Você está na página 1de 12

Stephanie Moulton

Charles Wise
Ohio State University

Shifting Boundaries between the Public and Private Sectors: Senior–Junior


Exchange
Implications from the Economic Crisis

What are the differences between the public and private At the height of the “privatization era,” Wise pointed Stephanie Moulton is an assistant
sectors as well as their interrelationships in light of the out that the fundamental question was not which was professor in the John Glenn School of Public
Affairs at the Ohio State University. Her
recent financial crisis? Has the global economic crisis better, public or private, but rather “what configuration research focuses on the publicness and
fundamentally shifted the boundaries between the two of organizations, public and private, is needed and what performance of nongovernmental organiza-
sectors? This essay examines the nature and extent of the arrangements between them provide the most effective tions engaged in public service, including
nonprofit organizations and organizations
shift. The authors present an analysis of the Troubled relationships to perform the needed functions” (1990, implementing low-income housing policies
Asset Relief Program (TARP) to highlight the massive 142). Too often, policy makers have restructured public and programs.
transformations that are taking place and to introduce organizations and public service programs without E-mail: moulton.23@osu.edu

lessons for future policy initiatives. an adequate conceptualization and understanding of


Charles Wise is founding director of the
the “configuration of organizations impacting public
John Glenn School of Public Affairs at the
Between financial rescue missions and the economic services, and also without considering the modes of Ohio State University. He previously served
stimulus program, government spending accounts for a interaction that the public organizations will have with as managing editor of Public Administra-
tion Review and received the William E.
bigger share of the nation’s economy—26 percent—than significant officials and organizations” (Wise 1990,
Mosher and Frederick C. Mosher Award for
at any time since World War II. The government is 142). Now, the “object” has been turned around—it is best article in PAR three times.
financing 9 out of 10 new mortgages in the United not public services but private goods and services that E-mail: wise.983@osu.edu

States. If you buy a car from General Motors, you are are the central focus. However, the question is quite
buying from a company that is 60 percent owned by the analogous: what is the most effective configuration of
government. If you take out a car loan or run up your public–private organizations to bring about particular
credit card, the chances are good that the government is outcomes in the private economy while still observing
financing both your debt and that of your bank. the requisites of democratic government?

—Edmund Andrews and David Sanger, New York As public administration scholars, it is critical that we
Times, 2009 evaluate the public–private configurations that are em-
ployed, not only for the problem at hand, but also for

W
hile understanding the longer-term reconfiguration
the interrelatedness of the public management sys-
of the public and … what are the key tem. Essentially, what are the key
private sectors has been perhaps considerations that should guide considerations that should guide
one of the most essential and the emerging reconfiguration of the emerging reconfiguration of
enduring challenges for public public and private institutions? public and private institutions?
administration over the past In this analysis, we consider one
few centuries (Bozeman 1987, particular case: the Troubled
2007; Dahl and Lindblom [1953] 1976; Dewey Asset Relief Program (TARP). Though initiated as a
[1927] 1954; Lindblom 1977; Wamsley and Zald series of targeted, short-term public investments of up
1973), recent events in the nation’s economy have to $700 billion in private institutions, TARP inter-
elevated a fundamental questioning and reordering of ventions have resulted in a reconfiguration of public
the relationships between public and private. In the and private institutions with long-term implications.
current economic crisis, lines between the public and This paper proceeds as follows. First, we briefly review
private sectors are rapidly being redrawn through new recent reforms targeting public–private configura-
organizations, policies, programs, and regulations. tions. Then, we present the public interest, economic,
Questions arise about the systemic effects, intended and management dimensions as analytical frames by
and unintended, that ultimately will result from these which to evaluate public–private configurations. Next,
initiatives. we employ the dimensions to evaluate two initiatives
Shifting Boundaries between the Public and Private Sectors 349
in the Troubled Assets Relief Program. Finally, we conclude with Table 1 Core Dimensions and Key Questions
implications for research and practice moving forward. Dimension Question
Public Interest How will the public interest, including substantive public
Background values and democratic accountability, be preserved and
Over the past two decades, the privatization movement has enhanced through this public–private configuration?
(re)defined the relationship between public and private institutions Economic What coordinated inputs between government and the
private sector are necessary to achieve the desired public
in many countries. Privatization refers to a variety of phenomena (and private) outcomes?
in the arrangement of government–business relationships, from Management Is the government capacity and authority in place to
contracting to load shedding (Wise 1990). The emphasis in this initiate, manage, and evaluate the configuration?
movement has been on the superiority of business operations, bring-
ing businesses principles into the operations of government, and/or organizations are public” to some extent (Bozeman 1987). The
turning over areas of government responsibility to private businesses long-term success of public–private configurations in ensuring
altogether. The Grace Commission report presented to Congress democratic governance and achieving desired objectives is contin-
during the Ronald Reagan administration and the National Per- gent on the appropriate balance between overlapping public inter-
formance Review conducted by the Bill Clinton administration est, economic, and management dimensions (Wise 1990). When
both promised greater efficiencies through the integration of mod- there is a shift in the configuration-—such as through the addition,
ern business methods. The George W. Bush administration adopted reduction, or alteration of government authority—it is essential
rules for putting federal jobs up for competition with private firms to reevaluate each dimension. Here we provide key considera-
(OMB 2003). tions under each dimension (with key questions summarized in
table 1), followed by a discussion of the complementary role of the
Recent policies adopted since the onset of the economic crisis have dimensions.
been based on a quite different premise—that business organizations
have failed and that government organizations must be involved Public Interest, Economic, and Management Dimensions
in business operations to curb their excesses, to improve them, to First, because of the extension of government authority, public–pri-
prevent further failures and harm to the public, and to foster greater vate configurations should be aligned with the public interest. The
economic development for the nation as a whole. Other coun- key question from the public interest dimension is, how will the
tries, such as Great Britain, have adopted similar stances. Like the public interest, including substantive public values and democratic
privatization of public organizations, the increasing influence of the accountability, be preserved and enhanced through this public–
public sector on the private sector is not an easily identified strategy. private configuration? Determination of the precise meaning of the
Rather, it comprises diverse instruments or tools of government public interest has long been considered problematic (Dewey [1927]
(Salamon 2002), ranging from the regulation of private sector eco- 1954; Pesch 2008; Shubert 1961), but as Bozeman points out, it
nomic activity or management practices (such as executive compen- continues to carry significant meaning “because legislators continue
sation), to an infusion of public funds (as with the Capital Purchase to make laws citing the ‘public interest,’ regulators continue to regu-
Program), to direct ownership or “takeover” of privately held firms late in the ‘public interest,’ and courts continue to rule in the ‘public
(such as in the auto industry). interest’ (2002, 148). Rather than a clearly defined objective, the
public interest is a normative ideal that includes both substantive
In the short term, certain government interventions may have been values and procedural aspects (Bozeman 2007; Dewey [1927] 1954;
effective in preventing a more severe economic crisis. For example, Wise 2002). Substantive values may be derived from a nation’s
if large U.S. financial institutions and automakers had been al- founding documents, or “fundamental laws” (Bozeman 2002, 2007;
lowed to fail, there is no doubt that the short-term impact on the Jørgensen and Bozeman 2002). In the United States, substantive
economy would have been substantial. This is not to deny that there values include, but are not limited to, such things as civil rights,
is significant debate about the proper role of government in private liberty, limited government, and equal treatment (Jørgensen and
enterprise. That debate is ongoing, and perhaps has been intensified Bozeman 2002; Wise 2002). Procedural aspects of the public inter-
by recent government actions. Nonetheless, rather than engage that est in a democracy seek to enhance democratic accountability by
issue or the short-term effects of government intervention, our point consent of the governed, the responsiveness of public officials to the
of departure is to consider the resulting reconfigurations of pub- governed, and the appropriate use of sovereign power (Bovens 2005;
lic–private institutions and the long-term implications for public Wise 1990; Wise and Freitag 2002).
administration.
Second, the economic dimension of public–
Public–Private Configurations: Public–private configurations private configurations is of critical impor-
Dimensions for Analysis exist wherever government tance. Broadly speaking, the economic dimen-
Public–private configurations exist wherever sion refers to the coordination system for
authority is extended to private
government authority is extended to private producing outputs, or the task environment
firms for the production of outcomes that firms for the production of (Scott 2003; Wamsley and Zald 1973). The
achieve public (as well as private) objectives. outcomes that achieve public question is not whether government should
There are a variety of tools of government (as well as private) objectives. intervene in the private sector, but “[w]hat
action (ranging from regulation to contracts coordinated inputs between government and
to direct ownership) that extend government authority to private the private sector are necessary to achieve the desired public (and
firms (Salamon 2002). Indeed, one might make the case that “all private) outcomes?” Two important considerations help guide the
350 Public Administration Review • May | June 2010
development of this coordinated system: (1) economic assumptions, dimension to ensure that the “means–ends system” selected is work-
or hypothesized relationships between means and ends; and (2) the ing toward publicly desired ends through publicly acceptable (and
“institutions” included directly in and implicated by the configura- accountable) means. Further, without the capacity and authority in
tion and the effects on the broader economic system. While in some place to initiate, manage, and evaluate the configuration, even an
task environments, there is a very clear relationship between inputs appropriately selected economy in line with the public interest will
and outputs, in other, more complex task environments, there may not be sustained and will fail to meet its objectives.
be several, sometimes conflicting hypothesized relationships between
the appropriate means to accomplish desired ends (Scott 2003; Case Study: Troubled Asset Relief Program
Wamsley and Zald 1973). Identifying the operational assumptions The recent economic crisis in the United States has resulted in a
between means and ends thus becomes an important component of myriad of public initiatives and programs to prevent systemic failure
the economic dimension of public–private configurations. Further, of the entire economy. Many of the public initiatives have been
while specific initiatives may be targeted at a specific “set” of firms, targeted at the private sector, resulting in new or revised public–pri-
all firms are part of a larger institutional environment (Scott 2003). vate configurations that have transformed our understanding of
The success of public–private configurations depends in part on the public–private relations. While there are a plethora of case studies
set of institutions that exist in an environment at any given point to consider, perhaps one of the best known public initiatives that
in time and on the ability to coordinate, design, and reform the encompasses many of the complexities of the new configurations is
institutions (Olsen 2006; Przeworski 1997). the Troubled Asset Relief Program. TARP was initiated in October
2008 under the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act (EESA) to
Third, whereas the economic dimension focuses on the coordination purchase, sell, and manage “toxic” assets; however, TARP quickly
system for public–private configurations, the (public) management was refocused to include a much broader purview. A quarterly
dimension refers to the coordination ability of public administra- report from the Special Inspector General for TARP in April 2009
tion. The key question becomes, is the government capacity and au- comments on the magnitude of its coverage: “From programs
thority in place to initiate, manage, and evaluate the configuration? involving large capital infusions into hundreds of banks and other
Public–private configurations require uniquely equipped public financial institutions, to a mortgage modification program designed
management capacity that includes knowledge of and skill with the to modify millions of mortgages, to public/private partnerships
appropriate management tools (Mosher 1980; Salamon 2002), an purchasing ‘toxic’ assets from banks using tremendous leverage pro-
“energetic executive” equipped to carry out ongoing management vided by Government loans or guarantees, TARP has evolved into a
responsibilities (Light 2008), and the authority (and credibility) to program of unprecedented scope, scale, and complexity” (SIGTARP
provide direction and shape outcomes (Koppell 2001; Moe 2001; 2009b).
Moe and Stanton 1989).
Table 2 provides a summary of the $474.70 billion in TARP funds
Public–private configurations are more complex than ideal-type gov- spent on various programs as of November 30, 2009, reported by
ernment institutions that are responsive only to hierarchical political the Congressional Oversight Panel (COP 2009a). Here, we will
controls or ideal-type market-driven firms that are responsive to cus- focus on two of the largest programs under TARP, which together
tomers and, ultimately, to shareholders (Moe 2001; Mosher 1980; represent 59 percent of the total funds allocated to date
Salamon 2002). The combined authority relations in public–private (see figure 1). The largest portion of funds (43 percent) was spent
configurations make strategic behavior on the part of the participat- on the Capital Purchase Program (CPP), which invests in qualified
ing institutions inevitable (Agarwal et al. 2009; Leone 1981; 1986; financial institutions, such as banks and bank holding companies,
Oliver 2008; Shaffer 1995). Government institutions charged with that are viewed as important to stabilizing and growing the U.S.
coordinating such configurations must have the prerequisite capac-
ity and authority to anticipate strategic behavior and make adjust-
Table 2. TARP Disbursements and Commitments as of November 30, 2009
ments as needed in line with the public interest. (Billions of Dollars)

Complementary Role of the Dimensions Program Disbursed Committed

The public interest, economic, and management dimensions are not Capital Purchase Program $204.7 218.0
mutually exclusive; rather, there is substantial overlap between the Targeted Investment Program 40.0 40.0
dimensions that is critical to the success of the configurations (Wise Capital Assistance Program TBD TBD
1990). Under the political economy perspective, market mecha- Systematically Significant Failing Institutions 69.8 69.8
nisms are viewed as a means to achieve publicly desired ends—not Term Asset-Backed Securities Lending Facility 20.0 20.0
as ends in and of themselves (Dahl and Lindblom [1953] 1976; Asset Guarantee Program 5.0 5.0
Lindblom 1977; Wamsley and Zald 1973). In their discussion of Automotive Industry Financing Program 77.6 77.6
the political economy of public administration, Wamsley and Zald Supplier Support Program 3.5 3.5

(1973) point out that there are multiple “economies” that can be Making Home Affordable Program 27.4 50.0
Consumer and Business Lending Initiative 0.0 15.0
selected to transform inputs into outputs; one can think of several
Public Private Investment Program 26.7 30.0
different mechanisms that could be employed, for example, to
Total committed $474.70 $528.90
produce military equipment or to provide food to hungry children.
Total uncommitted N/A 169.80
The selection of the economy (or the means to produce desired
ends) is as much a political decision as an economic decision. In this TOTAL $474.70 $698.70
regard, the public interest dimension complements the economic Source: Congressional Oversight Panel (2009a).

Shifting Boundaries between the Public and Private Sectors 351


from additional capital for lending activity or stability. As of No-
vember 2009, preferred shares and subordinated debentures of 692
financial institutions were purchased for $205 billion, 50 financial
institutions had redeemed their preferred stock, and 30 had also re-
purchased their warrants (U.S. Department of the Treasury 2009e).

The CPP constituted only one component of the federal govern-


ment’s stabilization efforts, which also included programs run by
the Federal Reserve and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
(FDIC). As of December 2009, the Federal Reserve had a maxi-
mum possible exposure of $1.73 trillion, which exposed the Federal
Reserve to potential losses of up to $220.4 billion; the FDIC maxi-
mum possible exposure was $666.7 billion. Altogether, the estimate
of the federal government’s maximum possible exposure was $3.1
Figure 1 TARP Expenditures to Date trillion, including uncommitted TARP funds (COP 2009a, 77).

Public Interest Dimension


economy. Four qualified financial institutions have received nearly The public interest dimension is concerned with preserving and
one-half of the allocations under the CPP to date—Bank of Amer- enhancing both procedural accountability and substantive public
ica, JPMorgan Chase, Wells Fargo, and Citigroup—although more values. Procedurally, from the inception of the CPP, there have been
than 600 institutions have received some amount of funding under questions about the selection of “healthy” firms to receive capital
the CPP (SIGTARP 2009c). Previously, firms had to wait three years infusions (and the disclosure of selection criteria and processes). A
to repay the CPP funds, but revisions to the legislation now permit committee within the Treasury Department reviewed literally thou-
repayment if the firm can demonstrate its financial sustainability.1 sands of applications from banks, savings and loans, insurers, and
The second-largest investment of TARP funds, representing 16 per- others (deemed eligible by their federal regulator) to select finan-
cent of the total invested to date, has occurred through the Automo- cial institutions for funding. Treasury officials did not disclose the
tive Industry Financing Program, namely, to General Motors and criteria used in deciding which institutions were sufficiently healthy
Chrysler. The purpose of the investment is to prevent a shock to the to warrant assistance and which were not, stressing that the process
U.S. financial markets and the economy more broadly that would had to be confidential so that rejected banks did not suffer damage
result from the failure of these large private firms. The other notable in the markets, further harming the financial system (Landler 2008).
expenditures are investments in specific firms, including investments
in AIG under the Systematically Significant Failing Institutions Pro- With regard to implementation, Congress imbued multiple organi-
gram (15 percent of the total) and investments in Citigroup under zations with accountability mandates under TARP: the Special In-
the Targeted Investment Program (8 percent of the total). spector General of the Troubled Assets Relief Program (SIGTARP),
the Government Accountability Office (GAO), the Congressional
The complexity underlying the public– Oversight Panel (COP), and the Financial
private configurations implicated in the The complexity underlying the Stability Oversight Board (FINSOB). The
Capital Purchase Program and Auto Industry public private configurations challenge in getting the accountability bal-
Financing Program is formidable. Unpack- ance right in the Capital Purchase Program
implicated in the Capital
ing this complexity provides important lies in the trade-offs between investing the
considerations not only for the success of Purchase Program [(CAP)] accountability agents (SIGTARP, GAO, COP,
these particular initiatives, but also for future and Auto Industry Financing FINSOB) with sufficient powers to obtain
public–private configurations moving for- Program is formidable. (adequate) information but not overly intru-
ward. Through a review of these two cases, we sive powers that give financial institutions a
highlight some of the issues that are pertinent to the public inter- disincentive to participate, thereby decreasing the chances of restor-
est, economic, and management dimensions. This information is ing financial stability. This trade-off is exemplified by the informa-
then used to derive implications for future research and practice of tion that must be disclosed by the recipients of TARP funds. While
public–private configurations. the Treasury Department has issued several reports and includes
some data on its Web site, SIGTARP and COP have continually
Capital Purchase Program recommended that the Treasury Department collect additional
The primary vehicle under TARP for the stabilization of financial data from TARP recipients on the actual use of funds, a step that is
markets is the Capital Purchase Program. The purpose of the CPP is necessary to meet the Treasury’s stated goal of bringing transparency
to provide additional capital to healthy financial institutions by pur- to the TARP program and informing the American people and their
chasing preferred shares of the financial institutions in exchange for representatives in Congress about what is being done with their
dividends and warrants. By increasing the capital base of the healthy money (SIGTARP 2009c, 8). The Treasury Department rejected
institutions, the institutions should have increased capacity to lend the recommendation, and claimed that the exact use of federal aid
to businesses and consumers, thereby stimulating the economy. The cannot be tracked because “money in a bank is like water poured
CPP could invest up to $250 billion in viable financial institutions into an ocean” (Appelbaum 2009). The GAO also has continually
(recommended by their federal regulator), which would benefit found that the Treasury has not developed “a means of regularly
352 Public Administration Review • May | June 2010
and routinely communicating its activities to relevant congressional of 1946 (15 U.S.C. sec. 1021), the federal government has assumed
committees, members of the public, and other critical stakeholders” the responsibility for economic stability of the country.2 A primary
(GAO 2009d), speaking directly to the procedural public interest rationale for the Capital Purchase Program was to head off the sys-
function of democratic control. temic failure of the credit markets and the collapse of the financial
system, which was projected to lead to a serious price deflation and
In addition to procedural accountability to the public interest, resultant depression in the economy. The president, the Secretary
substantive public interest concerns have been raised regarding the of the Treasury, and the head of the Federal Reserve all claimed that
executive compensation policies of CPP (and other TARP) recipi- capital support to private financial institutions was needed to pre-
ents. Ignited by outrage over the $165 million in AIG retention bo- vent these results and to restore growth in the capital markets.
nuses (Cooper 2009), focus on executive compensation has been a
central component of TARP. According to Section 111 of the EESA, Under the CPP, the government’s intent is to restore financial activ-
“TARP Recipients [may] not have pay packages that promote exces- ity in the market by directly investing money (in the form of capi-
sive risk” (P.L. 110-343 Division A, codified as 12 U.S.C. 5221). tal) in financial institutions. “The program is designed to generate
Since 2008, most all iterations of TARP have included provisions a positive return to the taxpayer while strengthening the backbone
related to executive compensation. The Interim Final Rule on TARP of and providing confidence in our nation’s financial system” (U.S.
Standards for Compensation and Corporate Governance, issued by Department of the Treasury 2009f ). Before exiting the program and
the Treasury Department on June 10, 2009, stipulated an annual repaying government, financial institutions have to demonstrate
compensation limit of $500,000, in addition to limits on bonus that they are well capitalized through nongovernmental sources.
and incentive compensation, until TARP funds are repaid. Further, The success of the CPP is dependent on at least three economic
a special master (Kenneth Feinberg) was appointed by Treasury Sec- assumptions: that selecting financial institutions for capital infusion
retary Timothy Geithner to formally review compensation packages will indeed increase lending activity and signal legitimacy/stability
at TARP-assisted firms (U.S. Department of the Treasury 2009b), to private market participants, that the taxpayer funds will be paid
thereby increasing perceived public accountability. back with a return on the investment, and that financial institutions
will remain in the program until they are healthy enough to gener-
For CPP recipients, issues of executive compensation limits are ate and sustain private capital and lending activity. If any of these
particularly troubling. Many of the rationales for reform are tied three assumptions is miscalculated, the CPP may be ineffective.
to the assumption that executive compensation practices are linked
to the performance of a firm (Bebchuck and Fried 2003; Bebchuk The success of the CPP is also influenced by dynamic factors outside
and Spamann 2010), and to allegations that previous compensa- of direct government control. For example, the market may respond
tion policies within financial institutions led to the type of excessive in unexpected ways to the capital infusions by government into finan-
risk taking that lies at the very heart of the financial crisis (CNBC cial institutions. “While government intervention has the potential
2009). However, because executive compensation restrictions are to stabilize the system by shoring up bank capital, it can also risk
limited to those firms receiving TARP subsidies, and because the further scaring away private capital by creating new forms of risk
restrictions are lifted when TARP funds are repaid under the CPP, and uncertainty” (COP 2009c, 7). This risk is largely attributable to
the long-term public interest in reforming executive compensation the propensity of government to pay below-market prices for assets.
may not be substantively addressed (Bhagat and Romano 2009). Indeed, although the government is being repaid and earning a de-
cent return on its investment (estimates at the end of August total $4
In summary, both procedural and substantive public interests under- billion repaid at an equivalent of 15 percent annually), some financial
lying the CPP have been a motivating force, but have yet to be fully experts say that the Treasury paid too much for the assets, and could
realized. In the first days, the Treasury Department shifted from its have earned three times the amount of return (COP 2009b, 2).
stated intent to purchase “toxic assets” to direct investment. It did
not disclose its decision criteria for selected institutions to receive as- Numerous other institutions—independent of the CPP—also
sistance, and it has been criticized by the oversight agencies for failing drive the success (or failure) of the market. As the GAO has noted,
to track the uses of TARP funds. Further, while there are substantive isolating and estimating the effect of the CPP (and other TARP
public interests driving executive compensation reforms for assisted programs) includes discerning the influence of other large capital
firms, the adopted reforms, which apply only to assisted firms par- infusion programs initiated separately by the Federal Reserve, and
ticipating in the CPP, are more likely to result in strategic behavior the dynamics of world markets and money flows. In June 2009, the
on the part of firms (to pay off the TARP funds before they are truly GAO noted that indicators of risk in credit markets had improved
healthy) than in the substantive achievement of the public interest. since March, although the cost of credit had risen in some markets
Treasury officials have asserted that the nature and demands of the (GAO 2009b, 68; 2009c). However, determining the role that the
financial markets and the need to adapt to such markets have deter- CPP played in this, as one of several interdependent institutional
mined their actions. Such conflicts illustrate the difficulty of striking influences, is extremely difficult.
the right balance between the requisites of democratic control, public
values, and executive evaluation of market conditions and dynamics. The COP concluded that while TARP’s effects are impossible to iso-
late, the consensus is that TARP was an important part of a broader
Economic Dimension government strategy that stabilized the U.S. financial system by re-
The economic dimension is concerned with the coordinated inputs newing the flow of credit and averting a more acute crisis. However,
between government and the private sector necessary to achieve the COP also stated, “It is apparent that after fourteen months the
desired public outcomes. Since passage of the Full Employment Act TARP’s programs have not been able to solve many of the ongoing
Shifting Boundaries between the Public and Private Sectors 353
problems Congress identified. Credit availability, the lifeblood of implementation and oversight bodies were instituted, and the
the economy, remains low. In light of the weak economy, banks acquisition of sufficient expertise to manage a complex and shifting
remain reluctant to lend, while small businesses and consumers are investment program. The first decision for policy makers is whether
reluctant to borrow. In addition, questions remain about the capital- to assign the new responsibility to an existing organization or to cre-
ization of many banks, and whether they are focusing on repairing ate a new organization; generally, policy makers favor the creation of
their balance sheets at the expense of lending” (COP 2009a, 112). a new, “less rigid” organization (Johnson 1990; Wise 2002).4 In the
The panel also found that bank failures continue at a nearly unprec- case of the CPP, the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008
edented rate, toxic assets remain on the balance sheets of many large mandated that an Office of Financial Stability (OFS) be established
banks, and the foreclosure crisis continues to grow (COP 2009a, 5). within the Treasury Department to administer the funds appropri-
ated under the act, a hybrid between the old and new.
With regard to the goal of recouping taxpayer money, by the end of
2009, financial institutions that had received CPP funds had paid In effect, the Treasury Department was required to create a new
back $164 billion. Financial institutions still owing the government organization that immediately had to distribute hundreds of billions
money included Citigroup, to which the government had provided of dollars, somewhat like building an airplane while flying it. The
$45 billion, of which $25 billion was provided in exchange for financial stability effort was put into place by appointing an interim
common stock, making the federal government the largest single assistant secretary for financial stability and other interim officials.
shareholder with 36 percent of shares. Toward the end of 2009, Coming in the last days of an outgoing presidential administration,
TARP realized its first direct losses of $2.63 billion as a result of the appointment of permanent officials who would bear continu-
failures of three financial institutions. In addition, 38 banks have ing responsibility for the program was not realistic. The slowness
missed dividend payments, and six others have deferred dividends of the political appointments and confirmation processes further
(COP 2009a, 31). The COP observed, “In addition to costing tax- constrained the capacity of the Treasury Department to provide
payers, the recent bank failures call into question Treasury’s assertion political and policy leadership for the program at the departmental
that CPP funds were only available to ‘healthy’ or ‘viable’ banks” level.5 As a result, the major policy decisions involved in the CPP,
(2009a, 31). The Special Inspector General provided additional cor- as well as the numerous other programs, were made by the Treasury
roboration through his audit, which found that “Treasury and other Secretary and a group of unofficial senior advisors who had not been
regulators’ descriptions of the financial conditions of the first nine appointed by the president or confirmed by the Senate (Andrews
institutions as ‘healthy’ were inconsistent with the private beliefs and Labaton 2009). Sheila Baird, chair of the FDIC, observed,
of decision makers at Treasury and the Federal Reserve, and later “There are a couple of go to people trying to do five different jobs. I
proved to be inaccurate” (SIGTARP 2009d, 8).3 do think that’s a real issue . . . I think being unable to get their own
people has hampered their ability” (Cho 2009).
In summary, the Capital Purchase Program may have contributed to
averting an acute financial crisis, but the jury is still out on whether The Treasury Department also faced a number of challenges in hiring
it can sufficiently increase lending activity, how much return on professionals with sufficient expertise to staff the OFS and oversee the
investment taxpayers will receive, and whether financial institu- CPP (GAO 2009b, 2009c).6 Because of the skills needed to manage
tions were kept in the program for a sufficient amount of time to a complex investment program such as the CPP, candidates who had
generate and sustain healthy lending activity. the right skills often worked for a financial
While several banks have paid back their CPP A noteworthy issue in any new regulator that could offer a more competitive
funds, the largest bank, Citibank, has not. At government initiative, including salary than the OFS (GAO 2009b, 2009c).
this time, it remains uncertain whether those Conflict of interest considerations increased
the CPP, is whether the focal
banks exiting the program are really “healthy” the time needed to recruit and hire personnel
enough to withstand further economic tur- government agency has the for the OFS and, in some cases, caused quali-
moil or to increase their lending to businesses management capacity to achieve fied individuals to withdraw from consider-
and home owners (or whether their exit is the desired impact. . . . In the ation. To supplement the efforts of the profes-
simply strategic to reduce public interference, case of the CPP, the Emergency sional staff, the Treasury Department turned to
as with executive compensation practices). The Economic Stabilization Act contractors, and by June 1, 2009, it had com-
federal government’s leverage, while substan- pleted 40 TARP financial agency agreements,
of 2008 mandated that . . .
tial, is not controlling and must be assessed contracts, and blanket purchase agreements
within a system in which trillions of dollars [a new agency] be established (GAO 2009b, 2009c). Of course, employing
are circulating according to the actions of a within the Treasury Department private sector contractors to be involved with
myriad of institutions—hedge funds, sover- to administer the funds. . . . In activities that fund and regulate other private
eign wealth funds, and government lenders. effect, the Treasury Department sector organizations poses potential conflicts of
was required to create a new interest, a matter of significant concern to the
Management Dimension oversight agencies (GAO 2009b, 2009c).
organization that immediately
A noteworthy issue in any new government
initiative, including the CPP, is whether the had to distribute hundreds of In summary, an assessment of the apparatus
focal government agency has the manage- billions of dollars, somewhat within the federal government to manage a
ment capacity to achieve the desired impact. like building an airplane while program as large and unprecedented as the
The primary management issues with the flying it. CPP reveals significant management capacity
CPP relate to the speed with which the issues, including the extremely short time to
354 Public Administration Review • May | June 2010
establish a new organization and to secure sufficient personnel with Another substantive public interest issue lies in the public objectives
the requisite expertise to manage the program. The program has of the government in investing in these two companies. The COP
been largely managed on an ad hoc basis, with insufficient staff and found that the Treasury Department’s public statements cited differ-
many staff assigned on a temporary basis. The establishment of man- ent objectives at various times and had not clarified them, making
agement systems and authority relationships is an ongoing process. it difficult to evaluate the success of the AIFP (COP 2009d).9 The
panel recommended that the Treasury Department clarify its policy
Automotive Industry Financing Program objectives, reasonable expectations, and the implications of these
Beginning in late 2008, the U.S. Treasury launched the Automotive policy decisions in the automotive bailouts, and that if the objec-
Industry Financing Program (AIFP) to prevent a catastrophic failure tives included more than the rescue of the two companies but also
of two of the largest U.S. automakers.7 Such a failure was expected other aims such as environmental improvement, support for pen-
to cause “systemic risk” to market stability and the economy at large sion obligations, or continued employment, the department should
(U.S. Department of the Treasury 2009a). Specifically, the Treasury make that clear and provide transparency on the costs of such objec-
Department provided $79 billion in loans and equity investments to tives (COP 2009d, 112).
General Motors (and its lending arm, GMAC) and Chrysler (and its
lending arm, Chrysler Financial) by November 30, 2009, resulting in Procedurally, potential for conflicts of interest exists by virtue of
government ownership of 61 percent of General Motors and 10 per- the government’s dual ownership and regulator roles in the two
cent of Chrysler (COP 2009a, 71). As a result of their participation companies. Can the government safeguard the public interests as
in the AIFP, both companies have taken on a government-advised a regulator, and ensure the viability of the firm as an owner? The
restructuring program and adhere to “rigorous standards” to protect COP pointed out that most courts have found that the controlling
taxpayer interests (U.S. Department of the Treasury 2009a). GMAC, shareholder has a fiduciary duty to the corporation, but that the
to which the Treasury Department originally committed $12.5 bil- pursuit of public policy objectives using an investee corporation
lion in AIFP funds, received an additional $3.8 billion at the end of could violate these duties. Even under the best of intentions, the
December 2009, making the federal government the majority stock- potential for conflict exists, and the longer the government plays
holder with 56 percent of shares. As a result of the increase in owner- the role of both regulator and regulated, the greater the opportunity
ship, the Treasury Department will appoint four of the nine members for a conflict to occur (COP 2009d). The panel pointed out that
of GMAC’s board (U.S. Department of the Treasury 2009c). a further complicating factor is the risk of political interference in
government-owned entities. The risk was realized when Congress
Public Interest Dimension passed legislation to give arbitration rights more than 2,000 auto
The public interest dimension, including both substantive and pro- dealers whose franchises had been withdrawn by General Motors
cedural components, is critical in the AIFP. First, based on author- and Chrysler in moves to cut costs and reorganize their sales. The
izing statutes, there is some question as to whether the expenditure legislation allows dealers to have their cases considered by an arbitra-
of TARP funds through the AIFP is legitimate. The EESA does not tor, who can make a binding decision to reinstate the franchise.
explicitly state that TARP is available to provide assistance to the The interest of the dealers seeking to have their franchises restored
automotive industry or to any specific industry except the financial likely conflicts with the viability interests of the auto companies and
and banking industry.8 When asked before the House Financial the government, and could also conflict with other private interests
Services Committee about auto companies and TARP, Treasury (competitors) that in many cases benefit from rejected franchises
Secretary Henry Paulson testified, “I don’t see [preventing the failure (Wilson and Roland 2009).
of one or more auto companies] as the purpose of TARP. Congress
passed legislation that dealt with the financial system’s stability” Thus, in summary, the Auto Industry Financing Program reveals
(2008, 18–19). In fact, the House of Representatives passed a significant issues related to the public interest dimension, beginning
specific bill to appropriate $14 billion for the auto companies, but with the decision to use TARP funds to purchase stakes in and lend
the bill was defeated in the Senate. At that point, the administration to automobile companies in the first place. The legality of this re-
reversed its position and claimed that EESA’s definition of “financial mains in question. The issue of what public objectives are being pur-
institution” was broad enough to include automotive companies, sued in the implementation of the program also remains. The issue
whose failures “would pose a systemic risk to financial market stabil- of what special interests will be able to influence decisions affecting
ity and have a negative effect on the economy of the United States” the companies remains. Procedurally, conflicts of accountability arise
(U.S. Department of the Treasury 2009d). between the dual role of government as both owner and regulator.

Both constitutional and statutory issues potentially arise from Economic Dimension
the use of TARP funds under the AIFP. The COP concluded that The public–private configurations in the AIFP have critical eco-
“[w]hile Treasury (and President Bush) have made various state- nomic dimensions that will largely determine the success (or failure)
ments regarding their interpretations of the statute and the au- of the entire intervention. In December 2008, the Treasury De-
thority to use TARP in this way, it is not clear that any of these partment issued “bridge loans” to General Motors and Chrysler
statements is sufficient to qualify as speaking with the force of law, totaling $22.9 billion, with the caveat that the auto companies
especially since there has not been one coherent statement but a mix would present restructuring plans to the Treasury in February.
of court filings, oral argument, and statements by Treasury officials” After reviewing the plans, the Treasury Department deemed that
(COP 2009d, 77). The panel recommended that “Treasury provide the companies needed to undergo serious restructuring (eventually
a legal opinion justifying the use of TARP funds for the automotive initiated through bankruptcy) before they could be on a financially
bailouts” (COP 2009d, 115). viable path and thereby receive additional federal dollars (GAO
Shifting Boundaries between the Public and Private Sectors 355
2009d). A series of economic assumptions underlie the probability to manage the federal government’s investment in General Motors
of the AIFP’s success: that the challenges for achieving “financial and Chrysler, the president created an interagency structure, the
viability” can be appropriately identified, that these challenges can Presidential Task Force on the Auto Industry, co-chaired by the
be overcome through restructuring and federal investment, and that secretary of the treasury and the director of the National Economic
the actions taken by the government to help restructure General Council and including four other cabinet secretaries, as well as the
Motors and Chrysler—if successful—will have a positive net effect directors of the Office of Management and Budget, the Environ-
on the auto industry and the economy. mental Protection Agency, and the White House Office of Energy
and Climate Change and 10 other staff of various White House
In an April 2009 report on the AIFP prior to the restructuring, the and departmental entities. In addition, he named two advisors (Ron
GAO noted several challenges facing General Motors and Chrysler Bloom, a former investment banker and advisor to the president
that, though perhaps beyond their control, will impede the effort to of the United Steelworkers, and Steven Ratner, the cofounder of a
achieve financial viability. These include weak economic conditions, private equity firm) to lead the now-defunct Treasury Department
frozen credit markets, the solvency of suppliers, the costs of devel- “auto team,” which had responsibility for evaluating the companies’
oping advanced technology vehicles, reductions in the number of viability plans and negotiating terms of assistance.11
dealerships to align with sales volumes, uncertainty over future fuel
economy standards, and debt reduction (GAO 2009d). Any one of Before disbanding, the auto team noted dual roles for the govern-
these factors might be considered a formidable challenge. Develop- ment’s management strategy in the AIFP: (1) to avoid intervening
ing the appropriate restructuring package to meet these challenges in day-to-day corporate management and refrain from becoming
(and others not anticipated) through “planned interventions” rather involved in specific business decisions, as its role was not to manage
than market processes is daunting. but to serve as a “potential investor of taxpayer resources” with the
goal of promoting “strong and viable companies” (Bloom 2009a);
Further, assuming that General Motors and Chrysler emerge— and (2) to “behave in a commercial manner” (Bloom 2009b). The
which is questionable—what is the intended objective with auto team made conflicting statements about how the Treasury
regard to the larger economy? The ultimate “public end” pur- Department would fulfill the first role—not intervening in day-
sued by the configuration should not be firm specific, but rather to-day management. On the one hand, the Treasury Department
should benefit the economy at large. The market share trend line stated that it would manage its shares in a “hands-off manner,”
for domestic automakers is steadily decreasing (GAO 2009a).10 voting only on core governance issues, including the selection of
By buying shares in only General Motors and Chrysler, it would directors and other major corporate actions and transactions (Bloom
appear that the government is trying to turn the domestic auto- 2009a, 9). On the other hand, the team stated that in order to cre-
maker sales trend line upward—essentially reshaping the market. ate conditions most likely to lead to sustained viability for General
Thus, a successful General Motors and Chrysler emerging from Motors and Chrysler, it was necessary to change the culture within
this crisis would indicate a reallocation of market share from auto the companies (Maynard 2009). The COP questioned this more
companies not receiving federal intervention toward the reconfig- involved management strategy: “The lingering issue is whether the
ured General Motors and Chrysler. Several questions are raised by government can really change the culture of these companies and
this attempt. Is it within the capacity of government to reshape help improve their profitability while it remains a (supposedly)
such a large market by making selective investments? What are disinterested shareholder with a ‘hands-off’ approach to manag-
the criteria for making such investments, other than firms that are ing its investment” (COP 2009d, 83). The panel opined that if the
on the verge of failing? Should other domestic producers (such as government intends to be a silent partner, then it remains to be seen
Ford) receive compensation if they lose market share as a result how it intends to protect the interests of the taxpayers as sharehold-
of government action? This broader industry perspective must be ers (COP 2009d, 83).
taken into account when configuring and evaluating the political
authority interventions. In examining the Treasury’s intent to “behave in a commercial
manner,” the COP found that the department’s performance in
In summary, the economic viability of the two auto firms receiving protecting the interests of taxpayers in the support of auto compa-
direct government support is still uncertain. Their survival will de- nies is somewhat mixed. On one hand, the department negotiated
pend on numerous factors, many of which are not subject to leverage aggressively in the transactions, demanded significant concessions
by the federal government. Beyond viability is the issue of what the from the other stakeholders, and protected taxpayers as if it were a
federal government is attempting to achieve in the U.S. automobile private sector investor. On the other hand, the COP found that the
market as a whole. Can and should the federal government realign decision to enter into the transactions in the first place suffered from
market share in the transportation sector? The a lack of transparency (COP 2009d, 111).
impacts of the attempt will be revealed regard- The management dimension is The panel also observed that the longer the
less of whether the companies survive. concerned with the capacity and Treasury Department lingers on the decisions
of management, the greater the opportunity
Management Dimension
authority to not only initiate a that such decisions could become politicized
The management dimension is concerned public–private configuration, (COP 2009d).
with the capacity and authority not only to but also to manage and evaluate
initiate a public–private configuration, but that configuration toward the In addition to concerns about day-to-day
also to manage and evaluate that configura- desired outcomes. management, there are substantial challenges
tion toward the desired outcomes. In order with evaluating the success of the AIFP. As
356 Public Administration Review • May | June 2010
noted in the public interest dimension, the primary objectives and to implement the initiatives. Typically, the notion of “popular
the strategy for pursuing them are not clearly stated under the AIFP, control” implies that programs are executed by agencies based on
making it difficult to evaluate “success” (COP 2009d). The most authority granted by Congress. However, in large part, the Treasury
clearly communicated objective was perhaps expressed by the leader Department has been responsible for not only defining but also
of the now-defunct auto team, who stated that the primary metric redefining its own authority to intervene on behalf of the “public
for success of TARP investments (in General Motors and Chrysler) interest.”
is whether taxpayers see a return of their money (Bloom 2009a).
However, the COP found that “there are significant obstacles to the This is further complicated by a lack of transparency, reducing the
two companies’ ever achieving the level of profitability that would accountability of both the public agencies and the private partici-
permit the return of all the taxpayer funds expended, and Treasury’s pants. And, perhaps more perplexing, even if there is some degree
best estimates are that some significant portion of those funds will of accountability (through reporting on observable indicators),
never be recovered” (2009d, 110). Thus, while measurable, a return the bigger question is, accountable to whom and for what? Whose
of taxpayer money clearly was not the primary objective for the interests—shareholders, taxpayers, businesses—is the government
AIFP initially. responsible to protect, when all are so tightly interrelated? What
defines a successful outcome in the public interest, when there are
The loan agreements that the Treasury Department executed with competing “publics” and competing interests?
the companies stated that the funding should be used to enable the
automakers to develop a viable and competitive business and to Second, public–private configurations are based on a set of economic
develop the capacity to produce energy-efficient advanced technol- assumptions about how government action will affect market dynamics.
ogy vehicles, among other things. However, the GAO found that These assumptions must be made explicit and open to continuous review
the goals stated in the loan agreements included concepts that and evaluation to ensure that the intended consequences are maximized
were not defined, such as rationalized manufacturing capacity and and the unintended consequences are minimized. With regard to
competitive product mix. The GAO also found that in addition to TARP, the two cases demonstrate substantial variation in the
lacking clear definitions, some of the Treasury’s goals may work at explicability and accessibility of the underlying assumptions. For
cross-purposes and require an assessment of the relevant trade-offs the CPP, there is an underlying logic linking capital infusions with
among the goals. Mirroring the findings of the COP, the GAO increased lending activity, thereby stabilizing (and stimulating) the
concluded that it will be important for the Treasury Department economy at large. Regardless of whether one agrees with the logic
to clearly articulate what it intends to achieve with this assistance and its assumptions, they are relatively explicit, and thus open to
(GAO 2009a). evaluation. In the case of the auto industry, on the other hand, the
underlying logic might be that intervention is necessary to prevent
In summary, major management challenges, particularly related to systemic failure; however, this logic does not lend itself to evalu-
the objectives of the strategies and the metrics for assessing prog- ation. What is success and what is failure? Is success based on the
ress, still remain before the implementing agency. As discussed, the lack of “failure” of the two firms targeted for the intervention, or the
goals of the program have not been clarified and potentially conflict success of the auto industry as a whole, including the competitors of
with one another. The strategy for pursuing the government’s the two assisted agencies?
goals—both remaining “hands off” and behaving in a “commercial
manner”—are likewise potentially conflicting. Politicization has Indeed, in public–private configurations, public managers must
already occurred as Congress has legislated over dealer closures, and monitor the impact not only on the targeted firm engaged in the
that decision sets the precedent for further potential politicization of configuration, but also on the larger economy that will be affected
management decisions. by the intervention. Organizations operate as part of a larger orga-
nizational field, and they respond to incentives and disincentives
Conclusions: Implications for Practice and Research created by other participants in the field. To the extent that govern-
It has become commonplace to refer to the “blurring” of the public ment extends its authority to shape the direction of a particular
and private sectors. Indeed, private actors frequently are relied on to firm’s success (or failure), it reshapes the success (or failure) of other
provide public services, and, as demonstrated by the recent econom- market participants and the economy as a whole.
ic crisis, public actors are relied on to ensure functioning private
markets. The idea of a strict dichotomy between sectors is more of Finally, public–private configurations require the requisite capacity of
a “straw man” than a reality. However, rather than “blurring” into government—both organizational and human resource capacity—to
a homogenous, autonomous entity, these public–private configura- initiate, implement, and monitor the configuration toward the intended
tions have critical dimensions that require continuous monitoring impact. As demonstrated through the TARP cases, this requires
and shaping. clear identification of agencies with specific responsibilities, to be ex-
ecuted in line with clearly defined objectives and strategies. In each
First, these configurations, endowed with varying degrees of “political of the cases, a reoccurring challenge is the multiplexity of imple-
authority” through formal institutions of government, have a respon- mentation “actors” with varying degrees of capacity and authority.
sibility to act in the public interest, both substantively serving public From injecting capital into financial institutions to taking on the
values and procedurally being democratically accountable to the public. ownership and risk of large auto companies, a first and essential task
In the case of TARP, the challenges in fulfilling this public interest is to ensure that the team on the ground is equipped with skilled
responsibility are significant. Many of the initiatives under TARP players and a game plan. Both seem to be lacking to varying degrees
have been broadly defined, with even broader executive discretion across the TARP initiatives.
Shifting Boundaries between the Public and Private Sectors 357
A further challenge is matching the strategies 4. Legislators often have a bias toward creating new
and capacities of government with the strate- A . . . challenge is matching organizations under the supposition that the new or-
gies and capacities of the private participants. the strategies and capacities of ganization will pursue the stated program objectives
Private corporations are skilled at harness- with greater vigor than would an existing organiza-
government with the strategies
ing the “tools” of government to create new tion. Often, however, hopes for new agencies are
and capacities of the private soon eclipsed by the realities of organizational life
private strategies and competitive advantage
in the market. The capacity of government,
participants. in government. Start-up times and costs are often
therefore, must be “nimble” enough to predict greater than proponents foresee, and the lack of ex-
and respond to strategic behavior, while still operating under clear perience, expertise, and learning leads to a struggle rather than aggressive pursuit
lines of accountability to the public. The implications of the shifting of policy priorities.
boundaries between the public and private sectors are both retro- 5. By the middle of March 2009, every key political appointee position, with the
spective and prospective. Retrospectively, policy makers, public exception of Secretary Geithner, was either vacant or awaiting confirmation.
managers, and analysts need to monitor and adjust programs such By September 2009, almost a full year after the program’s inception, only 13 of
as those in TARP that are already being implemented to ensure 33 Treasury appointees had been sent to the Senate for confirmation, and only
realignment with public interest, economic, and management seven had been confirmed (White House Transition Project n.d.).
dimensions. Prospectively, policy managers, public managers, and 6. The program had a staff of 48 (only five of whom were permanent staff) as of
analysts need to evaluate the new programs and organizations being November 21, 2008, which grew to 90 (38 permanent staff) by January 26,
proposed that further alter public–private configurations that affect 2009, and 166 (137 permanent staff) by June 2009 (GAO 2009b, 2009c). The
major sectors of the economy. Treasury Department estimated that it would need 225 full-time employees to
operate the OFS at full capacity (GAO 2009b).
While the degree of increased involvement by the federal govern- 7. In addition to the AIFP, TARP also includes allocations to support auto suppliers
ment in the management of private firms by means of TARP is (Auto Supplier Support Program) and automobile warranties (Auto Warranty
substantial and perhaps unprecedented, the readjustment of the Commitment Program). These additional allocations total less than $6 billion.
boundaries between the public and private sectors is by no means The primary focus of this case study is the AIFP.
over. A myriad of proposals are before Congress with the avowed 8. The EESA states, “The Secretary is authorized to . . . purchase, and to
purpose of ensuring that the problems experienced in the economic make and fund commitments to purchase, troubled assets from any financial
crisis do not happen again. Whether they are suited to the task institution, on such terms and conditions as are determined by the Secretary,
should be the subject of careful analysis and debate. Careful analysis and in accordance with this Act, and the policies and procedures developed
of the public interest, economic, and management dimensions will and published by the Secretary” (sec. 101[a][1]). A financial institution is
need to be conducted to guide those deliberations. Lessons learned defined as “[a]ny institution, including, but not limited to, any bank, savings
from the public–private configurations implicated by initiatives such association, credit union, security broker or dealer, insurance company”
as TARP can help inform these future decisions. (sec. 3[5]).
9. The panel stated, “Treasury must be clearer, more transparent, and more
Acknowledgments accountable in its TARP dealings, providing the American people with the
The authors wish to thank Matthew Potoski and the participants information needed to determine the effectiveness of Treasury’s efforts” (COP
at the 2009 Public Management Research Association Conference 2009d, 5).
for their helpful comments, critiques and suggestions on an earlier 10. The overall market for autos decreased from 16.1 million in 2007 to 10.6 mil-
draft. Any conclusions or errors are solely those of the authors. lion in 2009. However, the domestic companies’ market share has been declining
for several years. For example, General Motors’ market share fell from 27.2
Notes percent in 2004 to 22.1 percent in 2008 (GAO 2009a).
1. Further, the largest firms (18 large bank holding companies) were evaluated un- 11. The auto team was to report to the Task Force and its co-chairs, who then would
der the Capital Assistance Program to determine whether they had sufficient capi- report to the president. The Treasury’s auto team, which was actively involved
tal to withstand upcoming economic events (referred to as “stress tests.” From this in recruiting many of the new directors who now sit on the new boards of
evaluation, 10 firms were identified that need an additional $75 billion in capital General Motors and Chrysler and articulated the goals, objectives, and manage-
to bring them to financial health. This additional capital may come through ment strategy of the government’s involvement with the two companies, was
private or public funding under the Capital Assistance Program. As of July 2009, disbanded during the summer of 2009. Given that these were temporary (and
6 of the 10 firms had already raised the additional needed capital through private unconfirmed) officials, it is unclear what staying power attaches to their articu-
channels. Other firms had until November 2009 to raise additional capital. lated positions. Nonetheless, the statements of the leaders of this team constitute
2. The act encourages the federal government to promote maximum employment, the government’s statements about strategy.
production, and purchasing power. Its mandates were reinforced by the Full
Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978. The imperatives of these acts References
no doubt infused the perceived need for the government to act when the finan- Agarwal, Rajshree, Jay B. Barney, Nicolai J. Foss, and Peter G. Klein. 2009. Hetero-
cial crisis began. geneous Resources and the Financial Crisis: Implications of Strategic Manage-
3. The Special Inspector General pointed to the consequences of the mischaracter- ment Theory. Strategic Organization 7(4): 467–84.
ization of the banks as healthy: “In addition to the basic transparency concern, Andrews, Edmund L., and Stephen Labaton. 2009. Geithner, with Few Aides, Is
that this inconsistency raises, by expressly stating that the ‘healthy’ institutions Scrambling. New York Times, March 8.
would be able to increase overall lending, Treasury created unrealistic expecta- Appelbaum, Binyamin. 2009. Obama Defends Financial Overhaul: Fault Lines
tions about the institution’s conditions and their ability to increase lending” Emerge as Industry Groups Blast Plan to Create Consumer Agency. Washington
(SIGTARP 2009a, 30). Post, June 18.

358 Public Administration Review • May | June 2010


Bebchuk, Lucian A., and Jesse M. Fried. 2003. Executive Compensation as an Agency Problem. Journal of Economic Perspectives 17(3): 71–92.
Bebchuk, Lucian A., and Holger Spamann. 2010. Regulating Bankers’ Pay. Georgetown Law Journal 98(2): 247–87.
Bhagat, Sanjai, and Roberta Romano. 2009. Reforming Executive Compensation: Focusing and Committing to the Long Term. Law and Economics Research Paper no. 374,
Yale University. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1336978## [accessed February 8, 2010].
Bloom, Ron. 2009a. Testimony before the Congressional Oversight Panel regarding the Treasury’s Automotive Industry Financing Program. 111th Cong., 1st sess., July 27.
http://cop.senate.gov/documents/testimony-072709-bloom.pdf [accessed February 8, 2010].
———. 2009b. Testimony before the Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs. The State of the Domestic Automotive Industry: Impact of Federal Assistance.
111th Cong., 1st sess., June 10.
Bovens, Mark. 2005. Public Accountability. In The Oxford Handbook of Public Management, ed. Ewan Ferlie, Laurence E. Lynn, Jr., and Christopher Pollitt, 182–208. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Bozeman, Barry. 1987. All Organizations Are Public: Bridging Public and Private Organizational Theories. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
———. 2002. Public Value Failure: When Efficient Markets May Not Do. Public Administration Review 62(2): 145–61.
———. 2007. Public Values and Public Interest: Counterbalancing Economic Individualism. Washington, DC: Georgetown University Press.
Cho, David. 2009. Staffing Shortage Hinders Treasury’s Progress. Washington Post, March 10.
CNBC. 2009. Wall Street Compensation Must Be Fixed: Summers. September 18.
Congressional Oversight Panel (COP). 2009a. December Oversight Report: Taking Stock: What Has the Troubled Asset Relief Program Achieved?
http://cop.senate.gov/documents/cop-120909-report.pdf [accessed February 8, 2010].
———. 2009b. February Oversight Report: Valuing Treasury’s Acquisitions. http://cop.senate.gov/documents/cop-020609-report.pdf [accessed February 8, 2010].
———. 2009c. June Oversight Report: Stress Testing and Shoring Up Bank Capital. http://cop.senate.gov/documents/cop-060909-report.pdf [accessed February 8, 2010].
———. 2009d. September Oversight Report: The Use of TARP Funds in Support and Reorganization of the Domestic Automotive Industry. http://cop.senate.gov/
documents/cop-090909-report.pdf [accessed February 8, 2010].
Cooper, Helene. 2009. Obama Orders Treasury Chief to Try to Block A.I.G. Bonuses. New York Times, March 16.
Cooper, Helene, and Eric Dash. 2009. Obama Presses Biggest Banks to Lend More. New York Times, December 14.
Dahl, Robert A., and Charles E. Lindblom. [1953] 1976. Politics, Economics, and Welfare: Planning and Politico-Economic Systems Resolved into Basic Social Processes. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Dewey, John. [1927] 1954. The Public and Its Problems. Athens, OH: Swallow Press.
Johnson, Cathy Marie. 1990. New Wine in New Bottles: The Case of the Consumer Product Safety Commission. Public Administration Review 50(1): 74–81.
Jørgensen, Torben Beck, and Barry Bozeman. 2007. Public Values: An Inventory. Administration & Society 39(3): 354–81.
Koppell, Jonathan G. S. 2001. Hybrid Organizations and the Alignment of Interests: The Case of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Public Administration Review 61(4):
468–82.
Landler, Mark. 2008. New Terrain for Panel on Bailout. New York Times, November 3.
Leone, Robert A. 1981. Government Regulation of Business: Developing the Managerial Perspective. Boston: Harvard Business School.
———. 1986. Who Profits: Winners, Losers, and Government Regulation. New York: Basic Books.
Light, Paul C. 2008. A Government Ill Executed: The Decline of the Federal Service and How to Reverse It. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Lindblom, Charles E. 1977. Politics and Markets. New York: Basic Books.
Maynard, Micheline. 2009. U.S. Takes On the Insular Culture of G.M. New York Times, June 10.
Moe, Ronald C. 2001. The Emerging Federal Quasi Government: Issues of Management and Accountability. Public Administration Review 61(3): 290–312.
Moe, Ronald C., and Thomas H. Stanton. 1989. Government-Sponsored Enterprises as Federal Instrumentalities: Reconciling Private Management with Public Accountabil-
ity. Public Administration Review 49(4): 321–29.
Mosher, Frederick. 1980. The Changing Responsibilities and Tactics of the Federal Government. Public Administration Review 40(6): 541–48.
Office of the Special Inspector General for the Troubled Asset Relief Program (SIGTARP). 2009a. Emergency Capital Injections Provided to Support the Viability of Bank of
America, Other Major Banks, and the U.S. Financial System. Audit report, October 5. http://www.sigtarp.gov/reports/audit/2009/Emergency_Capital_Injections_
Provided_to_Support_the_Viability_of_Bank_of_America . . . _100509.pdf [accessed February 8, 2010].
———. 2009b. Quarterly Report to Congress, April 21, 2009. http://www.sigtarp.gov/reports/congress/2009/April2009_Quarterly_Report_to_Congress.pdf [accessed
February 8, 2010].
———. 2009c. Quarterly Report to Congress, July 21, 2009. http://www.sigtarp.gov/reports/congress/2009/July2009_Quarterly_Report_to_Congress.pdf [accessed
February 8, 2010].
———. 2009d. Quarterly Report to Congress, October 21, 2009. http://www.sigtarp.gov/reports/congress/2009/October2009_Quarterly_Report_to_Congress.pdf [accessed
February 8, 2010].
Oliver, Christine. 2008. The Effectiveness of Strategic Political Management: A Dynamic Capabilities Framework. Academy of Management Review 33(2): 496–520.
Olsen, Johan P. 2006. Maybe It Is Time to Rediscover Bureaucracy. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 16(1): 1–24.
Paulson, Henry. 2008. Statement before the House Financial Services Committee. 110th Cong., 2nd sess., November 18.
Pesch, Udo. 2008. The Publicness of Public Administration. Administration and Society 40(2): 170–93.
Przeworski, Adam. 1997. The State in a Market Economy. In Transforming Post-Communist Political Economies, edited by Joan Nelson, Charles Tilly, and Lee Walker, 411–31.
Washington, DC: National Academy Press.
Salamon, Lester, ed. 2002. Tools of Government: A Guide to the New Governance. New York: Oxford University Press.
Schubert, Glendon. 1961. The Public Interest. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.
Scott, W. Richard. 2003. Organizations: Rational, Natural, and Open Systems. 5th ed. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Shaffer, Brian. 1995. Firm-Level Responses to Government Regulation: Theoretical and Research Approaches. Journal of Management 21(3): 495–514.

Shifting Boundaries between the Public and Private Sectors 359


U.S. Department of the Treasury. 2009a. Automotive Industry Financing Program (updated September 4). http://www.financialstability.gov/roadtostability/autoprogram.html
[accessed February 8, 2010].
———. 2009b. Interim Final Rule on TARP Standards for Compensation and Corporate Governance. 31 C.F.R., Part 30, RIN 1505-AC09. http://www.treas.gov/press/
releases/reports/ec%20ifr%20fr%20web%206.9.09tg164.pdf [accessed February 8, 2010].
———. 2009c. Treasury Announces Restructuring of Commitment to GMAC. News release, December 30. http://treas.gov/press/releases/tg501.htm [accessed February 8,
2010].
———. 2009d. Treasury Releases Congressional Report on EESA. News release, January 6. http://www.treas.gov/press/releases/reports/0010508105_a_report.pdf [accessed
February 8, 2010].
———. 2009e. Troubled Asset Relief Program Transactions Report for Period Ending November 25, 2009. http://www.financialstability.gov/docs/transaction-reports/11-30-
09%20Transactions%20Report%20as%200f%2011-25-09.pdf [accessed February 8, 2010].
———. 2009f. U.S. Treasury Fact Sheet on Capital Purchase Program. http://www.financialstability.gov/roadtostability/CPPfactsheet.htm [accessed February 8, 2010].
U.S. Government Accountability Office (GAO). 2009a. Auto Industry: Summary of Government Efforts and Automakers’ Restructuring to Date (Report to Congressional Com-
mittees). Washington, DC: Government Printing Office. GAO-09-553. http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d09553.pdf [accessed February 8, 2010].
———. 2009b. Troubled Asset Relief Program: June 2009 Status of Efforts to Address Transparency and Accountability Issues (Report to Congressional Committees). Washington,
DC: Government Printing Office. GAO-09-658. http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d09658.pdf [accessed February 8, 2010].
———. 2009c. Troubled Asset Relief Program: Status of Efforts to Address Transparency and Accountability Issues (Report to Congressional Committees). Washington, DC: Gov-
ernment Printing Office. GAO-09-296. http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d09296.pdf [accessed February 8, 2010].
———. 2009d. Troubled Asset Relief Program: Status of Efforts to Address Transparency and Accountability Issues (Testimony before the Senate Committee on Finance). Washing-
ton, DC: Government Printing Office. GAO-09-539T. http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d09539t.pdf [accessed February 8, 2010].
U.S. Office of Management and Budget (OMB). 2003. Circular A-76, Revised May 29, 2003. http://oam.ocs.doc.gov/docs/OMB%20Circular%20A-
76%20Revised%202003.pdf [accessed February 8, 2010].
Wamsley, Gary L., and Mayer N. Zald. 1973. The Political Economy of Public Organizations: A Critique and Approach to the Study of Public Administration. Lexington, MA:
Heath.
White House Transition Project. n.d. http://www.whitehousetransitionproject.org [accessed February 8, 2010].
Wilson, Amy, and Neil Roland. 2009. A Big Win—With Many Pitfalls: If Rejected Stores Are Closed, Arbitration May Be Too Late. Automotive News, December 14.
Wise, Charles R. 1990. Public Service Configurations and Public Organizations: Public Organization Design in the Post-Privatization Era. Public Administration Review 50(2):
141–55.
———. 2002. The Public Service Configuration Problem. In Modern Organizations: Theory and Practice, 2nd ed., edited by Ali Farazmand, 135–58. Westport, CT: Praeger.
Wise, Charles R., and Christian M. Freitag. 2002. Balancing Accountability and Risk in Program Implementation: The Case of National Fire Policy. Journal of Public Adminis-
tration Research and Theory 12(4): 493–523.

Conference Announcement…

4th International
Public Procurement Conference

August 26–28, 2010


Seoul, South Korea

The Korean Public Procurement Service and an impressive list of international co-
sponsors invite you to attend the 4th International Conference of Public Procurement
(IPPC2010). The conference aims to extend and deepen topics of interest by present-
ing contributions of theoretical, empirical, practical and institutional nature. Get more
information at:

http://www.ippc2010.kr

360 Public Administration Review • May | June 2010

Você também pode gostar