Explorar E-books
Categorias
Explorar Audiolivros
Categorias
Explorar Revistas
Categorias
Explorar Documentos
Categorias
Xos Manuel Carreira Rodrguez, n 1400957, Emmanuel Pereso Aliceu Jovo, n 1402550, Agostinho Alberto
Queba, n 1501082 e Sheila Joaquim Come, n 1500957.
Introduo.
O artigo em apreo apresenta um estudo efectuado no Japo para determinar os padres de consumo
domstico que permitam um equilbrio entre as necessidades econmicas e as ambientais. Alm disso, o artigo
revela quais as contribuies percentuais nos encargos ambientais que so devido, em primeiro lugar, a
emisso de CO2 por queima dos combustveis fsseis (sector industrial); seguindo lugar, por encargos
domsticos (cozinhas) e em terceiro lugar por outros servios. A tarefa do grupo Nansai 1 foi a de fazer anlise
do artigo (em termos da sua qualidade) e com base no artigo construir o modelo de anlise (V de Gowin).
1.a) Anlise formal do artigo: Titulo, introduo e objectivos.
a1. Ttulo.
Segundo o professor Donald Huisingh (Vdeo II- qualitative manuscript: article structure), um bom ttulo
deve ser especfico, conciso, completo e atraente para os leitores.
No caso deste artigo, o seu ttulo :
Coerente com o objectivo e pertinente.
No atractivo.
Falta a localizao de onde decorreu o estudo.
uma generalizao, ao invs do estudo de caso.
a2. Introduo.
Segundo Huisingh (ibidem), num bom artigo a introduo dever ser objectiva, significante, apresentar a
real inquietao e no deve conter mtodos ou concluses.
No caso do artigo que apresentado, a introduo:
Contm justificativa e referencial.
Porm, mais explicativa do que problematizadora.
Figuram elementos que deviam estar nas concluses, por exemplo: the model demonstrated multiple
optimal state, increase and decrease, of household consumption for each commodity, by setting
different objective function of minimizing nn environment burden).
a3. Objectivos:
Objectivos devem ser certeiros e avaliveis. Certeiros, no sentido de serem definidos de forma clara e
rigorosa. Avaliveis, de modo a que no final da investigao possa determinar com exatido se os atingiu ou
no, Carmo, (2013:11). Estes devem ser adequados a metodologia, coerentes e precisos (Assis et.al., s/d).
No caso deste artigo, os objectivos:
Adequam-se metodologia e so avaliveis.
So mais declarativos do que certeiros.
So apresentados no presente de indicativo.
1.b) Construo do modelo de anlise com base em V Gowin
O artigo comea por revelar que a questo dos padres de produo e consumo ao nvel global sempre
estive na manga para a sua discusso, sendo uma preocupao para a sociedade contempornea; por isso, a
Agenda 21 no seu captulo 4 faz meno da questo de produo e consumo sustentveis. Com base no
pargrafo seguinte; today, it is important that we examine ideal patterns of Japanese household consumption
so that Japan can maintain a sustainable balance between economic and environmental needs, verifica-se que
o artigo identifica a finalidade da pesquisa. Embora haja a fundamentao do problema, porm, o artigo no
faz referncia a outros estudos similares sobre esta matria.
2.b) Metodologia.
b1. Estratgicas metodolgicas.
No estudo apresentado o mtodo usado para entrada e sada dos dados para a sua anlise (modelo
input-output de programao linear).
Estudo de base populacional, porm no acompanhado pelo tamanho da amostra.
No se faz meno ao respaldo tico (questes ticas) e nem faz referncia do seu acautelamento.
No faz aluso aos instrumentos usados para a recolha dos dados e nem se quer aborda a sua
validao.
Estudo quantitativo.
b2. Recolha e tratamento de dados.
Os dados so apresentados de forma sequencial.
Apoia-se das tabelas dos estudos anteriores, por exemplo, a tabela 1.
Na fig.1 peca-se por trazer duas situaes (waste e NOx) com representao de barras da mesma corisso dificulta a sua distino;
No referenciao das grandes tabelas de entrada e sada.
b3. Limitaes do mtodo utilizado.
Uso de valores substitutos e/ou estimados;
No permite uma interpretao clara dos resultados;
No usa mdias e desvio padro para facilitar a anlise dos resultados;
Dificuldades em estimar os coeficientes de capital adequados.
2.c) Apresentao e discusso dos resultados.
O artigo explica a significncia dos resultados e compara os resultados encontrados com as previses
tericas;
Contudo, nos grficos (fig. 2 e 3) h dificuldades em distinguir os resultados referentes ao lixo e/ou
resduos (waste) dos de oxido de nitrognio (NOx).
Em algumas situaes difcil fazer uma extrapolao para a leitura rigorosa dos resultados
percentuais e das frequncias acumuladas.
Os comentrios das figuras e tabelas so apresentados muito a posterior e isso no permite o seu
relacionamento para sua melhor compreenso.
O uso do termo commodities, que nos remete para matrias-primas ou mercadorias bsicas, em
lugar de bens e servios, d lugar a alguma confuso.
3
3. Concluses.
A avaliao da sustentabilidade da produo e o consumo mediante um nico indicador baseado na
anlise input-output foi investigado em vrios artigos por Nansai et al. (2007). Noutro artigo coetneo dos
mesmos investigadores japoneses, por exemplo, o consumo de electricidade foi escolhido como medida da
eco-velocidade, com base na analogia com a noo de velocidade na fsica.
A anlise input-output uma ferramenta quantitativa de alto nvel macroeconmico. Consiste no uso de
tabelas de insumo-produto e emisses por sector para calcular os impactos ambientais. Schaltegger (1996)
critica que este mtodo no tem a dupla perspectiva (de cima para baixo e de baixo para cima) que seria
necessria para uma medio completa da sustentabilidade.
Outras crticas anlise input-output esto relacionadas com as enormes necessidades de dados de boa
qualidade, bem como os pressupostos simplificadores necessrios no tratamento de dados, que devem ser
explicitados (Paloviita, A., 2004). P.ex. as restries K**, L** e GDP** ficam constantes e no caso de GDP** os
autores assumem o valor do ano 1995, o que pode gerar dvidas no leitor. Os autores fazem um ajuste de
dados e indicam simplesmente se a correlao positiva ou negativa, mas os intervalos de confiana da
classificao no se encontram disponveis no artigo analisado. Em ausncia de dados desagregados, a
alocao de impactos para produtos e servios diferentes torna-se difcil (Paloviita, A., 2004). Tudo isto faz com
que o modelo seja dificilmente replicvel por outros investigadores como exige o editor Donald Huisingh.
Entrando nos resultados, a segmentao de bens e servios escolhida pelos autores no equilibrada e
resulta pouco eficaz. Da amostra de 94 bens e servios analisados, na categoria 1 -inaceitveis- esto 47,
enquanto na categoria 2 -aceitveis- esto apenas 9 deles. Nas categorias que no do um juzo nem positivo
nem negativo -3 (depende das circunstncias) e 4 (inclassificveis) - ficam classificados 38 elementos. Por
outras palavras, a maior parte so items perniciosos ou no se podem avaliar.
Hertwitch (2010) aponta que este tipo de anlise seria vlido para as circunstncias locais de consumo e
produo. Cada pas ou regio ter uma seleco diferente de factores determinantes, pelo que a
generalizao dos resultados fora do mbito japons no imediata. Assim, concordamos com Schaltegger
(1996) que chama para o uso de ferramentas mais simples.
Finalmente, muitas iniciativas de indicadores de sustentabilidade como o presente estudo podem ser
criticadas por causa da ausncia da dimenso social (Veleva, V. et al., 2000). A fragmentao de disciplinas no
permite uma viso holstica. Uma caracterstica comum de muitos modelos quantitativos o facto de que eles
continuem dominados pela disciplina onde se originaram (Todorov, V. et al., 2011). Hertwitch (2010), por
exemplo, reconhece que os estudos quantitativos de optimizao de cenrios sustentveis como o de Nansai et
al. (2007) ainda no esto bem desenvolvidos, que a sua importncia precisa ser colocada em perspectiva, mas
podem oferecer vises valiosas de polticas interessantes para o futuro.
Referncias bibliogrficas:
1. Agenda 21 (1992). United Nations Conference on Environment & Development Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, 3
to 14 June 1992.
https://sustainabledevelopment.un.org/content/documents/Agenda21.pdf
2. Assis, B., Morais, C. e Alves C. (s/d). In: Seminrio: Anlise crtica de artigo cientfico. Universidade
Federal de Gois, Brasil.
https://ppgnut.fanut.ufg.br/up/240/o/analise_artigo_cientifico_2.pdf
3. Bauer, M. A. L. (2015). Teorias Ambientais. Universidade Federal do Rio Grande do Sul. Brasil.
https://www.passeidireto.com/arquivo/2869730/teorias-ambientais
4. Caeiro, S., Ramos, T. B., & Huisingh, D. (2012). Procedures and criteria to develop and evaluate
household sustainable consumption indicators. Journal of cleaner production, 27, 72-91
5. Carmo, H, 2013, Sistemas de orientao na pesquisa: formulao de objetivos, hipteses e modelo de
anlise, in Manual de metodologia das cincias sociais e polticas, Lisboa, ISCSP/UTL, no prelo.
6. Hertwich, E. (2010). Assessing the environmental impacts of consumption and production: priority
products and materials. UNEP/Earthprint.
http://www.unep.org/resourcepanel/Portals/24102/PDFs/PriorityProductsAndMaterials_Report.pdf
7. Huisingh, D. (2014) Vdeos sobre como escrever um artigo. Universidade Aberta.
- Vdeo I: Before starting to write http://player.vimeo.com/video/84054629
- Vdeo II: Writing a Quality Manuscript: article structure http://player.vimeo.com/video/84054630
- Vdeo III: Writing a Quality Manuscript: language, technical issues, submission, revision and responses
to the reviewers http://player.vimeo.com/video/84756341
- Vdeo IV: Writing a Quality Manuscript: Accepting rejection, ethical, peer review, etc.
http://player.vimeo.com/video/84876893
8. Nansai K., Kagawa, S. & Moriguchi, Y. (2007). Proposal of a simple indicator for sustainable
consumption: classifying goods and services into three types focusing on their optimal consumption
levels. Journal of Cleaner Production, 15 (10), 879-885.
9. Nansai, K., Kagawa, S., Suh, S., Inaba, R., & Moriguchi, Y. (2007). Simple indicator to identify the
environmental soundness of growth of consumption and technology:Eco-velocity of consumption.
Environmental Science & Technology, 41(4), 1465-1472.
10. Paloviita, A. (2004). Matrix sustainability: applying input-output analysis to environmental and
economic sustainability indicators: case: Finnish Forest Sector. University of Jyvskyl.
https://jyx.jyu.fi/dspace/bitstream/handle/123456789/13193/9513919897.pdf
11. Schaltegger, S. (1996). Life Cycle Assessment (LCA)Quo vadis?. Springer Science & Business Media.
https://books.google.es/books?id=rXKN6OAa8dcC
12. Todorov, V., & Marinova, D. (2011). Modelling sustainability. Mathematics and Computers in
Simulation, 81(7), 1397-1408.
http://www.curtin.edu.au/research/cusp/local/docs/modeling-sustainability-marinova.pdf
13. Veleva, V. & Ellenbecker M. 2000. A proposal for Measuring Business Sustainability. Addressing
Shortcomings in Existing Frameworks. Greener Management International 31. Autumn 2000, 101-120.
http://www.ifba.edu.br/professores/armando/Eng531/Unid%20I/MIT%20Lowell%20Indicatorsustenab
leproduction.pdf
Research Center for Material Cycles and Waste Management, National Institute for Environmental Studies, 16-2 Onogawa, Tsukuba,
Ibaraki 305-8506, Japan
b
Graduate School of Information Sciences, Tohoku University, Aoba, Aoba-ku, Sendai 980-8579, Japan
Received 31 March 2005; accepted 27 February 2006
Available online 18 May 2006
Abstract
We calculated optimal consumption patterns of Japanese households using a linear programming model, taking into account the different
environmental burdens to be minimized. Ninety-four industrial sectors and 94 commodities were defined in the model. In terms of environmental
burdens to be minimized, this study considered energy consumption, CO2 emission, waste, and NOx emission. According to the direction
(increase or decrease) of adjusted final demand for a commodity in the household, commodities were classified into three types: (1) a commodity
for which optimal demand should be decreased in all cases of reducing various environmental burdens; (2) a commodity whose optimal demand
should be increased in all cases; and (3) a commodity whose optimal demand depends on the type of environmental burden. Among 63
commodities whose final demand was assumed to be adjustable, 47 were categorized as commodity type 1, nine were categorized as commodity
type 2, and seven belonged to commodity type 3. This work also characterized each type of commodity from the viewpoint of economic and
environmental properties.
2006 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
Keywords: Indicator; Consumption pattern; Multiple-environmental burdens; Household consumption; Linear programming model
1. Introduction
In recent years, ideal patterns of consumption have been
discussed under the concept of sustainable consumption.
This concept has been incorporated into international policies
[1]. In 1992, for example, Chapter 4 of Agenda 21 referred to
sustainable consumption and production, and the United Nations has compiled guidelines for consumer protection that
provide governments with a comprehensive framework for setting policy for more sustainable consumption and production.
At the World Summit on Sustainable Development held in
Johannesburg in 2002, the agenda called for the development
880
Commodity
Industry
Imports
Value added
Total supply
Commodity
Industry
Household
consumption
Other
final
demands
Total
demand
X
V
M
q
g
qT
V
gT
and
g;
VT Cb
where b
g denotes a diagonal matrix with the vector g, whose
element number is the same as the number of commodity
and VT is the transposed matrix of V.
We express the direct environmental burden factor of each
commodity by vector ec, which represents the amount of direct
environmental burden accompanied by the unit commodity
consumption. The total direct environmental burden caused
by commodity consumption can be calculated as follows:
direct ec h f ec C Bg:
The model calculates the optimal state of vector g. Hereafter, we describe it as vector g*.
2.1.3. Constraints
2.1.3.1. Commodity supplyedemand balance. We assumed
an adjustable range for the final demand for household
consumption. Representing the upper range of the household
consumption as vector hU and the lower range as vector hL, the
commodity supplyedemand balance should meet these criteria:
hU f Cg Bg hL f:
That is, the difference between the total supply Cg and the
intermediate demand Bg is more than the sum of hL and the
881
Table 2
Sector numbers and names of commodity and industrial sectors
Sector
number
Sector name
Final
demanda
Sector
number
Sector name
Final
demanda
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
e
no
e
e
e
e
un
un
un
e
un
no
e
un
un
un
un
un
un
un
un
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
no
no
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
no
no
e
e
e
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
64
65
66
67
68
69
70
71
72
73
74
75
76
77
78
79
80
81
82
83
84
85
86
87
88
89
90
91
92
93
94
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
no
e
e
e
e
e
e
no
no
no
un
e
e
e
e
e
un
un
un
un
e
un
e
e
e
no
un
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
e
un
e
un, Unadjustable final demand commodity; no, commodity with no final demand by households.
882
Table 3
Economic and environmental changes from the present state in Japan by each
minimization of environmental burdens (Maximum adjustable range of the household consumption for each commodity is assumed as 10% of the present state)
State items
11
and
Energy
CO2
Waste
NOx
Economy
GDP
Labor
Capital
0.00
0.43
0.00
0.00
0.43
0.00
0.00
0.37
0.00
0.00
0.43
0.00
Environment
Energy
CO2
Waste
NOx
2.37
1.99
1.27
1.10
2.37
1.99
1.27
1.10
1.35
1.08
1.34
0.98
2.37
1.99
1.27
1.10
B AC;
10
12
40
Energy
CO2
Waste
NOx
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
-40
11
16
21
26
31
36
41
46
51
56
61
66
71
76
81
86
91
883
Energy
30
CO2
NOx
Waste
CFD
0.8
20
10
0.6
0
0.4
-10
-20
0.2
-30
1.0
40
0.0
-40
0.23
0.30
0.34
0.36
0.39
0.40
0.44
0.48
0.51
0.61
0.68
0.72
0.83
ec and ei for energy consumption, CO2 emission, waste emission, and NOx emission. For energy consumption and CO2
emission, environmental burden factors or energy intensity
and CO2 emission factors for industrial sectors were estimated
by converting environmental burden factors for commodity
sectors [4]. In terms of waste, emission factors for industrial
sectors, ei, were obtained from Kagawa et al. [5], and those
for commodities were originally determined by using the total
quantity of municipal waste and its composition [6]. For emission factors of NOx, we used impact-based emission factors
expressed as the product of the emission amount and the number of its receptors per unit output [7].
30
Energy
Waste
CFD
CO2
NOx
0.8
20
10
0.6
0
0.4
-10
-20
0.2
-30
-40
0.003
1.0
40
0.0
0.015
0.025
0.029
0.036
0.043
0.049
0.054
0.059
0.069
0.082
0.109
0.131
13
Fig. 1 shows the optimized status of final demand from household for each commodity by respective minimizations of environmental burdens. The x-axis contains the commodity sector
number, and the y-axis represents accumulated values of respective changes in the optimized consumption (h*) from the current
level (h). Commodities can be classified into three types: (1)
a commodity for which optimal demand should be decreased
in all cases of reducing various environmental burdens; (2)
a commodity whose optimal demand should be increased in
all cases; and (3) a commodity whose optimal demand depends
on the type of environmental burden. Among 63 commodities,
47 commodities for which final demand was relaxed are classified as commodity type 1, nine are classified as commodity type
2, and seven are classified as commodity type 3. The type 3
884
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
0.1
10
100
1000
Type 2
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
10
100
1000
10000
commodities, whose optimal demand depends on the type of environmental burden, were petroleum refinery products, forestry,
tobacco, telecommunication, broadcasting, goods rental and
leasing, and administration. But unfortunately, it is difficult to
determine the truly optimal demand state of these commodities
without comprehensive environmental assessment methods for
proper weighting in the model. Accordingly, we focused on
type 1 and 2 commodities here, which contribute to all environmental reduction and economic sustainability factors. In an optimized household consumption system, households should
refrain from consuming type 1 commodities as a means to reduce environmental burdens and could shift the surplus money
raised by the refrainment to consumption of type 2 commodities.
In this study, our model considers only 94 commodity sectors,
however, and does not allow the classification of all commodities existing in Japan. Therefore, we attempted to characterize
commodities by their environmental and economic properties
and discover ways of distinguish the type (1 or 2) a commodity
can be classified into.
To identify the characteristics of type 1 commodities, we
looked into the relationships between the demand change and
primary properties of each commodity. Fig. 2 illustrates the
Type 2
Type 1
1
Type 1
1
Type 1
Type 2
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
0.001
0.01
0.1
10
100
1000
10000 100000
885
4. Conclusions
1
Type 1
Type 2
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
1
10
100
1000
10000
relationship between the optimized states of demand for commodities and their value-added factors (million yen [MY]/
MY). In general, type 1 commodities had small value-added factors: 80% of type 1 commodities can be identified by a valueadded factor of 0.50, as illustrated by the cumulative frequency
in Fig. 2. Most of the type 2 commodities have a value-added
factor above 0.62, whereas type 3 commodities have a valueadded factor above 0.53, making it difficult to distinguish these
two commodity types by their value-added factors.
It is also hard to confirm the specific characteristics of type
1 commodities from the relationship between demand fluctuation and the labor factor (Fig. 3). Compared with value-added
factors, type 2 commodities have a wide dispersion within the
range of labor factors. Thus, it would not be effective to characterize commodity type on the basis of labor factors.
Recently, for instance, from product environmental reports
and case studies of life cycle assessment, it is getting to be relatively easy for us to know an environmental performance value
for a commodity. Figs. 4e7 illustrate the relationship between
the direct environmental burdens imposed by unit production
(MY) of a commodity, which are elements of eiCT, and the frequency of the commodity being considered type 1 or 2. By
grouping the commodities by their direct environmental burden
per unit production, we calculated the ratios of type 1 and 2 commodities to the total commodities in the same range of direct environmental burden per unit production. The frequency of being
classified as a type 1 commodity increased sharply above certain values of direct environment burden per unit production.
For instance, to correctly identify a type 1 commodity with
a frequency of more than 80%, we should focus on commodities whose direct environmental burden per unit production is
more than 10 GJ/MY of energy, more than 100 kg-C/MY of
CO2, more than 100 kg/MY of waste emission, or more than
100 Mt person/MY of NOx impact-based emission.
References
[1] Sonnemann G. Political issues on sustainable consumption. In: Proceedings of the second international workshop on Sustainable Consumption,
Tokyo, Japan; 2003. p. 6e9.
[2] MCAG. 1995 Inputeoutput tables. Tokyo: Management and Coordination
Agency, Government of Japan; 1999 [in Japanese].
[3] Dorfman R, Samuelson AP, Solow MR. Linear programming and economic analysis. New York: Dover; 1987. p. 300.
[4] Nansai K, Moriguchi Y, Tohno S. Compilation and application of Japanese
inventories for energy consumption and air pollutant emissions using
inputeoutput tables. Environmental Science & Technology 2003;37:
2005e15.
[5] Kagawa S, Moriguchi Y, Tachio K. An empirical analysis of industrial
waste embodied in the 1995 Japanese economy. Journal of Applied Inpute
Output Analysis 2003;9:69e92.
[6] JESC. Fact book: waste management and recycling in Japan. Kanagawa:
Japan Environmental Sanitation Center; 2000. p. 95 [in Japanese].
[7] Nansai K, Moriguchi Y, Suzuki N. Site-dependent life-cycle analysis by
the SAME approach: its concept, usefulness, and application to the calculation of embodied impact intensity by means of an input-output analysis.
Environmental Science & Technology 2005;39:7318e28.