Você está na página 1de 20

World Development, Vol. 23, No. 9, pp.

1475-1494, 1995
Copyright Q 1995 Elsevier Science Ltd
Pergamon
Printed in Great Britain. All rights reserved
0305-750x/95 $9.50 + o.txl
0305-750x(95)00059-3

India and China: Contrasts in Economic


Liberalization?

DEEPAK LAL*
University of California, Los Angeles, U. S. A.
and
International Centre for Economic Research, Turin, Italy

Summary. -It is argued that in both India and China despite some important differences: (a) similar cul-
tural and political imperatives led to similar systems of dirigisme and economic outcomes - with the
Chinese growth higher than the Indian because of higher investment; (b) crises engendered by their
dirigiste regimes impelled reform; (c) their attempts to replace the plan by the market have striking simi-
larities but (d) ultimately because of continuing atavistic attitudes to toward trade and commerce the
reforms remain insecure

1. INTRODUCTION bases for forming objective judgments about eco-


nomic performance in the two countries are so marked
At long last the two Asian giants seem to be on the that even the most basic questions concerning the size
move. The 1990s could be the era of economic liber- and growth of national income and population in
alization in India and China, which together account China cannot be answered with any great certainty, as
for over two billion of the worlds 5.3 billion people. compared with India.* (We take this question up in
If the economic reforms underway are successfully greater detail when we try to form judgments on rela-
completed, these countries could repeat the growth tive performance.)
miracles of much smaller Asian economies, and like Section 2 seeks to show the similar cultural and
them should be able to eliminate mass poverty. This political imperatives which led to similar systems of
would indeed be the Great Transformation. But will dirigisme and economic outcomes in both countries,
the countries stay the course, and complete what, in the first three decades after their independence in
judging from Latin American experience (e.g., in the late 1940s. Section 3 attempts to delineate the rea-
Chile and Mexico), can be an arduous journey through sons for reform and the stages it has followed and what
many rocky shoals, and which could take over a decade? the outcome has been in the two countries. Section 4
This paper attempts to answer this question within tries to peer into the future, by attempting to answer
a comparative framework. This approach was com- the rhetorical question which forms the subtitle of the
mon in the 1960s and 1970s but has been rarer since paper.
the beginning of the Chinese reforms in 1978. Unlike
most of the existing comparisons which concentrate
* This is a substantially revised version of a paper written for
largely on purely economic variables, I am as con- the international conference Liberalizing Indias Economy:
cerned with culture and politics, as I argue that these The Cultural Context and Political Constraints, Centre for
have been important determinants of the past eco- Indian Studies, University of Hull, November 1993. The
nomic systems, and are likely to determine the success paper was written while the author was a visitor at the Centre
of the ongoing liberalization in the two countries. The of Economic Performance, London School of Economics,
focus of the paper is therefore less on the mechanics during 1993-94, and revised while he was fellow of the
of liberalization in the two countries, than on answer- ICER, Turin (199695). The author is grateful to Justin Lin
ing the more nebulous but important question: of the Development Research Centre of the State Council,
and Peking University for organizing a lecture tour of China
whether longstanding atavistic attitudes toward the
in September 1993, and for discussions with numerous
market have changed sufficiently in both countries to Chinese officials and academics; to Dr. S. N. Rao of the
allow the current move from the plan to the market to NCAER, New Delhi for an institutional home in March-
be completed and to endure? April 1994; and to two anonymous referees of this journal
There is one serious problem in making this com- whose suggestions greatly helped to improve the paper. Final
parison. The differences in the comparative statistical revision accepted: March 27, 1995.

1475
1476 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

2. DIRIGISME and only rarely encompassed the subcontinent under


Imperial rule (Lal, 1988); compared with the more
There are some striking similarities in the cultural centralized social control in an absolutist state - in a
attitudes and economic history of the two giant Asian relatively integrated national market - run by
economies both in the more distant and recent past. Confucian mandarins in China, which has remained
Culture consists of the system of concepts or ideas united politically from Sung to modem times with
which guide thought and action. It is transmitted only relatively brief periods of disruption between
socially, and at least for historical materialists (which regimes (McNeill, 1983, p. 49) when the Mandate
economists inevitably are) these cultural traits can of Heaven was transferred from one dynasty to
change as the environment changes. But such endo- the next.
geneity of cultures remains contested by other social Rowe sums up the enduring characteristics of late
scientists (see, e.g., Gellner, 1988). For our limited imperial China as
purposes in this article, it is sufficient to establish that
there are distinct cultural attitudes which have perpet- an ethos that stressed harmony, social order, continuity,
uated dirigiste policies in India and China and to and community service, all prompted by the State via that
examine whether these have altered sufficiently to unparalleled vehicle of elite indoctrination, the civil ser-
allow a move to the market to be secure in our two vice examination system; a fairly successful state monop-
countries.3 olization of the approved channels of upward mobility;
an emphasis on merit; a customary law of partible inher-
itance, which made downward mobility over generations
an ever present possibility for the elite; and an orthodoxy
(a) Historical cultural stability and economic that to a greater or lesser extent viewed commerce with
stagnation suspicion and disdain. Perhaps paradoxically, the late
imperial Chinese economy was marked by the existence
Both countries were marked at independence in of comparatively strong property rights and based on
the 1940s by centuries of cultural stability and eco- these rights, an agrarian system emphasizing free alien-
nomic stagnation - the subtitle of my The Hindu ation of land, household-scale proprietorship, and an
Equilibrium. (On China see Elvin.) The stagnation elaborate and flexible system of mortgaging and leasing
was in per capita income, so that with the relatively (1990, p. 243).
modest population growth of the past there was exten-
sive growth (in Lloyd Reynoldss felicitous phrase) Thus unlike India where the land market was cre-
but no obvious signs of intensive growth - which ated by the Raj, the Chinese have supported a dynamic
leads to a secular increase in per capita income.4 This land market for centuries. In addition, the Chinese
in turn was due in large part to both countries having meritocratic acquisition of status contrasts with the
made near perfect adaptations to the environments in ascription of status through the Indian caste system.
which their respective organic economies (bounded The ancient role of education in acquiring status has
by the productivity of land) had been placed (see led to a greater emphasis on mass education in China
Wrigley, 1988).5 than in India. In fact, in India, as Weiner (1991) has
Both had succeeded, by the middle ages, in creat- argued, when education and status became correlated
ing economies which maintained what Elvin calls a - at least since Independence - the upper castes
high equilibrium trap (for India see Lal, 1988), controlling the state apparatus have thwarted the
which yielded an average level of living for their peo- lower castes desire for education by soft pedalling the
ples which was the envy of the contemporary world. constitutional commitment for the provision of uni-
But the forms of cultural stability and political orga- versal elementary education.
nization differed, reflecting in part the differing ethnic Both countries had social systems which accorded
compositions of the two countries. Chinas remark- merchants and traders a lowly status and their wealth
able ethnic homogeneity contrasts with Indias long was not translated into political inBuence.6 Most eco-
history of maintaining a multi-ethnic society. nomic historians have noted the importance of the rise
Secondly, whereas political instability has been the of the merchant in the polities of Western Europe as
norm in India, China has shown a remarkable political an important component in their great transformation
unity under centralized imperial rule for millennia. (see Hicks, 1969; North and Thomas, 1973; Jones,
These differences did not, however, prevent the 1988; Gellner, 1988). An essential element in this was
emergence of relatively stable Revenue economies the evolution of institutions to bind the state against its
(Hicks), and what I call predatory states (Lal, 1988, predatory instincts. An important question in judging
chapter 13.2) in both countries. The main cultural and the sustainability of the reforms in China and India is
political differences were: the decentralized form of whether their atavistic attitudes toward commerce and
social control as embodied in the Indian caste system, merchants have changed and whether there are signs
and the relatively autarkic village communities, in a that the state has tied itself Ulysses-like to the mast
polity which has usually been regionally fragmented against these voices from the past.
INDIA AND CHINA 1477

Neither India or China, however, could escape the advantage officials had in any and every encounter
from their high equilibrium trap without moving as with merely private men of wealth (McNeill, 1983,
the West did from an organic to a mineral-based pp. 50-Y).
energy economy, whose productivity is no longer
bounded by the fixed factor of production - land. Its This form of predatory partnership under the Sung
centerpiece was the utilization of the capital stock of between government and business in many ways is
stored energy represented by fossil fuels, in particular echoed in the current liberalization in China (see below).
coal, through the development of the steam engine, Just as in Sung times it can be expected to yield inten-
which provided virtually unlimited supplies of sive growth. But, as this was subsequently aborted in
mechanical energy (Wrigley, 1988, pp. 5-6). Secular part because of the reassertion of the atavistic attitudes
intensive growth which could eradicate mass poverty toward trade and commerce, and the failure to bind the
had become feasible. This was different, qualitatively, state against its predatory rent-seeking, an important
from the type of intensive growth that Adam Smith question is whether enough has changed in China
had shown could be generated even within an organic today to prevent a repetition of this historical cycle.
economy, through the replacement of the mercantilist
system by his form of capitalism and free trade. But
the land constraint would remain binding in this (b) Development strategy
Smithian form of intensive growth.
For India there is little historical evidence of inten- In both China and India, the modem ideologies
sive growth of either type occurring before the mod- under which they sought to foster intensive growth
em era, whereas for China there is evidence that the after their independence - Communism in China,
Smithian variety occurred in Sung China, and that all Fabian socialism in India-did nothing to undermine
the technological ingredients were present for the these traditional attitudes toward trade and commerce.
emergence of the technologically determined variety Both countries were opened up to the modem world
(see McNeill, 1983; Jones, 1988). The subsequent through the force of Western arms. The nationalism
stagnation of the Chinese economy despite this this provoked has sought to adopt the Wests technol-
medieval creativity is one of the great historical puz- ogy, particularly military, without abandoning its
zles, which goes beyond the remit of this paper. But soul. Xenophobia and a suspicion of foreigners
there is one set of explanations which is relevant remains endemic in both countries, while both have
because of its contemporary resonance. sought to promote heavy industries through dirigiste
McNeil1 (1983), Jones (1988), and Lin (1992) for means. This had more to do with the political impera-
instance all relate to the so-called Needham problem tive of providing the material means for resisting
to the creation of the Confucian mandarinate, which future military threats to their independence than a
was charged with implementing the official doctrine desire to promote economic welfare.
[which] held that the emperor should consider the Both have thus found the Soviet model resonant in
Empire as if it formed a single household (McNeill, their drive for industrialization - though in India, in
1983, p. 31).8 This household following Confucian the softer tones associated with a democracy. The
values despised both soldiers and merchants. The resulting development strategy was also by and large
mandarinates task was to manage both, recognizing similar as both countries followed hot-house indus-
that both were needed to maintain the physical trialization through the promotion of heavy industry
integrity of the Empire. Systematic restraint upon under the aegis of state enterprises. Both followed
industrial expansion, commercial expansion, and mil- relatively autarkic trade policies accompanied by a
itary expansion were built into the Chinese system of battery of trade and exchange controls, which pro-
political administration (p. 40). The market increased gressively cut any link between domestic and world
the economys flexibility, and the resulting relative prices. This had well-known deleterious
effects on the economys efficiency and thence pro-
new wealth and improved communications enhanced the ductivity.
practical power Chinese officials had at their disposal. Both also systematically discriminated against
Discrepancies between the ideals of the marketplace and agriculture by taxing it directly or indirectly. But this
those of government were real enough; but as long as policy went much further in China during the Maoist
officials could bring overriding police power to bear Great Leap Forward and the establishment of com-
whenever they were locally or privately defied, the com- munes. This was a disaster. It led to one of the worst
mand element in the mix remained securely domi-
famines in human history, and set back Chinese agri-
nant. ..in every encounter the private entrepreneur was at
a disadvantage, while officials had the whip hand. This cultural productivity for a decade. This policy was
was so, fundamentally, because most Chinese felt that the completely reversed by the establishment of the
unusual accumulation of private wealth from trade or household responsibility system in the late 1970s.
manufactures was profoundly immoral official ideol- By contrast India switched in the late 1960s to various
ogy and popular psychology thus coincided to reinforce policies to promote agriculture, which led - in eco-
1478 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

logically suitable parts of the country - to what is figures is that the figure of $370 in 1990 as Chinas per
termed the Green Revolution. capita GNP reflects the consideration that a more realis-
Since the late 1970s moreover, both countries have tic figure might soon make China ineligible for loans
been gradually trying to escape from the dirigiste sys- from IDA, the soft loan affiliate of the World Bank (p. 5;
see also Lardy, 1992. Appendix B. and Malenbaum,
tem of controls of foreign trade and industry that they
1990).
had previously set up. We need to briefly outline the
consequences of this dirigisme, which might provide Nor has the scholarly discussion reached any mea-
reasons for this move to liberalization, which is dis-
sure of agreement (see Rawski, 1989; Ma and
cussed in the next section.
Gamaut, 1992; Kumar, 1992; Demberg and Eckaus,
1987; Malenbaum, 1990). For the base period, 1950,
the most plausible inference is Kumars: The per
(c) Relative pe$ormance capita income of both India and China was very low
in 1949 and given the margin of error, it is not worth
A comparison of the relative performance of the arguing about which country was the poorer (1992,
two giant Asian economies is bedeviled by statistical p. 30). Furthermore the distortions in the Chinese rel-
problems relating to estimates of Chinese GDP and ative price structure where there were few links
population. By contrast Indian national income figures between prices and the respective marginal rates of
and population data are much more secure. The prob- substitution in consumption or of transformation in
lems with the Chinese data - which have sadly been production, make any inferences of Chinese produc-
used even by reputable international organizations tive capacity or welfare from its GNP at domestic
such as the World Bank - can be readily highlighted prices highly dubious. Purchasing power parity esti-
by looking at the implications of the World Bank esti- mates of Chinese GDP have been made however by
mates of per capita GNP and its growth rate for Heston and Summers (1991), and by Maddison (1991)
1965-90 in India and China. According to the World and are summarized in Table 1. Given all the problems
Bank (1992, World Development Report, Table 1) the surrounding the basic data and the price comparisons
average rate of growth of per capita income was 5.8% made, these can at best provide broad orders of mag-
for China and 1.9% for India over this period. The
nitude, and of the two, in my judgment, the Maddison
level of per capita income in 1990 was $370 for China estimates ring truer.
and $350 for India. These figures imply that per capita These problems of estimating Chinese GDP are
incomes in China in 1965 could only have been 41% compounded by problems in estimating its population.
of Indias As Srinivasan (1993) rightly comments: The only proper censuses in China were in 1982 and
No knowledgeable analyst of the two countries would 1990. All earlier estimates are based on partial sur-
subscribe to this relative value of Chinas GNP per capita veys. Moreover, the numbers emerging from the
in 1965! A plausible explanation for these paradoxical recent 1990 census are marred by the underreporting

Table 1. Comparative growth performance

Heston et al. estimates


(Growth rates, % p.a.)
GDP GDP/POP POP*
China 196&73 4.6 2.3 2.3
1973-80 5.3 3.7 1.6
1980-88 9.2 7.8 1.4
India 1960-73 2.5 0.2 2.3
1973-80 2.3 0.0 2.3
1980-88 5.0 2.8 2.2
Maddison estimates
Per Capita GDP Growth Rates (% pa)t
GDP/POP ($1 GDP/POP GDP
China 1950 415
1973 774 2.76 5.06
1987 1748 3.46 5.06
India 1950 399
1973 513 1.08 3.38
1987 662 1.07 3.21
*POP column derives from Heston et al. estimates as GDP-GDP/POP.
tGrowth rate figures are derived from Maddisons (1991) estimates of GDP/POP ($), and from
POP in (A)
INDIA AND CHINA 1479

of female births due to the one child population sector. From then on, there were long drawn-out and
policy (see Yi et al., 1993). convoluted attempts to remove the bias against
So what can we conclude on relative performance? exports through various forms of indirect subsidiza-
It would appear that until the late 1970s China grew tion of exports. These did have the effect of providing
faster than India. This was largely due to differences some modest boost to exports. This process of trade
in the rates of growth of industry. The rate of growth liberalization was supplemented by some easing of
of agricultural output was about the same. In China industrial licensing and fiscal reform in Rajiv
during 1952-78 (before the introduction of the house- Gandhis early administration. But many of the
hold responsibility system) it was 2.9%, in India dur- promised reforms of the foreign trade system (replac-
ing 1950-86 it was 2.6%; while grain output grew at ing quantitative restrictions by tariffs), and the public
2.4% in China and 2.6% in India (Srinivasan, 1993 p. sector (easing exit of unviable units recommended
20). But the performance of both was well below that in the Economic Survey 1985-86) remained merely
of the Asian newly industrializing countries (NICs) in plans, as the government became embroiled in the
terms of industrialization and other developing coun- Bofors scandal and reform was put on the back burner.
tries (e.g., Kenya, Indonesia and Pakistan) in terms of It was not until the macroeconomic crisis of 1991
agricultural growth. forced India into the arms of the World Bank and the
Reported social indicators appear to be better in International Monetary Fund (IMF) that a more seri-
China than India, but the overall level of inequality, ous attempt at liberalization was undertaken.
particularly in rural areas was about the same (the Gini This crisis which threatened international bank-
coefficient was 0.31 in 1979 for rural China and 0.34 ruptcy for India, and the response to it, was a replay of
in rural India in 1973-76 (World Bank, 1983, Table dramas enacted in many parts of Latin America in the
3.19). Though the same sources report a somewhat 1980s. I have charted the anatomy of this cycle of eco-
higher inequality in urban income distribution in nomic repression - macroeconomic crisis - reform
India, because of the large weight of rural areas in both elsewhere, in greater detail (Lal, 1987, 1993; La1 and
countries overall income distribution was roughly Myint, 1995). Two points, however, which are rele-
similar (Srinivasan, 1993, p. 18). Despite different vant for my present purposes may be noted. First,
political systems, the overall performance of the two these crises are fiscal crises caused by the unsustain-
economies in their dirigiste postindependence phases ability of the vast system of politically determined
was thus not too dissimilar-in particular well below entitlements to income streams created by past
their respective potential. dirigisme in the microeconomy.g Second, they arise
when all possible means of financing them seem to be
at an end. One means is through taxation. But tax rev-
3. REFORM enues are less than buoyant both because growth has
been damaged by the productivity-damaging effects
In discussing reforms it is useful to distinguish of dirigisme, and because of the inescapable rise of the
between the policy induced distortions created by irra- black economy as more and more seek to escape the
tional dirigisme in commodity and factor markets. taxed economy.iO With entitlements growing, at some
China has suffered from marked distortions in all of stage a fiscal deficit will emerge. This can only be
these markets. Its complete delinking between world financed by three means: internal or external borrow-
and domestic prices until the early 1980s the reluc- ing or the levying of the inflation tax. Given underde-
tance to change the controlled prices that were set in veloped domestic capital markets, internal borrowing
the early days of planning in the 195Os, and the com- is limited. So the usual option is to increase foreign
prehensive control of trade and foreign exchange borrowing. India did this, and in an echo of China (but
through state monopolies meant that no economic with important differences in the form) tried to tap the
rationality could be adduced to the resulting domestic riches of its worldwide diaspora (the nonresident
price structure. Though India too had many distortions Indians-NRIs). But as in Latin America this capital
in its domestic price structure, they were never likely inflow was short-term and hence volatile. With the
to have reached the Chinese extreme. In both cases the continuing political instability and little sign of
dirigiste system systematically discriminated against improvement in the productivity and hence capacity to
exports. repay of the economy, these investors are at some
stage likely to take fright-as the NRIs did leading to
the balance-of-payments crisis which triggered the
(a) India latest Indian reforms. This leaves only the inflation-
ary tax. But this too is unsustainable, as economic
In the relatively more open mixed Indian econ- agents take countervailing action-in a democracy as
omy the bias against exports resulted in periodic bal- inflation-shy as the Indian, also through the ballot box.
ance-of-payments crises, one of which in 1966 led to The ensuing crisis appears as a balance-of-payments
the first abortive attempt at liberalizing the external and fiscal crisis, and it provides a small window of
1480 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

opportunity for radical reform. This, at the most basic The start of the Chinese reform process is, thus,
level, involves rescinding all the politically deter- rightly identified with the rural reforms. They began
mined entitlements created by dirigisme - and there- with the partial dismantlement of the communes in
in lies the rub. For the losers already know who they 1962, but did not reach fruition till the household-
are, while the gainers from the increased productivity based farming system was established in 1979. Their
which results from liberalization are only potential, impetus was a crisis for the state, because of one
i.e., unknown. For this reason I have been an advocate important historical lesson of Chinas lOOO-yearhis-
of a big bang when a crisis presents an opportunity tory of dynastic transitions - the link between food
for reform.i* production and political and social stability. This
India, fuurmieux, did not follow this apparently political wisdom is capsuled in an often cited motto
politically risky course for a minority government. wu nong bu wen (without a strong agriculture, the
Besides success in macroeconomic stabilization, it society will not be stable) in the agriculture policy
made some headway in dismantling the mercantilist debates in China (Lin 1990b, p. 151). The results
system of industrial licensing, price controls and trade were dramatic.
and exchange controls. But it failed to rescind one of
the major entitlements - secure jobs in the loss-mak- The growthrate of grain in 1952-78 was 2.4 percent per
year, only 0.4 percent above the population growthrate.
ing public enterprises, and the bloated bureaucracies
The per capita availability of grain, therefore, increased
in state and central governments, in parastatals and the only 10 percent over a quarter of a century Between
nationalized banking sector. With the passions 1979-84, agricultural output and grain output, respec-
aroused by the Ayodhya issue, and the accompanying tively, grew at 11.8 percent and 4.1 percent annually
political reverberations, the reform process seems to while population grew at 1.3 percent in the same period.
be stalled. Speculations about its future are left to the Although agriculture as a whole still grew at a
next section. respectable rate of 4. I % p.a. after 1984, gram production
Of the factor markets - the land market (most of has, nevertheless, stagnated after teaching a peak of 407
which is rural) has been virtually free in India. The million tons in 1984 The main reason was the failure
major factor market distortions are in the market for of the government to implement a market-oriented price
reform for grain (Lin, 199Ob, pp. 150-151).
labor in the so-called organized sector, and in the cap-
ital market through the workings of the nationalized What this suggests is that, the marked rise in the
banking sector. post-1979 Chinese growth rate was largely the result
of making up ground after the disaster of the Great
Leap Forward. Its basis was the household responsi-
(b) China bility contract, which comes very close to what in the
Western world is a grant of private property in land.
By contrast, China had severe distortions in all its The clear, if minor, departure is that the Chinese ver-
factor markets in addition to those in the commodity sion takes the form of leasehold instead of fee simple;
market. Its land market was extinguished with collec- that is the contract is not in perpetuity (Cheung, 1990,
tivisation. The practice of assigning jobs bureaucrati- p. 23). While informants during a visit in 1993
cally for life to urban workers, together with, in effect, informed me that while the land cannot be sold (as it
strict controls of migration, froze the labor market. In belongs to the state), leases can be transferred or sold,
the command economy of a Communist country there so various forms of tenancy have arisen as the initial
was clearly no place for a capital market. Factor mar- owners of the lease move to other more lucrative occu-
kets require some delineation of property rights. pations. This privatization of land was not resisted by
Under Chinese communism with everyone a ward of the cadres because they often end[ed] up with several
a state which had socialized all property - including responsibility contracts (Cheung, 1986, p. 66).
individual labor-there could be no factor markets. The liberalization of commodity markets in China
But the extinguishing of land and labor markets in
began with the partial trade liberalization of 1972, fol-
Chinese agriculture also led to a rapid denouement.
lowing Nixons opening to China. Unlike the rural
With the establishment of the communes during the
reforms, however, these were
Great Leap Forward, as Li Xiannian is reported to
have told one visitor: the peasants simply downed motivatedlargely by geopoliticaland strategic consider-
tools and turned their bottoms to the sun (cited in ations and not by economic factors. Relations with the
Evans, 1993, p. 250). The resulting famine was the West were improved to enhance Chinas leverage vis-
worst in the world in this century. The setback to agri- d-vis the Soviet Union not because there was a high level
cultural output and productivity was not reversed until political consensus that China should abandon its long-
the household responsibility system restored virtual time policy of self-sufficiency (Lardy, 1992, p. 1 I).
private property rights in land (see Cheung, 1990).13
Total factor productivity in agriculture did not reach The Cultural Revolution which seems to have
its 1952 level till 1983 (Lin, 1990a, p. 1246).i4 caused more havoc to the party than the economy (see
INDIA AND CHINA 1481

Evans, 1993), set back this process of opening to the changes in it due to the reforms that have so far taken
West. But this political theme was reasserted with place) are all that different in the two countries. Thus
Deng Xiaopings victory over the Gang of Four. The for China, according to the World Bank, total factor
result was that between 1978 and 1990 the average productivity in agriculture and industry combined
annual pace of trade expansion was in excess of 15 declined at an annual rate of - 1.41% between
percent, over three times the rate of growth of world 1957-65, rose at only 0.62% during 1965-76, and in
trade (Lardy, 1992, p. 11). This raised Chinas share the reform era (1980-88) grew at 2.4% in the state sec-
of world exports, which had fallen from 1.25% in tor, 4.63% in the collective sector and 6.44% in the
1952-55 to0.75% in 1978, to 2% in 1991. By contrast agricultural sector (World Bank, WDR, 1992 Table
Indias share of world exports declined from over 2.3).15Given the statistical difficulties outlined earlier
2% in the early 50s to stabilize around 0.5% in the these can not be taken as hard figures but merely
80s (Srinivasan, 1993, p. 12). To put these figures in as indicating trends. For India, Ahluwalias estimates
perspective it may be noted that Korea with a popula- for industry indicate that total factor productivity in
tion of 43 million in 1990 (compared with 1,134 mil- manufacturing grew at 3.4% in the first half of the
lion for China and 850 million for India) exported 1980s as compared with a decline of 0.3% per annum
more (US $65 billion) than China ($62 billion) and in the previous 15 years.
India ($18 billion).
Given the distortions in Chinese GDP estimates it
is much harder to provide a firm conclusion of the (d) Trade liberalization
changing degree of openness of the Chinese as com-
pared with the Indian economy. Lardy after a detailed This inference about the similarity in the perfor-
discussion concludes that: mance of the two countries would be made more
secure, if the nature of the trade liberalization that has
taken place in the two countries to date is compared.
if Blocks calculation of Chinas GDP in 1980 is taken as
meaningful . the trade ratio in China rose from 5.8% in
Using the phase methodology developed in the
1978 to 9.4% by 1988. If the Summers and Heston esti- Bhagwati-Krueger study (see Krueger for details),
mate is taken as meaningful, the trade ratio rose from Srinivasan has categorized the past trade history of
2.1% to 3.4% over the same period (p. 154). India in terms of the following phases (where higher
order phases categorize more liberalized trade and
While in the earlier period if the World Bank
payments regimes): 1956-62 (Phase I); 1962-66
(1983) is to be believed the trade ratio in 1980 was the
(Phase II); 1966-68 (Phase Ill); 1968-75 (Phase II);
same as in 1950. By contrast India, for which the data 1975-85 (Phase Ill); 1985-mid-1991 (Phase Ill con-
are more secure, tinued); mid-l991-(Phase IV?). For China Lardy
argues in a thorough analysis of its trade reforms that
the trade liberalization that has taken place since the
the share of trade in GDP fluctuated-until the early six-
late 1970s should be taken as
ties it averaged over 12%. only to decline to a low of less
than 10% in the early 70s and to slowly rise thereafter to
reflectinga transition from a stage one to a stage two lib-
about 16% in 1979-80 (Srinivasan, 1993, p. 12).
eralization of an import substitution trade regime . The
previous direct monopoly on all trade transactions exer-
From this it appears that despite the media hype, cised by the Ministry of Foreign Trade corresponds to
China remains more of a closed economy than India. Kruegers stage one in which there is heavy reliance on
and that its spectacular export performance is only quantitative restrictions. Stage two is characterized by
increasingly complex quantitative restrictions rather than
so judged by a reference point of near autarky! Once
across the board restrictions of phase one Chinas
again, as in agriculture, an economy even more highly
increasing use of import duties, export subsidies, and
repressed than Indias has shown a spectacular perfor- other types of price measures designed to buttress
mance relative to its immediate past only because of quantitative restrictions is also common to phase two
how far it lay inside its production-cum-trade feasibil- (1992, p. 43)
ity frontier.
as are the various import entitlement schemes based
on retention of foreign exchange which grew in the
(c) Growfh effects ofreforms 1980s. Given the continuing large divergences
between domestic and international prices (until the
This raises the question: why is Chinas growth rate 1990s) as documented in Lardys (1992) Table 4.2, it
about twice Indias? The answer lies in the rate of is more than likely that many of the exports were prof-
investment, which in 1990 was nearly 40% of GDP in itable privately but not socially. Evidence of this exists
China as compared with 23% in India. There is little for India (see La1 (1980)). For China Lardy believes
evidence that the productivity of investment (and this was also the case and that in at least a few cases
1482 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

the value added of energy intensive export products (f) Property rights and state enterprises
measured at international prices was negative (p. 96).
Moreover, just as the Phases II and III-type reforms Ike growth of the nonstate enterprise sector in
in India were motivated less by a conversion of the China, where from all accounts much of recent
policy makers to the case for free trade, than by the Chinese growth outside agriculture has taken place,
exigencies of the balance of payments, Lardys care- has in effect meant the growth of a de facto private
ful analysis suggests that something very similar lay sector. But the property rights of the individuals who
behind the gradual trade liberalization in China to have established these enterprises and are seen to be
date. In the centrally planned Chinese economy, with their defacto owners are not recognized de jure.16 This
a state monopoly of foreign trade, there will not be any is because of the ideological imperative of preserving
unplanned imbalance between the value of imports the fiction of state ownership of assets, so that private
and exports measured in foreign currency. Because of property may be practiced in nature, but not in name
the separation between domestic and international (Cheung, 1990, p. 25). This puts a limit on the capi-
prices, however (an airlock system according to the talist process whereby individuals rights to income
World Bank, 1985, p. 97) characteristic of the streams from capital can be traded. This distortion in
Chinese command economy pre-1978, there could be the efficient working of the capital market cannot be
a surplus or deficit on the trade balance in domestic
removed without giving up the ideological fiction and
currency even when in terms of foreign currency it
converting the de facto into de jure private property
was in balance. As Lardy shows reforms of Chinas
rights in the nonstate sectors.
foreign trade system frequently have been stimulated
This fortunately is not a handicap India shares with
by the occurrence of domestic currency losses on for-
China. But the problems of dealing with state enter-
eign trade (1992, p. 20).
prises are similar. In both countries, though the forms
differ, most state enterprises essentially provide unvi-
(e) Foreign capital able politically enforced entitlements to future income
Both India and China were wary in the past of pri- streams to their managers and workers. In both for
vate foreign capital inflows. An essential element in political reasons there has been a reluctance to rescind
their reform programs is a reversal of this policy. An them. Instead, there is an attempt to work around them
important part of the opening up of China involved the by, as it were, building a cordon sanitaire around
creation of special economic zones in Southern China these enterprises, and ensuring that the problem is
and the active promotion of direct foreign investment contained rather than reduced or eliminated. The hope
in joint ventures. These have largely taken place with is that with the growth of the rest of the economy, the
nonstate enterprises which represent the extension of share and hence the deadweight cost of these enter-
the rural household responsibility system to industry. prises to the economy will progressively decline. But
These are so-called village, township and collective in the interim, in both countries they continue to hem-
enterprises. They and direct foreign investment has orrhage the fist and cast a shadow over the sustain-
boomed. Here again, like India, China has sought to ability of the limited reforms that are currently in
mobilize the capital of its international diaspora for its place.
development.
But the nature of the capital inflow has been differ-
ent because of the differing nature of the two streams (g) Fiscal reform and macroeconomic policy
of migrants. Whereas the Indian diaspora (at least of
its more affluent members) has largely consisted of the
(i) China
professional classes, the Chinese diaspora, particu- The problem is particularly deadly in China
larly to Hong Kong and Taiwan, was of entrepreneurs
- many of whom had migrated from Shanghai and because of the Communist fiscal system. In the pre-
reform period, the state enterprises were the prim-
Canton after the Communist takeover. Thus whereas
India could at best hope to mobilize short-run capital ary tax-collecting vehicle - as in other Communist
inflows in the form of bank deposits and bonds, China countries. Wong (1991) describes this as follows:
was able to get foreign equity from its diaspora. Apart
The pre-reform fiscal system in China [had] over-
from the bundle of entrepreneurship, technology and
whelming dependence on industry, and a reliance on
marketing this brings, it also makes a debt crisis of the profits of state-owned enterprises, along with taxes for
Latin American variety less likely. On the other hand, government revenue. Using administrative prices that
given the large distortions in the domestic price struc- systematically discriminate against agricultural and raw
ture, and the accompanying large variance of effective materials producers in favor of industry, artificially high
protective rates, there is likely to be little correspon- profits are created in the industrial sector. These are then
dence between the private and social profitability of captured for government coffers through a combination
such direct foreign investment (see La1 (1975)). of turnover taxes and expropriation of profits (p. IO).
INDIA AND CHINA 1483

As the process of liberalization proceeds, however, choked off credit to the state enterprises, which are
then unable to finance the unviable entitlements which
effective property rights devolve more to the (state the Chinese government is still unwilling to rescind.
owned) enterprises themselves, and perhaps to a nar- There is, thus, a built-in conflict between the needs of
rowly enfranchised private sector . . . By giving up con- liberalization and the desire to maintain socialist state
trol over state propetty, the government in effect gives
enterprises. This is reflected in the continuing debate
away its tax base (McKinnon, 1992, p. 7).
between those officials who seek a return to the sys-
tem of centralized foreign exchange planning and for-
Furthermore, even if the government clings to its
eign exchange control on the one hand, and more rapid
state enterprises, as China has done, the freeing of
movement toward convertibility on the other (Lardy,
commodity markets still erodes the revenue base as:
1992, p. 111). This debate between the conservatives
First, the price system can no longer be rigged to keep and the reformers was supposed to have been settled
agricultural procurement prices - and thus real product at the recent Central Committee meeting. But the
wages - artificially low so as to transfer an easily cap- Financial Times concluded that the communique
tured surplus to industry. Second, industrial enterprises which was issued traded off some monetary easing
-owned by the central or diverse local governments that (desired by conservatives keen to preserve state enter-
had generated monopoly profits - may now face sub- prises) for a further commitment to deepening reform
stantial competition from each other (as amongst town- (desired by the reformers). It reflected not a consen-
ship enterprises in China), from newly enfranchised sus but a failure to agree . . . What is lacking . is a
private or cooperative enterprises, and (possibly) from
willingness by central and regional officials to allow
freer imports. The upshot is that the industrial profit base
itself will tend to decline as the monopoly positions of the enterprises to go bankrupt, to accept that richer
old state-owned industrial enterprises are undermined provinces must pay higher taxes, and to obey central
(McKinnon, 1992, p. 7). bank
November directives
16, lgg3).tyl Times, editorial,

This is borne out by the Blejer et al. (1991) estimate


that the consolidated revenue of the central, provincial (ii) India
and local governments in China fell from 34% of GNP India, despite its more orthodox and transparent
in 1978 to only 19% in 1989, and most of the decline macroeconomic system of control has also not been
was accounted for by a drop in profit remittances able to tackle the problem of large budgetary subsidies
from state enterprises. for fertilizers, energy, the public distribution system,
This erosion of its traditional tax base has forced and those implicit in carrying loss-making public
the government to in effect create a form of tax farm- enterprises and redundant labor in the central and state
ing - with local governments contracting with the bureaucracies.
center to share revenues form local nonstate industry.
This has greatly eroded the power of the central gov-
emment.r8 With local governments also increasingly (h) Labor markets
concerned by the large regional divergences in indus-
trialization and in inflows of private investment, inter- These continuing unviable entitlements in both
nal trade barriers to bottle up domestic resources and countries are largely related to the labor market. In
to protect local factors of production are reportedly prereform China, labor markets were much more rigid
growing, giving rise to fears (as one informant put it) than in India. There was little labor mobility, and the
of economic warlordism. following features which still characterize state-
The resultant periodic macroeconomic crises that owned enterprises applied virtually to the whole econ-
have beset China on its path to liberalization have omy (as there were restrictions on rural-urban and
been caused both by the loose budget constraint faced interregional migration). Lardy notes that still
by the state enterprises and their own unviability at
in the state owned sector, most workers continued to be
international prices. With the domestic prices of 90%
assigned permanent jobs when they finished their educa-
of Chinese imports being based on the international
tion. Workers had no right to quit or leave their assigned
price by 1990 (as compared with 43% in 1984), but jobs and enterprises had no right to dismiss redundant
with domestic export prices still being relatively insu- labor. Furthermore, workers were dependent on their
lated from world prices, the financial losses of the state work units for their housing, medical care, retirement
enterprises have mounted. In 1990 the total of their pensions, and a range of other benefits (1992, p. I 1I).
losses amounted to $20 billion, getting on for 5% of
national income (Evans, 1993, p. 312). This has dire With the growth of non-state enterprises, however,
consequences for macroeconomic balance. the government has relaxed the requirement that all
The inflations that ensued were cured by the tradi- employment be assigned by the state. This has led -
tional means of monetary deflation. This in effect at least in Southern China - to the virtual privatiza-
1484 WORLDDEVELOPMENT

tion of the labor market, except for the existing work- But despite these deficiencies Indias financial sec-
ers in state enterprises who maintain their guaranteed tor is far more developed than the Chinese. Indias
job security and retirement benefits (see Cheung, financial institutions-the Reserve Bank of India and
1990, pp. 23-24). the Bombay stock exchange - were established at the
In India, the rigidities in the labor market are turn of the century. The Reserve Bank of Indias con-
largely confined to the organized sector and are based trol over the money supply may be loose but in China
on labor legislation which goes back to the 19th cen- the banking system appears to have very little control.
tury, as well as on the implicit commitment of a job for The Indian stock exchange had a capitalized value of
life in the government and public enterprises (see Lal, US $48 billion in 1991 -greater than Brazil -China
1989). No attempt has been made in India to rescind is just learning how to operate a stock market. Thus
these entitlements. As in China the hope is that by despite the continuing problems of financial liberal-
allowing the rest of the nondistorted economy to ization, linked primarily to the political problems of
grow around this incubus (which itself will not be dealing with the entitlements of the nationalized bank-
allowed to grow), its relative weight will decline over ing sector, India is much better placed with many of
time. But given the budgetary implications of main- the institutions for a market economy in place as com-
taining these entitlements in the near future. It is pared with China.
unclear whether, in either case, reform can continue
without some successful confrontation of these deeply
entrenched vested interests. (i) Conclusion

A crisis is usually the ideal time to deal with such


(i) Financial sector reform deep-seated political problems. India has probably left
it too late after its 1991 crisis to deal with the neces-
In both countries nationalized banking systems sary reform of its labor market. The Chinese have yet
need to be reformed to cope with the move from the to experience a similar macroeconomic crisis. But if
plan to the market. The Chinese system has adopted the dynamic process observed in other countries faced
the form of a market system . . . but not the reality with living with the consequences of dirigisme is any-
(Perkins, 1994, p. 42). While commercial banks were thing to go by, such a crisis-which may provide the
separated from the central bank formally in the early Chinese polity the necessary will to deal with these
years of reform, they continued to follow central politically determined entitlements - may not be too
direction, and took for granted that the central bank far off.
would bail them out if they got into trouble, which in Summarizing, we have seen that past dirigisme had
turn means that the industrial customers of these banks created distortions in both commodity and factor mar-
faced soft budget constraints (p. 38). There would kets in both countries. But they were much more
seem to be no halfway house from genuine privatiza- severe in China - particularly in factor markets,
tion of the financial sector, but it is doubtful if ideol- which had been virtually extinguished. In both coun-
ogy will permit this. As The Economist noted: tries the liberalization of commodity markets started
with partial trade liberalization in the early 197Os,and
China has freed the farms and almost entirely freed has followed a tortuous route since then. Despite con-
prices. Its remaining problems - the governments siderable liberalization of its near autarkic trade
deteriorating finances, the financial system itself, the regime, China probably has a less liberal trade regime
loss-making state firms and the welfare system they today than Indias and a less open economy. In the fac-
provide for their 107m workers - are all linked tor markets, even though the Indian capital market is
together (August 1, 1993,p. 29). inefficient, it is still way ahead of the Chinese, who are
just beginning the process of setting up an efficient
The problem is again political - and ideological! banking system and stock markets. The land market
Though the privatization of Indian state-owned has been virtually free in India, while its extinction in
banks, and the creation of a fully market-oriented China led to a collapse in agricultural output, which
financial sector would appear to be easier in India, it provided the major impetus for the reforms under
will be difficult to institute without taking on the pow- Deng. But unlike India the delineation of property
erful white collar bank workers unions which have rights and their legal enforcement is still limited -
battened on the politically determined entitlements partly for ideological reasons. In both countries major
that the nationalized banking system has provided distortions in the labor market, particularly for those
them and other politically favored constituents. Nor is in the public sector remain. Both countries are trying
Indias much larger and deeper stock market yet a to circumvent the problem of dealing directly with the
fully efficient instrument for financial intermediation, large inefficient public sector, by attempting to allow
as the 1992 market-cum-banking scandal, which nearly the buoyant private economy to grow rapidly and
brought down the Finance Minister, has demonstrated. thence reduce the share of the state sector. But in both
INDIA AND CHINA 1485

countries, the resulting hemorrhaging of the fist has leaders in the two countries? In India though there can
led to problems of macroeconomic stability. It was a be no doubt about the commitment of the Finance
macroeconomic crisis which led to Indias latest Minister Dr. Manmohan Singh, and to date of the
attempt at reform. In both countries, their atavistic and Prime Minister Narasimha Rao, the same cannot be
nationalist objections to foreign capital are being said of the other members of the ruling political party,
overcome. Both have used the capital of their dias- nor of the major opposition parties. This is largely
pora, but given their differing composition, the because of the long ideological shadow that has been
Chinese have been able to obtain more stable flows in termed, Nehruvianism -a variant of Fabianism -
the form of direct investment, whereas the Indians which still influences the political and intellectual
have to rely on more short-term inflows in the form of classes. The press comments by both ministers and
bank deposits. It was their reversal which triggered the many (but by no means all) press commentators were
Indian macroeconomic crisis of the late 1980s. hostile to many of the eminently sensible suggestions
Given these similarities rather than differences in made in the July 1993 Bhagwati-Srinivasan report
the course of liberalization and the roadblocks in its commissioned by the Minister of Finance. The old
continuation, as well as in the prereform initial con- shibboleths - maintaining some form of socialism to
ditions, the similar effects - in terms of some boost help the poor, for which the public distribution system
in productivity and growth rates - as reform pro- as well as parts of the public sector, and a continuing
gresses, which were summarized above, are only to be ban on consumer goods imports are deemed essential
expected. - despite all the countervailing evidence (see e.g.,
Lal, 1988; Bhagwati, 1993) were yet again on display.
The long-standing and atavistic Brahminical disdain
4. FUTURE for commerce and trade was also in evidence, as was
the continuance of a prickly nationalism - as some
What of the future of reform in the two countries? took umbrage at an official report written by NRI
Again, though the current euphoria in the media and economists!
financial circles about China, in contrast with the This nationalism, however, provides some hope for
growing despondency about India - beset by various the future. One of the important themes of the Lal-
ethnic and religious conflicts - might suggest that the Myint comparative study is the role of nation-build-
course of reform is assured in China but not in India, ing in explaining the rise of dirigisme and its reform.
appearances can once again be deceptive. As we have For the dirigisme which is invoked to foster order,
seen, the obstacles in the path of reform are essentially leads over time to the unintended consequence of
political in both cases - and involve the dismantling breeding disorder, as economic agents seek increas-
of systems of unviable entitlements, in particular to ingly to escape the official net. Liberalization is then
organized labor and the bureaucracy. It might appear undertaken by nationalists to restore order in what
that a dictatorship committed to reform would find it seem to have become ungovernable economies.
easier to do so than a democracy. But it is this issue of Heckschers historical work on mercantilism provides
commitment which is in question in both countries. an almost exact parallel in this cycle of dirigisme-dis-
Recently The Economisr summarized the necessary order - liberalization, in post-Renaissance Europe.
conditions for successful liberalization that have The Indian case as I have briefly indicated in the pre-
emerged from Latin American experience in the catch vious section fits this thesis. Hence if nationalism is
phrase, commitment, competence and consensus. still alive and well in India, it may lead its adherents
This, it argued, in Latin America involved people at to see that further liberalization is essential to acquire
the top committed to it; other people technically qual- the economic strength without which the nation will
ified to implement it; a national trauma, such as hyper- not be safe from disorder, originating from within or
inflation, that lives on in the memory of voters as a without. The media hype about China has helped in
horror to which they never wish to return (The this context.
Economist, November 13.1992, LA survey, p. 14). Of Moreover, there has been a remarkable alteration in
these conditions the second seems to be met, as there the climate of public opinion, where the empower-
are undoubtedly competent technical teams in both ment of the common man against the many tyrannies
countries capable of implementing reform. It is doubts of the Permit Raj promised by the reformers, gladdens
about the first and third conditions which give one many middle-class hearts hankering after Western
cause to pause in both countries. style consumerism! Meanwhile the relatively shrink-
ing rewards from public service as compared with
those in the private sector are persuading many of their
(a) India children to seek commercial careers. This should help
to undermine the long-standing Brahminical attitudes
Take the condition regarding commitment. What is against Banias. These cultural attitudes which in the
the degree of commitment to reform of the current past favored seemingly selfless mandarins over selfish
1486 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

markets have also been undermined by the contempt officers but also the karamchari unions in nationalized
in which nearly all politicians and many bureaucrats banks, parastatals, and the central and state govem-
- seen as equally corrupt - are increasingly held by ments. The government has not tackled the thorny
the public. If both mandarins and markets are now issue that a large number of them will have to be made
seen as corrupt (in the Augustan sense - see redundant, in the interests of both economic efficiency
Pocock, 1975; Lal, 1985), the ethical preference for and the fist. The example of the DGTD, whose func-
the former is undermined, and the efficacy of the two tions became redundant with the ending of industrial
alternatives in promoting opulence becomes the licensing, does not augur well for the future. Evident-
paramount consideration. Even the partial liberaliza- ly, even though redundant, the officers of the DGTD
tion that has so far taken place may have helped to still come to their offices even when there is no work
strengthen this shift to attitudes toward the market. for them, and continue to draw their pay and perquisites!
One straw in the wind is the very different reaction Finally, until recently the conversion of the states to
that Prime Minister V. P. Singhs desire to implement economic liberalization was less in evidence than that
the Mandal Report on caste reservations in govem- of the center. As the states in India control agriculture,
ment jobs evoked from the universities compared with irrigation, power, road transport, health and education
the virtual silence that greeted the Rao governments - amounting together for over half of GDP - this
actual implementation of the report on instructions matters. But more recently prompted by their own fis-
from the Supreme Court. Some commentators in India cal crises the states seem to be reforming,20 at a time
have suggested that with the liberalization undertaken when given the easing of the centers fiscal and for-
in 199 1, job prospects in the private sector look much eign exchange crisis, it seems to be cooling its heels
brighter to the upper-caste young than in the public until the next elections due in 1996.
sector, so the policy of reservations is of lesser rele- There are clearly many rocks ahead in the path of
vance to their future! Indian economic reforms. The technical competence
Against these hopeful signs are more dire ones - is there, and I have argued that there is also a general
based on interest. The major potential losers from the consensus in the country for reform, but the commit-
reform are businesses in previously protected sectors, ment of the politicians and hence the credibility of the
and the bureaucracy. Ihe interlocking interests of the reforms must still remain in doubt.
politicians, industrialists and bureaucrats in perpetuat-
ing the rents generated by the Permit Raj which
financed politics, are well known. An alternative (b) China
source of electoral finance is still not in place; without
it, the continuing commitment of Indian politicians to What of China? Here I can do no more than specu-
economic liberalization must remain questionable. late on the basis of what little we know of the inner
The losers among the businessmen are already group- workings of the Chinese government. (But see
ing together and lobbying for more gradual reforms as Baums reconstruction of the palace struggles during
well as various concessions to allow them to play on Dengs ascendancy.) Unlike India there would seem
an equal playing field with foreign investors. (at least as long as Deng Xiaoping is alive) that those
Implicit threats are being made that they might finance committed to reform in the Chinese polity will remain
the BJP which has played the populist anti-foreign on top, purely because Deng has repeatedly reiterated
card, and argued for internal liberalization with no (or
his continuing support for reform. This raises the
little) liberalization of foreign trade and direct foreign
question of why Deng supported liberalization and
investment. Interestingly, though, the newer business
how if at all he envisages it to proceed. A few clues are
groups (e.g., the Ambanis) have lobbied for a faster
provided in a recent biography by a former UK
process of liberalization as they, unlike their older
Ambassador to China (Evans, 1993). Three themes
brethren, feel they can compete in global markets.
emerge: Deng as a passionate nationalist, a man keen
The most recalcitrant group is likely to be the
on preserving the Communist party, and the morale of
bureaucrats. It is not the production workers in public
its members and, finally, a socialist for whom social-
sector enterprises who are the problem - they can be
ism was associated with prosperity [and who] was
pensioned off through the National Renewal fund, or
ready to try a wide variety of means in the quest for
some other severance scheme (see Fiszben, 1992;
prosperity (p. 146). He did not have any particular eco-
Diwan, 1993). It is the white-collar bureaucracy, num-
nomic theory to guide him. Evans reports him as saying:
bering in the millions who are the problem. They all
seek the job security, perks and perquisites of the All
I am a layman in the field of economics. I have made a
India services, and seek, like them, to enlarge the base few remarks on the subject, but all from a political point
of their respective job pyramids so that there are more of view. For example I proposed Chinas economic pol-
worthwhile jobs on top. In the traditional Indian icy of opening to the outside world, but as for the details
casteist framework they want to protect not merely or specifics of how to implement it, I know nothing
their incomes but status! They include not only the (Evans, 1993, p. 236).
INDIA AND CHINA 1487

We also learn from Evans that during one of his extra budgetary resources generated approximately
periods of disgrace Deng turned to reading Chinese Y 30 billion in military income in 1992 - accounting
history and his speeches thereafter reflected this edu- for almost half the PLAs total outlays (1994, p. 379).
cation. It is pure speculation, but if he did read the These constitute important groups whose self-interest
history of the Sung, could that not have provided him must now lie in continuing reform. This effective
with the vision of a vigorous China ruled by man- cooption of uppartchih and the army in reform, in
darins under an imperial dynasty which nevertheless contrast to India, makes the commitment of the polit-
tolerated a market economy and the prosperity it ical elite to reform much more credible.
begat? It would reconcile Though it may seem redundant to discuss any pop-
ular consensus about reform in a dictatorship, Chinese
the contradictions many outside China have seen history is replete with examples where - while
between Dengs readiness to experiment boldly in the authoritarian dynastic rule has been the norm - a
economic sphere and his political conservatism. Far from
seeing political liberalization as a necessary condition for
dynasty could see another replace it if, in the eyes of
economic liberalization, he has seen it as a serious poten- the people, it lost the Mandate of Heaven! Here, as in
tial threat to social and political stability and therefore to India, the dirisgiste system established by the
development (Evans, 1993, p. 219). Communists did conform with atavistic cultural atti-
tudes. It is impossible to judge how far the current
If Dengs commitment to reforms (as long as they dynasty and in particular the reformers have been
are controlled by the party) is assured, that cannot be tarred with the visible signs of the blatant rent-seeking
said of the rest of the party. The debates between those and corruption which has accompanied economic
who want to return to planning and those who want to liberalization.23
go further in economic liberalization continue, and Finally, as regards competence, the Chinese suffer
given the past history of the turns in the roulette wheel from having lost a whole generation of youth to mal-
in intraparty disputes, it would be foolhardy to predict education during the Cultural Revolution. The only
what the outcome will be when Deng meets Marx (see technically sound economists are very young, and
Baum, 1994). though there are enough of them now around the
As in India there are conflicting tendencies. First, world, it is difficult to judge whether they can be put
the sapping away of both administrative and fiscal together into a team and given their head, as India has
authority from the center has made the regions and been able to do spectacularly.
their officials more powerful in determining Chinas Thus for slightly differing reasons, but ultimately
future.* Those in the South have benefited personally because of problems concerned with politics and cul-
from all forms of effectively privatized enterprise in ture the reforms in both China and India remain inse-
which they and their relatives have become partnersz2 cure. So though, as ever, the potential of the two Asian
Second, the army (from all accounts) has also taken to giants remains immense if only they could be
joint ventures and commerce in a big way. Thus Baum unshackled from dirigisme, it is not as yet certain that
notes: According to foreign intelligence estimates, it will be realized.

NOTES

1, For the earlier period see Baran (1957). Malenbaum Rubin (1986), Demberger and Eckaus (1987). Swamy
(1959). Moore (1966), Raj (1967), lshikawa (1967). Bardhan (1989). Dreze and Sen (1989). Rosen (1990, 1992). Bhalla
(1969). Chen and Uppal (1971). Richman (1972, 1975). (1992) and Srinivasan et al. (1993).
Swamy (1973, 1977). Harris (1974), Bhattacharji (1974).
Desai (1975). Gurley (1975). Weisskopf (197%. 1975b), 2. See Malenbaums (1990) review of Demberger and
Byres and Nolan (1976) and Bergmann (1977). As Matson Eckaus (1987). in which he pointedly notes the inconsistency
and Selden (1992) note these comparisons were mainly used in the conclusions the authors draw jointly about the com-
lo demonstrate the superiority of socialism over capitalism parative performance of the two countries, as contrasted with
in mobilizing resources for rapid economic growth and ame- that in their individual chapters about each. Thus no matter
liorating widespread destitution and poverty in predomi- stands out more clearly in Chs. 2 and 3 of this study than the
nantly agrarian poor colonial societies. After the 1978 contrasts between Chinas highest level Confucian rate of
Chinese reforms reexaminations of the Chinese experience growth and Indias bottom level Hindu rate of growth.
have debunked long-standing shibboleths (p. 701). See Indeed this is the most fundamental difference in the official
Lardy (1983). Harding (1987). Riskin (1987). Feuchtwang, economic records of the two nations, 1950-85 (p. 398). and
Hussain and Pairault (1988). Nolan (1988) and Selden yet Ch. 1, essentially cancels the extraordinary economic
(1988, 1992). achievement record of China presented in Ch. 2, while it
The more recent comparisons of Indian and Chinese retains the official development performance of India, ana-
development experience include Malenbaum (1982, 1990), lyzed in Ch. 3 (p. 404). The authors conclude jointly that
1488 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

the PRC economy in the mid-1980s was in the process of rationality. What defines the market is not that people
being overtaken by Indias economy; the change is in exchange things, but that they do so in the spirit of maxi-
absolute as well as relative terms. This conclusion is consis- mizing economic advantage and above all, that they do it
tent with other professional views; mostly, however, Chinas with a complete disregard of other considerations.. .What
development achievements have been judged more success- defines a market society is of course not the presence, but the
ful than Indias and by a growing margin (p. 405). predominance of such relations (pp. 130-I 31). Traders have
par excellence been agents of instrumental rationality, but in
3. A referee has questioned this cultural argument. He most agrarian societies, such activity is . ritually circum-
raises several points. First, that while traditional Confucian scribed, a small island in a sea of producers of subsistence
values might have bolstered the anti-capitalist mentality of (Gellner, 1988, p. 276). My concern in this paper in part is
the Communist regime, it does not provide any useful insight therefore to examine to what extent this atavistic attitude in
to argue that the failure of the Communist regime resulted the two countries has been eroded, for that will determine the
from its anti-capitalist attitudes. Second, if these attitudes sustainability of a market society in the future. While one of
have continued into the reform period, then Dengs much the assertions is that both Chinese Communism and Indian
repeated statement to get rich is glorious needs to be Fabian socialism reflected and strengthened these atavistic
explained. Third, why are overseas Chinese (presumably attitudes.
under the Confucian spell) such great business people? Third, as regards the specific worries (second to fifth
Fourth, why were so many Chinese on the mainiand quick to above) of the referee they can now be easily disposed of.
become agricultural and commercial entrepreneurs when Dengs exhortation to his people to get rich in fact shows the
reforms created such opportunities? Fifth, while these atti- continuing prevalence of the opposite cultural attitude -
tudes might have reinforced bureaucratic efforts to stifle pri- otherwise why would he bother? You do not find US presi-
vate initiatives, Chinese bureaucrats have been notorious for dents making similar exhortations to their people! As regards
using public resources for private profit. the overseas Chinese, as noted in the body of the paper, the
There are answers at several levels to these worries. The relevant groups transforming postreform China were in fact
first is a definition of culture. The one most congenial to my the class of merchants and traders who fled the Revolution.
argument is Gellners: A culture is a distinct way of doing They have been acting out their traditional role, while the
things which characterizes a given community (p. 14). It predatory bureaucracys relationship with them is much as it
underpins the rules of the game in any society, and pro- was in medieval China. None of this constitutes by itself a
vides in Norths (1990) terms the informal constraints on change in the culture of China in favor of a market society.
human interaction (Ch. 5) which in a world of limited infor- The important question is whether the instrumental rational-
mation and computational ability reduce the costs of such ity of the merchant has been accepted by the majority of
interaction. Moreover, these behavioral constraints are Chinese.
socially transmitted a form of transmission which unlike Finally, as regards the entrepreneurship shown by the
genetic transmission, does perpetuate acquired characteris- common people in the reform period in China, this is no sur-
tics. In fact, culture, consists of sets of acquired characteris- prise because as economists we would expect, ceteris
tics (Gellner, 1988, p. 14). Furthermore as North argues paribus that the economic principle (viz. people would act
these informal constraints often survive changes in the for- economically; when the opportunity of an advantage was
mal rules (e.g., constitutions). Hence we find that the same presented to them they would take it, Hicks, 1979, p. 43) is
formal rules and/or constitutions imposed on different soci- universal (also see Schultz, 1990). What we cannot deduce
eties produce different outcomes But what is most strik- from this is the extent to which their own entrepreneurial
ing is the persistence of so many aspects of a society in activity has changed their atavistic attitudes toward trade and
spite of a total change in the rules Even the Russian commerce.
Revolution perhaps the most complete formal transformation The referee in a rebuttal demurs with this view citing
of a society we know cannot be completely understood with- Granovetter who claims that the new institutional economics
out exploring the survival and persistence of so many infor- - of which I am a subscriber - is based on a contradictory
mal constraints (North, p. 37). oversocialized and undersocialized conception of
For an empirical validation of the importance of these cul- human behavior. But as Granovetter (1985) notes (though
tural factors in determining current outcomes in Italy despite disapprovingly) both conceptions have in common a con-
changes in the environment see Putnam (1993). It should ception of action and decision carried out by atomized actors.
also be noted that while immigrants may carry over the habits In the undersocialized account, atomization results from nar-
of their past culture to their new environment, we would row utilitarian pursuit of self-interest; in the oversocialized
expect that over the generations it is the culture of their host one, from the fact that behavioral patterns have been inter-
society (if it has a dominant culture) which is likely to pre- nalized and ongoing social relations thus have only periph-
vail. Hence the recent econometric exercise by Carroll, Rhee eral effects on behavior. That the internalized rules of
and Rhee (1994) to discover if here are cultural effects on behavior are social in origin does not differentiate this argu-
savings by examining the savings patterns of immigrants to ment decisively from a utilitarian one, in which the source of
Canada from different cultures is beside the point. utility functions is left open, leaving room for behavior
Second, I am particularly concerned with the atavistic guided entirely by consensually determined norms and val-
attitudes found in both countries toward trade and commerce ues -as in the oversociahzed view (p. 485). Social influ-
(also see Lal, 1985). As Gellner notes this was a common fea- ences are all contained inside an individuals head, so, in
ture of settled agrarian civilizations with their qualitative actual decision situations, he or she can be atomized as any
division of labor between three orders of men, those who Homo economicus. though perhaps with different rules for
fight, pray and work (1988, p. 277). As he notes, one dis- decision (p. 486). Quite. Thus there is nothing contradictory
tinctive feature of a market economy is its instrumental for example in the Victorian entrepreneurs relentless pursuit
INDIA AND CHINA 1489

of profit (undersocialization) and his using the wealth ism was a typical product of the European genius. If it should
thereby obtained to buy a landed estate to gentrify himself be considered laughable to write European history in caste
and his progeny (oversocialization)! Similarly, I find no con- terms by the same token applying feudalism in Indian history
tradiction in arguing that Chinese peasants and businessmen should be treated as maladroit (p. 2146).
are happy to truck and barter (on the economic principle) but For China, Dull (1990) notes: The Chou period is some-
their attitudes to merchants and commerce in general are times referred to as feudal, but whether one has the Western
governed by the ascription of relative status by the high cul- Chou or the Eastern Chou in mind, the designation is not
ture. On the usual complaint by sociologists, including applicable Three characteristics of Western feudalism
Granovetter, that the new institutional economics falls foul of highlight the differences. First, the relationship between a
some methodological prescription concerning functional- lord and his vassals in the West was a legal one in which both
ism see La1 (1988) pp. 4-7. parties were equal before the law; the notion of a legally
binding contract between equals was not present in the Chou
4. But as Jones (1988) emphasizes, China did have one period, nor was it ever to become a feature of later Chinese
period of intensive growth during the Sung period. law. Second the process of subinfeudation by which [the]
vassalic pyramid was built, although not totally unknown in
5. An organic economy is defined by Wrigley as an China at this time, was not common ___Third, the primary
economy bounded by the productivity of land (1988, p. 5). function of the Western knight was to fight for his lord; in
In such an economy - and historically this has been the Chou China there were simply no knights (pp. 59-60)
dominant type over the globe - there is a universal depen-
dence on organic raw materials for food, clothing, housing 8. It should be noted that the role of Confucian culture in
and fuel. Their supply is in the long run inevitably con- promoting anti-market and anti-merchant attitudes remains
strained by the fixed factor - land. This was also true of tra- controversial Thus some scholars (see e.g., de Bary, 1991;
ditional industry and transport. Most metal-working Weiming, 1990; Redding, 1990) maintain that Confucian
industries were dependent upon charcoal (a vegetable sub- values were not directly anti-market but were against ill-got-
stance) for smelting and working crude ores. Hence in an ten and excessive wealth. While aspects of the culture -e.g.,
organic economy, once the land frontier is reached, dimin- familialism, a bureaucracy chosen by examinations, and the
ishing returns will take their inexorable toll. importance of education in conferring status through the
mandarinate -have been important for the economic devel-
6. Thus as Spear (1965) notes of the growing mercantile opment of the neo-Confucian miracle economies of East
class in Mughal India: The merchants did not dare to display Asia (see Hicks and Redding, 1993; Vogel, 1991). While a
their wealth like the merchants of London or Amsterdam; referee has suggested that like other absolutist states, whether
they appeared at court more often as victims of a squeeze in Europe or Asia, the Chinese imperial state established
than as respected financial advisers (p. 47). Also see institutions that restricted trade and expropriated wealth from
Chaudhri (1985) who argues that India failed to define the its merchant community. In this respect there was nothing
legal position of the merchant and hence commerce remained distinctive about China. He argues that it was the Communist
tainted by usury. On China see Feuerwerker (1984). While party which translated the Confucian disdain for ill-gotten
Keightley notes: Despite the remarkable commercial activ- and excessive wealth into anti-merchant and anti-market atti-
ity that characterized many cities of post-Sung China tudes.
merchants in China did not achieve the kind of political, legal But others see a greater continuity in attitudes and values
and economic independence that they did in the West. This between the classical imperial state and the communist one.
is a distinction of fundamental importance whose deep and Thus Jenner (1994) notes: The communist state is in many
ancient roots are partly to be found in a political system that ways a reinvention of the bureaucratic monarchy The
gave kinship ties and their political extensions priority over founders of the Communist party were products of Qing
commercial and legal ones (1990, p. 47). China, educated in its schools and culture and soaked in its
Similarly Pye notes: In China, merchants were assigned values. To them it was only natural that the state should be
low social status, hence denied power; and they could only absolute and that a bureaucratic monarchy was the normal
improve the status of their heirs by educating them as form it should take Attitudes to state power remain heav-
scholar-officials (1985, p. 49). That these are atavistic atti- ily influenced by traditional values. The states power
tudes cultivated by most stable agrarian societies is argued in remains absolute and sacrosanct. Though it can often be got
Gellner (1988). For a discussion of how these atavistic atti- around, it cannot be challenged. Politics at the top is played
tudes have continued to infect the modem world see La1 by the rules of palace struggles, which owe more to the polit-
(1985). ical pundit of the third century BC Han Fei than to Marx
(pp. 35-36).
7. Thus Bloch (1965) has argued that feudalism in the West Baum (1994) provides a detailed reconstruction of these
was such an institution because of the emphasis it placed on continuing palace struggles at the top of the Chinese state in
the idea of an agreement capable of binding the rulers (vol. Dengs reform period.
2, p. 452). By contrast though there has been interminable Jenner also notes that the essential feature of the high
controversy about whether the Hindu social order was a vari- culture which has dominated China is one which has pro-
ant of European feudalism, Rudra (1981) is right and devas- moted the values of a premodem imperial bureaucracy.
tating in denying that it was. Imagine two men face to face There is plenty of evidence that Chinas business cultures
says Marc Bloch while describing the ritual of homage; well, have long been able to flourish if only they were allowed to.
we simply cannot imagine two men face to face in the con- but for over two thousand years states have preferred to keep
text of Indian social history (p. 2144). The caste system is business divided, confined and controlled (Jenner. 1994,
a characteristic product of the Indian genius, just as feudal- p. 178).
1490 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

As regards the role of Confucian familial values in 18-21% as estimated in a report of the National Institute of
explaining the success of the overseas Chinese (see Redding, Public Finance and Policy (March 1985).
1990). a recent, important paper by Greif (1994) is relevant.
He examines the institutional responses to the familial (col- 11. In Lal(l990) I estimated that the public sector borrow-
lectivist) cultural beliefs of Maghribi traders and the individ- ing requirement which was about 8% in 1960, and 7.5%
ualist ones of Genoese ones in the Mediterranean trading in 1970, had risen to 12.3% of GDP by 1985-86. Much of
world of the 1lth century. It was the very familialism of the this was due to the rise in nondevelopmentalexpenditure,as
Maghribiworld which while accountingfor theircommercial capital expenditures had stagnated at about 10% of GDP
success, neverthelesspreventedthe institutionalinnovations while overall government expenditure rose from about
- most importantlythe development of contractand com- 19% of GDP in 1960 to over 34% in 1985, tax receipts
mercial law-which emerged as a matter of necessity in the rose from 11% of GDP in 1960 to about 21% in 1980, and
individualistic Genoese trading world, and which were even- then stagnated.
tually an important factor behind the rise of the West.
Similarly, I would argue, it is the continuing hold of these 12. But see Lin, Cai and Li (1994) for an alternative view,
atavistic familial values which has prevented those legal which seeks to provide a rationale for the more gradualist
underpinnings of a modem commercialized market economy approach adopted in China, andfaur mieur in India, as com-
from emerging in China. pared with Russia and many East European countries. Their
As regards the success of the overseas Chinese and the argument is that with the heavy industry biased development
neo-Confucian societies of the East Asian edge, Jenner strategy, the economys production point is far beyond the
(1994) is surely right in stating that their success has little to Pareto-efficient point (given by comparative advantage)
do with Chinas past but with European economics, com- toward the heavy industry axis on the production possibility
mercial law, science and technology (p. 172). Onlywhen curve of the economy, where all other goods are the other
these alien, Western factors came into play were certain ele- light industry and agriculture category. As it is difficult to
ments within some inherited East Asian value systems able shiti resources out of the heavy industries speedily, it may be
to bring about successful capitalist development (p. 170). In second best to keep their output frozen and put incremental
the absence of the dynamic, alien, Western institutions and resources into the other sectors. Thus over time the econ-
forms of economic organization that have transformed omy will approach its efficient point on the shifting PPP
these other countries the familistic values [of the mainland] curve. This they argue will avoid the otherwise unavoidable
are more likely to impede than to support change and devel- losses of output as the heavy industries become unviable
opment. In particular, China is still under the rule of a thinly under a big bang.
disguised, premodem imperial bureaucracy, unlike those for-
mer colonies (pp. 172-173). A similar explanation and 13. But as Perkins (1994) notes these property rights were
prognosis of the different parts of the Chinese world is pro- not complete even in the 1990s. The buying and selling of
vided by Pye. Also see Morishma, (1982) who also argues long term land leases was only allowed in urban areas.
that it is deviations from Japans Confucian past which in Acquiring rural land for factory use typically involved
large part explain its extraordinary economic success. laborious negotiations in which the factory guaranteed jobs
Finally, Vogels argument that the meritocratic bureau- and other benefits to displaced farmers in exchange for the
cratic tradition of China, based on entrance exams has been use of their land.Land transfer within rural areas typically
an important contributor to East Asias success can be coun- involved guaranteeing a basic grain ration to those giving up
tered by two counterexamples. India and the United their land use rights (Perkins, 1994, p. 29).
Kingdom established modem meritocratic bureaucracies,
with considerable social cachet in the late 19th century. They 14. Wen (1993) provides a detailed analysis of total factor
compare favorably on every dimension with those of East productivity (TFP) changes in Chinese agriculture during
Asia. But, nevertheless, these mandarins have not been 1952-89. He finds that the mutual aid groups and elementary
able to improve the economic prospects of their respective cooperatives of the early and mid- 1950sdid not damage TFP,
countries. confirming Lins (199Oa) conjecture that an institutional
arrangement which allows for free entry and exit does not
9. No comprehensive estimates of the magnitude of these damage economic performance. The subsequent period of
politically determined entitlements are available. But the communes raised land productivity but worsened labor
Bardhan (1984) has estimated that direct subsidies on food, productivity, because of incentive effects. Lin (199Ob)esti-
fertilizers, and exports, amounted to half the gross capital mates that losses due to poor incentives were as much as 20%
formation in manufactuting in the public sector in 198&8 1. of TFP. The introduction of the household responsibility sys-
While subsidies granted by the central and state governments tem in 1982 raised both land and labor productivity, accord-
in 1982-83 were 40 times the levels of 1960-61. In addition ing to Wen. Since 1985 the growth of crop production has
were the subsidized losses of public sector units, public ini- slowed down but that of noncrop production has continued to
gation works, state electricity boards and state road transport grow. This is partly due to the continuing control of grain
commissions. The gross domestic product for public admin- prices, which provided farmers an incentive to shift acreage
istration rose seven-fold during 1950-80, as compared with to higher valued cash crops, and because with the growth
a rise in the. overall gross domestic product of less than three of rural industry farmers preferred to invest in this highly
times during the same period (Bardhan, 1984, pp.62-64). profitable new opportunity (see Perkins, 1994).

10. Statistical estimates of the black economy in India, 15. Jefferson, Rawski and Zheng (1992) show that TFP after
which is notoriously difficult to measure, vary from about reform rose in both the state and nonstate industrial sectors
40-45% of GDP (Mohammed and Whalley, 1984) to but it rose faster in the nonstate sector.
INDIA AND CHINA 1491

16. Yusuf (1994) notes with regards to the collectives which brankruptcies of large firms until the early 1990s and not
comprise the bulk of rural enterprises that: on paper these many then (p. 39).
have remained the property of the community. But in an
increasing number of instances, collectives have either 20. Thus The Economist (August 6, 1994) reported: State
been established by individuals with their own capital or governments are now bust, largely because they are getting
leased to local entrepreneurs. Theii ownership claims are less cash from Delhi, and bankruptcy is now driving radical
tacitly recognized, although in the formal sense rights are change Uttar Pradesh, Indias largest state, has raised
fuzzy (p. 76). power tariffs sharply, put 28 sugar mills up for sale and out-
lined plans to privatize power generation and distribution.
17. The problem is more severe in China where the state sec- The chief minister of Madhya Pradesh proposes to sack
tor accounts for about 52% of economic activity as compared 28,000 workers. Several other states are privatising loss-
with the Indian public sectors sham of about 24%. making companies and cutting payrolls (p. 50).
Moreover, India is using the national Renewal Fund to pen-
sion off workers in the National Textile Corporation for 21. As Baum notes by the early 1990s: with the center con-
instance, so that nonviable firms can be wound up. But India trolling a steadily diminishing share of the nations material
also has its problem of sick industries. The Indian state and fiscal resources, Beijings relations with the provinces
refuses to allow its capitalists to close them down because its had come to resemble a semi-anarchic game of mutual bar-
politicians and bureaucrats accuse them of taking public gaining, backscratching, and bickering, rather than a hierar-
loans and then running them into the ground. They as a result chical game of centralized command and control (1994,
continue to deplete the fist. p. 328).

18. But it should be noted that despite its more centralized 22. Lin, Cai and Li (1994) note: After the reforms a market
and authoritarian polity, the Chinese Communist state price existed, legally or illegally, along with a planned price
has provided more economic power to its provinces than for almost every kind of input or commodity that the State
do the states in the democratic federal Indian polity (see controlled. The difference between the market price and the
Rosen, 1990, p. 281). Yusuf (1994) claims that: decentral- planned price was economic rent. It is estimated that the eco-
ization has a long history in China; traditionally, the nation nomic rent from the controlled commodity price, the interest
was governed by an exceedingly small central bureaucracy rate, and the exchange rate was at least 200 billion yuan,
which depended on gentry managed, local administrative about 21.5 percent of the national income. in 1988. In 1992
networks to exercise control (p. 73). But he then goes on the economic rent from bank loans alone reached 220 billion
to state in a footnote (no. 4): decentralizing tendencies yuan (p. 20). Baum notes that by October 1992, in the anti-
occurred towards the latter part of each dynastic period corruption drive launched in 1990: the cumulative total had
in China. For instance, in the twilight years of the risen to 733,543 party cadres disciplined for economic cor-
Ching dynasty in the mid-late-19th century, decentralization ruption, of whom 154,289 were expelled from the party
was on the rise and was particularly notable in the first (p. 3 17).
three decades of the 20th century. Rather than the
relatively decentralized nature of the traditional Chinese 23. One straw in the wind is the report (Daity Telegraph,
polity, which Yusuf seeks to muddle with the decentrahza- September 20. 1994, p. 12) that worried that the relaxation
tion associated with the withdrawal of the mandate of of communist ideology has left Chinese youth drifting, the
heaven from a dynasty, what we may now be witnessing is nation has embarked on a moral education campaign that
the latter, and this would naturally be of concern to the combines patriotism with old fashioned Confucian values.
present dynasty! The important unanswered question is whether Dengism rep-
resents the last throw of a dynasty about to lose the Mandate
19. Perkins (1994) notes that though China had a bankruptcy of Heaven, or a revitalization of the existing dynasty
law in place in the latter half of the 1980s. there were no through embracing a mercantile culture.

REFERENCES

Ahluwalia, I. J., Productivity and Growth in Indian Union and China: A Comparative Analysis (Van Gorcun,
Manufac?uring (New Delhi: Oxford University Press, Assoc., 1977).
1991). Bhagwati, J., India in Transition - Freeing the Economy
Baran, P., The Political Economy of Growth (Berkeley, CA: (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1993).
University of California Press, 1957). Bhagwati, J. and T. N. Srinivasan, Indias Economic Reforms
Bardhan, P., The Political Economy of Development in India (New Delhi: Ministry of Finance, Govt. of India, 1993).
(Oxford: Blackwells, 1984). Bhalla, A. S., Uneven Development in the Third World, A
Bardhan, P., Agriculture in China and India: Output, input Study of China and India (London: Macmillan, 1992).
and prices, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 4, Nos. Bhalla, A. S., Rural-urban disparities in India and China,
l&2 (1969) pp. 129-136. World Development, Vol. 18, No. 8 (1990). pp.
Baum, R., Burying Mao - Chinese Politics in the Age of 1097-l 110.
Deng Xiaoping (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Bhattacharji, D., India and China: Contrast and comparison,
Press, 1994). 1950-1972, Journal of Contemporary Asia, Vol. 4,
Bergmann, T., The Development Models of India, the Soviet No. 4 (1974). pp. 439-459.
1492 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Blejer, M. et al., China: Economic Reform and problem of embeddedness, American Journal of
Macroeconomic Management IMF Occasional Paper 76 Sociology, Vol. 91, No. 3 (1985). pp. 481-510.
(Washington, DC: IMF, 1991). Greif, A., Cultural beliefs and the organization of society: A
Bloch, M., Feudal Society, 2 ~01s. (London: Routledge, historical and theoretical reflection on collectivist and
1965). individualist societies, Journal of Political Economy,
Block, H.. The Planetary Product in 1980: A Creative Vol. 102, No. 5 (1994). pp. 912-950.
Pause? (Washington, DC: Bureau of Public Affairs, U.S. Gurley, J. G., Discussion (of China and India: During the
Dept. of State, 198 1). last 25 years), American Economic Review, Vol. 65, No.
Byres, T. J. and P. Nolan, Inequality: India and China 2 (1975).
Compared, 1950-1970 (Milton Keynes: The Open Harding, H., Chinas Second Revolution: Reform After Mao
University, 1976). (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1987).
Carroll, C. D., B. K. Rhee and C. Rhee, Are there cultural Harris, N., India-China: Underdevelopment and Revolution
effects on saving? Some cross-sectional evidence, (Delhi: Vikas, 1974).
Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. CIX (1994). pp. Heckscher, E., Mercantilism, 2 vols, rev. Second edition
685-700. (London: Allen and Unwin, 1955).
Chaudhri, K. N., Trade Civilization in the Indian Ocean: An Heston, A. and R. Summers, The Penn world table: An
Economic History from the Rise of Islam to 1750 expanded set of international comparisons, 1950-1988,
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985). Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. CVI (1991).
Chen, K. 1. and J. S. Uppal (Eds.), India and China: Studies Hicks, J. R., A Theory of Economic History (Oxford:
in Comparative Development (New York: Free Press, Clarendon Press, 1969).
1971). Hicks, G. L. and S. G. Redding, The story of the East Asian
Cheung, S., Privatization vs. special interests: The expcri- economic miracle, Pts. I and II, Euro-Asia Business
ence of Chinas economic reform, in J. Dom & W. Xi Review, Vol. 2, No. 3 and Vol. 2, No. 4 (1983), pp. 18-22.
(Eds.), Economic Reform in China - Problems and Ishikawa, S., Economic Development in Asian Perspective
Prospects (Chicago: University of Chicago, 1990). (Tokyo: Kinokuniya, 1967).
Cheung, S., Will China Go Capitalist?, Second edition Jefferson, G. H. and T. G. Rawski, Enterprise reform in
(London: Institute of Economic Affairs, 1986). Chinese industry, Journal of Economic Perspectives,
de Bary, W. T., The Trouble With Confucianism (Cambridge, Vol. 8, No. 2 (1994), pp. 47-70.
MA: Harvard University Press, 1991). Jefferson, G. H.. T. G. Rawski and Y. Zheng, Growth, effi-
Demberger, R. F. and R. S. Eckaus, Financing Asian ciency, and convergence in Chinas state and collective
Development, II: China and India (Baltimore, MD: industry, Economic Deveiopment and Culturaf Change,
University of America Press, 1987). Vol. 40, No. 2 (1992). pp. 240-266.
Desai, P., Discussion (of China and India: During the last 25 Jenner, W. J. F., The Tyranny of History - The Roots of
years), American Economic Review, Vol. 65, No. 2 Chinas Crisis (London: Penguin Books, 1994).
(1975), pp. 365-368. Jones, E. L., Growth Recurring - Economic Change in
Diwan, I., Efficient Severance Payment Schemes, Mimeo World History (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1988).
(Washington, DC: World Bank, May, 1993). Keightley, D. N., Early civilization in China: Reflections on
Dom, J. and Wang Xi (Eds.). Economic Reform in China - how it became Chinese, in P. S. Ropp (Ed.), Heritage of
Problems and Prospects (Chicago: University of Chicago China (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press,
Press, 1990). 1990) pp. 15-54.
Dreze, J. and A. K. Sen, Hunger and Public Action (Oxford: Kumar, D., The Chinese and Indian economies from ca
Clarendon Press, 1989). 1914-1949. Research Programme on the Chinese
Dull, J. L., The evolution of government in China, in P. S. Economy, CP No. 22, STICERD (London: London
Robb (Ed.), Heritage of China (Berkeley, CA: University School of Economics, 1992).
of California Press, 1990). pp. 55-85. Lal, D. and H. Myint, The Political Economy of Poverty,
Elvin, M., Why China failed to create an endogenous indus- Equity and Growth - A Comparative Study (Oxford:
trial capitalism: A critique of Max Webcrs explanation, Clarendon Press, in press).
Theory and Society, Vol. 3, No. 3 (1984). Lal, D., The Repressed Economy - Causes, Consequences,
Elvin, M., The Pattern of the Chinese Past (London: Reform, Economists of the Twentieth Cenrury Series
Methuen, 1973). (Aldershot, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 1993).
Evans, R., Deng Xiaoping (London: Hamish Hamilton, Lal, D., Economic Growth in India, Country Studies No. 3,
1993). International Centre for Economic Growth (San
Feuchtwang, S., A. Hussain and T. Pairault (Eds.), Francisco: ICS Press, 1990).
Transforming Chinas Economy in the Eighties, 2 vols Lal, D., The Hindu Equilibrium, vol 2: Aspects of Indian
(Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1988). Labor (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1989).
Feuerwerker, A., The State and the economy in late imper- Lal, D., The Hindu Equilibrium, vol I: Cultural Stability and
ial China, Theory and Society, Vol. 13 (1984). Economic Stagnation (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1988).
Fiszben, A., Labor retrenchment and redundancy compen- Lal, D., The Political Economy of Economic Liberaliza-
sation in state owned enterprises: The case of Sri Lanka, tion, World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 1, No. 2 (1987).
South Asia Region, Report No. IDP 121 (Washington, Lal, D., Nationalism Socialism and Planning, World
DC: World Bank, Dec., 1992). Development, Vol. 13, No. 6 (1985).
Gellner, E., Plough, Sword and Book - The Structure of Lal, D. Prices for Planning - Towards the reform of Indian
Human History (London: Collins Harvill, 1988). Planning (London: Heinemann Educational Books,
Granovetter, M., Economic action and social structure: The 1980).
INDIA AND CHINA 1493

Lai, D. and associates, Appraising Foreign Investment in (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1988).
Developing Countries (London: Heinemann Educational North, D., Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic
Books, 1975). Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
Lardy, N. R., Agriculture in Chinas Modern Economic 1990).
Developmenr (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, North, D. and R. P. Thomas, The Rise of the Western World
1983). (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973).
Lardy, N. R., Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China Perkins, D., Completing Chinas move to the market,
- 1978-1990 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 8, No. 2 (1994),
1992). pp. 23-46.
Lin, J. Y., The Needham Puzzle: Why the industrial revolu- Pocock, J. G. A., Early modem capitalism-The Augustan
tion did not originate in China, Dept. of Economics perception, in E. Kamenka and R. S. Neale (Eds.),
Working Paper No. 650 (Los Angeles: UCLA, 1992). Feudalism, Capitalism and Beyond (London: Arnold,
Lin, J. Y., Collectivization and Chinas agricultural crisis in 1975).
1959-1961, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98 Putnam, R. D., Making Democracy Work (Princeton, NJ:
(1990a). Princeton Univ. Press, 1993).
Lin, J. Y., Institutional reforms in Chinese agriculture: Pye, L. W., Asian Power and Politics - The Culturul
Retrospect and prospect, in J. Dom & W. Xi (Eds.), Dimensions of Authority (Cambridge, MA: Harvard
Economic Reform in China - Problems and Prospects University Press, 1985).
(Chicago: University of Chicago, 1990b). Raj, K. N., India. Pakistan and China: Economic Growth
Lin, J. Y., F. Cai and Z. Li, Why Chinas Economic and Outlook (Bombay: Allied Pub., 1967).
Reforms have been successful: Implications for other Rawski, T. G., Economic Growth in Prewar China
reforming economies, Mimeo (Beijing: Dept. of Rural (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1989).
Economy, Development Research Centre, April 1994). Redding, G. S., The Spirit of Chinese Capitalism (Berlin and
Ma, G. and R. Gamaut, How rich is China: Evidence from New York: de Gruyter Press, 1990).
the food economy, Working Paper, Dept. of Economics Reynolds, L. G., Economic Growth in the Third World.
(Canberra: Research School of Pacific Studies, Australian 1850-1980 (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press,
National University, 1992). 1985).
Maddison, A., Postwar growth and slowdown: A global Richman, B., Chinese and Indian development: An inter-
view, in G. Gahlen, H. Hesse and H. G. Ramser (Eds.), disciplinary environmental analysis, American
Wachstumstheorie Und Wachstumpolitik (Tubingen: J. C. Economic Review, Vol. 65, No. 2 (1975). pp. 345.-355.
B. Mohr, 1991). Richman, B., Economic development in India and China,
Malenbaum, W., A gloomy portrayal of development Pacific Afsairs (1972). pp. 75-91.
achievements and prospects: China and India, Economic Riskin, C., Chinas Political Economy: The Quest for
Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 38, No. 2 (1990), Development since 1949 (New York: Oxford University
pp. 391-406. Press, 1987).
Malenbaum, W., Modem economic growth in India and Rosen, G., Contrasting Styles of Industrial Reform: China
China: The comparison revisited, 195&1980, Economic und India in the 1980s (Chicago: Chicago University
Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 3 1, No. I (1982). Press, 1992).
pp. 45-84. Rosen, G., India and China: Perspectives on contrasting
Malenbaum, W., India and China: Contrast in develop- styles of economic reform, Journal of Asian Economics,
ment, American Economic Review, Vol. 49, No. 3 Vol. 1, No. 2 (I 990). pp. 273-290.
(1959), pp. 284-309. Rowe, W. T., Modem Chinese social history in comparative
Matson, J. and M. Selden, Poverty and Inequality in China perspective, in P. S. Ropp (Ed.), Heritage of China
and India, Economic and Political Weekly (April 4, (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1990), pp.
1992). pp. 701-715. 242-262.
McKinnon, R. I., Macroeconomic control in liberalizing Rubin, B. R., Journey to the East: Industrialization in India
socialist economies: Asian and European parallels, and the Chinese experience, in D. Basu and R. Sissons
Pacific Basin Working Paper Series, No. PB92-05 (San (Eds.), Social and Economic Development in India: A
Francisco: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, 1992). reassessment (New Delhi: Sage Publishers, 1986), pp.
McNeil], W. H., The Pursuit of Power (Oxford: Blackwell, 67-88.
1983). Rudra, A., Agamst feudalism, Economic and Political
Mohammed, J. and J. Whalley, Rent seeking in India: Its Weekly, Vol. 16, No. 52 (1981).
costs and policy significance, Kyklos, Vol. 37, No. 3 Schultz, T. W., Restoring Economic Equilibrium (Oxford:
(1984). Blackwell, 1990).
Moore Jr., B., Social Origins of Democracy and Selden, M., The Political Economy of Chinese Development
Dictatorship: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the (Armonk, NJ: M. E. Sharpe, 1992).
Modern World (Boston: Beacon Press, 1966). Selden M., The PolitIcal Economy of Chinese Sociulism
Morishima, M.. Why Has Japan Succeeded? (Cambridge: (Armonk, NJ: M. E. Sharpe, 1988).
Cambridge University Press, 1982). Spear, T. G. P.. A Histoy of India, Vol. 2 (London: Penguin,
Needham, J., The Grand Titration - Science and Society in 1965).
Easr and West (London: Allen and Unwin, 1969). Srinivasan, T. N., Overview and Economic liberalization
Nolan, P., State and Market in the Chinese Economy: Essays and future prospects, in T. N. Srinivasan et al., Agricul-
on Controversial Issues (London: Macmillan, 1993). ture and Trade in China and India: Policies and Perform-
Nolan, P., The Political Economy of Collective Farms clnce since 1950. ICEG (San Francisco: ICS, 1993a).
1494 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Srinivasan, T. N. et al., Agriculture and Trade in China and performance, American Economic Review, Vol. 65, No.
India: Policies and Performance Since 19S0, KEG (San 2 (1975b). pp. 356-364.
Francisco: ICS Press, 1993b). Wen, J. G., Total factor productivity change in Chinas
Swamy, S., Economic Growth in China and India -A Pers- farming sector, 1952-l 989, Economic Development and
pective by Comparison (New Delhi: Vikas Publishers, 1989). Cultural Change, Vol. 42, No. 1 (1993). pp. l-41.
Swamy, S., The Economic Distance between China and World Bank, World Development Report 1992 (New York:
India, 1955-1973, China Quarterly, Vol. 70 (1977) pp. Oxford University Press, 1992).
371-381. World Bank, China: Reform and the Role of the Plan in the
swamy, s., Economic growth in China and India, 1990s (Washington, DC: World Bank, 1992a).
1952-1970: A comparative appraisal, Economic World Bank, China: Long Term Issues and Options
Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 21, No. 6, Pt. 2 (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins, 1985).
(1973). World Bank, China: Socialistic Economic Development,
Vogel, E. F., The Four Little Dragons (Cambridge, MA: Vol. 1 (Washington, DC: World Bank, 1983).
Harvard University Press, 1991). _ Wong, C., Economic Reform in China (Manila: Asian
Weimine. T.. The Confucian tradition in Chinese historv. Development Bank, 1991).
in P.S. Ropp (Ed.), Heritage of China (Berkeley, CA: Wrigley, E. A.. Continuity, Chance and Change: The
University of California Press, 1990), pp. 112-137. Character of the Industrial Revolution in England
Weiner, M., The Child and State in India (Princeton, NJ: (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988).
Princeton University Press, 1991). Yi, Zing et al., Causes and implications of the increase in
Weisskopf, T. E., China and India: A comparative survey of Chinas reported sex ratio at birth, Population and
economic performance in economic development, Development Review, Vol. 19 (I 993).
Economic and Political Weekly, Annual Number (1975a), Yusuf, S.. Chinas macroeconomic performance and man-
pp. 175-194. agement during transition, Journal of Economic
Weisskopf, T. E., China and India: A comparative survey of Perspectives, Vol. 8, No. 2 (1994), pp. 71-92.

Você também pode gostar