Você está na página 1de 9

FX Focus

14 September 2016

Introducing CACIB’s FX fair value model: G10 VALFeX

 We introduce CACIB’s new FX fair value model for G10 VALFeX. The Valentin Marinov
model produces estimates of fair value of the G10 USD-crosses based Head of G10 FX Strategy
on relative productivity, external imbalances, terms of trade and rate +44 20 7214 5289
differentials. valentin.marinov@ca-cib.com

 We use panel cointegration analysis that combines dynamic and cross


sectional quarterly data spanning the G10 space, and going back till Jennifer Hau
2000. We aim to update the model on a standalone basis, and as part of FX Strategist
the FX Weekly and the Key FX Views publications. +44 20 7214 7468
jennifer.hau@ca-cib.com
 The model points at undervaluation for EUR, GBP and SEK; and
overvaluation for AUD, NZD and CHF. The results for the crosses
suggest that European currencies are looking cheap against Asian and
commodity block currencies.

 A trading strategy based on the model under-/overvaluation signals of


G10 VALFeX has returned on average 5.9% over the last 15 years with a
sharp ratio of 0.74. We will be using the model as input in our upcoming
G10 FX scorecard.

EUR and GBP look cheap, Antipodeans expensive


Our G10 FX fair value model – G10 VALFeX - suggests at present that both EUR
and GBP are quite undervalued with fair values for EUR/USD and GBP/USD
estimated to be 1.26 and 1.51 respectively at the end of Q216 (Figure 1). JPY
remains undervalued with the model suggesting a fair value of 98.6. At the other
end of the ranking are the two antipodean currencies where our model suggests
fair values of 0.70 and 0.62 for AUD/USD and NZD/USD respectively. Elsewhere,
the model results suggest that CHF is quite overvalued as well (USD/CHF fair
value of 1.04), followed by NOK and CAD (fair values for USD/NOK and
USD/CAD of 8.80 and 1.33 respectively). Last but not least, SEK looks
undervalued as well with the model giving a fair value for USD/SEK of 7.97.
To test the quality of the G10 VALFeX valuation signals, we construct a trading
strategy where we would buy/sell the currency against USD if the prevailing FX
spot rate is under/overvalued compared its ‘fair value’ at the end of the quarter.
We hold the position for the following quarter. The strategy has an average
annual return of 5.9% over the last 15 years with a Sharp ratio of 0.74 (Figure 2).

Fig 1. Misvaluation vs USD based on VALFeX in Q2 2016 Fig 2. Trading performance based on VALFeX (%)
120%
15%
100%
10%
80%
5%
60%
0%
40%
-5%
20%
-10%
0%
-15%
NZD AUD CHF NOK CAD JPY SEK EUR GBP -20%
Misvaluation vs VALFeX Mar-01 Jun-03 Sep-05 Dec-07 Mar-10 Jun-12 Sep-14

Source: Crédit Agricole CIB, OECD, IMF, Bloomberg Source: Crédit Agricole CIB

https://catalystresearch.ca-cib.com
FX Focus

For the trading strategy we adopt a weighted approach, whereby a larger


under/overvaluation compared to a short-term rolling standard deviation (on a per
currency pair basis) would have a larger weight in the portfolio. The trading
strategy only puts on a trade if the under/overvaluation is considered
‘meaningful’; we consider this to be greater than 1 standard deviation.
When looking at the breakdown of performance of the trading strategy by
currency pairs, we find that USD/JPY is by far the best performing currency pair,
with a sharpe ratio of almost 1. The performance for GBP and CHF are also fairly
decent with a sharper ratio of around 0.5, the performance for AUD, NZD, EUR
and SEK are modest, while the performance for CAD and NOK is relatively poor
under this strategy (Figure 3).

Fig 3. Trading performance based on G10 VALFeX


Currency AUD CAD CHF EUR GBP JPY NOK NZD SEK Portfolio
Annualised Return 1.3% -0.6% 1.9% 1.0% 1.9% 4.7% -3.7% 1.7% 1.6% 5.9%

Annual Risk 8.4 4.7 3.7 7.1 5.2 6.8 7.8 7.2 6.8 8.0

Sharpe Ratio 0.16 -0.12 0.50 0.14 0.37 0.69 -0.48 0.23 0.24 0.74

Max Drawdown 27% 21% 5% 15% 5% 7% 44% 14% 18% 12%

Source: Crédit Agricole CIB

In-depth analysis of the G10 VALFEx results


The gap between EUR/USD and its fair value has widened considerably since
the introduction of the ECB’s negative rates in June 2014 and QE in January
2015 (Figure 4). The policies were implemented in response to deteriorating
Eurozone fundamentals (weaker productivity relative to the US) and resulted in
tightening in the real rate differentials to the US. At the same time, the Eurozone
current account (CA) surplus and commodity terms of trade (ToT) improved
relative to the US, keeping our estimate of fair value well above current spot
levels. The G10 VALFeX estimate tracks spot moves and identifies overbought/
oversold levels in EUR/USD better than the purchasing power parity (PPP)
measure.

Fig 4. EUR undervalued compared to VALFeX and PPP Fig 5. GBP undervalued compared to VALFeX and PPP

1.6 2.1
1.5 2.0
1.4 1.9
1.3 1.8
1.2 1.7
1.1 1.6
1.0 1.5
0.9 1.4
0.8 1.3
Mar-00 Aug-02 Jan-05 Jun-07 Nov-09 Apr-12 Sep-14 Mar-00 Aug-02 Jan-05 Jun-07 Nov-09 Apr-12 Sep-14
EUR/USD PPP VALFeX GBP/USD PPP VALFeX

Source: Crédit Agricole CIB, OECD, Bloomberg Source: Crédit Agricole CIB, OECD, Bloomberg

The GBP/USD undervaluation is a relatively recent development and can be


attributed almost entirely to the selloff ahead of the Brexit vote (Figure 5). While
weaker UK external imbalances and lower real rates did not help the pound,
better productivity and improving terms of trade relative to the US stopped the fair
value for GBP/USD from falling in tandem with FX spot since the beginning of
2016. Recent history indicates that GBP/USD deviations from fair value of the
current magnitude are difficult to sustain. Similar conclusions could be drawn
from the valuation analysis based on PPP. The combined results for EUR and
GBP suggest that the cross is trading at close to fair value at present (Figure 6).

14 September 2016 2
FX Focus

Fig 6. EUR/GBP close to VALFeX but well below PPP Fig 7. JPY looks undervalued compared to VALFeX

1.00
150.0
0.95
140.0
0.90
0.85 130.0
0.80 120.0
0.75 110.0
0.70 100.0
0.65 90.0
0.60 80.0
0.55 70.0
Mar-00 Aug-02 Jan-05 Jun-07 Nov-09 Apr-12 Sep-14 Mar-00 Aug-02 Jan-05 Jun-07 Nov-09 Apr-12 Sep-14
EUR/GBP PPP VALFeX USD/JPY PPP VALFeX

Source: Crédit Agricole CIB, OECD, Bloomberg Source: Crédit Agricole CIB, OECD, Bloomberg

The USD/JPY drop this year has brought the pair closer to the fair value implied
by G10 VALFeX although it remains overvalued (Figure 7). Improving external
imbalances and terms of trade in Japan as well as renewed widening of real rate
spreads to the US could explain the level of the fair value. At the same time, the
Japanese productivity remains inferior to the US one and that could keep a floor
for USD/JPY fair value and FX spot in the coming quarters. The model result
differs from the PPP fair value, which suggests that USD/JPY is no longer
expensive.

Fig 8. CHF overvalued relative to VALFeX and PPP Fig 9. SEK undervalued relative to VALFeX and PPP

11.0
1.8
10.0
1.6
9.0
1.4
8.0
1.2 7.0
1.0 6.0

0.8 5.0
Mar-00 Aug-02 Jan-05 Jun-07 Nov-09 Apr-12 Sep-14 Mar-00 Aug-02 Jan-05 Jun-07 Nov-09 Apr-12 Sep-14
USD/CHF PPP VALFeX USD/SEK PPP VALFeX

Source: Crédit Agricole CIB, OECD, Bloomberg Source: Crédit Agricole CIB, OECD, Bloomberg

CHF remains the most overvalued G10 major currency according to G10
VALFeX (Figure 8). This reflects the impact of inferior productivity and terms of
trade relative to the US, which more than outweigh the effect of the Swiss
superior CA balance as well as the renewed tightening in the relative rate
spreads to the US. In contrast, SEK looks cheap with its fair value boosted by
superior productivity and improving terms of trade (Figure 9). A look at the PPP
fair value would suggest that the results for CHF are consistent with the findings
of our analysis. In the case of USD/SEK, PPP points at undervaluation.
The Antipodeans are the most expensive currencies in G10 according to G10
VALFeX (Figures 10 and 11). This reflects still considerable external imbalances,
weaker terms of trade, worsening productivity and shrinking real rate advantage
vis-à-vis the US (in the case of NZD). The results further suggest that AUD/NZD
is quite undervalued at present.

14 September 2016 3
FX Focus

Fig 10. AUD overvalued relative to VALFeX and PPP Fig 11. NZD overvalued relative to VALFeX and PPP

1.1 0.9
1.0 0.8
0.9
0.7
0.8
0.6
0.7
0.5
0.6
0.5 0.4

0.4 0.3
Mar-00 Aug-02 Jan-05 Jun-07 Nov-09 Apr-12 Sep-14 Mar-00 Aug-02 Jan-05 Jun-07 Nov-09 Apr-12 Sep-14
AUD/USD PPP VALFeX NZD/USD PPP VALFeX

Source: Crédit Agricole CIB, OECD, Bloomberg Source: Crédit Agricole CIB, OECD, Bloomberg

In the case of the two oil currencies NOK and CAD, our fair value model points at
overvaluation albeit less pronounced than in the case of the Antipodeans
(Figures 12 and 13). Still weak terms of trade in addition to lingering external
imbalances in the case of CAD and inferior relative productivity in the case of
NOK seem to keep the fair value estimates close to the recent lows. With the
notable exception of CAD, the results for all four G10 commodity currencies are
broadly consistent with the message we get from the PPP analysis.

Fig 12. CAD overvalued relative to VALFeX but not PPP Fig 13. NOK overvalued relative to VALFeX and PPP

1.7 10.0
1.6
9.0
1.5
1.4 8.0
1.3
7.0
1.2
1.1 6.0
1.0
5.0
0.9
0.8 4.0
Mar-00 Aug-02 Jan-05 Jun-07 Nov-09 Apr-12 Sep-14 Mar-00 Aug-02 Jan-05 Jun-07 Nov-09 Apr-12 Sep-14
USD/CAD PPP VALFeX USD/NOK PPP VALFeX

Source: Crédit Agricole CIB, OECD, Bloomberg Source: Crédit Agricole CIB, OECD, Bloomberg

Model specification and empirical methodology


We model the relationship between exchange rates and country fundamentals
using a stock-flow model for the determination of equilibrium real exchange rate
that was popularised by Alberola et al. (1999) 1. Our objective is to arrive at
comparable FX fair value estimates using the same cross-country variables in an
analytically rigorous way. In the model, the real exchange rate 𝑞𝑞 is defined as the
ratio of the foreign (𝑝𝑝∗ ) to domestic (𝑝𝑝) price level expressed in domestic prices
(in this case USD) using the nominal exchange rates (all in logarithms):
𝑞𝑞 = 𝑠𝑠 + 𝑝𝑝∗ − 𝑝𝑝
We denote with 𝛼𝛼 the share of tradable goods in the price index, 𝑝𝑝𝑇𝑇 is the level of
tradable goods and 𝑝𝑝𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁 – the level of non-tradable goods (both in logarithms).
Using the notation from the above equation, we can write the real exchange rate
as a function of tradables and non-tradables:
∗ ∗ ∗
𝑞𝑞 = �𝑠𝑠 + 𝑝𝑝𝑇𝑇 − 𝑝𝑝𝑇𝑇 � + (1 − 𝛼𝛼)[�𝑝𝑝𝑁𝑁𝑇𝑇 − 𝑝𝑝𝑇𝑇 � − (𝑝𝑝𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁 − 𝑝𝑝𝑇𝑇 )]

1
Alberola, E., Cervero, S., Lopez, H. And A. Ubide, 1999, Global Equilibrium Exchange Rates:
Euro, Dollar, “Ins”, “Outs”, and outher major currencies in a panel cointegration framework, IMF
WP No. 175 FX Strategy Focus 15 December 2008

14 September 2016 4
FX Focus

We refer to the first term in the above equation as the relative prices of tradable
goods between the US and each of the G9 economies and denote it by 𝑞𝑞 𝑇𝑇 . It is
determined by the equilibrium condition of their balance of payments (BoP). The
second term, denoted by 𝑞𝑞 𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁 , is the ratio of the foreign to domestic relative prices
of non-tradable goods. The greater the price of non-tradables relative to tradables
is, the more productive the economy. This is a reflection of the famous Balassa-
Samuelson effect. Productivity gains in the domestic economy (the US) relative to
abroad are reflected in an appreciating real exchange rate (𝑞𝑞 is lower).
The equilibrium exchange rate, 𝑞𝑞, should be consistent with simultaneous
external and internal equilibriums.
𝑇𝑇 𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁
𝑞𝑞 = 𝑞𝑞 + 𝑞𝑞
𝑇𝑇
The external equilibrium rate, 𝑞𝑞 , clears the tradable goods market and is
characterized by the achievement of the desirable stock of net foreign assets
(NFA). Adjustment to equilibrium is reflected in the evolution of the CA balance,
which in turn leads to accumulation of NFA. CA is reflecting the sum of the
balance of trade and the net income on foreign holdings. It thus depends on the
relative prices of tradable goods between the US and the rest of G10. A
sustainable balance of payments (BoP) positions is characterized by a CA
financed by sustainable accumulation of capital flows. Assuming that 𝐹𝐹 is the
desired level of NFA position one could derive the external equilibrium exchange
𝑇𝑇
rate, 𝑞𝑞 , from the BoP equilibrium:
𝑇𝑇
𝛾𝛾𝑞𝑞 + 𝑖𝑖 ∗ 𝑓𝑓 = 𝜂𝜂(𝐹𝐹 − 𝑓𝑓), 𝛾𝛾, 𝜂𝜂 > 0
where 𝑖𝑖 ∗ is the international interest rate, 𝑓𝑓 is the stock of net foreign assets and
𝑇𝑇
𝛾𝛾𝑞𝑞 represents the trade balance expressed as a function of the relative price of
tradable goods. If a country (US) is running a CA deficit that results in a build-up
of foreign liabilities above the desired level, the above equation suggests that the
𝑇𝑇
currency of the economy would depreciate (𝑞𝑞 will grow) on the back of concerns
about the sustainability of the CA deficit and the need to improve the trade
balance.
𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁
The internal contribution to the equilibrium exchange rate - 𝑞𝑞 - reflects the
relative prices of non-tradable goods across countries. These are determined
internally in each of the economies and depend on the relative productivity of the
tradable and non-tradable sectors. Productivity gains in the tradable goods sector
should spill over into non-tradable goods sector since the non-tradable goods
market clears domestically. This is once again the Balassa-Samuelson effect
𝑁𝑁𝑇𝑇
discussed above and 𝑞𝑞 is our way to compare the relative sectoral productivity
across economies (productivity) provided that equilibriums are achieved
domestically:
𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁 ∗ ∗
𝑞𝑞 = (1 − 𝛼𝛼)�(𝑦𝑦 𝑇𝑇 − 𝑦𝑦 𝑁𝑁𝑇𝑇 � − (𝑦𝑦 𝑇𝑇 − 𝑦𝑦 𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁 )]
where 𝑦𝑦𝑖𝑖 stands for sector productivity in sector 𝑖𝑖 (𝑖𝑖 = 𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁, 𝑇𝑇). We combine the
last three equations to get an expression for the equilibrium real exchange rate:
∗ ∗
𝑞𝑞 = 𝛾𝛾 −1 [𝜂𝜂𝜂𝜂 − (𝑖𝑖 ∗ + 𝜂𝜂)𝑓𝑓] + (1 − 𝛼𝛼)[�𝑦𝑦 𝑇𝑇 − 𝑦𝑦 𝑁𝑁𝑇𝑇 � − (𝑦𝑦 𝑇𝑇 − 𝑦𝑦 𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁 )]
The equilibrium real exchange rate is therefore a negative function of the NFA or
𝑓𝑓 in the above equation – implying that greater NFA in the home country (US)
should result in lower 𝑞𝑞. At the same time, the equilibrium real exchange rate is a
negative function of the productivity of the home country. The more productive
the US, the lower its 𝑞𝑞.
A direct rendition of the theoretical framework above into an econometric model
would require a proxy for the relative NFA of the G9 countries vs the US. One
such proxy can be constructed by accumulating the CA imbalances of the G9
economies and comparing them to the US. In the final G10 VALFeX model
specification we use the relative CA imbalances of the G9 countries vs the US,
however. This is because we found that they are more strongly correlated with
our dependent variable than our NFA proxy.
We took further steps to improve the quality of our fair value estimates by adding
to the model drivers of the G10 external imbalances with more direct impact on
the FX markets like commodity ToT and real interest rates spreads. In this way
we try to address persistent deviations of FX spot from fair value estimates based

14 September 2016 5
FX Focus

on NFA alone. Such deviations arise because the latter does not account for
market expectations about the future path of the external imbalances or the
countries’ ability to finance persistent CA deficits over longer periods of time.
The inclusion of commodity ToT makes our analysis of the relationship between
FX and external imbalances more forward looking. For example, investors’
expectations that improving commodity ToT will boosts the outlook for the trade
account of commodity exporters and keep commodity currencies supported
despite looming trade and CA deficits. We use commodity ToT because unlike
the broader terms of trade version the variable is predominantly driven by global
factors like the USD and the price of oil that make it particularly relevant in our
panel cointegration model.
In addition, the inclusion of real rate and bond yield spread allows us to model the
ability of some G10 countries to fund their sizeable CA deficits and keep their
currencies supported. In that, higher short rates and long-term bond yields
resulting in wider spreads to the US, should attract portfolio inflows over time. All
that should keep the higher-yielding G10 currencies supported despite looming
external imbalances.
We estimate a model of the following form:
𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒 𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅 𝐺𝐺9/𝑈𝑈𝑈𝑈𝑈𝑈 = 𝑞𝑞(𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝, 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶, 𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇, 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟 𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠𝑠)
As dependent variables we use real exchange rates or the G10 USD-crosses
adjusted for the relative differences in price levels between the G9 economies
and the US. Turning to the independent variables, we use the Balassa-
Samuelson measure of relative productivity discussed above. To this end, for
each country, we construct the ratio of its CPI and PPI as proxies for the prices of
non-tradables and tradables goods. We then calculate relative productivity
measures for G9 currencies vs USD. As a second independent variable we use
the differences between the CA balances between the G9 and the US expressed
as a percentage of their respective GDP. As a third independent variable we use
the ratio of the G9 commodity ToT and the USD. Last but not least, on the right-
hand side of the equation we include the 2Y rate, and 10Y bond yield real
spreads between G9 economies and the US.
Our econometric results suggested that the most important driver of the G9 USD-
crosses was relative productivity. It was followed by the relative CA imbalances,
the real rate and bond yield spreads, and the commodity ToT.
We use a panel cointegration econometric model to determine the fair value of
USD-crosses. We use a balanced panel of quarterly data with 9 cross-section
and 66 dynamic observations. Before estimating the empirical model, we make
sure that the series are non-stationary by running panel unit root tests. We then
run panel cointegration tests to verify the existence of a cointegration relationship
among the variables. A group of series is said to be cointegrated when all group-
members are non-stationary and their linear combination is stationary. The
stationary linear combination can be interpreted as a long-run equilibrium
relationship between the currencies and their drivers, and subsequently be used
for the calculation of the fair-value exchange rates. The panel cointegration tests
(Pedroni, Kao and Fisher) all indicated the existence of a cointegration
relationship among the series.
When fitting the model we run Whu-Hausman and Breuch-Pagan model
specification tests. Both indicated that the fixed effects cross section specification
is to be preferred to the random effects one. The fixed effects model specification
implies that we conduct the analysis using deviations of the level data from their
cross-section means. The econometric model is estimated in logarithms and has
a good overall fit with R2 reaching 80% for our final specification. All coefficients
have the expected signs and the most important driver seems to be relative
productivity.
Based on the above results we estimate a panel regression model of the
following form:
𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 = 𝛼𝛼𝑖𝑖 + 𝛽𝛽1 𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 + 𝛽𝛽2 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 + 𝛽𝛽3 𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 + 𝛽𝛽4 2𝑌𝑌𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 + 𝛽𝛽5 10𝑌𝑌𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 + 𝜂𝜂𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖
where 𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 represents the vector of dependent variables – real G10 USD
exchange rates 𝑖𝑖 (𝑖𝑖 = 1,2, … 9) in period 𝑡𝑡. 𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 represents the vector
with the relative productivity variables for each G9 country 𝑖𝑖 in period 𝑡𝑡. 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 is

14 September 2016 6
FX Focus

the vector with the relative current account balances between the G9 country 𝑖𝑖 in
period 𝑡𝑡 and the US. 𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 is the vector of the terms of trade variables for each
G9 country 𝑖𝑖 in period 𝑡𝑡 relative to the US. 2𝑌𝑌𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 and 10𝑌𝑌𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 are the vectors of the 2Y
and 10Y bond yields for each G9 country 𝑖𝑖 vs the US in period 𝑡𝑡. 𝛼𝛼𝑖𝑖 is the fixed
(time invariant) effect for country 𝑖𝑖. 𝜂𝜂𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 is a white noise error term with 𝜂𝜂𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 ~
𝜂𝜂𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 �0, 𝜎𝜎𝜂𝜂2 �.

14 September 2016 7
FX Focus

Global Markets Research contact details


v. 21/06/16 Jean-François Paren Head of Global Markets Research +33 1 41 89 33 95
Asia (Hong Kong & Tokyo) Europe (London & Paris) Americas (New York)
Macro Strategy Kazuhiko Ogata Louis Harreau Michael P. Carey **
Chief Economist Japan ECB Strategist Chief Economist US
+81 3 4580 5360 +33 1 41 89 98 95 +1 212 261 7134
Xavier Chapard Evan Carmean**
Global Macro Strategist US Associate
+33 1 41 89 13 45 +1 212 261 2686
Interest Rates Yoshiro Sato Mohit Kumar David Keeble **
Economist / Strategist - Japan Global Head of Rates Strategy Head of US Rates Strategy
+81 3 4580 5337 +44 20 7214 6651 +1 212 261 3274
Romain Blanchet Jonathan Rick **
IRD Strategist IRD Strategist
+33 1 41 89 00 64 +1 212 261 4096
Orlando Green CFA
Senior IRD Strategist
+44 20 7214 7467
Afsaneh Mastouri
Interest Rates Strategist
+44 20 7214 6737
Jean-François Perrin
Inflation Strategist
+33 1 41 89 94 22
Emerging Markets Dariusz Kowalczyk Sébastien Barbé
Senior Emerging Market Strategist Head of Emerging Market Research & Strategy
+852 2826 1519 +33 1 41 89 15 97
Gary Yau Jakub Borowski
Emerging Market Strategist Chief Economist - Crédit Agricole Bank Polska SA
+852 2826 1553 +48 22 573 18 40
Alexander Pecherytsyn
Chief Economist – Crédit Agricole Bank Ukraine
+38 44 493-9014
Guillaume Tresca
Senior Emerging Market Strategist
+33 1 41 89 18 47
Foreign Exchange David Forrester Valentin Marinov Vassili Serebriakov
FX Strategist Head of G10 FX Research & Strategy FX Strategist
+852 2826 1529 +44 20 7214 5289 +1 212 261 3309
Jennifer Hau
FX Strategist
+44 20 7214 7468
Manuel Oliveri
FX Strategist
+44 20 7214 7469
** employee(s) of Crédit Agricole Securities (USA), Inc.

Certification
The views expressed in this report accurately reflect the personal views of the undersigned analyst(s). In addition, the undersigned analyst(s) has
not and will not receive any compensation for providing a specific recommendation or view in this report.

Valentin Marinov Jennifer Hau


Important: Please note that in the United States, this fixed income research report is considered to be fixed income commentary and not fixed
income research. Notwithstanding this, the Crédit Agricole CIB Research Disclaimer that can be found at the end of this report applies to this report
in the United States as if references to research report were to fixed income commentary. Products and services are provided in the United States
through Crédit Agricole Securities (USA), Inc.

Foreign exchange disclosure statement to clients of CACIB


http://mediacommun.ca-cib.com/sitegenic/medias/DOC/85478/2015-12-08-foreign-exchange-disclosure-statement-to-clients-of-cacib.pdf

14 September 2016 8
FX Focus

Disclaimer
© 2016, CRÉDIT AGRICOLE CORPORATE AND INVESTMENT BANK All rights reserved.
This research report or summary has been prepared by Crédit Agricole Corporate and Investment Bank or one of its affiliates (collectively “Crédit
Agricole CIB”) from information believed to be reliable. Such information has not been independently verified and no guarantee, representation or
warranty, express or implied, is made as to its accuracy, completeness or correctness.
This report is provided for information purposes only. Nothing in this report should be considered to constitute investment, legal, accounting or
taxation advice and you are advised to contact independent advisors in order to evaluate this report. It is not intended, and should not be
considered, as an offer, invitation, solicitation or personal recommendation to buy, subscribe for or sell any of the financial instruments described
herein, nor is it intended to form the basis for any credit, advice, personal recommendation or other evaluation with respect to such financial
instruments and is intended for use only by those professional investors to whom it is made available by Crédit Agricole CIB. Crédit Agricole CIB
does not act in a fiduciary capacity to you in respect of this report.
Crédit Agricole CIB may at any time stop producing or updating this report. Not all strategies are appropriate at all times. Past performance is not
necessarily a guide to future performance. The price, value of and income from any of the financial instruments mentioned in this report can fall as
well as rise and you may make losses if you invest in them. Independent advice should be sought. In any case, investors are invited to make their
own independent decision as to whether a financial instrument or whether investment in the financial instruments described herein is proper,
suitable or appropriate based on their own judgement and upon the advice of any relevant advisors they have consulted. Crédit Agricole CIB has not
taken any steps to ensure that any financial instruments referred to in this report are suitable for any investor. Crédit Agricole CIB will not treat
recipients of this report as its customers by virtue of their receiving this report.
Crédit Agricole CIB, its directors, officers and employees may effect transactions (whether long or short) in the financial instruments described
herein for their own accounts or for the account of others, may have positions relating to other financial instruments of the issuer thereof, or any of
its affiliates, or may perform or seek to perform securities, investment banking or other services for such issuer or its affiliates. Crédit Agricole CIB
may have issued, and may in the future issue, other reports that are inconsistent with, and reach different conclusions from, the information
presented in this report. Crédit Agricole CIB is under no obligation to ensure that such other reports are brought to the attention of any recipient of
this report. Crédit Agricole CIB has established a “Policy for Managing Conflicts of Interest in relation to Investment Research” which is available
upon request. A summary of this Policy is published on the Crédit Agricole CIB website: http://www.ca-cib.com/sitegenic/medias/DOC/91928/2011-
politique-gestion-conflits-interets-ca-cib-va.pdf. This Policy applies to its investment research activity.
None of the material, nor its content, nor any copy of it, may be altered in any way, transmitted to, copied or distributed to any other party without the
prior express written permission of Crédit Agricole CIB. To the extent permitted by applicable securities laws and regulations, Crédit Agricole CIB
accepts no liability whatsoever for any direct or consequential loss arising from the use of this document or its contents.
France: Crédit Agricole Corporate and Investment Bank is authorised by the Autorité de Contrôle Prudentiel et de Résolution (“ACPR”) and
supervised by the European Central Bank (“ECB”), the ACPR and the Autorité des Marchés Financiers (“AMF”). Crédit Agricole Corporate and
Investment Bank is incorporated in France with limited liability. Registered office: 12, Place des Etats-Unis, CS 70052, 92 547 Montrouge Cedex
(France). Companies Register: SIREN 304 187 701 with Registre du Commerce et des Sociétés de Nanterre. United Kingdom: Approved and/or
distributed by Crédit Agricole Corporate and Investment Bank, London branch. Crédit Agricole Corporate and Investment Bank is authorised by the
ACPR and supervised by the European Central Bank (“ECB”), the ACPR and the AMF in France and subject to limited regulation by the Financial
Conduct Authority and the Prudential Regulation Authority. Details about the extent of our regulation by the Financial Conduct Authority and the
Prudential Regulation Authority are available from us on request. Crédit Agricole Corporate and Investment Bank is incorporated in France with
limited liability and registered in England and Wales. Registered number: FC008194. UK establishment number: BR001975. Registered office:
Broadwalk House, 5 Appold Street, London, EC2A 2DA. United States of America: This research report is distributed solely to persons who qualify
as “Major U.S. Institutional Investors” as defined in Rule 15a-6 under the Securities and Exchange Act of 1934 and who deal with Crédit Agricole
Corporate and Investment Bank. This report does not carry all of the independence and disclosure standards of a retail debt research report.
Recipients of this research in the United States wishing to effect a transaction in any security mentioned herein should do so by contacting Crédit
Agricole Securities (USA), Inc. (a broker-dealer registered with the Securities and Exchange Commission (“SEC”) and the Financial Industry
Regulatory Authority (“FINRA”)). The delivery of this research report to any person in the United States shall not be deemed a recommendation of
Crédit Agricole Securities (USA), Inc. to effect any transactions in the securities discussed herein or an endorsement of any opinion expressed
herein. This report shall not be re-distributed in the United States without the consent of Crédit Agricole Securities (USA), Inc. Italy: This research
report can only be distributed to, and circulated among, professional investors (operatori qualificati), as defined by the relevant Italian securities
legislation. Spain: Distributed by Crédit Agricole Corporate and Investment Bank, Madrid branch and may only be distributed to institutional
investors (as defined in article 7.1 of Royal Decree 291/1992 on Issues and Public Offers of Securities) and cannot be distributed to other investors
that do not fall within the category of institutional investors. Hong Kong: Distributed by Crédit Agricole Corporate and Investment Bank, Hong Kong
branch. This research report can only be distributed to professional investors within the meaning of the Securities and Futures Ordinance (Cap.571)
and any rule made there under. Japan: Distributed by Crédit Agricole Securities Asia B.V. which is registered for financial instruments business in
Japan pursuant to the Financial Instruments and Exchange Act (Act No. 25 of 1948), and is not intended, and should not be considered, as an offer,
invitation, solicitation or recommendation to buy or sell any of the financial instruments described herein. This report is not intended, and should not
be considered, as advice on investments in securities which is subject to the Financial Instruments and Exchange Act (Act No. 25 of 1948).
Luxembourg: Distributed by Crédit Agricole Corporate and Investment Bank, Luxembourg branch. It is only intended for circulation and/or
distribution to institutional investors and investments mentioned in this report will not be available to the public but only to institutional investors.
Singapore: Distributed by Crédit Agricole Corporate and Investment Bank, Singapore branch. It is not intended for distribution to any persons other
than accredited investors, as defined in the Securities and Futures Act (Chapter 289 of Singapore), and persons whose business involves the
acquisition or disposal of, or the holding of capital markets products (as defined in the Securities and Futures Act (Chapter 289 of Singapore)).
Switzerland: Distributed by Crédit Agricole (Suisse) S.A. This report is not subject to the SBA Directive of January 24, 2003 as they are produced
by a non-Swiss entity. Germany: Distributed by Crédit Agricole Corporate and Investment Bank, Frankfurt branch and may only be distributed to
institutional investors. Australia: Distributed to wholesale investors only. This research, and any access to it, is intended only for “wholesale clients”
within the meaning of the Australian Corporations Act.
THE DISTRIBUTION OF THIS DOCUMENT IN OTHER JURISDICTIONS MAY BE RESTRICTED BY LAW, AND PERSONS INTO WHOSE
POSSESSION THIS DOCUMENT COMES SHOULD INFORM THEMSELVES ABOUT, AND OBSERVE, ANY SUCH RESTRICTIONS. BY
ACCEPTING THIS REPORT YOU AGREE TO BE BOUND BY THE FOREGOING. 05/08/16

14 September 2016 9

Você também pode gostar