Você está na página 1de 2

Durable inequality

Chuck Tilly was an enormously creative historical sociologist, and he also had a knack
for a good title. This is certainly true of his 1998 book, Durable Inequality. The topic is
of particular interest today, in the contemporary environment of ever-more visible and
widening inequalities that pervade American society.
The contemporary facts in the United States are more clearly understood than ever: an
increasing separation between the top decile of income and the bottom forty percent of
the income distribution, a low level of social mobility relative to European countries,
and a high degree of permanent poverty. The Pew Economic Mobility Project provides
an important snapshot of social mobility in the United States; link; in brief, the
likelihood of the child of parents from the bottom quintile to remain in the bottom
quintile is 43%, while the likelihood of a child born to the top quintile remaining there
is 40%.
So the inequalities we confront in the United States are indeed "durable" and
multigenerational. But how do economic and social inequalities come about?
This is a large part of the agenda of Durable Inequalities. Here Tilly looks at social and
economic inequalities from a historical point of view. He is concerned with "categorical
inequalities" -- that is, inequalities across groups of people defined by relatively rigid
social discriminators. "Durable inequality depends heavily on the institutionalization of
categorical pairs" (8). Relevant social categories include gender, race, immigrant status,
or rural-urban origins. Tilly begins his book with an astounding statistic about durable
inequalities in nineteenth-century England: "poor boys of fourteen averaged only 4 feet
3 inches tall, while aristocrats and gentry of the same age averaged about 5 feet 1 inch"
(1).
The central intellectual task of the book is to account for how social categories often
result in categorical inequalities. Not all categorical distinctions among people result in
economic or political disparities across the resulting groups -- for example, "good sense
of humor/bad sense of humor" doesn't appear to result in income disparities across the
humorous and the humorless. But the male-female wage gap, the black-white wealth
gap, and the white-latino education gap all are examples of inequalities that follow
from, and are presumably caused by, the categorical status possessed by the two groups.
Categorical inequalities are particularly important because they appear to be wholly
indefensible. The fact that "skilled/unskilled" workers have differential incomes is not
surprising on grounds of productivity and value-added work; but the fact that equally
well educated women and men have differential incomes is indeed surprising.
The social mechanisms that Tilly identifies as being primarily responsible for
inequalities across social categories are exploitation and opportunity hoarding (10).
Exploitation, which operates when powerful, connected people command resources
from which they draw significantly increased returns by coordinating the efforts
of outsiders whom they exclude from the full value added by that effort.
Opportunity hoarding, which operates when members of a categorically bounded
network acquire access to a resource that is valuable, renewable, subject to
monopoly, supportive of network activities, and enhanced by the network's

modus operandi. (10)


Here are a few summary observations about these two mechanisms and how they work
within institutions and organizations.
Exploitation rests on unequal distribution of rewards proportionate to value added
among participants in the same enterprise.
Organizationally installed categorical inequality facilitates exploitation.
Organizations whose survival depends on exploitation therefore tend to adopt
categorical inequality.
Because organizations adopting categorial inequality deliver greater returns to their
dominant members and because a portion of those returns goes to organizational
maintenance, such organizations tend to crowd out other types of organizations.
Opportunity hoarding by collaborative agents complements exploitation.
Opportunity hoarding operates more effectively and at lower cost in conjunction with
categorical inequality.
...
Seemingly contradictory categorical principles such as age, race, gender, and
ethnicity operate in similar ways and can be organizationally combined or
substituted within limits set by previously established scripting and local
knowledge. (85-86)
What Tilly is trying to accomplish in this work is genuinely ambitious: it is to establish
both a natural history and a causal dynamics of socially generated
inequalities. Inequalities are not solely the natural outcome of differences in abilities,
talent, and motivation (individual characteristics); instead, they are the result of
institutions and social relations that have been strategically crafted over time by
individuals and groups for their ongoing advantage.
Exploitation, opportunity hoarding, emulation, and adaptation that incorporate
asymmetrically paired categories have for millennia promoted most of the inequality
that historians commonly attribute to individual differences in capacity or enterprise.
These causal principles combine with a vast historical record to provide the means of
constructing counterfactual accounts of durable inequality: forms of inequality or
equality that have existed in some times and places, that could have existed, that could
exist now, that could take shape in the future. (230)
And the forms of group discrimination that go along with categorical differences play a
key role in these inequalities.
How does this analysis fit with the two graphs provided above of income inequality and
slow social mobility in the United States? A careful analysis of the social mechanisms
that impede social mobility will certainly include the processes of exploitation and
opportunity-hoarding that Tilly discusses; it will include the impact of social categories
like race, gender, and ethnicity; and it will include the exclusive social network
mechanisms that permit the top segment of the society to retain its place through
selection and limited opportunities for the rest of society. So Tilly's historical analysis
in Durable Inequalities is highly relevant to our current efforts to understand and
address the widening inequalities that we see around us

Você também pode gostar