Você está na página 1de 26

World Development Vol. 33, No. 3, pp.

455480, 2005
2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved
Printed in Great Britain
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev 0305-750X/$ - see front matter
doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2004.09.009

Child Labor and Schooling Decisions in Urban


and Rural Areas: Comparative Evidence
from Nepal, Peru, and Zimbabwe
LIRE ERSADO *
The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA
Summary. This study sheds some light on the causes of child labor using crosscountry empirical
data. We nd that while poverty is the main cause of child labor in rural areas, there is a general
lack of support for the poverty hypothesis in urban areas. Similarly, improving access to credit has
a greater potential for alleviating child labor and enhancing school attendance in rural areas. On
the other hand, availability of alternative childcare options promises greater impact in urban areas.
Finally, the evidence from all countries suggests that eorts to bolster adult educational level and
wage will help curb the prevalence and intensity of child labor and improve the likelihood that chil-
dren stay in school.
2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words child labor, child schooling, poverty, Nepal, Peru, Zimbabwe

1. INTRODUCTION children under age 15 who work range from


100 to 200 million. UNICEF (1991) estimated
The rate of economic growth crucially de- that there were 80 million children aged 1014
pends on the stock of human capital in a coun- who undertook work so long or arduous that
try (Barro, 1991; Lucas, 1988; Mankiw, Romer, it interfered with their normal development.
& Weil, 1992; Romer, 1987). A low level of Though many, including parents themselves,
human capital development has long been iden- agree that childhood is a period of school learn-
tied as a major impediment to economic ing and physical and mental developmentand
growth and elimination of poverty in develop- not of primarily income-generating work
ing countries. Several studies (e.g., Glick &
Sahn, 2000; Vijverberg, 1993) nd high returns
in the labor markets for investments in educa-
* I would like to thank James Garrett, Harold Alder-
tion for both men and women. Glick and Sahn
(1997), using data from a developing country, man, John Maluccio, and Futoshi Yamauchi for helpful
show that the earnings of women and men in- comments on an earlier draft of the paper. The paper has
crease with schooling in both self-employment also beneted from comments by participants at the
and wage employment. Similarly, other studies American Agricultural Economics Association Annual
have consistently shown that child education Meetings in Montreal, Canada, August 2003 and at the
has higher returns than other physical assets International Conference on Poverty, Food and Health
(e.g., Psacharopoulos, 1994). Despite these appa- in Welfare, Lisbon, Portugal, July 2003, where an earlier
rent benets, the level of education and educa- version of the paper was presented. The research was
tional attainment remain remarkably low in funded by the Department for International Develop-
most developing countries, and child labor, ment (DFID) of UK. The ndings, interpretations, and
considered to be a competing activity to school- conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of
ing, continues to be a common phenomenon. the author and do not necessarily represent the views of
Child labor is widespread in developing the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries
countries. Estimates by the International Labor they represent.Final revision accepted: September 16,
Organization (ILO, 1996) of the number of 2004.
455
456 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

many young children in low-income countries higher. 1 Cross-sectional data from India and
participate in the labor force, and their chance other developing countries show that a higher
of receiving even primary education is minimal. incidence of poverty is not correlated with a
Although child labor is widespread, its causes higher incidence of child labor (e.g., Swamina-
are debatable. Poverty is considered as the pri- than, 1998). The Becker model and more re-
mary reason, but many theoretical and empiri- cently Ranjan (2001) imply that income does
cal analyses show that other factors, such as not matter if complete credit markets exist. A
access to credit, school quality, and labor mar- study by Jacoby (1994) nds that borrowing
ket opportunities, play equal or even greater constraints negatively aect childrens school-
roles in child labor and schooling decisions. ing attainment in Peru. Studies also exist
That there is a higher geographic concentration which suggest that child labor decision is part
of child workers in poor countries (see Basu, of a households risk-management strategy
1999) suggests there is an inverse association (Grootaert & Kanbur, 1995; Jacoby & Skou-
between child labor and income. For poor as, 1997). Lack of access to credit for smooth-
households, school investment decisions are ing income uctuations over time might,
associated with a host of decisions regarding therefore, lead to a higher prevalence of child
use of time and other resources. Changes in labor. Jacoby and Skouas (1997) use a mea-
household circumstances, such as becoming sure of variability of household income in rural
poor, may elicit important time-use changes, India and nd that school attendance declined
not only of children who are students or poten- with income variability.
tial students, but of parents as well. Basu and Lack of access to school and low school qual-
Van (1998) argue that the mass phenomenon ity could also aect child schooling and work
of child labor does not reect the selshness decisions. For households rationally maximiz-
of parents wanting to enjoy more leisure time ing welfare, a low demand for schooling might
while their children work, but rather that pov- arise because of low school quality or excessive
erty compels them to send their children to costs. Inaccessible or poor quality schools
work. In developing countries, often more than may thus spur parents to engage their children
one member of a household generates income in more immediate and protable pursuits (e.g.,
(e.g., Ersado, 2002 on Zimbabwe; Pradhan & Grootaert & Patrinos, 1999). Schooling costs
van Soest, 1997 on Bolivia), which often neces- since schooling is the main competing activity
sitates use of child labor. Several studies that for childrens timecould also be an important
looked at schooling determinants in developing determinant of child labor (e.g., Siddiqi &
countries nd that household wealth gures Patrinos, 1995). Some children may have to
prominently in child schooling and work deci- work to aord the direct costs of schooling.
sions (e.g., Basu & Van, 1998). Bhalotra Even with sucient access to school, child
(2000a) nds that in Pakistan child work is labor may still continue to be a common phe-
caused by poverty. nomenon if the household decision making
Studies, citing evidence mainly from Latin process gives more weight to income from a
America, argue that rates of child labor are childs labor and less weight to a childs school-
higher at times when children have better work ing because of other factors such as poverty
opportunities as measured by local labor mar- (Grootaert & Kanbur, 1995).
ket conditions (Binder, 1999; Levison, Moe, & While labor is the poors greatest asset, child
Knaul, 2001). Since a seminal paper by Becker labor raises important concerns. A households
(1964), many development researchers have rec- decision to increase the number of family mem-
ognized the importance of opportunity costs in bers in the labor market implies that mothers
schooling decisions. The opportunity costs of might have to give up vital household and
schooling increases as market wages for child la- childcare activities, and children might have
bor increase. Furthermore, dierences in labor to sacrice their education in order to partici-
market conditions by gender may dierentially pate in income generating activities. When the
aect schooling decision for boys and girls. poor depend on their childrens labor rather
Still others argue that factors such as cre- than invest in their future by educating them,
dit market imperfection, not poverty, play a they risk perpetuating poverty from one gener-
greater role in sending children to work or ation to the next (Moser, 1996). It is important
keeping them at home to take care of domestic to understand the tradeos that households
household responsibilities, even though returns make between child labor-market participation
on education (which accrue in the future) are and other vital time allocation decisions such as
CHILD LABOR AND SCHOOLING DECISIONS IN URBAN AND RURAL AREAS 457

schooling and household work. The empirical weaken the presumption that poverty drives
evidence briey summarized above, however, child labor.
shows a general lack of consensus on the causes Before discussing the descriptive results, it is
of child labor and suggests that its determinants important to describe how child labor is mea-
may vary across geographic regions. It also sured. The measurement of child labor depends
casts doubt on the notion that child labor is pri- on how it is dened, and by ethical and cultural
marily caused by poverty. views. For some, all nonschool, nonleisure
This paper, using household survey data activities of children constitute child labor. Oth-
from three geographic regions (Africa, Asia, ers dene it as only full-time employment in eco-
and Latin America), investigates the factors nomic activities or as bad child labor such as
driving child labor by analyzing and compar- backbreaking work in quarries or mines. This
ing crosscountry evidence on child labor force paper denes child labor as hours in both wage
participation and education-related decisions. and nonwage activities, as reported by these
It specically asks questions such as: Does multipurpose and countrywide household sur-
child labor mainly arise as a response to low veys. This is in line with the work of Skouas
income, lack of access to credit, an improved and Parker (2002), who argue that such a broad
labor market, or poor school quality? Do we measure provides a more accurate estimate of
see dierences in sub-Saharan Africa, Latin the household preferences toward leisure.
America, and Southeast Asia? Are urban
rural dierences important in child labor and (a) Child schooling and employment
schooling decisions? Empirical models that distribution by age
simultaneously consider several factors aect-
ing labor participation and schooling decisions Tables 13 show child employment and
are scant. Yet identifying the key determi- school attendance rates for Nepal, Peru, and
nants of child labor and schooling are of par- Zimbabwe by age, sex, and location. While
amount importance to targeted policy and nearly all children in Peru and Zimbabwe ap-
program designs to address current and future pear to attend school, about a quarter of Nepa-
poverty. lese children have never been to school. For all
age groups, the current school attendance rates
are the lowest in Nepal (61%), followed by Peru
2. DATA AND DESCRIPTIVE ANALYSIS (85%), and Zimbabwe (88%). Lower attendance
rates for Nepalese children may reect a lack of
We use data from Nepal, Peru, and Zimba- access to schools, but those enrolled appear to
bwe to examine the key determinants of child stay in school more so than both Zimbabwean
labor and schooling decisions. The data are and Peruvian children.
from the 199091 Zimbabwe Income Expendi- The data from all countries show lower atten-
ture Consumption Survey (ZICES), the 1994 dance and higher employment rates in rural
Peru Living Standards Measurement Survey areas. Disaggregating by age and sex shows
(PLSS), and the 1995 Nepal Living Standards that attendance rate dierence by gender grows
Survey (NLSS). The surveys are nationally rep- wider with age in Zimbabwe than in either Peru
resentative, lending themselves for comparison or Nepal. While this is the case for both urban
on individual, household, and community-level and rural areas in Zimbabwe, rural areas of
characteristics. The PLSS covers about 3,623 Peru and Nepal show the biggest disparities in
households, the NPLSS 3,373 households, and attendance rates between boys and girls. This
the ZICES over 14,000 households. The Nepal evidence is suggestive of more favor for school-
and Zimbabwe surveys report child schooling ing of boys than girls in rural areas, while
and employment data for 3,617 and 15,467 chil- school attendance rates in urban areas do not
dren aged 1017, respectively. The Peru sample appear to show a signicant gender bias.
contains child labor and child schooling On the other hand, child employment rates
information for 5,191 children aged 617. 2 These go in an opposite direction to attendance, pos-
large-scale household surveys provide informa- sibly suggesting that dropping out of schools is
tion on children who work or do not work and at least partly driven by employment decisions.
those who attend or do not attend school, thus In all countries, labor force participation in-
enabling us to model child labor and schooling creases with age. In urban areas overall,
decisions. We anticipate that the results based employment rates are higher for boys than for
on more than one country will help solidify or girls in Peru and higher for girls than for boys
458 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 1. Attendance and employment rates among Nepalese children in 199596


Age Attendance Employment
Urban Rural Urban Rural
Male Female Total Male Female Total Male Female Total Male Female Total
10 85.7 79.2 82.6 77.7 52.8 65.3 7.1 13.2 10.1 20.6 31.6 26.1
11 86.8 87.9 87.3 78.3 64.3 71.0 5.3 0.0 2.8 26.8 34.5 30.8
12 85.9 77.3 82.4 71.4 48.5 61.1 12.5 15.9 13.9 38.5 48.5 43.0
13 85.1 71.8 79.1 75.2 50.3 64.5 17.0 20.5 18.6 40.2 49.7 44.3
14 80.7 69.1 75.0 64.8 46.4 54.8 19.3 18.2 18.8 50.6 53.1 52.0
15 79.6 75.5 77.6 56.1 35.5 46.5 24.5 18.4 21.4 55.6 66.3 60.6
16 54.2 73.3 63.4 49.5 34.3 42.1 33.3 26.7 30.1 58.7 63.2 60.9
17 73.8 65.8 70.0 42.4 33.3 37.9 31.0 18.4 25.0 59.7 66.7 63.2
Total 79.3 74.7 77.1 65.5 46.1 56.1 18.5 16.9 17.7 42.9 50.8 46.7

Table 2. Attendance and employment rates among Peruvian children in 1994


Age Attendance Employment
Urban Rural Urban Rural
Male Female Total Male Female Total Male Female Total Male Female Total
10 96.8 95.7 96.3 94.7 91.2 92.8 9.5 6.0 7.8 55.8 35.4 44.7
11 99.3 96.6 98.1 94.4 90.7 92.4 12.5 8.5 10.7 62.2 37.4 48.7
12 96.9 96.3 96.6 88.6 91.3 90.0 10.9 8.9 9.8 71.4 48.1 59.8
13 97.1 91.0 93.9 89.7 80.4 84.7 14.0 11.1 12.5 61.5 50.0 55.3
14 95.6 91.3 93.3 75.0 78.3 76.5 26.3 14.3 19.8 76.0 62.7 69.9
15 88.8 85.2 87.0 78.2 67.1 72.5 31.3 14.1 22.7 78.2 61.0 69.4
16 84.9 77.1 81.1 71.4 58.1 63.8 29.5 18.6 24.1 89.3 59.5 72.3
17 62.1 59.6 60.8 60.0 37.7 49.0 39.3 16.3 27.0 82.5 44.2 63.7
Total 91.9 88.3 90.1 84.5 82.4 83.4 15.1 9.2 12.1 56.6 40.1 48.0

Table 3. Attendance and employment rates among Zimbabwean children in 199091


Age Attendance Employment
Urban Rural Urban Rural
Male Female Total Male Female Total Male Female Total Male Female Total
10 98.4 99.3 98.9 95.7 95.6 95.7 0.4 1.1 0.8 3.0 2.6 2.8
11 98.7 98.6 98.6 95.1 96.4 95.8 0.9 0.0 0.5 3.1 2.7 2.9
12 99.0 96.5 97.8 94.6 93.5 94.0 0.5 1.5 1.0 5.1 4.4 4.8
13 97.5 98.6 98.1 92.1 91.6 91.8 1.0 1.4 1.2 4.9 6.5 5.7
14 94.8 91.0 92.6 89.7 83.3 86.7 1.1 5.6 3.7 7.9 13.5 10.5
15 97.0 78.6 87.5 81.9 67.4 75.1 1.5 14.1 8.0 13.9 24.5 18.8
16 88.9 70.9 78.5 76.0 60.3 68.4 2.4 18.4 11.6 17.4 32.6 24.7
17 75.8 54.1 64.2 64.8 51.3 58.5 3.2 25.5 15.1 27.4 39.7 33.1
Total 93.9 85.4 89.4 87.1 82.0 84.6 1.3 8.8 5.3 9.7 14.1 11.8

in Zimbabwe. In rural areas, female employ- is true in Peru. For all age groups and in both
ment rates appear to be higher than they are urban and rural areas, child employment rates
for boys in Zimbabwe, whereas the opposite are highest in Peru, closely followed by Nepal,
CHILD LABOR AND SCHOOLING DECISIONS IN URBAN AND RURAL AREAS 459

and lowest in Zimbabwe. This is particularly ment with schooling. Child time allocation to
true in rural areas: While nearly half of Peru- school and work signicantly dier by house-
vian and Nepalese children are engaged in some hold wealth level. In relatively wealthier house-
kind of employment activity, less than 12% of holds, children school attendance rate is higher
Zimbabwean children claim to do so. and their labor market participation rate is
lower for all countries.
(b) Child time allocation by residence, sex and
wealth (c) The role of children in the household

Table 4 presents child time allocation to A descriptive statistics of selected household


schooling, employment, or both, by residence, and community characteristics variables is pre-
gender, and household wealth level. A large sented in Table 5. At the household level, mens
proportion of Peruvian children undertake share of household income is highest in Nepal,
both schooling and employment activities followed by Zimbabwe and Peru. In all coun-
simultaneously. Interestingly, however, the pro- tries, womens and childrens share of house-
portion of children who both work and go to hold income grows, while the corresponding
school is higher than that of those who are em- share for mens tends to shrink in urban areas.
ployed only. In all countries, rural children are Childrens share of household income is largest
more likely to go to school and work at the in Nepal, while there is a negligible dierence
same time than are their urban counterparts. between Peru and Zimbabwe. Rural children
With regard to gender, fewer girls than boys at- in Zimbabwe contribute more to household in-
tend school full time, and more girls than boys come than do their urban counterparts. Simi-
are employed full time and combine employ- larly, in rural Nepal, children contribute a

Table 4. Children time allocation into employment, schooling, and/or both


Activity Nepal Peru Zimbabwe
All Rural Urban All Rural Urban All Rural Urban
(%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%)
By residence
Schooling 52.4 46.6 75.8 64.6 42.4 78.7 87.0 85.9 90.9
Employment 26.8 30.8 10.6 5.6 10.1 2.8 8.3 10.0 2.8
Both 11.8 13.6 4.6 20.3 37.7 9.4 0.4 0.3 0.5
Neither 9.0 9.0 9.1 9.5 9.8 9.2 4.3 3.9 5.9
Total 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100

All Boys Girls All Boys Girls All Boys Girls


(%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%)
By sex
Schooling 52.4 59.5 44.9 64.6 67.2 62.0 87.0 89.8 84.2
Employment 26.8 21.2 32.6 5.6 4.7 6.6 8.3 6.1 10.6
Both 11.8 14.5 9.1 20.3 15.5 25.4 0.4 0.3 0.4
Neither 9.0 4.8 13.4 9.5 12.7 6.1 4.3 3.8 4.8
Total 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100

Bottom Middle Top Bottom Middle Top Bottom Middle Top


(%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%)
By household wealth level
Schooling 37.4 48.1 70.6 51.6 70.8 74.7 84.7 87.1 90.5
Employment 39.6 31.6 10.5 8.2 4.6 3.3 10.8 8.1 4.8
Both 10.8 11.4 14.0 30.2 16.6 11.7 0.3 0.3 0.5
Neither 12.2 9.0 4.9 10.0 8.1 10.4 4.2 4.5 4.3
Total 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100
460 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 5. Means of selected variables


Nepal Peru Zimbabwe
All Urban Rural All Urban Rural All Urban Rural
Household size 5.59 5.28 5.67 5.38 5.31 5.50 5.03 4.32 5.43
Urban (yes) 0.19 0.61 0.25
Child sex (female) 0.48 0.45 0.49 0.51 0.50 0.52 0.50 0.52 0.49
Child age 13.28 13.33 13.3 13.5 13.62 13.18 13.2 13.40 13.18
Nonwage income per capita 6,902 14,614 5,093 2,358 2,964 1,315 44 51 40
Mens share of total income 0.81 0.72 0.82 0.73 0.69 0.79 0.75 0.84 0.65
Womens share of total income 0.12 0.23 0.10 0.24 0.28 0.17 0.20 0.16 0.25
Childs share of total income 0.06 0.03 0.07 0.04 0.03 0.04 0.02 0.002 0.04
Ratio of childs to mens labor 0.27 0.13 0.31 0.12 0.08 0.19 0.06 0.02 0.08
Ratio of childs to womens labor 0.30 0.26 0.31 0.36 0.26 0.49 0.11 0.05 0.12
Child ever been to school (yes) 0.68 0.86 0.67 0.99 1.00 0.98 0.99 0.99 0.99
Child attending school (yes) 0.61 0.80 0.60 0.85 0.88 0.80 0.88 0.91 0.87
Child employed (yes) 0.40 0.13 0.42 0.26 0.12 0.48 0.08 0.03 0.10
Community level characteristics
School expensesa 82.9 217.2 66.1 106.5 137.5 42.8 28.4 65.19 18.07
Mens wage per hour 15.24 17.04 15.01 2.70 3.33 1.40 0.16 0.40 0.09
Womens wage per hour 15.77 17.32 15.58 2.07 2.49 1.20 0.09 0.27 0.04
Childs wage per hour 9.37 8.56 9.47 0.93 1.05 0.67 0.05 0.10 0.04
Electricity (yes) 0.33 0.89 0.25 0.74 0.97 0.26 0.21 0.87 0.03
Water storage (1 = best, 5 = worst) 3.50 2.98 3.57 2.22 1.49 3.71 3.52 1.49 4.09
a
Monetary gures are nominal and presented at the year of survey and using the respective currency of each country
(i.e., rupees for Nepal, sols for Peru, and Z$ for Zimbabwe).

nontrivial 7% of the household income, com- to country and by urban and rural areas within
pared to only 3% for their urban counterparts. countries, but all country evidence conrms
It should be noted, however, that quantifying that the number of children working is high
the share of child-generated welfare for a and worthy of policy concern.
household would be dicult and may be easily
underestimated since children contribute in sev-
eral ways that are not reected in monetary 3. EMPIRICAL FRAMEWORK
terms. In addition, the data may be decient
due to a high likelihood of underreporting of The conventional welfare economics ap-
the incomes generated by even gainfully em- proach provides a useful framework for inte-
ployed and remunerated children (Basu, 1999). grating determinants of child labor and
Table 5 also presents the ratio of childrens schooling decisions. The decision is guided by
labor hours to both mens and womens in the utility maximization determined by consump-
household. Child labor participation in all tion and leisure of household members, under
countries is closely related to their relative con- household budgetary and time constraints (see
tribution to household income. Child labor the theoretical model in Appendix A). A par-
participation is lowest in Zimbabwe, as is their ents decision to send a child to school, work,
share in overall household income. Urban or both is a time allocation decision. The deci-
rural disparities are interesting: The ratio of sion whether a child works or goes to school is
child labor hours to both mens and womens a simultaneous one as households may be
is larger in rural areas in all countries, under- choosing among child labor, schooling, or both
scoring the abundance of child labor in rural decisions at the same time. Moreover, the fact
household chores. However, the urban child- that an important fraction of children are both
labor environment is still alarming, with the working and going to school at the same time
ratio of child labor hours to adult labor hours underscores the simultaneity of the decision.
in excess of 1 in 10 in both Peru and Nepal. Therefore, we use a multinomial logit frame-
The descriptive statistics suggest that the rate work to examine child labor and schooling
of incidence of child labor varies from country decisions (see Appendix A). In this section, we
CHILD LABOR AND SCHOOLING DECISIONS IN URBAN AND RURAL AREAS 461

describe the explanatory variables and address only access to a commercial branch bank at
econometric issues pertinent to child labor the community level is used as a measure of ac-
and schooling choices. cess to the credit market. Since this still is not a
signicant measure of access to credit, the re-
(a) Explanatory variables and endogeneity issues sults should be interpreted with caution.
Other common determinants that gure
In line with the main objective of the paper prominently in child labor empirical work, such
and the conceptual model presented in Appen- as parents educational level, head age, and sex
dix A, an extensive list of explanatory variables are among the explanatory variables. We also
are used to examine the relative role of several include a measure of domestic responsibili-
individual, household, and community vari- ties in terms of the number of very young chil-
ables on child schooling and work decisions. dren in the household. This may adversely
The explanatory variables include measures of aect child schooling decisions and may be
labor market conditions, poverty, credit access, even more detrimental to schooling of girls. It
school availability and cost, and variables is widely accepted that girls are more likely
accounting for household domestic responsibil- than boys to help their mothers with house-
ities. These variables are considered as determi- work and childcare. Gender disparities in edu-
nants of child labor in the literature, but there is cation could also arise due to dierences in
a general lack of consensus as to which is most expected earnings or remittance propensities
important. We anticipate that the role of these among boys and girls. The inclusion of a child
variables varies signicantly between rural and gender dummy will address these and other
urban areas. In the following, we briey discuss possibilities that lead to dierential employ-
the measurement and rationale for selection of ment and attendance rates among boys and
the main explanatory variables. girls. Another variable of interest is whether
Child- and adult-labor market conditions are the mother works outside the home, which
measured by average wage paid per hour at the may be correlated with child working decisions;
community level, 3 not wage rates derived at a dummy variable that indicates whether a
the individual level. Community-level average mother works outside the home is used to cap-
wages provide a better description of prevailing ture this eect.
labor market conditions than individual-level Some school-related variables at the commu-
wages, and they are based on wages reported nity levelthe number of schools available and
by individuals who actually work. Further- the cost of schooling per pupilare included
more, being community-level averages, they among explanatory variables. Availability of
are less prone to endogeneity problems. Since school can aect schooling decisions to the ex-
incomplete pooling of resources among house- tent that child-time spent going to and from
hold members appears to be the norm in many school entails a signicant opportunity cost to
countries (Strauss & Thomas, 1995), we include the parent. Educational expenses per pupil
adult female and male wage variables sepa- could be a good measure of educational re-
rately. Explicit inclusion of separate wage and sources available to students as well as their
educational level variables would allow us to teachers in terms of facilities, tuition, books,
capture the dierential impacts of mens and and other school related expenses. Thus, the
womens income, preferences and bargaining cost of schooling is included because it could
power on work and schooling decisions for be an important determinant of the likelihood
their children. that children work. The inclusion of regional
Access to credit is found to be very dicult to dummies and community-level characteristics
measure from Living Standard Measurement variables helps capture variation in productiv-
Surveys (LSMS), which usually ask if a given ity, labor demand, and dierences in other
household had a loan and bank account. Hav- aspects such as culture and attitude. All right-
ing a loan alone is not a good measure of access hand side variables are carefully selected in
to credit since households that did not report such a way that consistent reduced-form esti-
receiving a loan might have access to credit mation is achieved by excluding potential
but no need to borrow. Note also that credit endogenous variables. 4
constraints are more likely to bind for the poor Finally, in accordance with the conceptual
since their incomes are lower and riskier, thus model in Appendix A, the household-level pov-
making access to credit potentially endogenous erty measure is based on nonwage income
to schooling and work decisions. As a result, from various sources such as prots from
462
Table 6. Simultaneous estimation of child labor and schooling decisions in rural areas
Explanatory variables Nepal Peru Zimbabwe
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
Schooling Employment Both Schooling Employment Both Schooling Employment Both
Sex (female) 1.61 0.71 1.84 0.66 1.40 1.64 0.29 0.48 0.34
(9.1)*** (4.0)*** (9.3)*** (2.6)*** (4.6)*** (6.3)*** (2.2)** (3.3)*** (0.8)
Age 0.18 0.25 0.10 0.42 0.17 0.29 0.48 0.10 0.38
(4.3)*** (5.9)*** (2.2)** (6.0)*** (2.0)* (4.1)*** (13.7)*** (2.4)** (3.8)***
Child wage 0.05 0.05 0.01 0.23 0.93 0.69 3.13 2.69 9.88
(0.9) (0.8) (0.2) (0.3) (1.1) (1.0) (1.0) (1.5) (1.5)
Mens wage 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.80 1.71 0.50 0.80 1.84 2.77
(3.3)*** (1.9)** (1.3) (3.0)*** (2.4)** (1.6) (2.5)** (4.1)*** (0.5)

WORLD DEVELOPMENT
Womens wage 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.07 0.29 0.20 0.11 3.84 4.71
(2.7)*** (2.5)** (0.6) (2.2)** (3.4)*** (0.4) (3.1)*** (1.8)* (0.7)
Nonwage income (pred.) 0.62 1.01 2.65 0.10 0.64 0.18 0.70 0.40 2.54
(3.5)*** (4.3)*** (3.5)*** (2.1)** (0.8) (0.2) (3.1) (3.1)*** (2.7)***
# Young children (age les 5) 0.05 0.05 0.12 0.22 0.14 0.20 0.31 0.19 0.53
(0.7) (0.7) (1.6) (1.7) (0.4) (0.6) (3.7)*** (2.1)** (2.2)**
Head sex (female) 0.60 0.42 0.90 0.56 1.40 1.07 0.11 0.13 0.14
(2.0)** (1.4) (2.8)*** (0.6) (1.3) (1.1) (0.6) (0.7) (0.2)
Head age 0.08 0.06 0.16 0.05 0.02 0.05 0.05 0.07 0.27
(3.3)*** (2.8)*** (2.1)** (0.4) (0.1) (0.3) (2.0)** (1.8)* (1.7)*
Mens education 0.06 0.01 0.04 0.37 0.18 0.09 0.15 0.01 0.07
(1.9)* (0.4) (1.2) (2.5)*** (0.6) (0.4) (3.6)*** (0.2) (0.5)
Womens education 0.06 0.10 0.04 0.12 0.76 0.06 0.27 0.07 0.57
(1.8)* (2.5)** (1.0) (0.4) (2.0)** (0.2) (5.7)*** (2.4)** (3.7)***
Mother works outside home (yes) 1.10 1.24 1.66 0.41 1.37 1.73 0.27 0.94 0.72
(5.4)*** (5.9)*** (5.9)*** (0.8) (2.3)** (3.2)*** (1.0) (2.5)** (0.6)
Educational expenses 0.08 0.01 0.05 3.60 1.82 3.68 5.85 6.11 14.98
(3.7)*** (0.3) (2.2)** (1.0) (2.4)** (1.0) (3.9)*** (3.6)*** (2.9)***
Access to a bank (yes) 0.19 0.12 0.61 3.12 6.88 2.15 0.74 1.57 0.02
(1.9) (0.5) (2.2)** (0.8) (3.3)** (0.5) (1.9)* (3.5)*** (0.0)
Number of schools 0.15 0.02 0.13
(5.4)*** (0.8) (4.0)***
Water storage (1 = best, 5 = worst) 0.12 0.28 0.08 0.49 0.41 0.14 0.93 0.47 2.49
(1.0) (2.3)** (0.6) (1.0) (0.6) (0.3) (5.7)*** (2.5)** (3.2)***
Electricity (yes) 0.34 0.46 0.35 2.30 1.12 0.52
(1.6) (2.1)** (1.4) (1.3) (0.5) (0.3)
Sewage (1 = best, 5 = worst) 0.59 0.46 0.59
(1.1) (0.7) (1.1)

CHILD LABOR AND SCHOOLING DECISIONS IN URBAN AND RURAL AREAS


Rural West-Hill 1.46 1.04 1.61
(5.2)*** (3.6)*** (5.1)***
Rural East-Hill 1.44 0.94 1.89
(5.4)*** (3.5)*** (6.3)***
Rural-West Tera 0.42 0.49 0.97
(1.7) (1.9) (3.2)
Siera North 0.30 0.26 0.79
(0.9) (0.6) (2.1)**
Siera Central 0.06 0.65 0.54
(0.1) (1.0) (1.0)
Selva Alta North 0.56 0.51 1.43
(1.1) (0.8) (2.6)**
Selva Alta South 0.72 1.44 0.04
(0.7) (1.0) (0.0)
Selva Baja 1.29 0.27 0.85
(0.9) (0.2) (0.6)
Coastal North 0.23 0.20 0.81
(0.5) (0.3) (1.8)*
Coastal South 1.16 32.10 2.00
(0.6) (0.0) (1.0)
Mashonaland N 0.01 0.45 0.60
(0.0) (1.5) (0.7)
Mashonaland E 0.67 0.18 2.15
(1.9)* (0.5) (1.5)
Mashonaland W 1.06 1.23 1.85
(3.7)*** (3.6)*** (1.9)*
Matabeleland N 0.59 0.11 0.92
(1.6)* (0.3) (0.9)
Matabeleland S 0.02 0.86 0.57
(0.1) (2.5)** (0.6)
Midlands 0.08 0.09 1.15
(0.3) (0.3) (1.4)
Masvingo 0.31 0.51 2.42
(0.9) (1.4) (2.0)*

463
464
Table 6continued
Explanatory variables Nepal Peru Zimbabwe
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

WORLD DEVELOPMENT
Schooling Employment Both Schooling Employment Both Schooling Employment Both
Constant 0.07 4.37 4.82 0.52 4.80 0.53 5.87 2.29 8.18
(0.1) (4.3)*** (4.3)*** (0.1) (0.9) (0.1) (6.1)*** (2.0)** (2.0)**
Wald test v2(40) = 907.0*** v2(48) = 457.5*** v2(44) = 1548.6***
Exogeneity test for F-statistic = 13.2 P-value < 0.01 F-statistic = 19.24 P-value < 0.001 F-statistic = 36.60 P-value < 0.001
nonwage income (F-test)
Test for relevance of F-statistic = 13.99 P-value < 0.01 F-statistic = 17.90 P-value < 0.01 F-statistic = 22.17 P-value < 0.001
instruments (F-test)
Observations 2,884 2,884 2,884 1,387 1,387 1,387 8,654 8,654 8,654
Absolute value of z statistics in parentheses.
*
Signicant at the 10% level.
**
Signicant at the 5% level.
***
Signicant at the 1% level.
CHILD LABOR AND SCHOOLING DECISIONS IN URBAN AND RURAL AREAS 465

self-employment in farming and nonfarming mated as a function of the same set of variables
activities, interest from household assets, and employed in modeling of schooling and work
other nonlabor income sources. This measure decisions. It is estimated using tobit and instru-
takes into account the intertemporal nature of mental variables (IV) tobit. The estimates of
child schooling and work decisions as shown child labor supply are presented in Tables 7
in Eqns. (A.2) and (A.3) in Appendix A. How- and 9 for rural and urban areas, respectively.
ever, nonwage income may be endogenous to Factors that signicantly aect child employ-
child labor and schooling decisions, primarily ment decisions aect the number of hours chil-
due to the fact that children may contribute dren actually work in the same direction. As
to nonwage income through involvement in such, intensity of work results are discussed
family farming and nonfarming activities that concurrently with the joint schooling and work
do not pay wages. 5 But our measure is an estimation. In the next subsections, child labor
improvement over most previous studies on and schooling estimates are discussed focusing
child labor and schooling decisions that use to- on the similarities and dierences between
tal household income to measure poverty. crosscountry results and separately for rural
Although we anticipate that nonwage income and urban areas.
suers less from endogeneity problems com-
pared to total household income, our empirical (a) Rural child labor and schooling decisions
strategy addresses the potential endogeneity of
nonwage income. Following the work of Smith All country results indicate that child school-
and Blundell (1986), we test whether nonwage ing is negatively associated with age and female
income is endogenous. The test involves testing gender, as girls and older childrens school
the signicance of the coecient on the residual attendance rates are signicantly lower than
from the rst-stage regression of nonwage in- those for boys and younger children. Corre-
come on all instruments and exogenous explan- spondingly, the probability of being employed
atory variables. Under the null hypothesis, the rises signicantly with age in all three countries.
residuals should have little or no explanatory The likelihood of employment only increases
power. with girls in Zimbabwe, but in Nepal and Peru,
boys tend to have higher propensities for
employment only.
4. RESULTS The impact of rural child labor market condi-
tions on schooling and work, as measured by
Child schooling and employment decisions child labor wages at the community level, is
are estimated using a multinomial logit frame- eectively zero for all countries, casting doubt
work with and without instrumenting for on the hypothesis that improved labor market
nonwage income. In order to save space, only conditions drive child labor in rural areas. On
the IV estimates are reported in Tables 6 and the other hand, evidence exists that improved
8 for rural and urban areas, respectively. In labor market conditions for adult household
general, the coecients on nonwage income members lead to higher school attendance rates
appreciably increases in its magnitude after and less employment for Nepalese children, and
instrumenting, thus indicating a downward bias lower employment rates for Peruvian children.
in the noninstrumented coecient of household Also, higher wages for adult women in rural
income. 6 The relevance test lends strong cre- Zimbabwe are associated with a low prevalence
dence to our use of household asset holding of child labor.
as instrument for nonwage income in both rural In rural Nepal and Zimbabwe, we nd sup-
and urban areas (with a P-value <0.0001). 7 portive evidence for Basu and Vans (1998) lux-
The Smith and Blundell exogeneity test indi- ury axiom that states, A family will send the
cates that nonwage income is endogenous in children to the labor market only if the familys
the child labor and schooling decisions in both income from non-child labor sources drops very
rural and urban areas, although the evidence is low. Although poverty reduces the probability
weaker in the latter. of child schooling, it signicantly increases the
The intensity of work also merits attention prevalence of child labor and intensity of work.
since the hours of work could exhibit substan- The labor supply estimates in Table 7 show that
tial variability among the children who are re- if a Nepalese household had its nonlabor assets
ported to be in the labor force. The intensity increased by Rs. 100, it would decrease child
of workhours of work per weekis esti- labor hours by about 5.76 hours per week.
466
Table 7. Child labor supply in rural areas
Explanatory variables Nepal Peru Zimbabwe
(1) Tobit (2) IV Tobit (3) (4) IV (5) (6) IV
Sex (female) 3.52 3.52 12.60 12.60 11.24 11.39
(3.3)*** (3.3)*** (8.2)*** (8.1)*** (4.7)*** (4.7)***
Age 3.97 3.97 2.81 2.76 14.55 14.54
(15.6)*** (15.5)*** (8.2)*** (7.9)*** (18.8)*** (18.7)***
Child wage 0.39 0.39 4.98 6.14 5.57 2.72
(1.1) (1.1) (1.5) (1.7)* (0.2) (0.1)
Mans wage 0.13 0.13 16.51 17.12 32.39 33.07
(2.5)** (2.5)** (3.3)*** (3.3)*** (1.2) (1.3)
Womans wage 0.10 0.10 3.80 2.90 134.03 130.08
(1.5) (1.5) (1.2) (0.9) (3.3)*** (3.1)***

WORLD DEVELOPMENT
Nonwage income 6.37 2.75 4.58
(4.9)*** (2.1)** (1.9)*
Nonwage income (predicted) 5.76 2.59 0.54
(1.7)* (0.2) (0.1)
Residue 6.46 2.74 4.91
(4.7)*** (2.1)** (2.0)**
# Young children 0.45 0.47 1.23 1.01 1.64 1.82
(1.0) (1.0) (1.7)* (1.1) (1.7)* (1.8)*
Head sex (female) 0.42 0.48 0.62 1.26 4.14 4.69
(0.2) (0.3) (0.2) (0.4) (1.5) (1.6)
Head age 0.78 0.79 1.37 1.46 1.20 1.11
(1.8)* (1.8)* (1.9)* (2.0)** (1.3) (1.2)
Mans education 0.76 0.77 2.66 2.26 2.63 2.52
(5.2)*** (4.9)*** (2.3)** (1.8)* (3.7)*** (3.4)***
Womans education 1.16 1.17 1.94 2.56 4.80 4.78
(4.8)*** (4.7)*** (1.7)* (1.5) (6.0)*** (6.0)***
Mother works outside home 3.37 3.40 11.22 12.83 10.86 10.01
(1.8)* (1.8)* (4.6)*** (3.6)*** (1.4) (1.3)
Educational expenses 0.49 0.50 12.88 18.22 59.99 62.87
(4.2)*** (3.9)*** (0.9) (1.1) (2.6)*** (2.7)***
Access to a bank (yes) 3.26 3.30 70.52 73.56 25.11 25.69
(2.0)** (2.0)** (3.0)*** (3.0)*** (3.6)*** (3.6)***
Number of school 0.72 0.72
(3.9)*** (3.9)***
Water storage (1 = best, 5 = worst) 2.79 2.77 3.40 3.79 3.77 3.67
(3.4)*** (3.4)*** (1.1) (1.2) (1.1) (1.1)
Electricity 3.81 3.83 29.82 29.63
(2.5)** (2.5)** (3.1)*** (3.0)***

CHILD LABOR AND SCHOOLING DECISIONS IN URBAN AND RURAL AREAS


Sewage disposal (1 = best, 5 = worst) 2.50 2.39
(3.8)*** (3.6)***
Rural West-Hill 5.31 5.32
(3.3)*** (3.3)***
Rural East-Hill 4.98 4.86
(2.8)*** (2.6)***
Rural-West Tera 5.05 5.07
(2.6)*** (2.6)***
Siera North 1.75 0.64
(0.7) (0.1)
Siera Central 7.04 6.87
(3.1)*** (3.0)***
Selva Alta North 6.45 6.51
(1.8)* (1.8)*
Selva Alta South 12.38 9.38
(2.1)** (1.0)
Selva Baja 6.39 6.58
(2.6)** (2.6)***
Coastal North 8.18 5.44
(2.4)** (0.9)
Coastal South 20.40 22.80
(2.0)** (2.0)**
Mashonaland N 6.34 5.98
(1.3) (1.3)
Mashonaland E 1.51 1.59
(0.3) (0.3)
Mashonaland W 24.12 24.75
(4.1)*** (4.1)***
Matabeleland N 8.53 8.57
(1.4) (1.4)
Matabeleland S 16.15 16.62
(3.0)*** (3.1)***

467
468
Table 7continued
Explanatory variables Nepal Peru Zimbabwe
(1) Tobit (2) IV Tobit (3) (4) IV (5) (6) IV
Midlands 2.89 3.29

WORLD DEVELOPMENT
(0.7) (0.8)
Masvingo 9.21 9.42
(2.1)** (2.1)**
Constant 51.61 51.67 18.78 20.55 286.28 286.16
(7.7)*** (7.7)*** (1.0) (1.1) (12.9)*** (12.9)***
Likelihood ratio test v2(21) = 545.6*** v2(20) = 527*** v2(24) = 290.8*** v2(25) = 287.9*** v2(22) = 877.0*** v2(23) = 877.3***
Observations 2,876 2,876 1,395 1,387 8,654 8,654
Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses.
*
Signicant at the 10% level.
**
Signicant at the 5% level.
***
Signicant at the 1% level.
CHILD LABOR AND SCHOOLING DECISIONS IN URBAN AND RURAL AREAS 469

Zimbabwean households would decrease child to the extent that the number of schools and
work hours by about 4.90 hours per week if school-related expenditures in terms of tuition,
there were a temporary positive shock (an in- books, teacher salaries, fewer students per tea-
crease of 100 Zimbabwe dollars) that would cher, etc. are indicators of access to school
make liquidity constraints less binding. In an- and school quality, improving the availability
nual terms, these are signicant reductions in of good schools could lead to less child labor
child labor hours, as would be predicted by and more schooling.
Basu and Vans (1998) model. If the households In rural Nepal and Zimbabwe, access to a
decision to send children to work stems from commercial bank has a positive eect on child
survival concerns, as the evidence from rural schooling and a negative impact on child labor.
Nepal and Zimbabwe indicates, the results sug- Access to credit appears to have a higher nega-
gest that parents would not send their children tive eect on employment than its correspond-
to work if their own wages were higher or ing positive eect on schooling. This may
employment opportunities wide enough to en- imply that credits are sought more to smooth
able their incomes to surpass the subsistence consumption and other household needs than
threshold. In rural Peru, nonwage wealth ap- for child schooling purposes. Rural credit needs
pears to have no impact on child labor and are driven by incidental risks and for temporary
schooling decisions and thus provides neither shocks, more so than a long term goal of child
support for nor evidence against the notion that schooling. This may imply that in the absence
poverty drives child labor. of such credit schemes, child labor may become
Other household-level variables, such as the part of a strategy to minimize the risk of inter-
educational levels of both the highest educated ruption of income stream. This nding is in con-
man and woman in the family, signicantly im- currence with Jacoby and Skouass (1997) and
prove child education and decrease the likeli- Sawadas (1999) empirical evidence that chil-
hood of child labor and intensity of work in all dren are taken out of school in response to
three countries. This nding reinforces the household income shocks in rural India and
widely accepted notion that parental education Pakistan, respectively. In both rural Nepal and
is the most consistent determinant of child edu- Zimbabwe, we nd evidence that access to
cation and employment decisions. Higher credit reduces child labor and improves child
domestic responsibilities in terms of the number school attendance, thus supporting Ranjans
of young children under age 5 do not lead to a (1999) and Lahiri and Jarey (1999) argument
signicant increase in the likelihood that their that incomplete credit market could be driving
older siblings work. However, the mother work- child labor. In rural Peru, on the other hand,
ing outside the home means a higher probability access to loan and banking services actually in-
of child work in Nepal and Peru, although it also creases child employment and decreases school-
appears to improve child schooling in Nepal. ing.
The positive eect on child schooling of the
mother working outside the home in rural Nepal (b) Urban child labor and schooling decisions
may be explained by the higher income eect,
which makes it possible to pay for daycare and Similar to rural cases, in urban areas, older
domestic help, so children are not necessarily ta- children are less likely to go to school, and girls
ken out of school when their mothers work. But are less likely to stay in school than boys in all
for lower income families, it is likely the case three countries (see Tables 8 and 9). Child age
that a mother working outside the home means continues to be positively correlated with the
less schooling and more work for children. likelihood of employment and the number of
Rural infrastructure and school-related com- hours worked. However, the impact of gender
munity-level variables signicantly aect on employment is mixed in urban areas: Boys
schooling and work decisions in all countries. (girls) are more likely to be employed in Peru
Higher average educational expenses at the (Zimbabwe), and gender is insignicant in
community level appear to improve school urban Nepal. Improved child labor markets
attendance rates and correspondingly decrease provide strong incentives for child employment
child employment and intensity of work in in urban Peru. The Peruvian result is compara-
rural Nepal and Zimbabwe. Similarly, a higher ble with ndings in other Latin American coun-
number of schools in a given community leads tries that suggest improved market conditions
to higher attendance and lower employment drive child labor (see, for instance, Binder,
rates and work hours per week in Nepal. Thus, 1999; Levison et al., 2001). Peru has the largest
470
Table 8. Simultaneous estimation of child labor and schooling decisions in urban areas
Explanatory variables Nepal Peru Zimbabwe
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
Schooling Employment Both Schooling Employment Both Schooling Employment Both
Sex (female) 1.03 1.04 1.65 0.87 1.95 1.55 0.36 1.61 0.14
(3.2)*** (2.5)** (3.2)*** (4.2)*** (3.5)*** (5.7)*** (2.1)** (4.2)*** (0.2)
Age 0.17 0.33 0.28 0.37 0.41 0.06 0.70 0.16 0.61
(2.3)** (3.2)*** (2.1)** (6.7)*** (1.6) (0.7) (11.9)*** (1.4) (4.5)***
Child wage 0.27 0.23 0.91 0.01 0.45 0.43 0.54 1.74 2.40
(1.6) (1.2) (3.0)*** (0.1) (3.1)*** (2.1)** (0.5) (1.1) (0.6)
Mens wage 0.12 0.08 0.19 0.09 0.14 0.06 1.95 5.56 9.50
(3.0)*** (1.8)* (3.3)*** (2.3)** (2.4)**

WORLD DEVELOPMENT
(0.3) (1.2) (1.6) (0.0)
Womens wage 0.03 0.00 0.03 0.40 0.21 0.39 3.68 10.61 101.08
(1.9)* (0.1) (0.5) (2.5)** (0.3) (1.3) (2.0)** (1.9)* (0.0)
Nonwage income (pred.) 0.05 0.29 0.19 0.50 0.04 0.15 0.00 0.04 0.04
(0.4) (1.2) (1.0) (1.1) (1.6) (1.5)** (0.6) (0.5) (1.4)
# Young children 0.19 0.17 0.00 0.39 0.51 0.46 0.05 0.16 0.25
(2.3)** (1.9)*** (0.0) (3.3)*** (1.1) (2.6)** (0.5) (1.9)* (0.8)
Head sex (female) 0.06 0.87 0.44 0.33 1.43 0.60 0.86 1.05 1.69
(0.1) (1.1) (0.6) (1.2) (1.5) (1.5) (3.3)*** (2.2)** (1.3)
Head age 0.31 0.04 0.60 0.22 0.82 0.25 0.06 0.53 0.36
(2.5)** (0.2) (2.5)** (2.0)** (1.2) (1.2) (0.6) (3.2)*** (1.2)
Mens education 0.07 0.09 0.08 0.32 0.83 0.24 0.05 0.18 0.10
(2.0)** (1.8)* (1.3) (2.5)** (2.9)*** (1.5) (0.7) (1.5) (0.4)
Womens education 0.09 0.10 0.00 0.27 0.61 0.03 0.10 0.32 0.19
(2.2)** (1.3) (0.1) (1.8)* (0.8) (0.1) (1.7)* (3.2)*** (0.8)
Mother works outside home (yes) 0.12 0.17 2.17 0.47 0.91 0.92 0.71 2.59 18.67
(0.4) (0.4) (2.9)*** (2.0)** (1.2) (2.5)** (2.5)** (3.2)*** (0.0)
Educational expenses 0.02 0.04 0.01 0.05 0.01 0.05 0.44 0.50 9.44
(0.8) (1.6) (0.2) (12.0)*** (1.0) (10.2)*** (1.0) (0.7) (9.5)***
Access to a bank (yes) 0.24 1.87 1.62 0.17 0.46 5.23 0.85 3.23 9.34
(0.5) (1.9)* (2.1)** (0.1) (2.1) (2.0)** (0.8) (1.8)* (0.0)
Water storage (1 = best, 5 = worst) 0.38 0.23 0.19 0.30 1.36 1.65 0.64 0.82 1.54
(2.1)** (0.9) (0.7) (0.6) (1.1) (2.4)** (1.0) (0.9) (0.8)
Electricity (yes) 1.17 1.69 3.86 3.81 1.93 1.20
(0.9) (1.2) (2.3)** (2.3)** (0.4) (0.5)
Sewage (1 = best, 5 = worst) 0.87 1.54 1.37
(2.3)** (1.0) (2.4)**
Other Urban-Hill 0.63 0.17 0.76
(0.9) (0.2) (0.9)

CHILD LABOR AND SCHOOLING DECISIONS IN URBAN AND RURAL AREAS


Other Urban-Tera 0.45 .91 1.4
(0.50) (0.83) (1.1)
Lima North 0.16 0.87 1.01
(0.4) (0.9) (1.4)
Siera North 0.79 0.87 1.58
(1.1) (0.7) (1.7)*
Siera Central 0.57 1.93 1.04
(1.0) (1.2) (1.3)
Selva Alta North 0.69 0.44 2.00
(1.2) (0.4) (2.7)***
Siera South 0.27 0.33 0.02
(0.4) (0.2) (0.0)
Selva Alta North 0.94 1.43 1.67
(1.0) (1.0) (1.5)
Selva Alta Central 0.63 0.52 0.33
(1.0) (0.4) (0.4)
Selva Alta South 0.41 1.54 1.17
(0.8) (1.7)* (1.7)*
Selva Baja 0.51 0.02 0.79
(1.0) (0.0) (1.1)
Coastal North 0.59 0.34 0.66
(0.9) (0.3) (0.8)
Coastal Central 1.22 0.87 2.73
(1.7)* (0.4) (2.5)**
Coastal South 0.16 0.87 1.01
(0.4) (0.9) (1.4)
Bulawayo 0.08 0.41 48.49
(0.2) (0.5) (0.0)
Mashonaland N 0.77 1.37 7.80
(1.3) (1.4) (6.3)***
Mashonaland E 0.61 0.78 45.98
(1.3) (0.8) (0.0)
Mashonaland W 0.57 0.26 24.10
(0.8) (0.2) (0.0)

471
472
Table 8continued
Explanatory variables Nepal Peru Zimbabwe
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
Schooling Employment Both Schooling Employment Both Schooling Employment Both
Matabeleland N 0.65 2.27 55.70
(0.7) (1.5) (0.0)
Matabeleland S 0.56 1.10 63.34

WORLD DEVELOPMENT
(0.9) (1.2) (0.0)
Midlands 1.21 3.76 27.19
(1.3) (2.1)** (18.5)***
Masvingo 0.13 0.86 6.11
(0.1) (0.4) (1.9)*
Constant 1.42 5.23 9.72 2.82 2.75 0.50 14.58 4.61 26.80
(0.6) (1.8)* (2.3)** (1.0) (0.2) (0.1) (7.1)*** (1.3) (0.0)
Wald test v2(38) = 175.1*** v2(58) = 562.9*** v2(48) = 345.7***
Exogeneity test for nonwage income (F-test) F-statistic = 8.45 F-statistic = 35.77 F-statistic = 19.30
P-value < 0.1 P-value < 0.001 P-value < 0.01
Test for relevance of instruments (F-test) F-statistic = 21.16 F-statistic = 9.36 F-statistic = 11.59
P-value < 0.001 P-value < 0.01 P-value < 0.01
Observations 701 701 701 2,170 2,170 2,170 3,218 3,218 3,218
Absolute value of z statistics in parentheses.
*
Signicant at the 10% level.
**
Signicant at the 5% level.
***
Signicant at the 1% level.
Table 9. Child labor supply in urban areas
Explanatory variables Nepal Peru Zimbabwe
(1) Tobit (2) IV Tobit (3) Tobit (4) IV Tobit (5) Tobit (6) IV Tobit

CHILD LABOR AND SCHOOLING DECISIONS IN URBAN AND RURAL AREAS


Sex (female) 4.99 5.07 14.28 17.75 30.49 30.96
(1.0) (1.0) (5.0)*** (5.0)*** (1.7)* (1.8)*
Age 7.43 7.45 5.73 7.18 22.87 22.91
(5.5)*** (5.5)*** (8.4)*** (5.4)*** (3.6)*** (3.6)***
Childs wage 0.48 0.50 4.80 6.89 156.90 153.63
(0.2) (0.2) (2.2)** (2.7)*** (2.0)** (2.0)**
Mans wage 0.19 0.19 2.85 0.70 79.34 147.22
(0.4) (0.4) (1.5) (0.3) (0.4) (0.7)
Womans wage 0.32 0.32 1.98 5.83 133.83 126.99
(1.2) (1.2) (0.6) (1.5) (0.4) (0.4)
Nonwage income 0.32 0.49 6.13
(0.2) (0.6) (1.5)
Nonwage income (predicted) 0.19 28.67 45.27
(0.1) (1.5) (1.2)
Nonwage income (residue) 0.46 0.30 5.25
(0.2) (0.3) (1.2)
# Young children 2.89 2.93 0.19 2.75 8.11 13.00
(1.1) (1.1) (0.1) (1.0) (0.9) (1.3)
Head sex (female) 10.47 10.69 2.23 8.73 13.60 38.70
(1.3) (1.3) (0.6) (1.6) (0.6) (1.2)
Head age 0.04 0.10 2.10 2.69 8.34 4.55
(0.0) (0.0) (1.5) (0.8) (1.1) (0.5)
Mans education 1.66 1.68 0.94 1.82 6.87 12.43
(2.7)*** (2.7)*** (0.5) (0.9) (1.3) (1.7)*
Womans education 1.97 2.00 8.49 2.51 12.31 15.97
(2.9)*** (2.8)*** (4.8)*** (0.6) (2.1)** (2.3)**
Mother works outside home (yes) 10.11 10.23 18.15 12.20 87.49 82.59
(1.7)* (1.7)* (4.9)*** (2.6)*** (2.1)** (2.1)**
Educational expenses 0.27 0.29 0.06 0.01 76.69 84.99
(1.1) (1.1) (3.1)*** (0.2) (1.4) (1.5)
Access to a bank (yes) 0.39 0.13 54.75 64.25 105.57 99.32
(0.0) (0.0) (1.9)* (2.1)** (1.2) (1.2)
Water storage (1 = best, 5 = worst) 4.57 4.59 12.42 16.52 35.92 22.85
(1.6) (1.6) (1.5) (1.9)* (0.7) (0.4)

473
Table 9continued

474
Explanatory variables Nepal Peru Zimbabwe
(1) Tobit (2) IV Tobit (3) Tobit (4) IV Tobit (5) Tobit (6) IV Tobit
Electricity (yes) 18.57 18.21 59.92 49.81
(1.4) (1.4) (2.2)** (1.7)*
Sewage (1 = best, 5 = worst) 6.30 0.38
(1.0) (0.0)
Other Urban-Hill 2.91 3.15
(0.4) (0.4)
Other Urban-Tera 5.87 6.06
(0.6) (0.6)
Lima North 15.10 22.02
(2.0)** (2.7)***
Siera North 14.33 8.41

WORLD DEVELOPMENT
(1.4) (0.8)
Siera Central 7.42 1.23
(0.9) (0.1)
Siera South 14.30 13.02
(1.7)* (1.6)
Selva Alta North 6.83 0.01
(0.7) (0.0)
Selva Alta Central 9.88 8.78
(0.9) (0.8)
Selva Alta South 12.89 7.70
(1.2) (0.7)
Selva Baja 20.91 21.73
(2.6)*** (2.7)***
Coastal North 7.52 3.07
(0.9) (0.4)
Coastal Central 21.08 15.26
(2.4)** (1.6)*
Coastal South 4.51 16.10
(0.4) (1.1)
Bulawayo 2.98 7.28
(0.1) (0.2)
Mashonaland N 30.47 11.93
(0.6) (0.2)
Mashonaland E 12.52 18.83
(0.3) (0.5)
Mashonaland W 89.90 90.87
(1.1) (1.1)
Matabeleland N 47.86 62.25
(0.9) (1.2)

CHILD LABOR AND SCHOOLING DECISIONS IN URBAN AND RURAL AREAS


Matabeleland S 42.77 11.44
(1.0) (0.2)
Midlands 36.93 52.83
(0.6) (0.9)
Masvingo 113.55 137.79
(1.6) (1.9)*
Constant 85.25 85.40 5.01 58.15 677.16 607.67
(2.5)** (2.5)** (0.1) (0.9) (3.3)*** (2.9)***
Likelihood ratio test v2(18) = 115.8*** v2(19) = 115.4*** v2(28) = 263.3*** v2(29) = 261.2*** v2(23) = 67.2*** v2(24) = 74.1***
Observations 692 692 2,203 2,170 3,218 3,218

Absolute value of z statistics in parentheses.


*
Signicant at the 10% level.
**
Signicant at the 5% level.
***
Signicant at the 1% level.

475
476 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

proportion of children who are both working works to help in childcare activities in rural
and going to school at the same time (see Table areas, as opposed to urban ones. Rural mothers
4). The fact that child wage is positively associ- might also have greater control over their time
ated with the employment decision may imply allocation for childcare and work due to the
that some children work for the purpose of nature of their jobs such as working on their
nancing their education. The number of hours own agricultural elds, while the urban women
children work also increases signicantly with could be working in factories and under super-
child labor wages in urban Peru and Zimbabwe. vision of employers. The availability of alter-
We do not nd sucient evidence from urban native childcare options such as providing
areas of all three countries for Basu and Vans working mothers with rm-level childcare will
(1998) luxury axiom that poverty drives child la- likely have more impact in urban areas in terms
bor. A similar analysis done separately for boys of lessening the responsibilities borne by school-
and girls by Ray (2000a, 2000b) also shows no age children in taking care of their younger sib-
evidence for the poverty hypothesis in Peru. lings. It has been observed that the presence of a
Although the theoretical literature on child daycare center decreases the likelihood that
labor, including Basu and Vans (1998), tends children engage in work at home (DeGra, Bils-
to lead many to believe that poverty is the pri- borrow, & Herrin, 1993; Goonesekere, 1993).
mary cause of child employment, our result shows Also note that having a working mother leads
that poverty does not appear to be the main cul- to signicantly more hours of child work in
prit of the prevalence of child labor in urban urban areas of all countries (see Table 9).
areas. While studies that lump together urban In Nepal and Zimbabwe, urban infrastruc-
and rural areas obscure these dierences, exam- ture and school-related community level vari-
ining urban and rural child labor responses sep- ables do not factor in schooling and work
arately could help shed a brighter light on the decisions, unlike in the rural areas. However,
causes of child labor. We nd more evidence in urban Peru, educational expenses at the com-
for the poverty hypothesis in rural areas and less munity level appear to improve child atten-
or no evidence for it in urban areas, as do Can- dance rates. Similar observations were made
agarajah and Coulombe (1998) in Ghana. for another Latin American country by Brown
Household educational level variables, espe- (2001) who states that . . . an increased cost
cially womens education, continue to signi- of schooling is associated with a lower proba-
cantly reduce the probability of child labor bility of work by Colombian children. Brown
and improve the likelihood of children staying also suggests that, at least in the Colombian
in school. Parental educational level has been case, the cost of schooling is a proxy for school
critical in improving household livelihood and quality. The deciencies in facilities, teacher
food and nutritional status of children (Ruel salaries, and other educational supplies are re-
et al., 1999; Strauss & Thomas, 1995). The ported to be pervasive in both rural and urban
urban result is similar to the results from other Peru (Brown, 2001). For instance, Brown
studies that underline the importance that points out that even in metropolitan Lima, only
parental, especially the mothers, education 60% of schools have electricity. If school-
has on childrens human capital development. related expenditures in terms of tuition, books,
A measure of domestic responsibilities, num- teacher salaries, etc. are plausible indicators of
ber of young children under age 5, plays a crit- school quality in Peru, our empirical results
ical role in urban areas by keeping children suggest that improving school quality would
away from school and forcing them into work. likely keep more children in school.
This result is in contrast to the rural result that
showed its impact is insignicant. The urban re-
sult is consistent with the ndings of Cochrane, 5. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
Kozel, and Alderman (1990) who report the
presence of children under ve signicantly re- The literature on child labor and schooling is
duces the educational participation of girls. voluminous and continually growing. However,
Similarly, a positive likelihood that a mother studies are scant that simultaneously examine
works outside the home leads to more child the various factors impacting child labor and
labor in all countries. This urbanrural dieren- schooling such as poverty, access to credit,
tial in the impact of domestic responsibilities labor market conditions, household domestic
and a mothers work decision could be due to responsibilities, school expenditures, and paren-
the availability of extended family and kin net- tal educational levels, along with community
CHILD LABOR AND SCHOOLING DECISIONS IN URBAN AND RURAL AREAS 477

characteristics important for such decisions. work participation rates in urban areas. In
This paper looked at the impact of each of these rural areas, policies such as a ban on child labor
factors while controlling for others at the same could thus have an adverse eect on both the
time. It examined urban and rural decisions sep- household and the children because child labor
arately, with the anticipation that urbanrural decisions are more likely made in response to
dierentials in livelihood strategies and oppor- poverty and subsistence requirements. The
tunities could be reected in child employment rural evidence is thus in line with the seminal
and schooling decisions. The simultaneous paper on the economics of child labor by Basu
examination of a list of determinants of child and Van (1998).
schooling and employment decisions, while Access to credit is likely to improve atten-
investigating their pertinence across countries dance rates and decrease employment rates in
and urban and rural areas within a given coun- rural areas of Nepal and Zimbabwe, in conver-
try, enabled us to identify the factors that are gence with the theoretical results, for instance,
more important than others. by Ranjan (1999) and Lahiri and Jarey
In all three countries and urban and rural areas (1999). Credit constraints are more likely to
alike, parental educational levels are essential be binding for the rural poor since their in-
factors in child employment and education, with comes are lower and riskier. Thus, with better
a signicant contribution to reduction of child access to credit, the rural poor in Nepal and
labor and improvement in the likelihood that Zimbabwe may nd it possible to borrow and
children stay in school. In concurrence with send children to school. However, access to
empirical evidence from other Latin American credit does not play a similar role in urban
countries, improved child labor market condi- areas. Access to credit may have actually en-
tions in terms of higher wages per hour increases abled rural Peruvian parents to overcome entry
both the probability and intensity of work in barrier and venture into own business activities
urban Peru and Zimbabwe, with no appreciable in which child labor may be utilized when there
eect in rural areas. Improvement in labor mar- are incomplete labor markets.
ket conditions for adult labor leads to a lower In sum, the evidence from Nepal, Peru, and
probability of child labor and a higher probabil- Zimbabwe indicates that the impact of poverty
ity of schooling. Bolstering adult wages may thus on a child depends on the location. While there
help curb child labor participation and increase is strong evidence that poverty drives child
the probability that children stay in school. labor in rural areas, there is a general lack of
Household domestic responsibilities and the support for the poverty hypothesis in urban
likelihood that the mother works away from areas. Similarly, improving credit access has
her home have more signicant impact on urban greater potential for alleviating child labor
child labor and schooling decisions than on those and enhancing school attendance in rural than
of rural areas. This suggests that the availability in urban areas particularly in Nepal and Zim-
of alternative childcare options would be more babwe. Finally, the evidence from all three
important in child labor decisions in urban than countries indicates that the availability of good
in rural areas. schools and eorts to bolster adult educational
Although poverty drives child work and levels and wages will help curb the prevalence
schooling decisions in rural areas, it does not and intensity of child labor and improve the
appear to signicantly inuence schooling and likelihood that children stay in school.

NOTES

1. Ranjan (1999), using a two-period overlapping 3. Communities are dened as primary sampling units
generation model, shows that credit constraints, not (PSUs) as provided in the household survey design. As
poverty, play a role in a households decision to use PSUs are levels at which random samples of households
child labor instead of sending their children to are drawn for the surveys, community level averages are
school. assumed as good representatives of prevailing conditions
in their communities.

2. To facilitate comparison among countries, only 4. Specic household- or school-level variables are
Peruvian children aged 1017 (about 3 599 children) likely to suer from endogeneity. For instance, house-
are considered in this paper. hold expenses on education are incurred only for
478 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

children for whom the decision was made to enroll in 6. See Psacharopoulos (1997), Patrinos and Psacharo-
school. Such variables are endogenous to child labor poulos (1997), Grootaert (1999), Grootaert and Patrinos
decisions. We circumvent this problem by averaging (1999), Canagarajah and Coulombe (1998), and others
household-level, school-related variables over relevant for a discussion on endogeneity of household income
geographic units in the survey or by using community and potential upward bias in its coecient. The upward
level variables whenever possible. bias may be due to the entanglement of substitution
eects with income eects when some productive assets
are used to proxy income (Bhalotra, 2000b).
5. One might also argue that nonwage income repre-
sents the accumulation of assets related to labor income 7. Bound, Jaeger, and Baker (1995) suggest an F statistic
over the life cycle. However, this presents less of a for identifying instruments in the rst-stage regression as
problem when dealing with child labor income. useful indicators of the quality of the IV estimates.

REFERENCES

Barro, R. (1991). Economic growth in a cross section of Population Council Seminar, New York, 910 June,
countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(2), 1992.
407443. Ersado, L. (2002). Income diversication in Zimbabwe:
Basu, K., & Van, P. H. (1998). The economics of child Welfare implications from urban and rural areas.
labor. The American Economic Review, 88(3), International Food Policy Research Institute, FCND
412427. DP# 152, Washington, DC.
Basu, K. (1999). Child labor: Causes, consequences, and Glick, P., & Sahn, D. (1997). Gender and education
cure, with remarks on international labor standards. impacts on employment and earnings in West Africa:
Journal of Economic Literature, 37(September), Evidence from Guinea. Economic Development and
10831119. Cultural Change, 45(4), 793823.
Becker, G. S. (1964). Human capital. New York: Glick, P., & Sahn, D. (2000). Schooling of girls and boys
Columbia University Press. in a West African country: The eects of parental
Becker, G. S., & Lewis, H. G. (1973). On the interaction education, income, and household structure. Eco-
between the quantity and quality of children. Journal nomics of Education Review, 19(1), 6387.
of Political Economy, 81(2), S279S288. Goonesekere, S. W. E. (1993). Child labor in Sri Lanka
Bhalotra, S., (2000a). Is child work necessary? STIC- Learning from the past. Geneva: ILO.
ERD Working Papers, DEDPS 26, London School Grootaert, C. (1999). Child labor in Cote dIvoire:
of Economics. Incidence and determinants. In Christian Grootaert
Bhalotra, S., (2000b). Child farm labor: Theory and & Harry A. Patrinos (Eds.), The policy analysis of
evidence. STICERD Working Papers, DEDPS 24, child labor: A comparative study. New York: St.
London School of Economics. Martins Press.
Binder, M. (1999). Community eects and desired Grootaert, C., & Kanbur, R. (1995). Child labor: An
schooling of parents and children in Mexico. Eco- economic perspective. International Labor Review,
nomics of Education Review, 18(3), 311325. 134(2), 187203.
Bound, J., Jaeger, D. A., & Baker, R. M. (1995). Grootaert, C., & Patrinos, H. A. (Eds.). (1999). The
Problems with instrumental variables estimation policy analysis of child labor: A comparative study.
when the correlation between the instruments and New York: St. Martins Press.
the endogenous explanatory variable is weak. Journal International Labor Organization (1996). Economically
of the American Statistical Association, 90(430), Active Populations, 19502010. Geneva.
443450. Jacoby, H. (1994). Borrowing constraint and progress
Brown, D. K., (2001). Child labor in Latin America: through school: Evidence from Peru. Review of
Policy and evidence. Department of Economics, Economics and Statistics, 76, 151160.
Tufts University. Jacoby, H., & Skouas, E. (1997). Risk, nancial
Canagarajah, S., Coulombe, H., (1998). Child labor and markets, and human capital in a developing country.
schooling in Ghana. Policy Research Working Paper Review of Economics and Statistics, 64, 407424.
No. 1844, World Bank, Washington, DC. Lahiri, S., & Jarey, S. (1999). Will trade sanctions
Cochrane, S., Kozel, V., & Alderman, H., (1990). reduce child labor?: The role of credit markets.
Household consequences of high fertility in Pakistan. Mimeograph, Department of Economics, University
World Bank Discussion Paper No. 111, Washington, of Essex, UK.
DC. Levison, D., Moe, K. S., & Knaul, F. M. (2001). Youth
DeGra, D. S., Bilsborrow, R. E., & Herrin, A. N. education and work in Mexico. World Development,
(1993). The implications of high fertility for chil- 29(1), 167188.
drens time use in the Philippines. In C. B. Lloyd Lucas, R. (1988). On the mechanics of economic
(Ed.), Fertility, family size and structureConse- development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22,
quences for families and children. Proceedings of a 342.
CHILD LABOR AND SCHOOLING DECISIONS IN URBAN AND RURAL AREAS 479

Mankiw, N. G., Romer, D., & Weil, D. N. (1992). A san (Eds.), The Handbook of Development Economics
contribution to the empirics of economic growth. (pp. 18832023). New York: North-Holland.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 407437. Swaminathan, M. (1998). Economic growth and the
McFadden, D. (1981). Econometric models of probabi- persistence of child labor: Evidence from an Indian
listic choices. In C. F. Manski & D. McFadden (Eds.), city. World Development, 26(8), 15131528.
Structural Analysis of Discrete Data with Econometric UNICEF (1991). The state of the worlds children 1991.
Applications (pp. 198272). Cambridge: MIT Press. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Moser, C. O. N. (1996). Confronting crisis: A compar- Vijverberg, W. P. W. (1993). Educational investments
ative study of household responses to poverty and and returns for women and men in Cote dIvoire.
vulnerability in four poor urban communities. Envi- Journal of Human Resources, 28, 933974.
ronmentally Sustainable Development Studies and
Monographs Series, No. 8, World Bank, Washing-
ton, DC.
Patrinos, H. A., & Psacharopoulos, G. (1997). Family
size, schooling and child labor in Peru: An empirical
analysis. Journal of Population Economics, 10(4), APPENDIX A. CHILD LABOR
387406. AND SCHOOLING DECISION:
Pradhan, M., & van Soest, A. (1997). Household labor A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK
supply in urban areas of Bolivia. Review of Econom-
ics and Statistics, 79(2), 300310.
Psacharopoulos, G. (1994). Returns to investment in Assume that a household is composed of one
education: A global update. World Development, parent and one child. Assume also that a repre-
22(9), 13251343. sentative household lives for two periods and
Psacharopoulos, G. (1997). Child labor versus educa- maximizes its utility function at time t:
tional attainment: Some evidence from Latin Amer-
ica. Journal of Population Economics, 10(4), 377386. U t U C t ; C t1 ; Lp;t ; Lc;t ; S c;t ; Ut ; A:1
Ranjan, P. (1999). An economic analysis of child labor.
Economic Letters, 64, 99105. where U is a concave utility function over joint
Ranjan, P. (2001). Credit constraints and the pheno-
menon of child labor. Journal of Development Eco-
consumption (C), child schooling (Sc), parent
nomics, 64(1), 81102. and child leisure times (Lp, Lc), and a vector
Ray, R. (2000a). Child labor, child schooling, and their of individual, household and community char-
interactions with adult labor: Empirical evidence for acteristics (U). Including child schooling in the
Peru and Pakistan. World Bank Economic Review, parents utility function assumes that education
14(2), 347367. is both an investment and consumption good
Ray, R. (2000b). Analysis of child labor in Peru and for parents (Becker & Lewis, 1973).
Pakistan: A comparative study. Journal of Population
In period t, the parent decides whether to
Economics, 13(1), 319.
Romer, M. P. (1987). Increasing returns and long-run send his child to school or work. If work deci-
growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), sion is made, the child earns wage Wc (a child
10021037. wage) at period t and Wu (unskilled adult wage)
Ruel, M. T. et al. (1999). Good care practices can at period t + 1. If the parent instead decides to
mitigate the negative eects of poverty and low send his child to school, the child earns wage
maternal schooling on childrens nutritional status: Ws (a skilled adult wage) in period t + 1. The
Evidence from Accra. World Development, 27(11), households total resources thus depend on
19932009.
Sawada, Y. (1999). Essays on schooling and economic the parents decision to send the child to work
development: A micro-econometric approach for or to school in period t. Since child schooling
rural Pakistan and El Salvador. Ph.D. Dissertation, and work decisions have intertemporal implica-
Stanford University. tions for the household, consider an intertem-
Siddiqi, F., & Patrinos, H. (1995). Child labor: Issues, poral budget constraint:
causes and interventions. Human Resources and
Operations Policy Working Paper 56, World Bank, At1 At  fdAt Pt Y t W t Ec;t
Washington, DC.
Skouas, E., & Parker, S. (2002). Labor market shocks W t T p  Lp;t  C t g; A:2
and their impacts on work and schooling: Evidence
from urban Mexico. International Food Policy where At is the total asset holding at the initial
Research Institute, Washington, DC. period; d is the interest rate. (Pt + dAt + Yt)
Smith, R., & Blundell, R. (1986). An exogeneity test for
a simultaneous equation tobit model with an appli-
comprises nonwage income, which includes
cation to labor supply. Econometrica, 54(3), 679685. prots from self-employment in farm and non-
Strauss, J., & Thomas, D. (1995). Empirical modeling of farm activities (P), interest income from house-
human resources. In Jere Behrman & T. N. Sriniva- hold assets (At), and transfers and other income
480 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

from nonlabor sources (Yt). Wt is a vector of the parents decision such as credit opportuni-
wage rates for parent and child; Tp is the total ties, accessibility to school, school fees, and
parent time; and Ec is the child paid labor time. other factors.
By denoting nonwage income by Xt and solving An indirect utility function that represents
for it using (A.2): the maximum utility a household receives,
under schooling alone, schooling and work,
Xt At1  At and work alone decisions, can be obtained by
substituting the vector of choices in (A.5) into
fC t  W t Ec;t W t T p  Lp;t g: A:3
the utility function in (A.1) (suppressing time
subscript):
Eqn. (A.3) implies that an intertemporally con-
sistent measure of nonwage income amounts to V j V j C W j ; P; A; Y ; U; A:6
asset accumulation or decumulation, which al-
where Vj is the utility under dierent child
lows agents to save (when Xt is positive) or dis-
schooling and work decision: schooling only,
save (when Xt is negative). This measure of
work only, both schooling and work at the
nonwage income, which excludes earnings from
same time, or none. Parents will decide to send
child labor, could be used as an exogenous pov-
children to school instead of work at time t if
erty measure in the estimation of child school-
they are better o with the enhanced human
ing and work decisions.
capital.
Finally, the household is subject to a child-
Parents decision whether a child works or
time constraint. In a typical developing coun-
goes to school is a time allocation as both activ-
try, child time may be allocated to three broad
ities are competing for their childs time. We
activitiesschooling, leisure, and paid and un-
therefore use a multinomial logit framework
paid labor:
to model child labor and schooling as simulta-
neous decisions. Parents have four alternative
T c Lc;t S c;t Ec;t : A:4 choices: schooling, work, both schooling and
work at the same, or none. Assuming indepen-
Maximizing (A.1) subject to (A.2) and (A.4) dently and identically distributed error terms
would lead to a vector of optimal choices that with an extreme value distribution, the proba-
are functions of prices, wages, household char- bility that alternative j is chosen from the n
acteristics, income, and other factors: alternatives can be represented as (see McFad-
den, 1981)
C W t ; Pt ; At ; Y t ; Ut ; A:5
expV j
Probchoice j Pn : A:7
j expV j

where Ut includes all community-level observed


and unobserved characteristics that likely aect

Você também pode gostar