Você está na página 1de 13

IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS, VOL. 23, NO.

4, NOVEMBER 2008 1783

A Comprehensive Assessment of the Evolution


of Financial Transmission Rights
V. Sarkar, Student Member, IEEE, and S. A. Khaparde, Senior Member, IEEE

Abstract—Financial transmission rights (FTRs) are complemen- Column vector containing the MW amounts of the
tary to the locational marginal pricing of energy. The basic aim base option FTRs.
of the FTR mechanism is to guard forward contracts from uncer-
tain congestion charges. FTRs are also useful to individual gener- Column vector containing the MW amounts of the
ators and loads for selling and buying power, respectively, at the base obligation FTRs.
prices of other locations. The concept has evolved, encompassing
many features such as a simultaneous feasibility test, various ways
diagonal matrix with equals to .
to conduct auctions and allocations and secondary trading. FTRs constant matrix containing the loading
also have a close relation to market power and transmission invest- factors of requested FTRs.
ment. This paper reviews most of the landmark research papers
on the evolution of the FTR concept. It reports a comprehensive constant matrix containing the loading
assessment of various facets of FTRs and allied issues. Financial factors of base FTRs.
transmission rights and flowgate rights (FGRs) are compared. The MW amount of an obligation FTR.
concept of long-term FTRs is discussed. The paper also touches
upon future proposals in this area. MW amount of an option FTR.
Index Terms—Allocation, auction, auction revenue right, finan- MW amount of a physical transaction.
cial transmission right, flowgate right, market power, obligation, Column vector containing the offer and bid
option, revenue adequacy, secondary trading, transmission invest- variables in the energy market.
ment.
Parameter vector (column) representing the net
nodal inelastic loads in the day-ahead market.
NOMENCLATURE: Vector (column) of net nodal injections caused by
the physical equivalents of active FTRs.
Price of an FTR of th type. Variable vector (column) signifying the net nodal
Path-branch sensitivity factor (or power transfer injections caused by .
distribution factor), relating the path of the th Upper limit on .
obligation FTR to a certain line, for a particular
network topology. constant matrix that converts nodal
injections into line flows.
Path-branch sensitivity factor, relating the path of
the th option FTR to a certain line, for a particular Variable vector (column) signifying the awarded
network topology. amounts towards all the FTR bids.
Variable vector (column) signifying the awarded
Total number of offers (from generators) and
amounts towards the obligation FTR bids.
bids (from loads and bilateral transactions) in the
energy market. Variable vector (column) signifying the awarded
amounts towards the option FTR bids.
LMP at the th price node.
Parameter vector (column) representing the base
LMP at the th price node minus LMP at the th amounts of all types of FTRs involved in the
price node. auction.
Number of rows in . Upper limit on .
Number of rows in . Parameter vector (column) representing the
Total number of network capacity constraints in pre-existing (i.e., existing before the auction)
the day-ahead dispatch problem. amounts of all types of FTRs involved in the
Bid price related to the th FTR bid. auction.
Column vector containing the line capacities
available in the day-ahead market.
Manuscript received May 22, 2007; revised June 08, 2008. First published
August 29, 2008; current version published October 22, 2008. Paper no. The forward capacity (as available in the day-ahead
TPWRS-00367-2007. market) of a certain line.
The authors are with the Department of Electrical Engineering, In-
dian Institute of Technology Bombay, Mumbai 400076, India (e-mail: The reverse capacity (as available in the day-ahead
vaskar@ee.iitb.ac.in; sak@ee.iitb.ac.in). market) of a certain line.
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/TPWRS.2008.2002182

0885-8950/$25.00 © 2008 IEEE

Authorized licensed use limited to: GOVERNMENT COLLEGE OF ENGINEERING. Downloaded on January 15, 2010 at 03:15 from IEEE Xplore. Restrictions apply.
1784 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS, VOL. 23, NO. 4, NOVEMBER 2008

Total number of nodes. term) forward contracts are desirable to increase competition in
vector of all zeros. the market as they play an important role in curbing the market
power of generators [10]–[12]. Therefore, the LMP mechanism
vector of all ones. also needs the support of some complementary methodology or
Value of the scalar or vector variable at the tool to guard the long- and medium-term forward contracts from
solution point of the power dispatch problem. congestion price risk.
Value of the scalar or vector variable (.) at the Financial transmission rights (FTRs) are risk-hedging instru-
solution point of the FTR auction problem. ments designed mainly with the aim to minimize the conges-
Convex social-welfare function. tion price risk for forward contracts [1], [13], and [14]. FTRs
are now successfully implemented in many power markets such
Optimal social-welfare as the function of . as PJM, New York, New England, and others [15]–[22]. Simi-
Objective function of the FTR auction problem. larly to the physical transmission rights (PTRs), FTRs also de-
fine transmission property rights, but in financial form. Under
Optimal value of as the function of .
PTR methodology, a market player must have sufficient trans-
mission reservation to get his transaction scheduled without any
I. INTRODUCTION network usage charge. A PTR is an option (i.e., the owner may
or may not use it) transmission right that may be either firm or
ONGESTION management in restructured power sys- of use it or lose it type. Unlike PTRs, FTRs are completely fi-
C tems can be carried out efficiently through locational
marginal price (LMP)-based energy pricing [1]–[7]. The basis
nancial in nature and do not interfere with the power scheduling
process. Basically, an FTR provides its owner with some finan-
of the LMP mechanism is the theory of electricity spot pricing cial support to pay the congestion price that he is charged in
by Schweppe et al. [8]. Under the locational marginal pricing the day-ahead energy market for his transaction. An individual
approach, the independent system operator (ISO) calculates generator or load can also buy an FTR to adjust its sale or buy
power dispatch schedules by maximizing the social welfare price, respectively, to the LMP of a different location. For this
function within the available network capacity. The price of purpose, a generator needs to buy an FTR “from” its location,
energy at a location is determined by the rate of decrease of whereas a load needs to buy an FTR “to” its location.
optimal social welfare with respect to the fixed load increase at The basic parameters defining an FTR are a source, a sink, a
that location. These prices are the locational marginal prices. validity period, and a MW amount. The source/sink of an FTR
Locational marginal pricing can be carried out either on a need not be a single bus. It could be a load zone, or a hub, or an
nodal basis or on a zonal basis. However, one major problem of interface for which an LMP is calculated and posted (i.e., it can
zonal pricing is accurately finding the zonal sensitivity factors be any price node). For instance, in PJM, a network transmis-
[9]. Thus, each pool participant (individual generator or load) sion service customer [23] can ask the ISO for an FTR from a
has to pay (load) or is paid (generator) the LMP at its loca- generator node to a load zone [17]. Moreover, in the case where
tion, whereas each bilateral contract has to pay a congestion energy prices are calculated on a zonal basis [24] rather than
charge (plus a loss charge if the system modeled in the LMP a nodal basis, FTRs are to be issued between individual zones
calculation is lossy) according to the LMP difference between rather than between nodes. Under a hybrid pricing approach, in
its sink and source locations. The net collection (which is which some energy prices are calculated at the node level and
generally nonnegative) of the ISO is termed the merchandizing others at the zone level, FTRs are available even between a node
surplus. This kind of energy pricing can generate useful price and a zone.
signals that assist in identifying suitable locations for building Each FTR is assigned a monetary value for each hour de-
new generators, load centers, and transmission facilities. For pending upon the day-ahead (or real-time if the day-ahead
instance, if the LMP at a certain location consistently displays market is absent) LMP outcomes for that hour (if network loss
a higher value, it provides an initial indication that this lo- is also considered in the dispatch model, only the congestion
cation may be a suitable place for building new generators. components of LMPs are to be used for calculating the hourly
At the same time, by penalizing each bilateral contract with values of FTRs [22]). The FTR owners are paid by the ISO
a location-dependent network usage charge, strong financial according to the hourly values of their FTRs. However, the
incentive is applied, making it account for the congestion in settlement can be over multiple hours at a time.
the transmission network. The pool prices also recognize the The FTR mechanism has evolved with success since its in-
system limits. The possibility of administrative transmission ception in 1992. The motivation of this paper is to acquaint
load relief (TLR) thus becomes very small. Moreover, due to the reader with a comprehensive assessment of the evolution of
the auction-based allocation of transmission capacity, relative the FTR mechanism. An attempt is made to summarize all the
needs of the market players for the transmission usage are salient features of this mechanism in a comprehensible format.
suitably assessed. The contribution of the paper is to provide insights into the
Although the LMP mechanism has an appeal for efficient con- subtle and intricate aspects of the FTR evolution from various
gestion management, this mechanism inherently creates price perspectives. Later developments which stem from the need for
risk (in the form of unpredictable congestion charges), espe- more flexible FTRs are also addressed in an integrated fashion.
cially for long-term forward contracts. This may hamper long- The rest of the paper is organized as follows: The risk hedging
term power trading. However, long-term (or, at least, medium- functionality of FTRs is described in Section II. The revenue

Authorized licensed use limited to: GOVERNMENT COLLEGE OF ENGINEERING. Downloaded on January 15, 2010 at 03:15 from IEEE Xplore. Restrictions apply.
SARKAR AND KHAPARDE: COMPREHENSIVE ASSESSMENT OF THE EVOLUTION OF FTRS 1785

adequacy issue and the concept of simultaneous feasibility test 1) If , the player always gets
are discussed in Section III. In Section IV, the FTR issuance benefit from (or, at least, never loses money due to) net-
processes are described in detail. Some current practices and work congestion. The player collects a net nonnegative
proposals for the treatment of the revenue shortfall problem payment of if , and
are discussed in Section V. The scope of the secondary trading of if . Therefore, he does not
of FTRs is discussed in Section VI. A comparison between fi- see any price risk for this transaction.
nancial transmission right and flowgate right is carried out in 2) If , the actual transaction is, in effect,
Section VII. The interrelationship between financial transmis- divided into the following three parts:
sion right and market power is explained in Section VIII. A a) A transaction of MW on Path .
small discussion regarding how FTRs can incentivize private b) A transaction of MW on Path .
transmission investments is presented in Section IX. The con- c) A transaction of MW on Path .
cepts of long-term FTR, contingent transmission right, and lo- The first of the above transactions is always charged with
cational FTR are outlined in Section X. Finally, the paper is con- the LMP difference between the sink and source locations.
cluded in Section XI. The second transaction is charged with this LMP difference
only when the sink LMP becomes lower than the source
II. RISK HEDGING FUNCTIONALITY OF FINANCIAL LMP. Finally, the third transaction is never charged with
TRANSMISSION RIGHTS the LMP difference. The above set of transactions is equiv-
alent to the original transaction and FTR combination in
With regard to the hedging adjustability, currently exercised
the sense that for both cases the net payment to the ISO re-
FTRs can be classified into two categories: options and obliga-
mains the same. Thus, it is clear that the player never loses
tions. An obligation FTR is basically a fixed hedge FTR that al-
money for the second and third transactions. Moreover, the
ways remains active. In contrast, an option FTR is an adjustable
second transaction gives him a benefit of in case
hedge FTR that becomes active only when congestion occurs
is negative. However, the second part does not give
in the forward direction. Irrespective of whether it is an option
any benefit when the player has to make a positive pay-
or an obligation, the value of an active FTR is always given by
ment for the first part, i.e., when . Therefore,
the product of its MW amount and the LMP differential on its
the first part remains completely risky for the player, but
path. Note that in the FTR context, a path is simply defined
he observes no price risk in the second and third parts.
by a source-sink pair rather than an alternating series of lines
3) If , the obligation FTR itself creates a price
and nodes. The value of an inactive FTR automatically becomes
risk for its owner in that the player will have to make a net
zero. Therefore, an obligation FTR may incur negative values at
positive payment of on the occurrence
certain hours owing to the occurrence of congestion in the re-
of congestion in the reverse direction (i.e., when
verse direction, whereas the value of an option FTR is always
).
nonnegative. The ability to implement transmission rights as
It can be seen that only a fixed physical transaction can be
obligations is one of the major advantages of FTRs over PTRs.
fully hedged by an obligation FTR alone. This transaction must
The risk hedging functionality of FTRs is described below.
be of the same MW amount as that of the obligation FTR and
At a certain hour, the target payment (TP) towards the port-
must be on the same path. That is why it is called a fixed hedge
folio of a MW obligation FTR and a MW option FTR
FTR. Even if the MW amount of this transaction falls below the
on Path is given by
MW amount of the respective obligation FTR, the market player
has risks having to make a net positive payment under network
if congestion. This price risk is generated by the obligation FTR
itself and, therefore, is termed the downside risk. In case the
if (1)
price risk is due to the physical transaction, it is called the upside
Now, in this hour, the owner of this FTR portfolio has a physical risk. For a case in which the transaction amount is not fixed, both
transaction of MW on the same path. His payment for this the upside risk and the downside risk can be avoided by using
transaction towards network congestion is given by a portfolio of an obligation FTR and an option FTR instead of
only an obligation FTR. This is because an obligation-option
combination is able to remove risk completely for a band of
(2) transactions. The MW amount of the obligation FTR defines the
lower boundary of this band, and its upper boundary is indicated
Therefore, the net payment made by the player for this transac- by the total portfolio amount. Therefore, the option FTR allows
tion and FTR combination is given by its owner to adjust his hedge position, or, in other words, this
FTR provides to its owner an adjustable hedge.
Although option FTRs can provide more benefit than do obli-
if gation FTRs, there is a certain trade-off that often makes obliga-
if (3) tions preferable to options, and this is explained in Section IV.
Moreover, the above discussion on risk hedging is based upon
From this expression of net payment, the following risk hedging the assumption that the direction of congestion is quite uncer-
functionality of the above FTR portfolio can be seen. tain on a path. In a real system, there may be certain paths where

Authorized licensed use limited to: GOVERNMENT COLLEGE OF ENGINEERING. Downloaded on January 15, 2010 at 03:15 from IEEE Xplore. Restrictions apply.
1786 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS, VOL. 23, NO. 4, NOVEMBER 2008

the probability of congestion in the reverse direction is very low, ward and reverse directions assigned to the lines. The elements
and for those paths option FTRs are redundant. This is because of are the line loading limits as available in day-ahead
the per MW value of an obligation FTR will most of the time be market. Constraint (5) is the power balance constraint and other
the same as that of an option FTR on such a path. constraints are self-explanatory. A numerical illustration of the
One point that should be explicitly mentioned here is that power dispatch problem can be found in [26]. However, the La-
the discussion above basically explains how FTRs perform risk grangian of this optimization problem can be written as,
hedging for which, actually, they have been designed. As far
as the settlement is concerned, each obligation or option FTR is (9)
settled individually and without any bearing on the actual energy
where , , , and are the vectors of Lagrangian mul-
schedules. Therefore, a market player does not need to have a
tipliers. The LMP at a node is defined as the rate of decrease of
transaction on the path of his FTR to get the value of this FTR. In
optimal social welfare with respect to the increase of fixed (or
practice even, a market player may sometimes choose to hedge
inelastic) load at that node. Therefore, from the theory of sensi-
the congestion price risk on a certain path by means of an FTR
tivity analysis [27]
on a different path. However, upon such a decision, the market
player becomes exposed to the risk of the difference between
the LMP differentials on these paths. (10)
III. SIMULTANEOUS FEASIBILITY TEST
AND REVENUE ADEQUACY Each pool contract is settled according to these LMP values. The
congestion price to be paid by a bilateral contract is given by
Revenue adequacy is an important consideration in the is-
the rate of decrease of optimal social welfare with respect to the
suance of financial transmission rights. There should be enough
increase of the fixed transaction amount on the respective path.
collection from the network congestion to pay full FTR credits.
Therefore, this price is equal to the LMP difference between the
Revenue adequacy can be ensured through a mechanism called
corresponding locations. The net congestion collection (NCC)
simultaneous feasibility test (SFT) [10], [13], [17], and [25],
of the ISO is given by the sum of the payments made by the
which can be stated as: If the network capacity available in a
bilateral contracts, plus the sum of the payments made by the
day-ahead market is sufficient to accommodate the power flow
loads, minus the sum of the payments made to the generators,
caused by the physical equivalents of active FTRs at the rele-
i.e.,
vant hour, the congestion collection (day-ahead) must be greater
than or equal to the total FTR target payment at this hour. Ide-
ally, the network model to be used in the SFT should be the
same as that used for power scheduling. The relationship be-
tween simultaneous feasibility and revenue adequacy is estab-
lished below.
The day-ahead dispatch problem can be mathematically for- (11)
mulated as follows:
According to complementary slackness condition of KKT rule
[27]

s.t. (12)

Therefore, the expression for NCC can be finally written as


(4)

(5) (13)

(6) Let the net injection pattern caused by the physical equiv-
alents of active FTRs results in a feasible power flow condition
(7) within the network capacity that is available in the above energy
(8) market. Therefore
where
(14)
if is a generation at Node
if is a load at Node The total target payment (TTP) towards these FTRs can be cal-
culated as
if is not related to Node
Constraints (4) are the network capacity constraints. The matrix
converts nodal injections into the line flows both for the for- (15)

Authorized licensed use limited to: GOVERNMENT COLLEGE OF ENGINEERING. Downloaded on January 15, 2010 at 03:15 from IEEE Xplore. Restrictions apply.
SARKAR AND KHAPARDE: COMPREHENSIVE ASSESSMENT OF THE EVOLUTION OF FTRS 1787

It should be mentioned again that irrespective of whether it is A. FTR Auction


an obligation or an option, the target payment towards an active
FTR is always given by the product of its MW amount and the The FTR auction is basically a central mechanism by which
LMP differential on its path. Finally, the surplus amount (SA) the requirements of the participating market players are jointly
of the congestion collection is given by assessed, compared, and then fulfilled to the best possible ex-
tent. In general, any market player can participate in an auc-
tion. First introduced in 1999 by NYISO, the auction mecha-
(16) nism is currently in practice in PJM, NYISO, ISO-NE, MISO,
and CAISO. The different aspects of the FTR auction process
Equation (16), in conjunction with (14) and the nonnegativity are discussed below.
condition of , proves that the surplus amount of the day-ahead 1) Participation Types: Market players can participate in an
congestion collection must be nonnegative if the physical FTR auction mainly in the following four ways.
equivalents of the active FTRs are simultaneously feasible. Self-scheduling: In this category of participation, a market
Note that such a relationship between simultaneous feasibility player submits a price-insensitive FTR request to the ISO,
and revenue adequacy can be proven only for a linear power i.e., the player is ready to spend any amount of money in
flow model, where each constrained network quantity can be order to procure his required FTR.
expressed as a linear function of nodal injections [as in (4)]. A Buy bid: In this category of participation, a market player
linear power flow model may be either a linearized ac power requests to the ISO for an FTR along with specifying the
flow model or a dc power flow model. It was argued in [13] maximum price he is willing to pay for this FTR.
that the above relationship between the simultaneous feasibility Surrendering: In this category of participation, a market
of FTRs and revenue adequacy equally holds, even for an player returns a portion of his current FTR to the ISO.
ac power flow model (which is nonlinear and nonconvex in The player is ready to accept any payment (even negative
nature). Currently, NYISO is the only market that employs this payment) for the returned FTR.
type of power flow model to perform power dispatch calcula- Sale offer: In this category of participation, a market player
tion and SFT. However, the proof provided in [13] assumes offers a portion of his current FTR for sale, while speci-
that in the dispatch problem, the injection at a node never hits fying the minimum sale price. A sale offer can be thought
its lower or upper limit. This may not be a valid assumption, of as a combination of a buy bid and a surrender. For in-
since at certain hours, the injection at a node may touch a limit. stance, a sale offer of 100 MW FTR at $20/MW is equiva-
More prominently, if the load at a certain node is inelastic, lent to the combined participation of a buy bid for 100 MW
the injection at this node always remains at the limit. This is FTR at $20/MW and a surrender of 100 MW FTR.
because the upper and lower limits for a variable representing There is also a proposal for the following type of participation
an inelastic load must be the same. In reality, an SFT based on [29].
an ac power flow model cannot guarantee revenue adequacy Conversion bid: In this category of participation, a market
[28]. player requests to the ISO to convert a portion of his cur-
In the above derivation, a lossless power dispatch model has rent option or obligation FTR into an obligation or option
been considered. It should be mentioned that FTRs are able to FTR, respectively. The player also specifies the maximum
provide hedges only against network congestion. Still no rev- price (nonpositive for option-to-obligation conversion) he
enue adequacy test model is available to support loss-hedging wishes to pay for this conversion.
(i.e., providing hedges against both network congestion and 2) Auction Formulation: Each FTR auction is cleared
loss) FTRs. In the case in which network loss is also consid- through an optimization calculation. A generalized auction
ered in the power dispatch model, each LMP is divided into formulation for the clearance of obligation FTRs can be found
energy, congestion and loss components, and the congestion in [30], whereas [31] and [32] explain how to modify this
components of LMPs are used to calculate the hourly values formulation when option FTRs are also included in the auction.
of FTRs. The total collection of the ISO is also accordingly The objective function (which is similar to the social welfare
divided in a net congestion collection and a net loss collection. function in the energy market) of the auction optimization
As before, the payments towards FTRs are made from the fund problem is the negated quote-based sum of the issued amounts
of net congestion collection. The power dispatch problem still towards all the FTR bids, and the function should be minimized.
employs a lossless power flow model for the calculation of line The cleared amount towards each bid must lie within its lower
flows, but some additional loads are created at the system nodes (which is zero) and upper (which is the requested amount)
to represent network loss [2]. As before, revenue adequate limits. In order to ensure revenue adequacy, the simultaneous
congestion collection can be ensured by testing simultaneous feasibility condition (derived from the concept of SFT) must
feasibility of the active FTRs on this lossless power flow model. be satisfied while issuing FTRs. In case all the FTRs are issued
for a same set of hours and conversion bids are absent, the
IV. FTR ISSUANCE PROCESS simultaneous feasibility condition can be stated as: The phys-
FTRs are issued by the ISO by means of auction and/or al- ical equivalent of each possible active-inactive combination
location. There may be different time horizons for the issuance of individual FTRs (base as well as requested) must result in
of FTRs. As an example, FTRs are auctioned both annually and a feasible power flow condition for each possible topological
monthly in the PJM market. scenario of the network. Here, the base FTRs are those entities

Authorized licensed use limited to: GOVERNMENT COLLEGE OF ENGINEERING. Downloaded on January 15, 2010 at 03:15 from IEEE Xplore. Restrictions apply.
1788 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS, VOL. 23, NO. 4, NOVEMBER 2008

whose quantity values are considered to be constants during conversion FTR of 20 MW on the same path in the auction.
the auction calculation. As an example, the FTR awarded to At the end of this auction, in essence, the player retains an
a market participant in an annual auction is to be considered obligation FTR of 30 MW and an option FTR of 20 MW on
as a base FTR in the subsequent monthly auctions. Similarly, Path 1–2.
a self-scheduled FTR is a base entity in an auction. FTR 3) Auction Pricing: Financial transmission rights are priced
surrenders are also considered through base case modeling by following the same marginal pricing rule as that for the pricing
subtracting the surrendered amounts from the original FTR of energy [17]. The auction optimization problem can be com-
amounts. pactly formulated as
Note that we have to consider different active-inactive com-
binations of individual FTRs. This is because an option FTR
becomes inactive if congestion occurs in the reverse direction.
Similarly, different topological conditions of the network have
s.t.
to be considered in order to take “ ” contingencies into ac-
count. Thus, using dc power flow model, the simultaneous fea- (18)
sibility constraints for a certain line under a particular network
topology can be written as (19)
(20)
Here, the vector contains all the requested obligation, op-
tion and converted FTR terms. Constraints (18) are the simulta-
(17)
neous feasibility constraints. and contain the loading fac-
tors of requested and base FTR terms, respectively, in simulta-
neous feasibility constraints. is the vector of scaling
The vectors , , and contain the loading fac- factors. The network capacity offered in this auction is given
tors (i.e., coefficient factors) of the different FTR terms in the by , whereas indicates the total
above simultaneous feasibility constraints. Here, , network capacity available for awarding new FTRs. Now, the
, and . The scaling Lagrangian of the above optimization problem can be written
factors and vary between 0 and 1. The value of a scalling as
factor would be 1 in case the corresponding constraint is already
overloaded or 100% of the available network capacity (i.e., ca-
pacity that is available for awarding new FTRs) is offered in the (21)
auction. However, in the annual auction of ISO-NE, only 50%
of the available network capacity is offered to the auction par- The price of an FTR similar to can be calculated
ticipants. In this case, both and are less than 1. The formu- as
lation of the simultaneous feasibility constraints is numerically
illustrated in [32].
Note that, similarly to PTRs, counterflows caused by the (22)
physical equivalents of option FTRs are also not considered in
the line flow constraints. In order to consider conversion bids In general, two FTRs are said to be similar (or of the same type)
in an FTR auction, only a small amendment is required to the if they have the same loading factor in any simultaneous fea-
above formulation. A conversion bid can be considered as the sibility constraint. Therefore, according to (22), the price of an
buy bid for a special type of FTR, termed a conversion FTR. FTR can be simply calculated by taking the sum of the products
The bid for a conversion FTR is to be treated in the same way of its loading factor and constraint shadow price over all the si-
as an obligation or option FTR bid is done. The upper limit on multaneous feasibility constraints. The auction participant pays
a conversion FTR variable is given by the requested conversion or is paid this price depending upon whether this FTR is issued
amount and the lower limit is zero. The loading factor of a or bought back, respectively, by the ISO.
conversion FTR term in a simultaneous feasibility constraint The FTR prices exhibit the following properties.
can be calculated simply by subtracting the coefficient factor of • Total collection from an FTR auction must be nonnegative
the original FTR from that of the new FTR. For example, the if .
loading factors of an obligation FTR and an option FTR on Path • In the case an FTR bid is fully or partially selected, the
1–2 are and 0, respectively, in a simultaneous feasibility price to be paid to the ISO for this FTR must be lower than
constraint. The loading factor of an obligation-to-option con- or equal to its bid price.
version FTR on Path 1–2 in the given simultaneous feasibility • In the case an FTR offer is fully or partially accepted, the
constraint can be then calculated as . Sim- price to be paid by the ISO for this FTR must be higher
ilarly, the loading factor of an option-to-obligation conversion than or equal to its offer price.
FTR can be calculated as . Next, consider • An FTR bid would be fully selected if its bid price is higher
that a market player initially (i.e., before the auction) had an than the clearing price of a similar FTR.
obligation FTR of 50 MW on Path 1–2. Upon a conversion • An FTR offer would be fully accepted if its offer price is
request, the market player is awarded an obligation-to-option lower than the clearing price of a similar FTR.

Authorized licensed use limited to: GOVERNMENT COLLEGE OF ENGINEERING. Downloaded on January 15, 2010 at 03:15 from IEEE Xplore. Restrictions apply.
SARKAR AND KHAPARDE: COMPREHENSIVE ASSESSMENT OF THE EVOLUTION OF FTRS 1789

It is beyond the scope of this paper to provide the mathemat- NYISO and CAISO [22], [33], and [34], and was formerly in
ical proofs of these properties. Furthermore, obligation FTRs practice in the PJM market. The same simultaneous feasibility
are, in general, cheaper than option FTRs. This is because [as condition as described in Section IV-A2 should again be sat-
obvious from (17)] the loading effect of (i.e., capacity consumed isfied when allocating FTRs directly. In order to enhance the
by) an option FTR on any simultaneous feasibility constraint retail-side competition, directly allocated FTRs are reassigned
cannot be lower than that of the obligation FTR with the same among the load serving entities (LSEs) on a daily basis fol-
parameters. lowing the movement of retail customers [33]. This reassign-
4) Time Differentiation of FTR Products: In order to track ment is realized by assigning counterflow FTRs to the load-
the time variations (seasonal, weekly, or daily) of load, finan- losing LSEs. A counterflow FTR is basically an obligation FTR
cial transmission rights are generally issued for different time that is assigned to a certain party in order to compensate the
intervals over any time horizon. For example, separate FTRs are power flow caused by the FTR assigned to another party [33]
issued for on-peak hours and off-peak hours in the PJM market and [35].
[17]. The PJM market also issues multi-interval FTRs with 24-h 2) Auction Revenue Right: Auction revenue right (ARR) is
validity within a day. A multi-interval FTR basically spans two a mechanism through which the proceeds from an FTR auction
or more individual time intervals, whereas a single-interval FTR are distributed among the firm transmission customers. For in-
remains valid only for the hours of a particular interval. In the stance, in the PJM [17], ARR mechanism is used to distribute
absence of multi-interval FTRs, an independent auction can be the annual auction collection among the firm point-to-point and
conducted for each individual interval. However, if multi-in- network service customers. Each ARR is defined between a cer-
terval provision is also included, the auction has to be cleared tain source-sink pair and for a certain MW amount. The ARRs
through a joint optimization calculation accounting for all the issued in the PJM market are all obligations, whereas only op-
time intervals simultaneously. There must be a separate set of tion ARRs are issued by the ISO-NE [17] and [33]. Similar to
simultaneous feasibility constraints for each individual time in- FTRs, ARRs can also be time-differentiated (such as on-peak
terval. The buyer of a single-interval FTR has to pay the price ARRs, off-peak ARRs, and 24-h ARRs). The value of an ARR is
for the corresponding interval only. However, the price to be calculated in the same way as the value of an FTR is calculated.
paid for a multi-interval FTR is the sum of the prices of the in- Here, the term “LMP difference” indicates the obligation FTR
dividual intervals spanned by this FTR [15]. price on the ARR path for the relevant time interval. If the FTR
5) Multi-Round Auction: Multi-round auctions are becoming auction is multi-round, the weighted average of the LMP dif-
increasingly popular. For instance, the annual auction in the ferences from all the rounds is used to calculate the value of an
PJM is conducted in four rounds [17]. In each round, a quarter of ARR. The ratio of the weight factors should be the same as that
the available network capacity (i.e., available for the auction as of the basic network capacities offered in the individual rounds.
a whole), plus any capacity not awarded in the previous round, Basic network capacity means the total network capacity that is
is offered to the auction participants. The results of a round are offered in a round minus the capacity that is carried over from
published before the next round begins. Any FTR awarded in a the previous round. The total network capacity, offered in the
certain round can be offered for sale in subsequent rounds. The auction as a whole, is given by the sum of the basic network ca-
main motivation behind the multi-round approach is to make the pacities offered in all the rounds.
auction process more flexible and competitive. This gives both In order to ensure revenue adequate auction collection, simul-
the winners and losers the opportunity to revise their bids and taneous feasibility must be checked while issuing ARRs, i.e., the
try again following the result of an auction round [29]. physical equivalent of each possible active-inactive combination
of ARRs issued for any time interval should collectively result
B. FTR Allocation in a feasible power flow condition within the network capacity
offered in the corresponding FTR auction. Although ISO-NE
Unlike an FTR auction, FTR allocation is not a bid-based offers only option ARRs, all ARRs are considered to be obli-
mechanism. Therefore, no market-based measure is associated gations in the SFT model, and their MW amounts are adjusted
with the FTR allocation process as to the relative needs of the later depending upon the price outcomes of the corresponding
participating market players. As a result, FTR allocation is gen- FTR auction. However, in case an ARR owner is paid the full
erally kept restricted to the firm transmission customers only. value of his ARR, this revenue completely neutralizes the pay-
Furthermore, as option FTRs consume more network capacity ment (plus giving him some additional benefit if it is an option)
than do obligation FTRs, FTRs of the former type are generally that he has to make for getting an obligation FTR of the same
not issued via allocation. Different measures in different mar- MW amount on the same path, i.e., ARR mechanism is, in ef-
kets exist for the allocation of FTRs, such as existing transmis- fect, an indirect procedure for allocating FTRs. The PJM market
sion reservations, past transmission usages and load ratio shares offers an additional flexibility to ARR owners, which is to con-
[17], [22], and [33]. FTR allocation can be carried out either on vert their ARRs directly into FTRs. Similar to directly allocated
a first-come-first-serve basis or through a joint clearance. There FTRs, ARRs also follow the shift of loads among the LSEs.
are two alternative approaches for allocating FTRs, and these It is often argued that the ARR mechanism is better than the
are discussed below. direct allocation approach because the revenue from an ARR
1) Direct Allocation: In this approach, an eligible market can be used to buy an FTR not only on the ARR path but also
player is awarded a firm FTR quantity completely free of cost. on a different path. However, the same benefit can also be ob-
Direct allocation of FTRs is currently carried out in MISO, tained from a directly allocated FTR. The owner of the directly

Authorized licensed use limited to: GOVERNMENT COLLEGE OF ENGINEERING. Downloaded on January 15, 2010 at 03:15 from IEEE Xplore. Restrictions apply.
1790 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS, VOL. 23, NO. 4, NOVEMBER 2008

allocated FTR can surrender this FTR in the forthcoming auc- the previous months. The same sequence is repeated for each
tion to generate an ARR equivalent revenue that can be utilized month within a planning period.
to buy an FTR on a different path. Furthermore, the FTR quan- Unlike FTRs that are settled daily, ARRs are settled on a
tities awarded through a direct allocation are firm having zero monthly basis in the PJM market. The shortfall in the auction
procurement cost. The ARR mechanism does not guarantee this collection is managed by derating the ARRs in the same way
benefit. In the case of the ARR mechanism, FTRs are physically as described above. At the end of each planning period, the un-
released only through the auction while the firm transmission paid ARR credits are partially or fully compensated with the
customers are provided with some financial support to buy their amount that remains in the above balancing fund after compen-
required FTRs. The main benefit of the ARR mechanism is that sating the shortfalls in FTR payments. In the case some amount
it helps in better management of the simultaneous feasibility of still remains in the balancing fund, it is distributed among the
FTRs. In addition, the ARR mechanism provides more flexi- firm transmission customers on a pro-rata basis irrespective of
bility to the ISO to deal with the problem of revenue deficiency whether or not they hold FTRs for their transmission services.
in an auction. However, it is beyond the scope of this paper to In [37], it was shown that the above procedure for derating
present a detailed discussion on this matter. FTRs may create a gaming opportunity for certain market
players, in that they can artificially create congestion on the
transmission system. In order to suppress such gaming op-
V. TREATMENT OF REVENUE SHORTFALLS portunity, a direct assignment technique was suggested in
Although every FTR issuance process employs some SFT [37] based on the constraint shadow prices, their capacity
model that is generally linear, there may be certain hours when degradations, MW amounts of the FTRs, and the path-branch
day-ahead congestion collection becomes insufficient to pay full sensitivity factors. The assumption behind this approach is that
FTR credits. The reason behind such revenue shortfall is that the network capacity degradation is the only reason for revenue
FTRs are issued over a period of time during which the path- inadequacy. Now, as mentioned earlier, there are also some
branch sensitivities, base power flows (e.g., loop flows from other factors which may create a revenue shortfall situation. As
the neighboring control areas), and the contingency consider- a result, the suggested method may fail at certain instances, e.g.,
ation in the power dispatch model may vary. Therefore, the when revenue shortfall is caused by a line outage. However,
SFT model may not be precise enough to cover all the hours the shortcoming of this direct assignment algorithm can be
of the time horizon of interest successfully. Also, the network eliminated by use of a small modification. Initially, the net
topology may get changed because of accidental line outages. In load caused by the physical equivalents of active FTRs on each
addition, line capacities may degrade. Owing to all these factors, simultaneous feasibility constraint is to be calculated. If the
the active FTRs at a certain hour may not be simultaneously fea- total load on a simultaneous feasibility constraint is found to be
sible with respect to the actual network constraints in the power greater than its limit, the amount of overload is to be measured.
dispatch model. Such infeasibility may, in turn, lead to inade- For example, if the limit of a constraint is 100 MW and the total
quate congestion collection from the day-ahead market. Also, it load on it is 120 MW, the amount of overload is 20 MW. Once
may not be possible to bridge completely the gap from the fund all the overload amounts are calculated, these quantities should
of the real-time congestion collection. be used in the formula of [37] in lieu of capacity degradation
However, as an ISO is a nonprofit-making entity, there must amount.
be some mechanism to compensate for any such revenue short-
fall. In NYISO, revenue shortfall is compensated by imposing
VI. SECONDARY TRADING OF FTRS
uplift charges on the transmission owners [36]. The objective
here is to link transmission maintenance standards with revenue Once awarded through central auction or allocation, FTRs
inadequacy. NYISO also allocates net congestion surplus and can be traded bilaterally in a secondary market. In the secondary
FTR auction revenues to the transmission owners. However, the market, an FTR can be split into multiple FTRs with different
NYISO approach seems unable to provide proper maintenance MW amounts and different validity periods. The new owner-
incentives due to the uniformity of uplift charges [37]. ships are registered on the market database. However, in order
In another practical approach, as followed by the PJM, to meet revenue adequacy criteria, the original FTR is not al-
CAISO, and MISO [37], FTR payments are derated when lowed to be broken into a collection of derived FTRs that loads
revenue shortfall occurs. In the PJM [38], the positive FTR some simultaneous constraints more than does the original. Fol-
payments are reduced (but never made negative) in proportion lowing are some simple rules followed in the PJM [17] for the
to the respective target payments when revenue deficit occurs. secondary trading of FTRs.
FTRs with negative targets are given full credits. The excess 1) Rule 1: Option and obligation FTRs must be traded as op-
congestion collection that gets accumulated over a month tions and obligations, respectively.
is transferred (if nonnegative) into a balancing fund. This 2) Rule 2: Each of the derived FTRs must be defined on the
balancing account also accumulates the excess FTR auction same path as that of the original FTR.
revenue from this month. After the balancing account is up- 3) Rule 3: The validity periods of two derived FTRs must not
dated, the ISO first uses this fund to compensate partially partially overlap.
(on a pro-rata basis) or fully the unpaid FTR credits of the 4) Rule 4: The sum of the MW amounts of all the derived
particular month. The remaining amount in this fund is used to FTRs with the same validity period must be equal to the
compensate (partially or fully) the unpaid FTR credits from all MW amount of the original FTR.

Authorized licensed use limited to: GOVERNMENT COLLEGE OF ENGINEERING. Downloaded on January 15, 2010 at 03:15 from IEEE Xplore. Restrictions apply.
SARKAR AND KHAPARDE: COMPREHENSIVE ASSESSMENT OF THE EVOLUTION OF FTRS 1791

5) Rule 5: The validity period of any derived FTR must not FGR is more tradable than an FTR. The flowgate approach is
exceed the validity period of the original FTR. based upon the following assumptions [41]:
In addition, an incremental limit has to be respected when 1) power transfer distribution factors (PTDFs) are relatively
splitting an FTR. In the PJM, this limit is 0.1 MW, i.e., the MW stable;
amount of each derived FTR transferred to a new owner must 2) the number of commercially significant flowgates (CSFs)
be an integer multiple of 0.1. is small and predictable.
However, due to the point-to-point nature of FTRs, the above Commercially significant flowgates are those flowgates
set of rules does not provide sufficient scope for the secondary which are likely to be congested very often. FGRs are to be
trading of these instruments. The extent of secondary trading issued only on CSFs. The higher tradability of an individual
can be enlarged by means of the exchange mechanism described FGR combined with a small number of CSFs can without doubt
in [39]. A simple interpretation (with a small modification) of enhance the overall tradability of transmission rights.
this exchange mechanism is that a market player can exchange The applicability of the FGR mechanism to a system relies on
an existing FTR with the ISO for a new set of FTRs at no addi- the structure of this particular system. This methodology is by
tional cost, where far compatible with zonal pricing with radial interconnections
1) the validity period of each new FTR must be less than or among the individual zones. However, as discussed in [42] and
equal to that of the original FTR; [43], FGRs may not be suitable for a meshed system owing to
2) the collective loading effect (may it be negative) of the new the following reasons:
set on any simultaneous feasibility constraint must not be 1) varying values of PTDFs;
higher than that of the original FTR for any hour within the 2) presence of a large number of contingent flowgates.
validity period of the original FTR. The PTDF between a link and the path of a transaction may
In a sense, this exchange mechanism complements the above vary depending upon the system loading condition. Also, other
secondary trading rules by providing market players with an controls, such as tap changing transformers’ tap positions, af-
additional provision to reconfigure their current FTRs. fect the PTDF values. Now, the matching portfolio of FGRs for
a certain transaction has a direct functional relationship with the
actual PTDF values. Therefore, the uncertainty in PTDFs is fi-
VII. FINANCIAL TRANSMISSION RIGHT
nally translated into the form of uncertainty that a market player
VERSUS FLOWGATE RIGHT
faces about the risk hedging capability of his FGR portfolio.
Flowgate right (FGR) mechanism is the alternative to the FTR However, a combined study of [44] and [45] indicates that the
mechanism in LMP markets. This mechanism was in practice in DC PTDFs with current nominal network parameters may be
the formerly ERCOT [19] zonal market. Unlike an FTR, which good references for defining the risk hedging ability of an FGR
is point-to-point (PtP), an FGR is defined on a transmission link portfolio over a long period of time.
(or flowgate) in a certain direction. By definition, each FGR is A very serious problem arises, however, owing to the contin-
an option. The product of its MW amount and the shadow price gency consideration in the power dispatch problem. The energy
of the corresponding link gives the hourly value of an FGR in market is generally cleared in such a way that the system can
the case that the link gets congested in the same direction. The sustain “ ” contingencies. Now, the PTDF values are dif-
shadow price of a link in the energy market is defined as the rate ferent for different topologies of the network. As a result, each
of increase of optimal social welfare with respect to the same physical line corresponds to multiple links or flowgates—one
capacity increase in both directions of this link. However, if the for each topological condition of the network (i.e., each flow-
relevant link remains uncongested or congestion occurs in the gate is defined by a physical line and network topology pair).
opposite direction, the value of the FGR becomes zero. This, in turn, may lead to a multitude of CSFs. For example, let
In order to preserve revenue adequacy, the total FGR amount the number of potentially congested lines in a power network
in any direction of a link is not permitted to be higher than be only 10. However, apart from the base network topology, 20
the capacity of the link in the particular direction. However, different contingent topologies are also considered in the power
no overall network-based SFT is required when issuing an dispatch model for the sake of system security. Therefore, the
FGR. Initially, FGRs are issued through the central auction or total number of CSFs can be as large as 200 (i.e., 20 10).
allocation process. In an auction, the purchaser of each FGR has Such myriad CSFs clearly invalidate Assumption-2 and indi-
to pay the shadow price of the capacity constraint considered cate the impracticality of the FGR approach for this system.
in the auction. Once issued through central auction or alloca- Moreover, an additional problem arises in case the base network
tion, FGRs can be freely traded in the secondary market. The topology gets changed because of some accidental line outages.
secondary trading rules for FGRs are similar to the secondary As a flowgate is defined by a certain line-topology combina-
trading rules for FTRs. A point-to-point transaction can be tion, most of the previous flowgates become undefined in this
fully hedged by a certain portfolio of flowgate rights. The MW new system. This, in turn, creates an extra task of redefining the
amount and direction of the required FGR on a flowgate are the existing FGRs with reference to the new system configuration.
same as those of the physical flow caused by the transaction on In the case of the FTR mechanism, the field of influence of the
the particular flowgate. above factors is the revenue adequacy issue. However, in most
The motivation behind the development of this link-based of the markets, “ ” contingencies are also considered in the
concept was to enhance the decentralized trading of transmis- SFT model. Although line outages and distribution factor varia-
sion rights [40]. Owing to its link-based nature, an individual tions can create a revenue shortfall problem, its severity may be

Authorized licensed use limited to: GOVERNMENT COLLEGE OF ENGINEERING. Downloaded on January 15, 2010 at 03:15 from IEEE Xplore. Restrictions apply.
1792 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS, VOL. 23, NO. 4, NOVEMBER 2008

reasonably minor [43]. The main reason for this is that simul- may fall below even the corresponding day-ahead prices. This,
taneous feasibility is sufficient but not necessary to make con- in turn, causes a load movement from day-ahead to real-time. If
gestion collection revenue adequate. Moreover, the set of FTRs the load movement is large, the day-ahead prices again fall. As a
issued may still be simultaneously feasible. In addition, any rev- result, the loads now become attracted to the day-ahead market,
enue shortfall can be compensated in future with excess conges- which again increases the day-ahead prices. When the transient
tion collections. As a result, most of the LMP-based power mar- subsides (or becomes sufficiently attenuated), the constrained
kets running successfully have found FTRs rather than FGRs in LMPs in the day-ahead market may be higher than those that
to be more suitable for their systems. Even in a radial system, would have been present if the FTR owners had not behaved
FTRs can be made equally tradable to FGRs through the im- strategically. However, it is debatable whether the strategy can
plementation of the FTR exchange policy, which is discussed in be continuously employed by an FTR owner.
Section VI.
IX. FTRS AND MERCHANT TRANSMISSION INVESTMENT
VIII. FTRS AND MARKET POWER The transmission system has a key role to play to make
With regard to the interaction between FTRs and genera- competition successfully materializes in the power sector. New
tors’ market power, there is consensus among some studies in investments are required in transmission system in order to get
previous literature on the point that FTRs increase the market increased power supplies from cheaper generators. Apart from
power of the generators at the importing nodes [46]–[48]. On the regulated investments, private (or merchant) investments can
other hand, an analysis based upon the prisoners’ dilemma and also be considered to reinforce the existing network. Unlike reg-
Cournot competition was presented in [49] with the inference ulated investments, a private investment is not passed through
that FTRs are able to curb market power. However, the anal- any central planning process, neither is there any regulated
ysis presented in [49] is basically concerned with the long-run tariff-based return on any private investment. However, efficient
profits of strategic generators rather than the long-run effect of transmission investments should be sufficiently incentivized. A
their strategies on market prices [50]. But, in the end, the rela- transmission investment is efficient if it increases social welfare.
tion of the term “market power” is with market prices, not with It may be that there will be investments that are beneficial to
the profits of generators. Therefore, [49] cannot properly justify the investor but harmful to the society. Disincentives should be
its proposition. provided to prevent such inefficient or detrimental investments.
The market power, induced by FTRs themselves, counter- The work of Bushnell and Stoft [53] suggested that incre-
acts to the competitive benefit that can be obtained by hedging mental FTRs (IFTRs) may provide correct investment incen-
the LMP risk of the forward contracts. In order to suppress tives to private investors. Under this paradigm, the additional
the growth of such market power, FTRs should be prevented FTRs, made possible by an investment, are issued to the in-
from falling into the hands of strategic generators. In [51], it vestor. Bushnell et al. proved that if the risk-hedging FTRs
was proposed that any FTR should be issued either from or to match the power dispatch schedules in aggregate before the ex-
a common point, determined by a certain measure called rel- pansion, the net value of the incremental FTRs will be no greater
ative cross-price sensitivity. However, this approach seems to than the increase of social welfare owing to this expansion. An
interfere with the risk-hedging objective of the FTR mechanism interesting two-bus example illustrating the incremental FTR
since a market player may not be able to collect the same quan- concept can be found in [54]. Incremental FTRs are currently of-
tity for both the load end and generator end FTRs to hedge his fered in CAISO, MISO and NYISO, whereas PJM and ISO-NE
transaction. As a result, it may not be accepted for practical im- offer incremental ARRs (IARRs) [33]. However, there are many
plementation. FTR-induced market power should be mitigated, obstacles to this particular market approach of transmission in-
but not at the cost of the risk-hedging benefit obtainable from vestment. The first problem is regarding the long-term issuance
FTRs. of IFTRs. Before issuing an IFTR, a base case must be prepared
Unlike firm PTRs, FTRs cannot be used to withhold trans- as to how many risk-hedging FTRs can be issued on the existing
mission capacity. This is because FTRs are purely financial in- network. An accurate modeling of such a base case is a diffi-
struments. However, by submitting a false schedule, an FTR cult task as risk-hedging FTRs are issued periodically (yearly
owner, having no physical transaction to hedge, may artificially and/or monthly). In [55] and [56], a proxy-award mechanism
increase the congestion level on the transmission system for was proposed to solve this problem, but the basis on which the
earning a higher profit. The situation is nicely exemplified in algorithm for determining proxy awards is built is not clear. An-
[52]. The player, then, has to withdraw this false schedule in other problem is that it may not be possible to restore simulta-
the real-time market. As the direction of congestion usually re- neous feasibility by issuing IFTRs according to the investor’s
mains the same in both the day-ahead and real-time markets, preference. In this context, a combined flowgate right and ad-
the real-time LMPs do not offset the day-ahead profit of the mittance right approach was proposed in [57] as an alternative
strategic market player. Although this kind of strategic activity to the IFTR approach. However, the suggested approach seems
does not indicate market power abuse, it causes a price rise at the not to be able to differentiate new investments from existing re-
constrained in (i.e., importing power) nodes in the day-ahead sources. Rather, this problem can be solved by issuing IFTRs in
market. At the same time, as the unsold cheaper generations in the reverse directions of some of the investor’s preferred paths.
the day-ahead market now appear in the real-time market, and as Other critical problems regarding merchant transmission invest-
the previously blocked transmission capacity is also released in ments are the possibility of the destruction of LMP differences
the same market, the real-time prices at the constrained in nodes owing to a transmission investment, lack of coalition between

Authorized licensed use limited to: GOVERNMENT COLLEGE OF ENGINEERING. Downloaded on January 15, 2010 at 03:15 from IEEE Xplore. Restrictions apply.
SARKAR AND KHAPARDE: COMPREHENSIVE ASSESSMENT OF THE EVOLUTION OF FTRS 1793

the investor and the market players that benefit (i.e., free rider LFTR is given by the product of its MW amount and the LMP
problem), and the need for some regulatory oversight to prevent (or the congestion component, or the congestion component
potentially harmful investments [58]–[61]. There is also a threat plus the energy component of the LMP) of the corresponding
of a reduction in the value of an IFTR owing to the future invest- location. If the LFTR is of the injection type, the negation of
ments. the above product gives its hourly value. The bid price associ-
ated with an injection type LFTR request is usually nonpositive,
X. OTHER FTR INSTRUMENTS whereas it is usually nonnegative for a withdrawal type LFTR
request. Thus, an LFTR allows an individual load or generator
A. Long-Term Financial Transmission Right to freeze its buy or sale price, respectively, in advance (when
the auction is conducted) for a certain MW quantity. In other
A long-term (LT) FTR is an FTR (or ARR) with a term longer
words, an LFTR is similar to a forward contract between the
than one year. LT FTRs can secure infrastructure financing and
ISO and a generator or load. Therefore, LFTRs may increase
can provide more price certainty to the transmission customers
the traded volume of power in the forward market, leading to the
serving long-term power contracts [33]. The interest in LT FTRs
enhancement of market competitiveness. An LFTR must be an
has started growing among various market participants in the
obligation. Apart from satisfying network capacity constraints,
U.S. markets since 2005. In July 2006, the Federal Energy Reg-
the physical equivalents of the LFTRs must be in balance (i.e.,
ulatory Commission (FERC) of the U.S. issued its final guide-
power balance) to ensure revenue adequacy.
lines [62] for the implementation of LT FTRs in organized [63]
electricity markets. These are summarized below.
1) An LT FTR must be a PtP transmission right.
2) LT FTRs must be fully funded unless the situation is ex- XI. CONCLUSION
traordinary or voluntary agreements have been signed be-
tween LT FTR owners and the ISO. This paper provides a comprehensive insight into the FTR
3) LT IFTRs must be made available upon request to any party mechanism employed in centralized power markets to provide
that pays for transmission upgrades or expansions. price guards to the forward contracts. An obligation FTR alone
4) The term lengths of LT FTRs must be sufficient to fulfill can hedge a fixed transaction only, whereas a band of trans-
the needs of LSEs to hedge their long-term power supply actions can be fully hedged by an obligation-option portfolio.
obligations. Simultaneous feasibility is an important consideration in the
5) LSEs must have priority over non-LSEs in the allocation issuance of FTRs. Auction and allocation are two alternative
of long-term risk-hedging FTRs. mechanisms for issuing FTRs. Market players can participate
6) LT FTRs must follow the movement of retail customers. in an auction in a number of ways. In order to have revenue ad-
7) The initial allocation of LT FTRs should be independent of equacy at any hour within the time horizon of the auction, it
FTR auction. must be ensured that each possible active-inactive combination
8) Allocation of LT FTRs should balance any adverse eco- of the FTRs be simultaneously feasible. All the FTRs issued in
nomic impact between participants receiving and not re- an auction are marginally priced. Time-differentiated FTR prod-
ceiving the right. ucts and multi-round auctions enhance the flexibility of market
players. The allocation of FTRs can be carried out directly or
B. Contingent Transmission Right through ARRs. Any centrally allocated or auctioned FTR can
be freely traded later in a secondary market. By means of an
Contingent transmission right (CTR) [64] is basically a exchange mechanism, it is also possible to reconfigure an FTR
group-FTR concept. A CTR allows its owner to hold FTR on without entering into any auction. Accidental line outages, line
a number of alternative paths. This added flexibility provides capacity degradations, and imprecisions in the SFT model em-
market players with an additional (and cheaper) support to ployed may sometimes cause revenue shortfall. Imposition of
overcome the congestion price risk originating from the uncer- uplift charges on transmission owners and temporary reduction
tainty in their transaction paths. of FTR values are two major approaches to compensate revenue
Structurally, a CTR is defined by a MW amount and a set shortfall. Strategic generators may acquire additional market
of paths. The owner of the CTR can choose any path (but only power through FTRs. This implies a need for some well-defined
one at a time) from the given path set to convert his CTR into an and feasible rules for appropriately restricting the ownership of
FTR. A CTR can be an obligation or an option. If it is an obliga- these transmission rights. The alternative to the FTR mechanism
tion, any FTR that it generates would be considered as an obliga- is the FGR mechanism. However, FGRs may not be suitable for
tion FTR. Similarly, if it is an option, any FTR that it generates a highly meshed network. Apart from risk hedging, FTRs can
would be considered as an option FTR. The generalized form of also be used to incentivize merchant transmission investments.
the contingent transmission right is the multidimensional finan- LT FTRs can provide more price certainty to long-term power
cial transmission right which is discussed in detail in [65]. contracts. The future CTR will provide market players with an
additional support to get relief from the congestion price risk
C. Locational or Unbalanced Financial Transmission Right
originating from the uncertainty in their transaction paths. Fi-
Unlike a PtP FTR, a locational FTR (LFTR) [13] is defined nally, by means of LFTRs, individual generators and loads can
only for a point of injection (injection type) or a point of with- develop the flexibility to lock their sale and buy prices, respec-
drawal (withdrawal type). The hourly value of a withdrawal type tively, in advance.

Authorized licensed use limited to: GOVERNMENT COLLEGE OF ENGINEERING. Downloaded on January 15, 2010 at 03:15 from IEEE Xplore. Restrictions apply.
1794 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS, VOL. 23, NO. 4, NOVEMBER 2008

REFERENCES [28] B. C. Lesieutre and I. A. Hiskens, “Convexity of the set of feasible


injections and revenue adequacy in FTR markets,” IEEE Trans. Power
[1] W. W. Hogan, “Contract networks for electric power transmission,” J. Syst., vol. 20, no. 4, pp. 1790–1798, Nov. 2005.
Reg. Econ., vol. 4, pp. 211–242, 1992. [29] O. Alsaç, J. M. Bright, S. Brignone, M. Prais, C. Silva, B. Stott, and
[2] E. Litvinov, T. Zheng, G. Rosenwald, and P. Shamsollahi, “Marginal N. Vempati, “The rights to fight price volatility,” IEEE Power Energy
loss modeling in LMP calculation,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 19, Mag., vol. 2, no. 4, pp. 47–57, Jul.–Aug. 2004.
pt. 2, pp. 880–888, May 2004. [30] M. I. Alomoush and S. M. Shahidehpour, “Generalized model for fixed
[3] X. Cheng and T. J. Overbye, “An energy reference bus independent transmission rights auction,” Elect. Power Syst. Res., vol. 54, no. 3, pp.
LMP decomposition algorithm,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 21, no. 207–220, Jun. 2000.
3, pp. 1041–1049, Aug. 2006. [31] R. P. O’Neill, U. Helman, B. F. Hobbs, W. R. Stewart, Jr, and M. H.
[4] A. J. Conejo, E. Castillo, R. Minguez, and F. Milano, “Locational mar- Rothkopf, “A joint energy and transmission rights auction: proposal
ginal price sensitivities,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 20, no. 4, pp. and properties,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 17, no. 4, pp. 1058–1067,
2026–2033, Nov. 2005. Nov. 2002.
[5] T. Wu, Z. Alaywan, and A. D. Papalexopoulos, “Locational marginal [32] V. Sarkar and S. A. Khaparde, “A robust mathematical framework for
price calculations using the distributed-slack power-flow formulation,” managing simultaneous feasibility condition in financial transmission
IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 20, no. 2, pp. 1188–1190, May 2005. rights auction,” in Proc. IEEE/Power Eng. Soc. General Meeting, Jun.
[6] L. Chen, H. Suzuki, T. Wachi, and Y. Shimura, “Components of nodal 18–22, 2006.
prices for electric power systems,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 17, [33] [Online]. Available: https://www.ferc.gov/industries/electric/
no. 1, pp. 41–49, Feb. 2002. indus-act /rto/notice/05–11-05.pdf.
[7] J. D. Finney, H. A. Othman, and W. L. Rutz, “Evaluating transmission [34] [Online]. Available: http://www.caiso.com/1b6a/1b6aa19966b10.doc.
congestion constraints in system planning,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., [35] [Online]. Available: http://www.caiso.com/1bfd/1bfd7c8244250.pdf.
vol. 12, no. 3, pp. 1143–1150, Aug. 1997. [36] A. R. Desell and G. R. Williams, “Some NYISO perspectives,” IEEE
[8] F. C. Scheweppe, M. C. Caramanis, R. D. Tabors, and R. E. Bohn, Spot Power Energy Mag., vol. 2, no. 4, pp. 52–53, Jul.–Aug. 2004.
Pricing of Electricity. Norwell, MA: Kluwer, 1988. [37] S. Oren, Derating CRRs. [Online]. Available: http://www.puc.
[9] R. Baldick, Shift Factors in ERCOT Congestion Pricing. [On- state.tx.us/rules/rulemake/27678/27678crr.pdf.
line]. Available: http://www.puc.state.tx.us/rules/rulemake/26376/ [38] PJM Manual on Operating Agreement Accounting, PJM Market. [On-
0114wks/ercot%5Fross.ppt. line]. Available: http://www.pjm.com.
[10] S. Stoft, Power System Economics. New York: Wiley, 2002. [39] M. Liu and G. Gross, “Framework for the design and analysis of con-
[11] A. K. David and F. Wen, “Market power in electricity supply,” IEEE gestion revenue rights,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 19, no. 1, pp.
Trans. Energy Convers., vol. 16, no. 4, pp. 352–360, Dec. 2001. 243–251, Feb. 2004.
[12] L. Qi and W. Huang, “The impact of contract for difference on the [40] H. Chao, S. Peck, S. Oren, and R. Wilson, “Flow-based transmission
market power in the restructured Zhejiang electricity market,” in Proc. rights and congestion management,” Elect. J., vol. 13, no. 8, pp. 38–58,
2004 IEEE/Power Eng. Soc. Power Systems Conf. Expo., Oct. 2004, Oct. 2000.
vol. 2, pp. 874–880. [41] F. L. Alvarado and S. S. Oren, “A tutorial on the flowgates versus nodal
[13] W. W. Hogan, Financial Transmission Right Formulations. [Online]. pricing debate,” in PSERC IAB Meeting Tutorial, Nov. 30, 2000.
Available: http://whogan.com. [42] W. W. Hogan, Flowgate Rights and Wrongs. [Online]. Available:
[14] S. M. Harvey, W. W. Hogan, and S. L. Pope, “Transmission capacity http://whogan.com.
reservations implemented through a spot market with transmission con- [43] L. E. Ruff, “Flowgates, contingency-constrained dispatch, and trans-
gestion contracts,” Elect. J., vol. 9, no. 9, pp. 42–55, Nov. 1996. mission rights,” Elect. J., vol. 14, no. 1, pp. 34–55, Jan.–Feb. 2001.
[15] X. Ma, D. I. Sun, G. W. Rosenwald, and A. L. Ott, “Advanced financial [44] R. Baldick, “Variation of distribution factors with loading,” IEEE
transmission rights in the PJM market,” in Proc. IEEE/Power Eng. Soc. Trans. Power Syst., vol. 18, no. 4, pp. 1316–1323, Nov. 2003.
General Meeting, Jul. 13–17, 2003, vol. 2, pp. 1031–1038. [45] M. Liu and G. Gross, “Role of distribution factors in congestion rev-
[16] X. Ma, D. I. Sun, and A. Ott, “Implementation of the PJM financial enue rights applications,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 19, no. 2, pp.
transmission rights auction market system,” in Proc. IEEE/Power Eng. 802–810, May 2004.
Soc. Summer Meeting, Jul. 25, 2002, vol. 3, pp. 1360–1365. [46] P. Joskow and J. Tirole, “Transmission rights and market power on
[17] PJM Manual on Financial Transmission Rights, PJM Market. [Online]. electric power networks,” RAND J. Econ., vol. 31, no. 3, pp. 450–487,
Available: http://www.pjm.com. 2000.
[18] A. Bykhovsky, D. A. James, and C. A. Hanson, “The introduction of [47] G. Bautista, V. H. Quintana, and J. A. Aguado, “Interaction of market
option financial transmission rights into the New England market,” in power and financial transmission rights in power networks,” in Proc.
Proc. IEEE/Power Eng. Soc. General Meeting, Jun. 12–16, 2005, pp. Can. Conf. Electrical and Computer Engineering, 2004, May 2–5,
284–289. 2004, vol. 2, pp. 1067–1072.
[19] T. Kristiansen, Markets for Financial Transmission Rights. [Online]. [48] P. B. Eriksen, F. Verrier, and P. Tsamasfyrou, “Assessing the impact of
Available: http://www.ksg.harvard.edu/hepg/Papers/Kristiansen.mkts. transmission rights on market power using the simulation model ares,”
for.ftrs.Oct.03.updated.May.04.pdf. in Proc. CIGRE/IEEE Power Eng. Soc., 2005. Int. Symp., Oct. 5–7,
[20] X. Ma, D. I. Sun, and K. W. Cheung, “Evolution toward standardized 2005, pp. 386–393.
market design,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 18, no. 2, pp. 460–469, [49] S. Stoft, “Financial transmission rights meet Cournot: How TCCs curb
May 2003. market power,” Energy J., vol. 20, no. 1, pp. 1–23, Jan. 1999.
[21] K. W. Cheung, “Standard market design for ISO New England whole- [50] T. O. Nasser, “Transmission congestion contracts and strategic be-
sale electricity market: An overview,” in 2004 Proc. IEEE Int. Conf. havior in generation,” Elect. J., vol. 11, no. 4, pp. 32–39, May 1998.
Electric Utility Deregulation, Restructuring and Power Technologies [51] L. Olmos and K. Neuhoff, “Identifying a balancing point for electricity
(DRPT 2004), Apr. 2004, vol. 1, pp. 38–43. transmission contracts,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 21, no. 1, pp.
[22] Midwest ISO Market Concept Study Guide. [Online]. Available: 91–98, Feb. 2006.
http://www.midwestmarket.org/Documents/EducationsMaterial/Gen- [52] J. Bushnell, “Transmission rights and market power,” Elect. J., vol. 12,
eral Guides. no. 8, pp. 77–85, Oct. 1999.
[23] PJM Manual on Transmission Service Request, PJM Market. [Online]. [53] J. B. Bushnell and S. E. Stoft, “Improving private incentives for electric
Available: http://www.pjm.com. grid investment,” Res. Energy Econ., vol. 19, no. 1-2, pp. 85–108, Mar.
[24] M. I. Alomoush and S. M. Sahidehpour, “Fixed transmission rights for 1997.
zonal congestion management,” Proc. Inst. Elect. Eng., Gen., Transm., [54] K. Lyons, H. Fraser, and H. Parmesano, “An introduction to financial
Distrib., vol. 146, no. 5, pp. 471–476, Sep. 1999. transmission rights,” Elect. J., vol. 13, no. 10, pp. 31–37, Dec. 2000.
[25] F. Wu, P. Varaiya, P. Spiller, and S. Oren, “Folk theorems on transmis- [55] W. W. Hogan, Financial Transmission Right Incentives: Applications
sion access: Proofs and counterexamples,” J. Reg. Econ., vol. 10, no. Beyond Hedging. [Online]. Available: http://whogan.com.
1, pp. 5–23, Jul. 1996. [56] T. Kristiansen, “Merchant transmission expansion based on financial
[26] V. Sarkar and S. A. Khaparde, “Implementation of LMP-FTR mecha- transmission rights,” in Proc. 38th Hawaii Int. Conf. System Sciences,
nism in an ac-dc system,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 23, no. 2, pp. Jan. 2005.
737–746, May 2008. [57] P. R. Gribik, D. Shirmohammadi, J. S. Graves, and J. G. Kritikson,
[27] S. Boyd and L. Vandenberghe, Convex Optimization. Cambridge, “Transmission rights and transmission expansions,” IEEE Trans.
U.K.: Cambridge Univ. Press, 2006. Power Syst., vol. 20, no. 4, pp. 1728–1737, Nov. 2005.

Authorized licensed use limited to: GOVERNMENT COLLEGE OF ENGINEERING. Downloaded on January 15, 2010 at 03:15 from IEEE Xplore. Restrictions apply.
SARKAR AND KHAPARDE: COMPREHENSIVE ASSESSMENT OF THE EVOLUTION OF FTRS 1795

[58] P. Joskow and J. Tirole, Merchant Transmission Investment. [Online]. .V. Sarkar (S’07) received the B.E. degree in electrical engineering from Bur-
Available: http://econ-www.mit.edu/files/1159. dwan University, Bardhaman, India, in 2002 and the M.E. degree in electrical
[59] L. Cameron, “Transmission investment: Obstacles to a market ap- engineering from the former Bengal Engineering College (currently Bengal En-
proach,” Elect. J., vol. 14, no. 2, pp. 25–38, Mar. 2001. gineering and Science University), Kolkata, India, in 2004. He is currently pur-
[60] W. W. Hogan, Transmission Market Design. [Online]. Available: suing the Ph.D. degree in the Department of Electrical Engineering at the Indian
http://whogan.com. Institute of Technology, Bombay, India.
[61] W. W. Hogan, Market-Based Transmission Investments and Competi- His current research involves power system restructuring issues.
tive Electricity Markets. [Online]. Available: http://whogan.com.
[62] [Online]. Available: http://ferc.gov/whats-new/comm-meet/
020206/E-3.pdf.
[63] [Online]. Available: http://www.ferc.gov/whats-new/comm-meet/ S. A. Khaparde (M’87, SM’91) received the Ph.D. degree in 1981 from the
2007/ 062107/E-3.pdf. Indian Institute of Technology, Kharagpur, India.
[64] R. P. O’Neil, U. Helman, R. Baldick, W. R. Stewart, Jr, and M. H. He is a Professor of electrical engineering at the Indian Institute of Tech-
Rothkopf, “Contingent transmission rights in the standard market de- nology, Bombay, India. He has authored several research papers and has coau-
sign,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 18, no. 4, pp. 1331–1337, Nov. thored two books. He is a member of the advisory committee of Maharastra
2003. Electricity Regulatory Commission, India. His current research activities are in
[65] V. Sarkar and S. A. Khaparde, “Introduction to multidimensional fi- the areas of power system restructuring.
nancial transmission rights,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 23, no. 1, Dr. Khaparde is on the editorial board of the International Journal of
pp. 47–57, Feb. 2008 Emerging Electric Power Systems.

Authorized licensed use limited to: GOVERNMENT COLLEGE OF ENGINEERING. Downloaded on January 15, 2010 at 03:15 from IEEE Xplore. Restrictions apply.

Você também pode gostar