globally during the final decade (Chen 2013). While we are not sure about the
exact timing of each of these stages, the trajectory sounds reasonable, i.e., the RMBs
role will be extended gradually from the neighboring areas to the global system.
The growing international role of the RMB, even if it is a gradual process, should
generate significant implications for the PRC, regional economies, and the rest of the
world. First, increasing its use in international trade and investment settlement could
remove one important economic riskexchange rate uncertaintyfor PRC households
and corporations. Exchange rate uncertainty is one of the main difficulties faced by
exporters, especially those of low-margin exports, and importers. Use of the RMB as a
settlement currency means that the exporters no longer need to worry about potential
losses caused by currency appreciation (or by currency depreciation for importers).
However, this is true only if exports or imports are priced in RMB. Currently, a large
portion of trade and investment settled in RMB are still priced in US dollars, which will
not remove the exchange rate risk for PRC exporters and importers. Therefore, a
critical step is to grant the RMB not only the function of means of exchange but also
unit of account.
Second, turning the RMB into an international reserve currency may help reduce the
PRCs balance of payment risks, in addition to the seigniorage revenue. On the one
hand, as the PRC is able to hold both international assets and liabilities in RMB, it
lowers the risk of a currency crisis, potentially forced upon the PRC by a sudden stop
or sudden reversal of cross-border capital flows. On the other hand, even if the country
suffers from an international payment deficit, the PBC would have the option of printing
more currency to meet the shortfall. International investor confidence in a global
reserve currency should also be less volatile than that in any other developing
economy currenciesand this should support overall financial stability.
Third, the RMB as a global reserve currency should facilitate regional economic
cooperation and integration. East Asia used to be a de facto US dollar block. In the
1980s, the yen became an important anchor for some regional currencies such as the
won and the NT dollar. This led Mundell to identify Asia dominated by the yen as one of
the three islands of stabilitythe other two were North America dominated by the US
dollar and Europe dominated by the euro (Mundell 1999). However, the yen quickly
peaked following stagnation of the Japanese economy. In the aftermath of the Asian
financial crisis, there was an important proposal for creating an Asian currency (Kawai
2008). This proposal, however, lost momentum as its role model, the eurozone, fell into
a debt crisis. However, if the RMB becomes an international currency, there is a
possibility for it to serve as an anchor of regional currencies in Asia. In fact, our earlier
analyses reveal that it already plays some kind of a role as a regional currency anchor
alongside the US dollar.
23

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
Last, the most important implication of RMB internationalization may be the associated
reforms the PRC is about to implement. As discussed earlier, such reforms range from
measures to make economic growth more sustainable to those leading to improvement
of efficiency and stability of financial markets as well as to economic and political
stability. In this sense, we may view RMB internationalization as having similar effects
on overall economic reform as accession to the World Trade Organization at the end of
2001, which almost completely revamped the PRCs economic system. If the
government seriously implements those reforms, the economy would certainly become
more efficient, more dynamic, and more powerful, regardless of whether the RMB
becomes an international reserve currency in the end. A stronger economy and a more
transparent regime can significantly strengthen the PRCs soft power in the world
(Helleiner 2003). Even for this purpose, RMB internationalization is a worthwhile
agenda to pursue.
However, internationalization of the RMB, like any other economic strategy, could have
its own downside risks. One potential risk is premature liberalization of the capital
account. Experiences of developing countries with financial liberalization in the 1980s
and thereafter were accompanied by frequent financial crises. At the moment, the PRC
already suffers from a series of important risks, including a high M2/GDP ratio at 200%,
large local government borrowing, and serious property bubbles. The governments
tentative reform program could mean speedy liberalization of interest rates, of
exchange rates, and of the capital account. It is not yet clear how big the shocks will be
for financial institutions and manufacturing industries. If the sudden rise of cost of
capital and rapid outflow of capital cause serious dislocations in the economy, growth
recession and financial crisis could easily materialize. Even if the RMB becomes an
international reserve currency, it will have to maintain a relatively open financial
system. Whether or not the PRCs economy and markets are strong enough to
withstand serious economic and financial shocks, including speculative attacks,
remains to be seen.
Another major challenge is that if the RMB becomes an international reserve currency
in the coming decades, the PRC should remain a developing country. It would be the
first time in history that a developing country currency serves as a global reserve
currency. Developing country currencies are, by definition, less stable. This could
potentially increase the instability of the international monetary system. More
importantly, if internationalization of the RMB is successful, the currency would likely
serve as one of the global reserve currencies, alongside at least the US dollar and the
euro. According to some experts, an international monetary system with more than one
global reserve currency is actually more unstable than one with a single reserve
currency (UN 2009). If that is indeed true, the international community should seriously
consider proposals for creating a supranational currency (Zhou 2009; UN 2009).
6. SUMMARY OF THE MAIN FINDINGS
The PBC started planning the internationalization of the RMB from at least 2006.
However, actual implementation picked up pace amid the global financial crisis, which
hinted at the potential weakening of the role of the US dollar and demand for an
alternative international currency. This process likely will accelerate further in the
coming years, as the new government focuses more on structural reforms. The PBC
adopted a two-track strategy for internationalizing the currency, with the first track
directly promoting the international use of the currency and the second track gradually
liberalizing the capital account.
24

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
So far, the emphasis has been on increasing the international use of the currency. This
includes use of the RMB for trade and investment settlement, mainly with neighboring
and regional economies; establishment of offshore markets in Hong Kong, China,
evidenced by the rapid growth of RMB deposits held by local residents; issuance of
RMB-denominated bonds and other securities in Hong Kong, China and London; a
large number of currency swap agreements; and holdings of RMB by some foreign
central banks as part of their foreign currency reserves. A significant increase in the
international use of the RMB so far is supported by three related factors:
encouragement of the government, strong growth of economic activities (the PRC is
already the largest trading partner of many regional economies), and expectations of
RMB appreciation.
However, the RMB is still far from being an international reserve currency. Many
optimists tend to pay a lot of attention to the PRCs already gigantic economy. The
logic is simple: the PRC is already a major economy in the world, and its currency
should therefore play some international role. A quick review of experiences of
international currencies during the 20th century suggests that size of the economy may
be an important favorable factor, but it is by no means a sufficient condition. We apply
quantitative methods to identify determinants of international currencies shares in
global reserves and then use the results to predict the RMBs potential share. We find
that if only GDP and trade weights are used, its potential share could be as high as
10% of the global reserves at the end of 2011. However, if policy and institutional
factors, such as capital account controls and economic freedom, are considered, the
RMBs potential share would only reach around 2%. These results suggest that the
main obstacles for the RMB to become an international reserve currency are policy
restrictions and institutional barriers.
So what should the PRC do to effectively internationalize its currency? It can certainly
continue to push on the first track, i.e., promoting its use in international economic
transactions, including establishment of more offshore markets, issuance of more
RMB-denominated assets overseas, and use for trade and investment settlement. The
PRC may also adopt two additional strategies for this purpose. One is to add the RMB
to the IMFs SDR basket, which should significantly raise the international profile of the
currency and make internationalization efforts a lot easier. And the other is to introduce
a new mechanism for intraregional cross-holding of reserve currencies in Asia.
However, for the purpose of currency internationalization, the broadly defined second
track of the two-track strategy is probably more critical as it creates the foundation of a
global reserve currency. We identify reforms in the following three areas for this
purpose.
The first area is to support the sustainable growth of the PRC economy. While
economic weights are not sufficient conditions for a global reserve currency, any hopes
for the RMB to become an international currency could collapse if the economy
suddenly stagnates, similar to what happened to the Japanese economy in the 1990s.
An imminent challenge for the PRC economy now is to change the growth model,
which may be characterized as a combination of strong growth and serious
imbalances. The key is to further economic reforms. The new governments economic
policy framework, popularly termed Likonomics, contains three important pillarsno
more major stimulus, deleveraging to control financial risks, and structural reforms.
Government officials and policy advisors are working on reform programs for a large
number of areas, including the financial system, fiscal policy, land use, administrative
controls, factor prices, income inequality, and household registration system.
Successful transformation of the growth model depends critically on the following
reformsliberalization of interest rates, exchange rates, and the capital account;
25

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
change of the local governments role from directly engaging in production and
investment to public goods provision; and breakdown of the monopoly power of the
state sector.
The second area is to create an open, large, efficient, and liquid financial market. To
serve as an international reserve currency, the RMB needs to be supported by a
financial market that is easily accessible by nonresidents. One major step is to
liberalize the capital account. This has been an ongoing process, with the capital
account control index declining from 100% in 1977 to 53% in 2011. The government
now plans to realize basic convertibility by 2015 and full convertibility by 2020. There is,
however, a major debate as to whether this might be too aggressive and could trigger a
financial crisis. The answer to this should be to keep a close eye on both the necessary
conditions and sequencing of liberalization. Nevertheless, capital account liberalization
is also a necessary step for currency internationalization. However, financial markets
need to be open, liquid, and efficient, and equipped with well-developed hedging
instruments.
The third area is to improve the credibility of the PRCs economic and political systems.
The essence of an international reserve currency is that international investors have
long-term confidence in it. To support such confidence, the PRC needs to improve its
economic, legal, and political systems. This is particularly important since all other
existing international reserve currencies are from developed economies that have well-
developed economic and political systems. We suggest three starting steps for the
PRC: (i) an independent monetary policy-making mechanism, (ii) a sound legal system
that protects property rights and enforces bankruptcy law, and (iii) a political system
that is more transparent and better represented.
Even if all these efforts are successful, we think the internationalization of the RMB will
be a long-term process. We do not think the RMB will become a global reserve
currency in the coming decade or any time soon after that. The RMBs international
role, however, may be extended steadily, perhaps first in the neighboring areas, then in
the region, and finally globally.
This process could also generate significant implications for the PRC, the region, and
the rest of the world. If the RMB is used as a unit of account, it would remove exchange
rate uncertainties for PRC households and corporations in international transactions. If
the PRC can hold its international assets and liabilities all in RMB, it should also reduce
the countrys balance of payment risks, in addition to the seigniorage revenue. The
most fundamental impact of RMB internationalization could be to push comprehensive
reforms in the PRC economy, similar to the effect of WTO accession on the economy
more than 10 years ago. For some PRC officials and scholars, this factor alone would
make currency internationalization a worthwhile agenda to pursue.
At the same time, an aggressive push of the reform agenda could also increase the
potential risk of financial instability. Even if the RMB successfully becomes an
international reserve currency, the PRC would have to withstand more frequent
financial shocks or even speculative attacks. It also remains to be seen if adding a
developing country currency to the global reserve currency basket increases or
decreases the instability of the international monetary system.
26

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
APPENDIX
We perform four types of robustness checks in this analysis. First, as argued in the
context, market capitalization is probably not an accurate representative of actual
degree of financial market development. The second column of Table A1 redefines
financial development as a share of private and public bond market capitalization to
gross domestic product (Beck, Demirg-Kunt, and Levine 2000). The alternative
specification suggests a positive impact from financial development on currency share
in global reserves, which is consistent with previous evidence.
Second, instead of classifying institutional development as economic freedom, we
choose the variables economic regulation and socioeconomic stability as indicating the
development of institutions. The third and fourth columns confirm the results and, not
surprisingly, show that there is no significant difference compared with the benchmark
model in Column 1 of Table A1.
Finally, we include log transformation to allow nonlinearity in determining currency
share in global reserves, as suggested in Chen, Peng, and Shu (2009). Clearly, as
suggested in the fifth column of Table A1, there is not much discrepancy in terms of the
significance and signs of the estimated coefficients.
Table A1: Robustness Check of Determination of Currency Shares
Explanatory Variables
Dependent Variable: currency share in global reserves
Benchmark Bond Market Regulation Socio-Eco. Log Tran.
GDP share 0.103* 0.102* 0.124** 0.149** 0.738**

(0.0523) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.37)
Trade share 0.092* 0.0736 0.0739 0.0517 -0.109

(0.052) (0.05) (0.06) (0.06) (0.33)
Inflation 0.0133 0.104 0.047 0.0905 0.377

(0.0871) (0.11) (0.12) (0.12) (0.72)
Exchange rate volatility 0.121 0.20 0.08 0.17 0.43

(0.0811) (0.14) (0.13) (0.13) (0.81)
Market capitalization 0.0169 0.015 0.00997 0.0273 0.144

(0.0194) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.12)
Financial development 0.000862 0.179*** 0.00297 0.00443** 0.0405***

(0.0014) (0.0354) (0.00) (0.00) (0.01)
Appreciation 0.0674*** 0.048*** 0.0695*** 0.0647*** 0.289***

(0.0093) (0.0099) (0.01) (0.01) (0.06)
Capital account liberalization 0.00849** 0.00726** 0.0162*** 0.0206*** 0.122***

(0.0036) (0.0042) (0.01) (0.01) (0.03)
Institution 0.0043* 0.000278* 0.00383** 0.00231*** 0.0395**

(0.0025) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.02)
Lag of share 0.891*** 0.911*** 0.883*** 0.865*** 0.848***

(0.0265) (0.02) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03)
Constant 0.048** 0.0433** 0.0529*** 0.0542*** 0.752***

(0.0226) (0.02) (0.02) (0.01) (0.18)
Observation 235 235 235 235 235
R-squared 0.958 0.963 0.958 0.96 0.935

27

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
REFERENCES
Beck, T., A. Demirg-Kunt, and R. Levine. 2000. A New Database on the Structure
and Development of the Financial Sector. The World Bank Economic Review
14(3): 597605.
Chen, Y. 2013. Toward a Core Country: Chinas Grand Financial Strategy and
Development Path. Renmin University of China, Beijing.
Chen, H., W. Peng, and C. Shu. 2009. The Potential of the Renminbi as an
International Currency. Currency Internationalization: Lessons from the Global
Financial Crisis and Prospects for the Future in Asia and the Pacific. BIS Paper
No. 61.
Chinn, M., and J. Frankel. 2005. Will the Euro Eventually Surpass the Dollar as
Leading International Reserve Currency? NBER Working Papers No. 11510.
Chinn, M., and J. Frankel. 2008. Why the Euro Will Rival the Dollar. International
Finance 11(1): 4973
Chinn, M., and H. Ito. 2008. A New Measure of Financial Openness. Journal of
Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and Practice 10(3): 309322.
Cohen, B. 2007. Toward a Leaderless Currency System. Conference manuscript in
Wither the Key Currency? Cornell University.
Dobson, W., and P. Masson. 2009. Will the Renminbi Become a World Currency?
China Economic Review 20(1): 124135.
Eichengreen, B. 2005. Sterlings Past, Dollars Future: Historical Perspectives on
Reserve Currency Competition. National Bureau of Economic Research
Working Paper No. 11336.
Fan, G., B. Wang, and Y. Huang. 2013. Intraregional Cross-Holding of Reserve
Currencies: A Proposal for Asia to Deal with the Global Reserve Risks. China &
World Economy 21(4): 1435.
Frankel, J. 2011. Historical Precedents for Internationalization of the RMB. Manuscript,
Council on Foreign Relations and China Development Research Foundation.
Frankel, J., and S. Wei. 1994. Yen Bloc or Dollar Bloc? Exchange Rate Policies of the
East Asian Economies. In Macroeconomic Linkage: Savings, Exchange Rates,
and Capital Flows, edited by T. Ito and A. Krueger. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press. pp. 295333.
Fratzscher, M., and A. Mehl. 2011. Chinas Dominance Hypothesis and the Emergence
of a Tri-polar Global Currency System. European Central Bank Working Paper
No. 1392.
Gao, H., and Y. Yu. 2012. Internationalization of the Renminbi. Currency
Internationalization: Lessons from the Global Financial Crisis and Prospects for
the Future in Asia and the Pacific. BIS Paper No. 61.
Garber, P. 2011. What Drives CNH Market Equilibrium? Manuscript, Council on
Foreign Relations and China Development Research Foundation.
Helleiner, E. 2003. The Making of National Money: Territorial Currencies in Historical
Perspective. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Helleiner, E. 2008. Political Determinants of International Currencies: What Future for
the US Dollar? Review of International Political Economy 15(3): 354378.
28

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
Huang, Y. 2010. Dissecting the China Puzzle: Asymmetric Liberalization and Cost
Distortion. Asia Economic Policy Review 5(2): 281295.
Huang, Y. 2013. What Likonomics Has to Offer? China Daily, 4 July.
Huang, Y., C. Fang, P. Xu, and G. Qin. 2013. New Normal of Chinese Development. In
China: A New Model for Growth and Development, edited by R. Garnaut, C.
Fang, and L. Song. Canberra: ANU E-Press.
Huang, Y., and K. Tao. 2010. Factor Market Distortion and the Current Account
Surplus in China. Asian Economic Papers 9(3): 136.
Huang, Y., and B. Wang. 2010. Cost Distortions and Structural Imbalances in China.
China and World Economy 18(4): 117.
Huang, Y., X. Wang, Q. Gou, and D. Wang. 2012. Achieving Capital Account
Convertibility in China. China Economic Journal 4(1): 2542.
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2011. Enhancing International Monetary Stability
A Role for the SDR? 7 January. Strategy, Policy, and Review Department.
Washington, DC.
International Monetary Fund. 2013. Peoples Republic of China: Article IV Consultation.
17 July. Washington, DC.
Ito, T. 2008. Influence of the Renminbi on Exchange Rate Policies of Other Asian
Currencies. In Debating Chinas Exchange Rate Policy, edited by M. Goldstein
and N.R. Lardy. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.
pp. 239258.
Kawai, M. 2002. Exchange Rate Arrangements in East Asia: Lessons from the 1997
98 Currency Crisis. Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan, Vol. 20,
No. S-1.
Kawai, M. 2008. Toward a Regional Exchange Rate Regime in East Asia. Pacific
Economic Review 13(1): 83103.
Kawai, M., and V. Pontines. 2014. Is There Really a Renminbi Bloc in Asia? ADBI
Working Paper Series No. 467. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute.
Kenen, P. 2002. The Euro versus the Dollar: Will There Be a Struggle for Dominance?
Journal of Policy Modeling 24(4): 347354.
Krugman, P. 1984. The International Role of the Dollar: Theory and Prospect. In
Exchange Rate Theory and Practice, edited by J. Bilson and R. Marston.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. pp. 26178.
Lane, P., and G. Milesi-Ferretti. 2007. The External Wealth of Nations Mark II: Revised
and Extended Estimates of Foreign Assets and Liabilities, 19702004. Journal
of International Economics 73(2): 22350.
Lee, J. 2010. Will the Renminbi Emerge as an International Reserve Currency?
Manuscript, Korea University.
Li, D., and L. Liu. 2008. RMB Internationalization: An Empirical Analysis. Journal of
Financial Research 11: 116.
Maziad, S., and J. Kang. 2012. RMB Internationalization: Onshore/offshore Links. IMF
Working Paper No. WP/12/133.
McKinnon, R. 1991. The Order of Economic Liberalization. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins
University Press.
29

ADBI Working Paper 482 Huang, Wang, and Fan
McNamara, K. 2008. A Rivalry in the Making? The Euro and International Monetary
Power. Review of International Political Economy 15(3): 439459.
Mundell, R. 1999. A Reconsideration of the Twentieth Century. Nobel Prize in
Economics documents 1999-5, Nobel Prize Committee.
Peoples Bank of China (PBC) Study Group. 2006. The Timing, Path, and Strategies of
RMB Internationalization. China Finance 5: 1213.
Quinn, D., and A. Toyoda. 2008. Does Capital Account Liberalization Lead to Growth?
Review of Financial Studies 21(3): 140349.
Subacchi, P. 2010. One Currency, Two Systems: Chinas Renminbi Strategy.
International Economics Briefing Paper, Vol. 1.
Takagi, S. 2011. Currency Internationalization: Lessons from the Global Financial
Crisis and Prospects for the Future in Asia and the Pacific. BIS Working Paper
No. 61.
United Nations (UN). 2009. Report of the Commission of Experts of the President of
the United Nations General Assembly on Reforms of the International Monetary
and Financial System. United Nations Conference on the World Financial and
Economic Crisis and Its Impact on Development. 2426 June. New York.
Williamson, J. 2009. Understanding Special Drawing Rights (SDRs). Peterson Institute
for International Economics Working Paper No. PB09-11.
Zhou, X. 2009. Reform the International Monetary System. Speech. Available at
http://www.pbc.gov.cn/publish/english/956/2009/20091229104425550619706/2
0091229104425550619706_.html [cited January 2010].

30

Você também pode gostar