Você está na página 1de 3

The Brenner debate: Agrarian

Class Structure and Economic


Development in Pre-Industrial
Europe
One of the defining controversies in the field of economic history in the past 35 years is the
Brenner debate. Robert Brenner published "Agrarian Class Structure and Economic Development
in Pre-Industrial Europe" in Past and Present in 1976 (link) and "The Agrarian Roots of European
Capitalism" in 1982. In between these publications (and following) there was a rush of substantive
responses from leading economic historians, including M. M. Postan and Emmanuel Le Roy
Ladurie. (Many of the most significant articles are collected in Aston and Philpin's The Brenner
Debate: Agrarian Class Structure and Economic Development in Pre-industrial Europe.) Brenner's
theories injected important new impetus into the old question: what led to the advent of capitalism?
(Maurice Dobb had stimulated a similar burst of scholarship on this topic with his 1963 Studies In
The Development Of Capitalism (link). Brenner's discussion of the Dobb debate can be found in
his essay, "Dobb on the transition from feudalism to capitalism" here.)
The core issue of the debate is large and important: what were the social factors that brought
about the major economic transformations of the European economy since the decline of
feudalism? Feudalism was taken to be a stagnant economic system; but in the sixteenth century
things began to change. There was something of an agricultural revolution in England, with
technological innovation, changes of cropping systems, and significant increase in land
productivity. There were the beginnings of manufacture, leading eventually to water- and steampowered machines. There was a population shift from the countryside to towns and cities. There
was industrial revolution. (Marx describes much of this process in Capital; here's an earlier post of
his concept of "primitive accumulation.") So what were the large social factors that caused this
widespread process of social and economic change? What propelled these dramatic changes of
economic structure?
The great economic historian M. M. Postan offered a simple theory: Behind most economic trends
in the middle ages, above all behind the advancing and retreating land settlement, it is possible to
discern the inexorable effects of rising and declining population (Medieval Economy and Society:
An Economic History of Britain in the Middle Ages, p. 72). Against this view, Brenner writes:
"Under different property structures and different balances of power, similar demographic or
commercial trends, with their associated patterns of factor prices, presented very different
opportunities and dangers and thus evoked disparate responses, with diverse consequences for
the economy as a whole. Indeed, . . . under different property structures and balances of class
forces . . . precisely the same demographic and commercial trends yielded widely divergent
results" (Brenner 1982:16-17). Key to Brenner's argument is the fact that agricultural change was
substantially different in England and France; so he insists that an adequate causal explanation
must identify a factor that varies similarly.
From the distance of several decades, the dividing lines of the Brenner debate are pretty clear.
One school of thought (Postan, Ladurie) attempts to explain the economic transformations
described here in terms of facts about population, while the other (Brenner's) argues that the
central causal factors have to do with social institutions (social-property relations and institutions of
political power). The demographic theory focuses its attention on the factors that influenced
population growth, including disease; the social institutions theory focuses attention on the

institutional framework within which economic actors (lords, peasants, capitalist farmers) pursue
their goals. The one is akin to a biological or ecological theory, emphasizing common and
universal demographic forces; the other is a social theory, emphasizing contingency and variation
across social space.
A voice that doesn't come into the debate directly but that is highly relevant is that of Douglass
North. His book (with Robert Paul Thomas), The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic
History, offers a theory of modern economic development that falls within the category of "social
institutional theory" rather than demographic theory. But whereas Brenner finds primary causal
importance in the institutions that define local class relations (a Marxian idea), North argues that
property relations that create the right kinds of incentives will stimulate rapid economic growth (a
Smithian idea). And North finds that this is the innovation that took place in England in the early
modern period. It was the creation of capitalist property relations that stimulated economic growth.
This schematic representation of the strands of argument in the Brenner debate suggests
competing causal diagrams:
population growth => economic activity => sustained economic growth (Postan)
weak peasant farmers, strong capitalist farmers => enclosure and farming innovations => rapid
agricultural growth (Brenner)
enhanced protections of property rights => incentive for profitable activity => sustained economic
growth (North)
But it seems clear in hindsight that these are false dichotomies. We aren't forced to choose:
Malthus, Marx, or Smith. Economic development is not caused by a single dominant factor -- a
point that Guy Bois embraces in his essay (Aston and Philpin, 117). Rather, all these factors were
in play in European economic development -- and several others as well. (For example, Ken
Pomeranz introduces the exploitation of the natural resources, energy sources, and forced labor of
the Americas in his account of the economic growth of Western Europe (The Great Divergence:
China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy). And I suppose that it would be
possible to make a climate-change argument for this period of change as well.) Moreover, each
large factor (population, prices, property relations) itself is the complex result of a number of great
factors -- including the others on the list. So we shouldn't expect simple causal diagrams of large
outcomes like sustained economic growth.
Not all the heat of this debate derives from a polemic between a neo-Marxist theorist and the
Malthusians; there is also a significant disagreement between Brenner and another important
Marxist economic historian, Guy Bois. Bois' Crisis of Feudalism appeared in 1976 -- the same
year as Brenner's first paper in the debate. The crisis to which Bois refers is an analogy with a
classic Marxist claim about capitalism: where Marx discerned a crisis in capitalism deriving from
the falling rate of profit, Bois found a crisis in feudalism deriving from a falling rate of feudal levy.
(Here is an interesting review by Chris Harman of another of Bois' books, The Transformation of
the Year One Thousand: The Village of Lournard from Antiquity to Feudalism.) Bois criticizes
Brenner's account for being excessively theory-driven. He argues that Brenner begins with a
commitment to class struggle as a fundamental explanation, and then forces the facts of French
and English rural life into this framework. Better, he argues, to let the complexity of the historical
situations emerge through careful evaluation of the evidence. "Brenner's thought is, in fact,
arranged around a single principle: theoretical generalization always precedes direct examination
of historical source material" (Aston and Philpin, 110). And Bois argues that the evidence will
suggest that it is the declining feudal levy rather than the capacity for resistance by French
peasants that best explains the course of events in France.
In short, one important consequence of the Brenner debate was the renewed focus it placed on the
question of social causation. Brenner and the other participants expended a great deal of effort in
developing theories of the causal mechanisms that led to economic change in this period. And in
hindsight, it appears that a lot of the energy in the debates stemmed from the false presupposition
that it should be possible to identify a single master factor that explained these large changes in
economic development. But this no longer seems supportable. Rather, historians are now much

more willing to recognize the plurality of causes at work and the geographical differentiation that is
inherent in almost every large historical process. So the advice that Bois extends -- don't let your
large theory get in the way of detailed historical research -- appears to be good counsel.

Você também pode gostar