Você está na página 1de 28

John Papaspanos

Seton Hall University Honors Department

Honors Thesis

Dr. Peter Ahr

21 December 2009

Renewable Energy Deployment:


The Role of Government in Driving Technological Innovation

“Substantive, mass promotion of renewable energy sources, combined with

energy savings, is the only realistic, effective and viable solution for dealing with climate

change and ensuring adequate energy supplies.”

European Environment Commissioner Stavros Dimas

1.1 Introduction

In recent years, the upward trend of fossil fuel prices and mounting evidence of

anthropogenic global warming have compelled policymakers in the European Union

(E.U.) to confront a burgeoning global crisis at the intersection of energy security and

climate change. With the adoption of Directive 2001/77/EC in 2001, the European

Commission has acknowledged the centrality of renewable energy sources (RES) to

meeting its long term energy objectives and fulfilling its Kyoto obligations. In 2008, the

E.U. Parliament adopted a climate package which included a RES directive with the

political aim of generating 20% of the E.U.’s total electricity generation from RES by

setting specific RES targets for each member state (MS).1 Due to the presence of several

market and institutional obstacles, such an ambitious objective can be fulfilled only with

the enactment of national support schemes that can stimulate the nascent RES market. In

the E.U., the two predominant RES support schemes used among MS are the green
certificate system (GCS) and the feed-in tariff (FIT). Even though both support schemes

have demonstrated some degree of success, I will outline the success of Germany’s

Renewable Energy Sources Act (EEG)—which is centered on a well-designed FIT—to

argue that the FIT is a more effective policy instrument in expanding the RES market on

the basis of two overarching criteria: economic effectiveness and ecological efficiency.

In this paper, I have examined the following research objectives: 1) Why is

government intervention necessary for the development and deployment of RES

technologies? What is the most effective national support scheme that can be employed

in the E.U.? What is the central problem concerning the widespread diffusion of green

technologies to the developing world and how can this be resolved?

1.2 The Role of Green Technology in Combating Climate Change

The E.U. cannot pursue a low-carbon, economic growth trajectory without the

development, deployment, and diffusion of RES-based technologies (green technologies)

that enable producers to efficiently harness the power of wind, solar, geothermal, and

other RES for the generation of low-carbon electricity (green electricity). However, such

green technologies cannot be widely adopted in the short term under current market

conditions due to the various obstacles that hinder the long term and complex process of

technological innovation.

1.3 The Technological Innovation Process

Joseph Schumpeter recognized the three distinct stages of the innovation process:

“innovation as the first practical demonstration of an idea; innovation as the first

commercial application and diffusion as the spreading of the technology or process

throughout the market.”4 Nevertheless, this process is not linear but follows an iterative

path that is “linked by learning and feedback that flow both ‘downstream’ from research

to design and develop, and ‘upstream’ from the development process to fundamental
research.”5 This perspective illuminates the learning that takes place by the innovators of

a technology and its end users through periods of trial-and-error.

With this conceptualization of the innovation process, radical scientific or

technological breakthroughs are not as economically significant as the long term series of

incremental improvements that are undertaken to reach a cost-effective product that can

attract consumers and investors.6 Historical examples of this observation are the

transistor and the gas turbine, in which both technologies were developed over the course

of many years—initially with the support of the public sector, and then, further enhanced

by the private sector.

1.4 Four Obstacles to Market Entry

Technological innovation largely occurs within the private sector. Market

participants are responsible for driving the innovation process of conducting research and

development (R&D), applying this knowledge to the development of a commercial

product, and deploying this technology in domestic and international markets.

If there is difficulty in any stage of the innovation process, investors will be very

reluctant in providing the necessary funding for the R&D activities due to the high

associated risk. In the energy sector, market actors encounter several market and

institutional barriers which hinder the acceleration of the innovation process. These

obstacles mainly revolve around the difficulties in penetrating the electricity generation

market: 1) high initial costs, 2) inadequate infrastructure, 3) distorted markets, and 4)

oligopolistic market structure.7

The first obstacle encompasses the inherent difficulties in accelerating the

learning process in production for new entrants in the electricity market. Since electricity

is a homogenous good, potential producers in this industry cannot penetrate through a

niche market and then expand to the broader market of end-users. Therefore, the RES-

harnessing technologies must directly compete against the more cost-competitive and
reliable incumbent technologies. Historical experience has shown that infant RES

technologies cannot compete in such an environment during the initial phase of market

entry and that decades are required before dynamic increasing returns emerge such as

“economies of scale and learning effects, which can lead to costs falling as production

increases.”8

The second obstacle lies with the nature of national electricity grids. Since the

electrical grids of MS are designed for the accommodation of conventional power plants,

investors confront severe difficulties in attracting capital funds for RES electrical

systems. First, if the proposed construction sites of RES electrical systems are located far

away from the electrical grid, then the utilities cannot provide access to RES producers.

In addition, the current electrical grids are usually not equipped to receive electricity from

multiple independent producers. Unless the electrical grids are restructured to absorb

green electricity from RES producers, the current status quo in electric power distribution

cannot be changed.

The third obstacle is centered on the current market distortions due to government

subsidies on existing fossil fuel technologies. The estimated subsidy for fossil fuels is

$150-250 billion per year globally.9 With such considerable support from the

government, utilities hold a competitive advantage in the energy sector and strive to deter

the entry of any potential competition. In the absence of government regulation (e.g. cap

and trade scheme or carbon tax), utilities hold a strong position because they are not

obligated to internalize the environmental externality of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions

into their cost structures. Given the fact that conventional power is more cost-

competitive, RES technologies cannot become a viable option in the short term, and thus,

the incentive to invest in the RES sector is negligible.

The fourth obstacle focuses on the market structure of the energy sector.

Generally, the electricity market is highly regulated and there is a limited number of
competing firms. For example, the French firm Électricité de France is the world’s

largest utility company, the dominant electricity provider of France, and the supplier of

22% of the E.U.’s electricity. The large utilities within this oligarchic structure tend to be

risk averse and predominantly use conventional fuels to generate electricity because

adopting new technologies may prove to be more costly or less reliable. Therefore, the

drive to innovate is negligible and there is a tendency for the status quo to remain.

1.5 Public-Sector R&D Investment

Even though the private sector is the principle agent in technological innovation,

the public sector can play an essential role in driving private spending until a certain

threshold is reached—to the point at which public funding begins to “crowd out” the

entry of private investment. If there are sufficient flows of private capital to the

development of a specific technology, then the government can withdraw its support

because the private sector can further advance the technology to maturity without the use

of public funds.

The role of public-sector R&D is also very important in maintaining the “public

good nature of major scientific advances1”. The government has historically been

successful in spearheading innovative activities that offered unexpected benefits for other

applications. For instance, the diffusion of knowledge from military R&D to civilian

applications occurred in the airframe industry when Boeing exploited knowledge

obtained in constructing World War II bombers and tankers for the U.S. Air Force in its

commercial designs and tooling for the 707.11 Specifically, the energy sector has

benefited from military R&D, the U.S. space program, and other sources of knowledge

such as the development of the gas turbine. Originally designed to propel a military jet

aircraft, the gas turbine is also used to power many electric power plants. These examples

“highlight the spillover effect that occurs between sectors and the need to avoid too

narrow an R&D focus”12


Last, the government is instrumental in the development of human capital, which

is a necessary step towards the aim of building a strong technological research base that

can stimulate the RES market. If the government expects scientific institutions and

laboratories to continue attracting young scientists and engineers, there needs to be an

adequate allocation of public funds for their education and to the R&D firms that employ

them. To this purpose, the government will strongly contribute to the stimulation of the

RES sector by deterring any potential volatility that may discourage private investment.

1.6 The Role of RES Support Schemes

As evidenced above, market actors do not only respond to price signals in the

market in order to maximize profits, but also adjust their market behavior to signals from

the government13. Without the presence of a national support scheme to support the

development and deployment of green technology, the current market dynamic and

regulatory framework does not provide the sufficient economic incentives for market

actors to undertake such innovative activities, especially with the urgency and scale

necessary to meet the E.U.’s indicative targets by the year 2020. The following diagram

demonstrates the role of government intervention in advancing this process by

internalizing the costs of carbon as an environmental externality and providing subsidies

as compensation to offset the cost disadvantages of green technology.

Since the E.U. did not prescribe a specific support scheme to achieve its RES

directive, each MS has selected a national support scheme that can overcome the

aforesaid barriers in order to promote their respective renewable energy sectors.

Presently, two major support schemes have emerged: “the older and more widely used

feed-in tariff (FIT) schemes on the one hand and the newer but increasingly popular

tradable quota models, referred to ‘green certificates’ (GC), on the other hand.”14

Generally, the FIT mechanism involves the obligation of a utility or energy

company to purchase electricity generated by RES producers in its service area at a


politically determined price and guaranteed for an established time horizon.15 The tariff

component of the law refers to the fixed price received by the producer for any kWh of

green electricity. In addition, modern FITs provide technology-specific tariffs

determined by the consideration of several factors such as manufacturing and operating

costs, resource endowments, and industry lobbying. With regard to financing the

legislation, the FIT applies the costs of the tariffs to the end users of the utility

companies.

In contrast, the GC system generally obliges “producers, distributors or

consumers to either produce or buy a certain amount of green electricity (in absolute

values or quota).”16 In its simplest form, the GC system the government imposes the

need to produce a politically determined share of their total electricity generation in a

certain time period (usually 1 year). In addition, the GC systems are usually

accompanied by a trading mechanism in which producers are given an option in fulfilling

their quota obligation: either to produce the green electricity themselves or to purchase

“credits”17 of green electricity generation from other producers.

1.7 Criteria of Effectiveness

The two criteria that will be employed in the comparison analysis between these

two support schemes are economic efficiency and ecological effectiveness. Economic

efficiency will be defined as the relative cost of this policy option as compared to other

support schemes and the absence of government intervention. The greatest level of

economic efficiency will entail the lowest possible cost of the support scheme to the body

politic.

The complimentary criterion is ecological effectiveness, which constitutes the

amount of installed capacity of electricity from green electricity generation. An

examination of Germany’s regulatory framework as a case study will focus on the


strengths and weaknesses of a model FIT and will be followed by a comparison to the

next leading E.U. support scheme—the GC system.

1.8 Case Study: The Support Scheme of Germany (EEG)

Among the industrialized countries, Germany is at the forefront of RES

deployment—ranked first in terms of installed capacity for wind energy and second for

photovoltaics (PV).18 Even though other countries have more favorable resource

endowments such as Italy, Spain, and Greece for solar energy and Scandinavia and the

UK for wind energy, Germany has exceeded the rest of Europe in RES deployment due

to its superior regulatory framework.

Since 1979, in the wake of the first oil crisis in 1974, Germany has been

enhancing its FIT legislation at the behest of the German Bundestag and the German

people at large. Introduced in 1990, the first fully formed modern feed-in law in

Germany was the Stromeinspeisungsgesetz (StrEG), which was designed to assist

electricity producers from small hydropower stations and wind energy installations.

After several modifications, the German government adopted the Erneuerbare Energien-

Gesetz (EEG and also known as the 2000 Renewable Energy Sources Act), which

“represented an update, refinement, and replacement of German renewable energy

policy.”19 The EEG was instrumental in the success of Germany’s FIT mechanism

because, unlike its predecessor, it included “a differentiation in tariff rates—depending

on the renewable energy type, size, and site.”2 Furthermore, the EEG expanded the range

of technologies that were supported by tariffs and the StrEG’s tariff percentage-based

rates were replaced with fixed rates over a set period of twenty years of operation for

each new RES electrical system. In 2004, the EEG was amended and its new provisions

called for the increase of the contribution of green electricity in the total electricity supply

to 12.5% by 2010 and catalyzed a boom in the solar industry by raising its respective
tariff. Last, a new concept of tariff rate digression was introduced for the different RES-

based technologies.

1.9 Practical Solutions in Overcoming the Market Obstacles

The features of the EEG and its attendant amendment have far-reaching

implications in achieving the aim of encouraging the development of a nascent RES

sector by resolving the inherent difficulties represented by the four aforementioned

obstacles.

The problems associated with the learning process are overcome with the

implementation of the EEG because the tariff is fixed and guaranteed over a specific

period of time (20 years) which ensures the profitability of the investment for producers

and a stable investment environment for manufacturers, financers, and suppliers. With

the guarantee that household and industrial producers are guaranteed a premium and

sustained price for green electricity, market demand is created and industry responds with

the increased production of RES-based technologies. Another implication of this

dynamic is that lenders are inspired to offer favorable loans to consumers willing to

purchase the RES-based equipment and to invest in the capacity expansion of

manufacturers in order to meet rising demand. Therefore, the establishment of stable

expectations and the guarantee of concrete incentives create the conditions that are

necessary for market creation.

Consequently, the increase of production leads to the creation of economies of

scale and the acceleration of the learning process. In the case of Germany, the price of

photovoltaic systems has decreased by more than 20% since 1999 because new products

are facilitating the mounting of such systems, economies of scale are reducing the

manufacturing costs of equipment, and the growing experience of dealers and craftsmen

are further reducing costs.21


The EEG addresses the second obstacle when the authorities impose an obligation

upon the utilities to connect RES producers to the electrical grid and to transmit the green

electricity to consumers. This requirement leads to the restructuring of the grid in order

to accommodate the influx of multiple RES electrical systems as compared to the current

model of centralized production units in the form of conventional power plants. In

addition, the transmittance of the green electricity through the grid will increase the total

supply of electricity and thereby reduce the demand for electricity produced by

conventional power plants.

The third obstacle of market distortion can be cleared with the shifting of

electricity production subsidies by the government from conventional sources to RES.

Traditionally, governments have offered subsidies to domestic energy industries to ensure

adequate domestic supply, to reduce energy prices, and to promote job creation. In fact,

the history of coal, oil, natural gas, and nuclear power demonstrates that no energy sector

was developed without the use of subsidies.22 In the case of the U.S., the government has

distributed $74 billion to fund the R&D for conventional and nuclear power from 1973 to

2003 whereas only $26 billion was spent on RES technologies and energy efficiency.23

Specifically, recent research has shown that even though the U.S. nuclear and wind

technology produced roughly the same amount of energy, the subsidy to nuclear

outweighed that to wind by a factor of over forty24. But in the case of the E.U., a lower

proportion of generation capacity has been in the private sector. Hence, a different form

of support has been granted to the formerly state-owned firms that are still benefitting to

the present-day, which includes infrastructure, R&D, capital investment, and subsidized

operating costs.25 Therefore, the EEG has succeeded in leveling the playing field by

facilitating the penetration of RES technologies into the market in order to compete

against incumbent technologies.

The fourth obstacle is resolved by the EEG indirectly by the measures mentioned

above. Essentially, the government establishes the framework in which RES deployment
can occur. In doing so, the broader interest of society supersedes the narrow interest of

the utilities.

2.0 Economic efficiency

As stated in Section 1.7, economic efficiency is defined as the relative cost of this

policy option as compared to other support schemes and the absence of government

intervention. The policy option with the highest level of economic efficiency compared

to the alternative policies will carry the lowest costs to society.

The societal costs can be differentiated between the costs to consumers and

producers, whereas the environmental externality is encompassed in the ecological

effectiveness criterion.

The costs to producers will be grouped with the investment risk of investors

because the majority of the economic burden in both support schemes is passed onto the

end user. In the literature reviewed for this thesis, there have been no findings of data

that attempted to measure the costs incurred by the utilities, the transmission operators,

and the capital investors. For this reason, I have adopted the standard used by the

Climate Change Advisory Group of Deutsche Bank in order to assess the attractiveness

of each support scheme to producers and investors.

Investors are attracted to the quality of incentives provided by a renewable energy

policy framework that is considered in light of three key considerations: transparency,

longevity, and certainty. Transparency is defined as the ease in which investors can

circumnavigate the bureaucracy and policy structure. Longevity represents the

correspondence between the investment horizon and the policy timetable. Investors seek

the confidence that a RES support scheme will retain the support of the government and

the public to remain operational. And last, the notion of certainty involves the capability

to precisely calculate the future cash flows of an investment given the market and

institutional conditions.
The costs to consumers will be accounted for by an analytical approach and the

use of statistics drawn by several reports conducted by multinational corporations and

university research studies. Although there are different technology-specific tariff rates

that could have been employed in this comparison, I mainly focused on wind and solar

because these RES have seen the highest rates of growth. The major statistic that is used

in this comparison is the cost of the tariff per household for a given RES-based

technology.

2.1 Economic Efficiency: Green Certificate System

The green certificate system creates a quota requirement of property rights to the

environmental benefits derived from generating green electricity26. A certifying agency

established by the government oversees the purchasing, selling, and trading of these

unique rights (certificates) on a certificate market. The price of a certificate is

determined by the costs associated with the generation of green electricity. When the

producer generates electricity from RES instead of the less costly conventional sources,

the certificate’s value on the market should cover the producer’s incurred loss—in

accordance with theory. The GC system separates the market for electricity (commodity)

from the market for certificates (rights to environmental benefits). Economic efficiency

is maximized because producers are allowed to make rational decisions in how they will

fulfill the predetermined quota, which represents an artificially-induced market demand.

The producers are given the option of either generating green electricity through their

own means or they can purchase the certificates from other producers.

However, in reality, the producers and investors are faced with uncertainty in

determining the best course of action due to the fluctuation of the price of the certificates,

which depends on different factors such as the location of the facility producing the green

electricity and the type of RES electrical system.27 The empirical data provides evidence

that even though the GC system has seen considerable success in MS at the beginning of
the decade, it currently encounters severe difficulties due to the high level of investment

uncertainty in the long term.

Furthermore, with regard to producers and investors, the rules of the certificate

market call for the drafting of bi-lateral contracts to settle the terms of the purchasing and

selling of certificates28. Such agreements are conducted on a case-by-case basis and the

price of the certificates is determined by laws of supply and demand. However, the

drafting of these bilateral agreements, in accordance with free market principles, creates

an environment of uncertainty—in addition to the incurred transaction and administrative

costs. Therefore, there is “very little transparency or certainty going into the

negotiation”29. The following diagram demonstrates the suite of external factors that

increase the uncertainty of the underlying value of the certificate.

Last, the nature of electricity does not permit its storage. In order to respond to

price signals, utilities need to install new generation capacity that may take from one to

five years to commission. This feature of the industry produces further uncertainty in

both the electricity and the certificate markets in the form of volatile prices and illiquid

capital assets, respectively.

With regard to consumer costs, the findings of the International Energy Agency

(IEA) have demonstrated new evidence that contradicts the prevalent claim that GC

systems are less costly than FIT mechanisms. The IEA research revealed that the GC

systems are more costly to consumers than the FIT. In the portion of the report focusing

on on-shore wind power, the research team suggested that only fixed tariffs above a

specified price can catalyze a specific RES market: “a minimum level of remuneration

appears necessary to encourage wind power deployment…none of the countries that

provide overall levels of remuneration below USD 0.07/kWh witnessed significant

deployment effectiveness”3.

The report proceeded to reveal that the leading countries in wind power

deployment—Germany, Spain, Demark, and recently, Portugal—used FIT with lower


average remuneration levels in 2005 (USD .09-.11/kWh) than those in countries that used

GC systems (USD .13-.17/kWh). This blaring discrepancy can be explained by the fact

that beyond a certain price ceiling, the degree of policy effectiveness is not necessarily

enhanced even with the continued increase of remuneration levels.

The cases of Italy, Belgium, and the United Kingdom and their use of GC systems

provide further evidence of this theory because even though these countries provide the

highest level of remuneration for wind power, none of these countries scored high levels

of deployment effectiveness. Therefore, the appropriate question is why did these

countries fail to promote their respective RES sectors? The report identifies two leading

factors that discouraged the use of green technologies: “non-economic barriers and

intrinsic problems with the design of the GC systems31”.

2.2 Economic Efficiency: Feed-In Tariff

In the case of the EEG and its feed-in tariff mechanism, the German regional or

national transmission system operators are obligated to feed in the full generation of

green electricity by independent producers at politically fixed prices according to the

RES technology. The price of the fixed tariff rates are agreed upon using a transparent

equation, and thus, are less vulnerable to fraud, manipulation, and volatility. The costs of

this support scheme are also borne by the end users; however, the economic burden for

the consumer under the conditions of a FIT mechanism is more predictable than the GC

system.
The German government has set a fixed tariff rate for each eligible green

technology. Every two years, regulators assess the capacity installation of each

technology and calibrate its respective tariff rate in accordance with a specified growth

trajectory. For example, the yearly energy produced by the German wind power sector is

approximately 40,000 GW h with an average tariff rate of about .07 Euros for every

kilowatt per hour. If the objective is to generate 50,000 GW h by the year 2030, the

German government will assess the expansion of wind power generation every two years

and calibrate the tariff rates to achieve moderate and sustained growth. In this way, an

accurate prediction of the total costs to the end user can be determined. For instance, the

monthly cost per household to fund the FIT for solar energy only averages about 3 Euros

in 2008.32 Albeit the higher relative costs of the FIT mechanism (e.g. up to .65/kWh for

solar photovoltaic systems), the economic burden of the support scheme can be easily

determined every year and an accurate prediction of future costs can be determined.

However, the most important implication of the FIT is that its transparent price

calculation provides a higher quality bundle of incentives for investors. The effect of

providing stable expectations for the investment period is evident in the remarkable

performance of the FIT mechanism as compared to other support schemes. In a

comparative analysis conducted by the University of Palermo, the FIT mechanisms in the

countries of Germany, France, Spain, and Italy have led to pay-back-periods of under 19

years. In the case of Germany, the EEG has provided the following statistics that guide

investors in making their decisions:

· Average pay-back period of photovoltaic systems: 16 years

· Average pay-back period of wind systems: 15 years

· Average internal rate of return for photovoltaic systems: 3%

· Average internal rate of return for wind systems: 3.5%


The pay-back period designates the cost of the project divided by the annual cash

flows, which will equal the total amount of time that is required in order to cover the

initial investment. In the German RES market, a household or utility is guaranteed that

the installation of a RES electrical system will pay for itself no later than 19 years. In

addition, the internal rate of return represents the discount rate that is used in capital

budgeting that will set the net present value of a project’s cash flows equal to zero. In the

case of Germany, the internal rate of return indicates that an investor covers the costs of

the initial capital investment, and also earns a premium bonus of approximately 3%.

In the cumulative cash flows comparison for non-integrated photovoltaic

systems33, the EEG provided the best stimulus for growth among the four leading

countries. This figure represents the category of RES energy projects that are funded in

part by local landowners and community members in the rural areas of Germany. A

growing social acceptance of community energy projects called “energy cooperatives”

has democratized the local supply of electricity for many German towns and has highly

contributed to the expansion of the RES sector.

Furthermore, the FIT has an economic advantage over the GC system because it

enables the economic burden of its implementation to be reversed by the consumer. If

the consumer decides to take out a low-interest rate loan and to install an independent

RES power generator, then the rate of return the RES electrical system will accrue can

cover the annual costs of the FIT. It may be the case that under a FIT mechanism, the

total economic costs to the consumer are greater than the GC system, but even so, the

economic burden under a FIT is not only more predictable, but also it can be mitigated

more readily if the consumer proceeds in purchasing a RES electrical system.

One of the major weaknesses in the FIT, with regard to consumer costs, has been

corrected during the initial phase of its implementation. Ringel identified this flaw in

design by observing that no “differentiation had to be made between network operators

with a high share of renewable in their operation area and operators with having
practically no green power producers to deal with, consumers were caught and simply

had to pay the additional costs34”.

For instance, northern Germany operators were mandated to feed in a large

portion of wind power whereas the operators in southern Germany had considerably less

green electricity generation. However, the German government solved this problem by

implementing a compensation scheme that distributed the economic costs of the FIT

equally between the operating areas and their respective consumers.

2.3 Ecological Effectiveness: Feed-In Tariff

With regard to ecological effectiveness, the GC system should theoretically

promote the greater amount of installed capacity of green electricity over the FIT

mechanism. However, consulting the empirical evidence of recent years will reveal the

multiple counterexamples that clearly signify an overriding trend that FIT tariffs are, in

fact, more effective in expanding RES generation capacity (Appendix 1). For example,

the “surge of wind energy in the E.U. has clearly taken place within countries that

selected the FIT as their national support scheme35”. The countries of Germany,

Denmark, and Spain surpass the E.U. 15 average by at least 2,000 GWh; however, the

country of Netherlands—which implements both a FIT and a GC system—is much closer

to the E.U. 15 average. The only difference between the Netherlands and the other three

countries is that the Netherlands does not obligate transmission operators to take green

electricity generated by RES producers. This observation suggests the importance of

each feature of a well-designed FIT because the other factors would most likely not

override the potential benefits of an effective FIT.

In the case of solar energy, Germany is dominant in the area of photovoltaic

generation, accounting for 47% of the world’s new PV generation capacity in 200736. In

terms of generation capacity, Germany installed 1.1 GWp in 2007, which elevates the

total photovoltaic capacity to 3.8 GWp. Accordingly, economists are predicting that this
growth rate will have a high impact on other major markets such as Spain, Italy, France,

Greece, Japan, and the US, particularly because the PV industry is expecting

manufacturing costs to continue decreasing.37

2.4 Ecological Effectiveness: Green Certificate System

A. Failure to Achieve E.U. Energy Objectives

The greatest disadvantage of the GC system in promoting the use of RES

generation is its inherent tendency to concentrate on a select few green technologies

within its country of jurisdiction. If the E.U. does not promote a high level of diversity

among RES technologies within the energy sector, then it will fail to achieve its long

term energy objectives—namely, to achieve energy supply security and to reach its

indicative RES targets.

The objective of energy security will not be reached with the implantation of a

GC system because of its inherent design. Since the price of the certificates is dependent

on supply and demand only, the purchasing party will seek out the certificates that have

been earned with the least cost. As a result, only the most efficient producers will be

better equipped to sell certificates at a more competitive price than less efficient

producers. This element of the GC system appears beneficial on the surface; however,

wind power, hydro, and biomass energy are the only green technologies in the energy

sector that reach efficiency levels that enable producers to competitively sell their earned

certificates and to continue producing green electricity. Under these market conditions,

technologies such as solar photovoltaic will not be able to compete, and thus, will not be

deployed.

The objective of energy security is particularly important for the E.U. because it is

highly reliant on foreign imports of fossil fuels. If the price of fossil fuels fluctuates, then

the E.U. will experience price hikes, possible supply disruptions, and grave economic

losses. In addition, Ringel cites the example of the Brazilian blackouts in 2003 to
demonstrate the danger of generation fluctuations in the case of natural catastrophe. The

series of black-outs occurred because a heat wave hindered the production of

hydroelectricity, which is a source of power generation that contributes a large share of

Brazil’s total capacity

Furthermore, the objective of reaching the E.U. indicative RES targets will not be

fulfilled unless a diverse portfolio of RES is stimulated. Many MS have specialized in

one or two RES in accordance with their respective resource endowments. For example,

the country of Austria has exploited its mountainous geography to harness the potential

of hydroelectric power, whereas Spain has extensively developed its solar power

generation capacity. Since the further deployment of such RES technologies will incur

rising marginal costs and other difficulties, it will become necessary for the MS to

stimulate the use of additional RES technologies in order to reach their indicative RES

targets. If a GC system cannot stimulate the more costly RES-based technologies, it

cannot be the support scheme of choice for many MS.

B. False Claim of Timeliness

Proponents of the GC system claim that, unlike the FIT and its reliance on

voluntary market participation, the imposition of volume quotas ensures that a RES target

is fulfilled in a timely manner. However, the caveats of this claim are numerous to the

extent that it does not hold true in practice. First, the binding volume target can be

avoided by utilities by accepting the compliance penalties for the failure to generate

green electricity or to purchase green certificates. Second, both support schemes are the

result of political negotiations whose incentives are not guaranteed beyond the provisions

of the legislation. The long term continuation of such programs is of the utmost

importance in inspiring confidence among producers and investors. Therefore, the

support scheme with the greatest and most sustained support from the body politic will

have the highest likelihood of continuation.


Given this proposition, the utilities of an energy sector would be more in favor of

a GC system because it is the least costly and it is more advantageous for large firms with

the resources and leverage to negotiate the bilateral contracts needed for the exchange of

certificates. In contrast, the FIT extends the incentives of the support scheme to any

independent producer—from the residents of a city apartment building to the farmers of a

small community. The FIT mechanism can enable any citizen to install a RES electrical

system and generate green electricity, and thus, the FIT is a more democratic and open

policy instrument. This feature of the FIT increases the likelihood that it can garner

greater public support and political backing.

C. Potential Reduction of the Volume Targets

Furthermore, government authorities are “sensitive to the impact that the binding

targets may have on electricity rates and some policies have clauses that explicitly

exempt the utility from compliance if the rate reaches a certain threshold38. Given this

fact, the indicated target may not be definitively binding for the energy sector; but

nevertheless, the costs are borne by the end users in exchange for minimal accrued

benefits.

The overall aim of generating 20% of the E.U.’s total electricity generation from

RES has been “split up into indicative targets for its member states due to different levels

of nationally available RES.”39 If the economic burden on the consumer becomes

overbearing and the countries with GC systems ease their generation obligations, then

every MS will be negatively affected because the integrity of the indicative RES targets

will be compromised. For this reason, the FIT mechanism is the most ecologically

effective support scheme because it creates a framework of incentives without

establishing a cap that may hamper RES growth rates. The primary example of this

proposition is the collapse of the solar market in Spain. Since the feed-in tariff was

stimulating the RES market to the degree that the Spanish government could not
sufficiently fund the program, the authorities imposed a cap. This restriction flooded the

market with participants who did not want to lose the opportunity. This created a further

strain on the Spanish government, and once the cap was reached, the solar tariff ended

and the market imploded soon after. This case is a useful lesson in the importance of

proper FIT design and implementation. Unlike the German FIT, Spain did not pass the

costs on to the consumer and they imposed a cap on the market, which led to drastically

counterproductive results.

2.5 Intellectual Property Rights and Technology Transfer

Without the deployment of emissions-reducing, energy-saving technologies,

countries cannot exploit the agricultural, industrial, and residential products and

software necessary to pursue a low-carbon economic growth trajectory. Such

climate-related technologies are central to the international effort to mitigate and

adapt to climate change. Historically, most of the world’s technological innovation

has originated in the industrialized “North” whereas the developing “South” confronts

several obstacles to accessing such technologies, which include: inadequate foreign

direct investment flows and minimal indigenous research and development (R&D).

Since the developing countries’ total greenhouse gas emissions are exceeding the

level emitted by the industrialized countries, the objective of bridging this

technological disparity becomes increasingly important. A major obstacle that

hinders technological transfer and a stumbling block for current negotiations in

Copenhagen is the issue of intellectual property rights (IPR).

On the one side of the debate, U.S., Europe, and Japan are entrenched in the

policy position that IPR protection is not an obstacle, but imperative in encouraging

innovation. Since innovative activities are both costly and risky, market actors must

be ensured of temporary monopolistic power in order to appropriate the benefits

accrued from their innovation. In addition, the dissemination of knowledge is


promoted because information from the patent claims is available to other inventors

and entrepreneurs, which can serve as a substrate for further innovation. Proponents

of IPR protect claim that in the absence of IPR protection, the threat of imitation

damages the incentive for any potential R&D. In contrast, the diplomatic coalition of

developing countries, the G-77, represents the antithetical view that the current IPR

regime is an obstacle to technology transfer because it stifles innovation and

knowledge diffusion. Proponents of this view generally believe that profiteering

multinational corporations withhold proprietary knowledge to the detriment of the

welfare of the South. For this reason, India, Brazil, and China have led efforts to

demand compulsory licensing, especially in the wake of the precedent-setting Doha

Declaration and the concession of the pharmaceutical companies in the Africa

HIV/AIDS epidemic.

These two views correspond to either extreme of the spectrum of policy

options. The optimal course of action is a balancing act between maintaining a strong

incentive for firms to engage in R&D while keeping costs low for new technologies,

especially for their use in developing countries. For this purpose, measures should be

taken to uphold the minimum standards of IPR protection established by international

treaties such as the World Trade Organization’s Agreement on Trade Related Aspects

of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS). If IPR protection is effectively enforced,

inventors and entrepreneurs will have the confidence to challenge the status quo by

experimenting and creating new innovations. Policymakers must be cautious of

providing excessive IPR protection because then proprietors of knowledge can

reserve their patents that may lower output and increase costs of the new technology,

which will hinder its deployment. But in the interest of the developing world, mature

technologies should be transferred as readily as possible in order to enhance the social

and economic welfare among the most vulnerable populations. To avert damaging
the incentive for future R&D, the transferred technologies can constitute information

and products that are behind the technological frontier by at least five years.

2.6 Resolution to the Debate

Unfortunately, both parties of the debate are entrenched in rigid positions and

the only viable solution may lie with the idea of cooperative international R&D

agencies. Since the majority of innovative activities occur within the private sector,

national governments can contribute funding to an international clean technology

institution that can allow countries to tap into its knowledge stock and to exploit its

technological solutions. This compromise will be mutually advantageous for the

producers of the North and the end users in the South. The most cutting edge

technologies will continue to be developed by free market firms and their profit

margins will not be reduced. In addition, the global clean technology institution can

direct its efforts in meeting the technological needs that are either non-existent in the

private sector or inaccessible. In addition, this source of knowledge and know-how

can stimulate a learning process that can enable firms in developing countries to

accelerate their transition from imitation to innovation.

In the wake of the failed Copenhagen negotiations, policymakers must reach a

consensus in this essential, but highly under-reported issue in the global climate

change debate. The balance between incentivization of R&D and the fulfillment of

social, economic, and ecological objectives should be struck in a manner conducive to

the spirit of multilateralism and cooperation. For this reason, the best resolution to

this debate is to establish an international clean technology R&D institution that can

provide useful environmentally sound technologies to those who stand to benefit the

most from them—the developing countries of the world.

2.7 Conclusion
This paper started its analysis with an examination of the role of RES-based

technologies in the effort to combat global climate change. In order to answer the

first research question, I provided a background of the technological process and the

obstacles that hinder its advancement. Then, I established that government

intervention is the only means in which these obstacles can be overcome by market

actors.

The research conducted for this paper has determined that public sector R&D

coupled with RES support schemes constitute the only way to achieve widespread

deployment of green technologies. I chose two leading support schemes to compare

in order to answer the second research question. The GS system and the FIT

mechanism represent my dependent variables because they affect the independent

variable of RES deployment. To determine which support scheme is the most

effective, I employed two criteria: economic efficiency and ecological effectiveness.

The results of my analysis are that GC systems should theoretically be less costly to

society (economic efficiency); however, the empirical record coupled with additional

factors of uncertainty has led to different conclusions. In addition, GS systems

should also perform better in pursuant to the ecological criterion, however, the FIT

has proven to be the better policy instrument in creating green electricity generation

capacity. In conclusion, this analysis has demonstrated that the FIT is the superior

support scheme in light of the two defined criteria that were used in the qualitative

approach.

Last, the issue of intellectual property rights is raised in the context of

technology transfer. If the green technologies are imperative to the international

strategy of mitigating and adapting to climate change, then the developing world is

entitled to assistance in advancing their technological innovation and adopting the use

of RES electrical systems (especially in light of the fact that the industrialized nations

have historically contributed the majority of greenhouse gas emissions into the
atmosphere). The final resolution to this dilemma between incentivizing innovative

activities and keeping costs low is the establishment of an international research

institution that can be tapped for knowledge and funding.

Bibliography
Alic, J. M. (2003). U.S. Technology and Innovation Policies: Lessons for Climate
Change. Pew Center on Global Climate Change.
Campoccia, A. D. (2009). Comparative analysis of different supporting measures for the
production of electrical energy by solar PV and Wind systems: Four representative
European cases. Solar Energy , 287-297.

Climate Change Investment Research. (2009). Paying for Renewable Energy: TLC at
the right price. New York: Deutsche Bank Group Climate Change Advisors .

Gipe, P. (2008, October 7). Retrieved November 2, 2009, from Wind-Works.org:


http://www.wind-works.org/FeedLaws/IEAFeed-inTariffsMoreEffective.html

Hoffmann, W. (2006). PV solar electricity industry: Market growth and perspective. Solar
Energy Materials and Solar Cells , 3285-3311.
John, Jonathod. (2008, December 23). Renewables--The power of the feed-in tariff.
Modern Power Systems , p. 31.

Lauber, V. a. (2006). Renewable Electricity Policy in Germany, 1974-2005. Bulletin of


Science, Technology, & Society , 105-120.
Martin, D. (n.d.). Feed-in Tariffs Have Earned a Role in U.S. Policy. Retrieved October
28, 2009, from SEMI PV Group:
http://www.renewableenergyworld.com/rea/news/article/2009/08/feed-in-tariffs-have-
earned-a-role-in-us-energy-policy

Mendonca, M. a. (2009, September 17). Feed-in Tariffs Go Global: Policy in Practice.


Retrieved November 4 , 2009, from Renewable Energy World.com:
http://www.renewableenergyworld.com/rea/news/article/2009/09/feed-in-tariffs-go-global-
policy-in-practice
Mendonça, M. (n.d.). Success Story: Feed-In Tariffs Support renewable energy in
Germany. Retrieved November 12, 2009, from e-Parliament Programme : http://www.e-
parl.net/eparlimages/general/pdf/080603%20FIT%20toolkit.pdf
Renewables Germany Supplement--Renewables incentives renewed. (2009, January 8).
Modern Power Systems , p. 32.

Ringel, M. (2006, May 26). Fostering the use of renewable energies in the European
Union: the race between feed-in tariffs and green certificates. Renewable Energy: An
International Journal , 1-17.

Seager, A. (2007, July 23). Germany sets shining example in providing a harvest for the
world. Retrieved October 2, 2009, from guardian.co.uk:
http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2007/jul/23/germany.greenbusiness/print

Stern, N. (2007). Part IV: Policy Responses for Mitigation. Retrieved October 4, 2009,
from The Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change: http://www.hm-
treasury.gov.uk/d/Part_IV_Introduction_group.pdf

Stryi-Hipp, G. (2004). The Effects of the EEG on Market, Technical, and Industrial
Development. Berlin, Germany: German Solar Industry Association.

1
Nicolosi and Fuersch pg. 25
2
Energy industries is a generic term for all of the industries involved the production and
sale of energy, including fuel extraction, manufacturing, refining and distribution
3
Pew Center on Global Climate Change pg. 7
4
Stern pg. 349
5
Pew Center on Global Climate Change pg. 7
6
Pew Center on Global Climate Change pg. 8
7
The four obstacles are derived from the analysis of the Stern Report
8
Stern pg. 350
9
Stern pg. 355
1
Stern pg. 361
11
Pew Center on Global Climate Change pg. 35
12
Stern pg. 361
13
Slater and Tonkiss pg. 124
14
Ringel pg. 6
15
Campoccia, Dusonchet, Telaretti, Zizzo pg. 289
16
Ringel pg. 8
17
Analogous to the notion of emissions allowances in a cap and trade scheme
18
Lauber and Mez pg. 105
19
E-Parliament memorandum pg. 3
2
E-Parliament memorandum pg. 3
21
Stryi-Hipp pg. 4
22
Pernick, Ron and Wilder, Clint
23
Pernick, Ron and Wilder, Clint
24
Goldberg
25
European Environment Agency pg. 16
26
Campoccia, Dusonchet, Telaretti, and Zizzo pg. 288
27
Campoccia, Dusonchet, Telaretti, and Zizzo pg. 289
28
The GC system favors large electricity generators with the resources to engage in
negotiations. This feature also increases transaction costs which are passed on to the
consumer.
29
Deutsche Bank Advisory Report pg. 50
3
Gipe pg. 2
31
Gipe pg. 2
32
Martin pg. 2
33
The term non-integrated photovoltaic systems refers to generators that are not
integrated into the exterior structures of buildings.
34
Ringel pg. 6
35
Ringel pg. 10
36
Modern Power System Magazine pg. 32
37
The experience of recent decades has shown that the cost of PV electricity is reduced
by 20% with each doubling of the total installed volume.
38
Deutsche Bank Advisory Report pg. 52
39
Ringel Pg. 2

Você também pode gostar