Você está na página 1de 12

American Economic Association

A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation


Author(s): James E. Anderson
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 69, No. 1 (Mar., 1979), pp. 106-116
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1802501
Accessed: 25-02-2018 00:50 UTC

REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
http://www.jstor.org/stable/1802501?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to The American Economic Review

This content downloaded from 147.96.1.236 on Sun, 25 Feb 2018 00:50:58 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation
By JAMES E. ANDERSON*

Probably the most successful empirical a justification, see Peter Isard). The gravity
trade device of the last twenty-five years is model constrains the pure expenditure sys-
the gravity equation. Applied to a wide tem by specifying that the share of na-
variety of goods and factors moving over tional expenditure accounted for by spend-
regional and national borders under dif- ing on tradeables (openness to trade) is a
fering circumstances, it usually produces a stable unidentified reduced-form function
good fit. Unfortunately, as is widely recog- of income and population. The share of
nized, its use for policy is severely ham- total tradeable goods expenditure ac-
pered by its "unidentified" properties. counted for by each tradeable good cate-
Insertion into the equation of policy in- gory across regions is an identified (through
struments such as border taxes has no preferences) function of transit cost vari-
theoretical justification; and inference ables. Partial identification is achieved.
about the effect of taxes from examining While other interpretations are possible
changes in the equation over times when (see for example Edward Leamer and
taxes have changed carries no guarantee of Robert Stern),2 the one advanced here has
validity.
The gravity equation ordinarily is speci- 2They offer three explanations. The first, based on
fied as physics, has little interest. The second identifies the
equation loosely as a reduced form with exogenous
demand-side variables (importer income and popula-
(1) Mijk = ak YI k y7kN kNjkd A,k Uijk
tion) and supply-side variables (exporter income and
where Mijk is the dollar flow of good or population). Alternatively, the importer and ex-
factor k from country or region i to country porter characteristics identify the size of the foreign
sector in each, with any flow a function of size at either
or region j, Yi and Yj are incomes in i and j,end. The third interpretation is based on a probability
Ni and Nj are population in i and j, and d1jmodel. Let Zi be country i's total imports, an uniden-
is the distance between countries (regions) tified reduced-form function of income, population,
and other possibly unobservable variables. The set
i andj. The Uijk is a lognormally distributed
IZil/T, where T = ,Z,, world trade, has the form of
error term with E(In Uijk) = 0. Frequently
a probability distribution. Alternatively Zi/T is a
the flows are aggregated across goods. trade potential. The probability of the occurrence of
Ordinarily the equation is run on cross- flow between i and j is taken to be ZiZj/T2. Alterna-
section data and sometimes on pooled data. tively, potential between i and ] is the product of the i
Typical estimates find income elasticities and j potentials. The expected size of the flow given

not significantly different from one and T is then Mii = ZiZj/T. The term T is constant in a
cross-section study and can be neglected. Resistance
significantly different from zero, and popu- to trade, proxied by distance, can be inserted and with
lation elasticities around -.4 usually sig- the log-linear form for all functions, we have the
nificantly different from zero.' gravity equation. This interpretation has the advantage
of explaining the multiplicative functional form, and
The intent of this paper is to provide a
has a useful flexibility. Leamer subsequently developed
theoretical explanation for the gravity a hybrid version of it to explain aggregate imports of
equation applied to commodities. It uses good k by country i. In the hybrid model, Zj becomes
the properties of expenditure systems with Zj(i) = 2jsiZj. Also, the parameters of the Zi and
a maintained hypothesis of identical homo- Zj(i) functions are permitted to vary by commodity
group k. Leamer's hybrid is thus
thetic preferences across regions. Products
are differentiated by place of origin (for M1k = Zi Zj(i) 'I(di, ti, tj(j))
where di is a vector of distance from i to all other
*Professor of economics, Boston College. I am in- countries, ti is a vector of i's tariffs, and tj(i) is a vec-
debted to Marvin Kraus and Edward Leamer for tor of all other countries' tariffs. The problem with
helpful comments. either the Leamer-Stern gravity interpretation or the
1 See for example Norman D. Aitken. Leamer hybrid is that while the potential or probabil-

106

This content downloaded from 147.96.1.236 on Sun, 25 Feb 2018 00:50:58 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 69 NO. I ANDERSON: GRA VITY EQUA TION 107

four distinct advantages. First, it explains national income and population. Total
the multiplicative form of the equation. trade expenditure is distributed across
Second, it permits an interpretation of dis- individual categories by share functions
tance in the equation, identifying the esti- which are identical across countries. With
mated coefficient, and can be used as part this structure, Section II produces a gravity
of an attack on estimating the effect of equation with potentially attractive prop-
instrument changes. Third, the vague erties. Section III discusses estimation of
underlying assumption of identical "struc- the model, shows that the usual technique
ture" across regions or countries is straight- may produce biased results, and suggests
forwardly interpreted as identical expendi- alternatives. Section IV integrates in dis-
ture functions. This suggests appropriate tance (as a proxy for transport costs) and
disaggregation. Finally, following the logic border taxes producing a full model sug-
of the present interpretation implies that gesting the possibility of identifying long-
the usual estimator of the gravity equation run tariff elasticities. A constant elasticity
may be biased, requiring change in the of substitution (CES) case developed in the
method of estimation. Appendix provides further details.
The present interpretation of the gravity Two areas for theoretical development
model makes it part of an alternative may be noted. The major remaining un-
method of doing cross-section budget identified part of the equation is the func-
studies. The bias problems now uncovered tion stipulating that trade's share of
may be quite severe, especially with transit budgets is dependent on income and
costs varying considerably, but there are population. While this is a well-established
efficiency gains to trade off against them. empirical relation, it would be nice to have
The background of difficulty in modelling an explanation. None is offered here.
trade flows requires respect for any po- Use of pooled cross-section and time-
tentially promising method. This paper series data requires a further development
shows that the gravity model may merit of the model also not attempted here. Two
continued development and use. requirements should be noted. First, a
Section I develops the simplest linear theory of how short-run responses to price
expenditure model, which produces an changes (revealed over time) are related to
equation like (1) but with the last three long-run responses (revealed over the cross
variables omitted and with Yi and Yj con- section) is needed. Second, a theory of how
strained to have unit elasticity. The major short-run responses to income changes (re-
portion of the explanatory power of the vealed over time in the Keynesian type of
gravity model is thus encompassed. While trade model) are related to long-run re-
yielding a gravity equation, the models sponses must be constructed. Part of the
would never sensibly be so estimated. second story must be the relation of trade
In the next two sections, the gravity ap- balance to asset accumulation stressed in
proach gains legitimacy as a device offering the recent monetary approach to the bal-
large gains in efficiency of estimation at a ance of payments.
possible cost of bias. An important fact of
life is large interregional and international I. The Pure Expenditure System Model
variations in shares of total expenditure
accounted for by traded goods, even across The simplest possible gravity-type model
regions or countries where spending pat- stems from a rearrangement of a Cobb-
terns are reasonably similar (for example, Douglas expenditure system. Assume that
the set of developed Western countries). each country is completely specialized in
These are assumed to vary as a function of the production of its own good (as in a
Keynesian-type trade model), so there is
one good for each country. No tariffs or
ity story is plausible, it lacks a compelling economic transport costs exist. The fraction of in-
justification. come spent on the product of country i is

This content downloaded from 147.96.1.236 on Sun, 25 Feb 2018 00:50:58 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
108 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 1979

denoted bi and is the same in all countries framework, the real variables of interest
(i.e., there are identical Cobb-Douglas are the non-income-dependent expenditure
preferences everywhere). With cross-section shares. The gravity equation is a silly speci-
analysis, prices are constant at equilibrium fication from an econometric standpoint
values and units are chosen such that they since it substitutes out the share (which in
are all unity. Consumption in value and the Cobb-Douglas case is the only param-
quantity terms of good i in country j (= im- eter). This section appends to the Cobb-
ports of good i by countryj) is thus Douglas expenditure system for traded
goods a differing traded-nontraded goods
(2) Mii = biYj
split and produces an unrestricted (non-
where Yj is income in countryj.
unit income elasticity) gravity equation.
The requirement that income must equal The next section shows that the gravity
sales implies that equation becomes far more sensible.
Traded-goods shares of total expenditure
(3) Yi = bi(2 Y1)
vary widely across regions and countries.
Solving (3) for bi and substituting into (2), Hollis Chenery and others subsequently
we obtain have found that in cross-section data such
shares are "explained" rather well by in-
(4) Mu = Yi Yj/2 Yj come and population. Moreover, the linear or
This is the simplest form of "gravity" log-linear regression line of traded goods
model. If we disregard error structure,3 a shares on income and population tends to
generalization of equation (4) can be esti- be stable over time. No identification of this
mated by ordinary least squares, with ex- relationship is attempted here, but loosely,
ponents on Yi, Yj unrestricted. In a pure income per capita is an exogenous demand-
cross section, the denominator is an ir- side factor, and population (country size)
relevant scale term. The income elasticities a supply-side factor. Trade shares "should"
produced (disregarding bias) should not increase with income per capita and de-
differ significantly from unity. The func- crease with size. Leamer and Stern have
tional form of the gravity equation and a also suggested including an endowment
major portion of the explanatory power is measure as an explanatory variable which
encompassed by the expenditure system would act somewhat like size.4 Accepting
model. the stability of the trade-share function,
the expenditure system model combines
II. The Trade-Share-Expenditure with it to produce the gravity equation.
System Model Assume that all countries produce a
traded and a nontraded good. The overall
The gravity equation of Section I is based preference function assumed in this formu-
on identical Cobb-Douglas preferences,
implying identical expenditure shares and
41t is easy to construct examples where the trade
gravity equation income elasticities of share is a simple closed form function of factor endow-
unity. It could be fancied up by allowing ment variables. Consider the small-country case in
policy induced price differences to produce which all traded goods may be treated as a composite
different expenditure shares in a less restric- and there is one nontraded good. Stipulate a simple
non-Cobb-Douglas utility function in traded goods
tive preference form such as the CES, but and the nontraded good and assume the linear version
there is little point in the exercise. While of the two-sector production model. When a model
a gravity equation is produced by such a of this sort is solved for an interior equilibrium-
traded-goods share assuming trade balance, it pro-
duces a relatively simple function of the endowments.
3Note that the manipulation which justified the Results analogous to the Johnson pro- and antitrade
presence of Yi in (4) means that there may be simul- bias analysis are embodied in the function. I have
taneous equation bias, with the Y's not being indepen- been unable, however, to discover a specification
dent of error terms postulated for the equations (2) which produces a traded-goods share function which
and (3). This problem is discussed in Section III. is log-linear in income and factor endowments.

This content downloaded from 147.96.1.236 on Sun, 25 Feb 2018 00:50:58 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 69 NO. I ANDERSON: GRA VITY EQUA TION 109

lation is weakly separable with respect to Solving (6) for 0i and substituting into (5),
the partition between traded and nontraded we have
goods: u = u (g(traded goods), nontraded
goods). Then given the level of expenditure (7) q7) Y j=
M1= yi Xi YiJi Yi
on traded goods, individual traded-goods , ,, E Xji yi E mii
j iij
demands are determined as if a homothetic
utility function in traded goods alone g( ) With F(Yi, N1) taking on a log-linear form,
were maximized subject to a budget con- (7) is the deterministic form of the gravity
straint involving the level of expenditure equation (1) with the distance term sup-
on traded goods. The individual traded- pressed and a scale term appended. More
goods shares of total trade expenditure realistically, if trade imbalance due to long-
with homotheticity are functions of traded- term capital account transactions is a func-
goods prices only.5 For simplicity, it is tion of (Yi, N1), we may write the "basic"
assumed g( ) has the Cobb-Douglas form balance Yiimi = (2jY,j)0, with mi =
in the rest of the text. Within the class of m(Yi, Ne), and substitute into (6) and (7).
traded goods, since preferences are identi- This yields6
cal, expenditure shares for any good are
identical across countries. Thus, for any (8) M1j = mA5 Yij Yj
consuming country j, 0i is the expenditure
i i
on country i's tradeable good divided by
total expenditure in j on tradeables; i.e., With log-linear forms for m and F, (8) is
Oi is an exponent of g( ). Let /j be the again essentially the deterministic gravity
share of expenditure on all traded goods in equation.
total expenditure of country j and 4j =
F( Yj, Nj). III. Estimation Efficiency
Demand for i's tradeable good in coun-
tryj (j's imports of i's good) is The model of linear expenditures of Sec-
tion I, while implying a gravity equation,
(5) Mij = "i Yj would never sensibly be so estimated.
The balance-of-trade relation for country Homothetic preferences identical across
i implies countries imply identical expenditure share
functions, and these can be estimated di-
(6) Yii= (Yjoj)0i rectly, treating distance and trade taxes ap-
value of imports of i value of exports of i propriately in a manner set out in Section
plus domestic spending = plus domestic spending IV. Simply divide the demand equations of
on domestic tradeables on domestic tradeables Section I or their analogue by own income
and find the mean over j of Mi,/ Yj = the
5Homotheticity of g( ) is imposed because the
estimator of Oi. The stochastic budget con-
presence of traded-goods expenditure as an argument straint information can also be utilized to
in the Oi function will greatly complicate estimation. (in effect) add one observation since7 0i =
Separability is imposed to permit the two-stage deci-
sion process which removes nontraded-goods prices
yi/Ij Yj.
The trade-share model of Section II on
from the 0i function. Some justification for separabil-
ity may be found in the observation that traded goods the other hand lends some legitimacy to the
are far more similar to each other than they are to gravity model. Eventually we will allow
nontraded goods. Homotheticity would imply that,
ceteris paribus, larger nations' trade expenditures are 6Balance-of-payments disequilibrium could be
scalar expansions of smaller nations' trade expendi- treated as part of the error terms in estimation. Use
tures. This may not do great violence to reality. A of the model is best restricted to equilibrium years,
gravity-type model which imposes neither restriction is however, since error terms due to disequilibrium may
possible, but it would be far more complex and dif- be correlated with Y,, Nj, and therefore cause errors
ficult to estimate. As with most empirical work on in estimation.
preferences, the restrictions' main appeal is conve- 7Again, we disregard the problem that the Y's de-
nience. pend on the error term through the budget constraint.

This content downloaded from 147.96.1.236 on Sun, 25 Feb 2018 00:50:58 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
110 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 1979

many tradeables for each country, with zero). The denominator of (8) and (8') then
tariffs and transport costs present, but ini- has only the included group's trade ex-
tially, as before, assume only one tradeable penditure.8 Under either interpretation, the
in each and no barriers to trade. The sys- identifying restrictions immediately allow
tem to be estimated is recovery of all structural exponents from
the estimator of (8'). Either interpretation
(5') M = Oj0 Yj Uj,
will also permit the complex constant term
(6') m1i bY, = Oi 01Yi
i
(km kl/k') to be unravelled, though the
estimators kmin kO , k' have only large sample
where Uii is a log-normal disturbance with
unbiasedness.9 Finally, form the set of esti-
E(/n Uij) = 0. Note that (6') states that
planned expenditures (reduced or increased mated values for traded-goods expenditures:
by the capital account factor) = planned (9) fj Yj = k/ Yky+I NjN
sales, and has no error term. Efficient esti-
mation requires that the information in (6') The individual traded-goods shares 0
be utilized. The most convenient way to do can be estimated using the instruments $^
this, since the constraint is highly non- (which are asymptotically uncorrelated with
Ujj):
linear in the Y's, is to substitute out Oi and
estimate the gravity equation:
8If neither of these alternatives is palatable, exports
(8) M i =
to the rest of the world can be fixed at Mi,n+ 1. Trade
m(Yi, Ni)F(Yi, Nj YiF(Yj, Nj) Yj balance is now

ZF(Yj,Nj)Y J
(a) miqi Yi = Oil k1 Y1 + Mi,n+ I
I

With the log-linear form for m( ) and F( ), When the trade balance is solved for Qi and sub-
stituted, the gravity equation is
m(Yi, N) = km YTYNTN
(b) M (Mi0i Yi Min+ l) )?jYj
and F(Yj,Nn) = k?,H': Nj
Z i ki
and the denominator made a constant term
Non-linear methods must be used to estimate (b).
we have
9Consider the worldwide identity of preferences
case. Using conditional expectations in (6'), the trade
(8') Mij = (km YYNy N )(kX Y/+YN/iN)Y balance requirement implies that

* (k,l y+NjN) YjUij k'


kmkl y l Yy+myN 4mN = E E(Mi) + M I
= (kmk,) Y+myY+' N7mN+'PN 1= 1

where Mi,n+ I is the exogenous nonrandom export


* YI
OY + lN
OfjNjUik
.k'
of i to the rest of the world. Replacing E(Mij) with its
This is the aggregate form of (1) with the solved values M1j, and the exponents with their esti-
mated values, we have
distance term omitted. Ordinarily it would
be fitted on a subset of countries in the (a)
world. Exports to the rest of the world are
kmk= [Z i + Min ^1] - N i
exogenous and imports from it are excluded J= 1

from the fitting. When this is done, the de- Using the definition of k', we have
nominator is still the sum of world trade
expenditures, and (6') implies that (8) and (b) k' = k,(Z YJ$YN $N) + E
(8') assume that Oi is the same in the ex-
cluded countries as in the included coun- Finally the estimated constant term k, is theoretically

tries. Alternatively, (6') can be interpreted related to the three constants km, k,0, k' by

as a payments union multilateral balance (c) k = kmk2/k'


constraint (which includes as a special case (a)-(c) can be solved explicitly for the three constants
the rest of the world account being always kmi ko, k'.

This content downloaded from 147.96.1.236 on Sun, 25 Feb 2018 00:50:58 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 69 NO. I ANDERSON: GRA VITY EQUATION 111

(10) Mij = ei j Yj Uij instrument might be lagged income, par-


ticularly for years when last year's income
which is estimated across countries for seems unlikely to be correlated with this
country i's exports (including the rest of the year's error term. Bias remains, but may be
world's exports to included countries), sub- reduced. The other alternative is to attempt
ject to the restriction that ZOi = 1. The al- dealing with simultaneity directly. Suppose
ternative without the gravity model is to a subset of countries is considered and
estimate the O's by regressing liMijI Yjpreferences
on for traded goods are everywhere
F( Yj, Nj) and then repeating the second the same. Rest of the world demand is con-
stage. The gravity equation in effect squares sidered exogenous. Run the gravity equa-
the number of observations used in estimat- tion using ordinary least squares on the log
ing the parameters of F(Y, N). For the of the equation (or non-linear estimation of
limited number of cross-section observa- the equation with an additive disturbance
tions available, the gain in efficiency should term) and obtain estimates of Xi, 4,, and
be large. mi, mi; i= 1,..., n.'0 The trade balance
It is ironic, however, that the very si- equations in matrix notation are
multaneity which allows substitution for Oi
(11) (diag m)(diag 0) Y = (Lt') (diag 4)
may imply that the Y's are mutually deter-
mined with the error terms of the expendi- y + M.n+ I
ture system. The model (5')-(6') postulates where M = rest of the world demand,
no random term in the trade balance con-
an n x I vector
straint and thus allows treatment of the Y's Y = n x 1 vector of incomes
as predetermined. Suppose alternatively
(diag ?) = n x n diagonal matrix
that the trade balance constraint is a sto-
with 4y, i = I. n on the
chastic form: diagonal
(6") mi(Z M}i) = L Mi1 o = n x I vector of O3i i =
I i
. ,, n
or mii Y '(ZjOUji) = 0i(Eqj YjU,1) Il = 1 x n row vector of ones
., I
(diag mr) = n x n diagonal matrix with
Then (8) becomes i,, i = 1,..., n on the
diagonal
(8") M11 = tn,k,Y ikY or"' Y = (diag )-'[I - OL]IMn+l
The left-hand side contains instruments for
the Y's which attempt to deal with the
where ij = Uij E OjUji /EZ U1i simultaneity problem, and which can then
be inserted into the gravity equation and
A regression based on (8") with m( ) and used to reestimate the W's, O's, and 0's.
F( ) assigned the multiplicative form will Continued iteration would have no neces-
produce biased results (with unknown di- sarily desirable property.
rection) due to the dependency of the Y's Either instrument would probably be
on the error terms. The relative stability of preferable if the simultaneity problem were
the equation over time in some applications severe, as in the European Economic Com-
may suggest that the bias is not serious, but munity (EEC). For groups of countries with
this is conjectural. Several alternatives are
possible, two of which will be discussed 10Since E(ln eij) s 0, previous methods of identify-
here. Something like the gravity equation ing km and kO, cannot be used. For simplicity, this de-
would be desirable, replacing the Y's in tail can be evaded by assuming km = kO = 1.
IIProvided 2jOi < 1, I - OL' has an inverse. We deal
the equation with the instruments highly with a subset of goods and countries, so the condition
correlated with the Y's but independent of is fulfilled. M., + I = e n + I Yn + l with the assumption
the demand equation error terms. One such of identical preferences for the rest of the world.

This content downloaded from 147.96.1.236 on Sun, 25 Feb 2018 00:50:58 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
112 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 1979

relatively small interdependence, the gravity Tijk'S for country j. Demand for import ik
equation with the Y's directly used might (with foreign port prices of unity as before)
be preferable, the greater efficiency of direct is
use of Y's dominating the bias. These are,
of course, only rules of thumb.'2 (12) Mijk = 1 ik (7i) i YJ

IV. Many Goods, Tariffs, and Distance Aggregate trade flows between i and j are
thus
Now consider the gravity equation under
the complication of many commodity classes (13) Mij = Mijk = Xj yj Oik(ri)
of goods flowing between each country i k k Tijk

andj, with a full set of national tariffs in The trade balance relation is
each country, and with transport costs
(14) miiYi = EMi
proxied by distance. Preferences for traded
goods are identical across countries and are
homothetic, with the traded-goods share, as = z j Yz Oik (Tj)
j k Tijk
before, a function of income and popula-
tion. Within each commodity class, goods Previously we set all t
are considered to be differentiated by place divide both sides of (1
of origin.'3 The gravity equation still has the aggregate share parameter for country i
use in the estimation of trade-flow equa- goods on the right: 2kOik. The left-hand
tions of this system. As in Section 111, it is a side was then substituted into (13) to obtain
device for increasing the efficiency of esti- the gravity equation
mation of the trade-share function param-
eters. Unfortunately, tariffs and transport (8) M =Mi0iY
costs create added sources of bias in esti-
mation of both stages. The gain may still
outweigh the loss. Note that with many goods, only the ag-
The landed value at country j of com- gregate version of the gravity equation is
modity class k goods produced in country i valid under the present interpretation. 14
is MijkTijk, where Mijk is the foreign port
value and Tiyk is the transit cost factor (in-
141Leamer has extended the gravity-type cross-
cluding all border adjustments and trans- section model to aggregation across partner countries
port costs). With identical homothetic j, estimating aggregate outward flows Mik. His model
preferences for traded goods, the traded- shares with the present interpretation unidentified
reduced-form trade potential functions similar to the
goods expenditure shares are identical func-
trade-share functions above. It is further unidentified
tions Oik (ri), where Tj is the vector of the
because Leamer gives no precise economic reason for
the appearance and form of the appearance in the
12We should note that in principle minimum- equation of trade potential at both ends of the trade
distance or full-information maximum-likelihood flow. Nevertheless, it has a certain plausibility and al-
techniques can be used to estimate the parameters of lows extension to the estimation of tariff elasticities.
system (5')-(6') and its generalization. Any model In correspondence concerning an earlier version of
which can be solved to isolate its disturbance terms this paper, Leamer suggested a method of obtaining
can be so treated (see A. R. Gallant). The costliness commodity-specific gravity equations not involving the
and convergence difficulties with such non-linear tech- trade potential interpretation. As before, the demand
niques makes compromises like those in the text function is
attractive.
13Isard offers an empirical justification for this
(a) Mijk = Oikkj Y]
assumption. On a theoretical level, note that the Country i's income from sales of the ik good is
gravity model almost necessarily implies differentia-
tion by place of origin. How else can (i) two-way flows (b) Yik = Oik E X Yi
be explained, and (ii) the flow of good k between
points i and j be modelled as a function of variables Suppose that the commodity classes k are defined so
at i and j alone? that income from their production across countries

This content downloaded from 147.96.1.236 on Sun, 25 Feb 2018 00:50:58 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 69 NO. I ANDERSON: GRA VITY EQUA TION 113

With the Tijk departing from unity the


(13 ) Mij = (I 0uk)4JYJ
division of both sides of (14) byk2j?j
U
f ~(d1i)
Yj pro-
duces
(15') miOiYi = ( Eik) E Yj
k j ~f(d1i)
(15) 1:
-Z4)Zjb1
Y, -O_k ik(r1)
(j Equation (13') states that the foreign port
J i
value of country j's demand for all of i's
goods equals country j's total expenditure
The gravity equation substitutes for the on traded goods (in home prices), 4j Yj,
share in (13), 1k(l1/Tik)0ik(Tj), a weighted times the common aggregate traded-goods
average of such shares across all countries j. expenditure share for i's goods 2:k ik de-
This will cause bias of unknown sign in the flated by the transit cost factor. Equation
gravity equation parameter estimator based (15') states that country i's expenditure on
on the stochastic version of (12)-(14), and all traded goods at i's prices 4i Yi times the
subsequently in the parameter estimator of capital account scale factor mi must equal
the demand equation (12).'5 Other factors the value at country i of i's exports to all
being equal, the bias will be less the more countries. The gravity equation can now be
closely the transit costs resemble one an- derived as
other. In the limit, we return to the model
of Section III. Evidently, similarity of mi0ibYi0b1Y1 1
(16) Mi. = m _ _ _ ____Y
transit costs should be a criterion for se- z yj f(dI)
lecting countries in the cross-section sample.
This is too stringent a criterion to permit
the viability of the gravity model and flies in
* E j yj f (dj)
the face of the role it assigns to distance. To i

breathe life back into it, we can argue that


With m and the ?'s made log-linear func-
with dissimilarity of restricted types it may
tions of income and population, (16) re-
still be possible to escape with small bias.
sembles (1), with three differences. First,
If transit costs of all sorts are an increas-
(16) is an aggregate equation rather than
ing function of distance and the same across
commodity specific. Second, 1 /f (dij) is not
commodities (T ik = f(dij) with f(O) = 1
a log-linear function.'6 Finally, the square
and f' > 0), then with Cobb-Douglas
bracket term is missing in (1). It can be
preferences the demand equation and trade
interpreted as saying that the flow from i to
balance equations are
j depends on economic distance from i to j
relative to a trade-weighted average of
economic distance from i to all points in the
is a stable function of GNP, population and resource system. The model leading to (16) is prob-
endowments Ei: ably the best case one can tnake for the ag-
(c) Yik = 7k( Yit Ni, Ei) Yi gregate gravity equation as it is usually
fitted in practice. The square bracket term
Substituting (b) and (c) into (a) we obtain a gravity
might have little variation across origin
form:
points i for a group of countries distributed
(d) Mik = lyk( yit Nit Ei) Yioj( Yjt Njt Ej) Yj geographically in a polygon (for example,
the EEC). Changing origin point i will
lengthen some distances and shorten others,
This may be a promising approach, although the with the potential for little change in the
stability of the yk functions is probably more con- weighted average. With small enough bias,
troversial than the stability of the kj functions.
15The demand equation as before would be esti-
mated using cj Yj as an instrument. Note that the 16Practitioners of the gravity model use it only be-
parameters to be estimated would in principle include cause it is so convenient, and some have adopted more
substitution parameters. theoretically appealing forms.

This content downloaded from 147.96.1.236 on Sun, 25 Feb 2018 00:50:58 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
114 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 1979

the greater efficiency of the gravity equa- flow system in the gravity model style ca-
tion (1) in aggregate form in arriving at pable of dealing with tariffs and even pos-
estimates of /jYj dominates,"7 and the O's
sibly with policy-induced change in shares
can be estimated from can be developed.

( 12') Mijk = [ (f) Y 0 ik LUijk V. Conclusion

If the bias from omitting the bracketed term The gravity equation can be derived from
is likely to be substantial, (16) can be esti- the properties of expenditure systems. In
mated with constant weights in the bracket this interpretation it is an alternative
term equal to observed trade total expendi- method of doing cross-section budget
ture shares. Non-linear least squares is re- studies, and one with potentially important
quired, implying some loss in efficiency. efficiency properties. Its use is at the widest
Which procedure is preferable depends on limited to countries where the structure of
the tradeoff. traded-goods preference is very similar and,
Practitioners may be able to get away subsidiarily, where trade tax structures and
with restrictions less extreme than either transport cost structures are similar. In
the identical transit costs or Cobb-Douglas future work, it would be desirable to learn
asstumptions. Consider the CES preference more about the tradeoff between bias and
case where trade taxes are the same across efficiency involved in the gravity equation.
all countriesj for any good k of country i Other extensions include building an inter-
(often an assumption which comes close to temporal version and identifying the trade-
reality, as in the EEC). Assume transport share function.
cost factors depend only on distance (not
on commodity group). Under these condi- APPENDIX: THE CES CASE
tions, the Appendix shows that a gravity
equation may still have some promise of The CES traded goods utility indicator is
providing efficiency gains which dominate
bias. The CES demand functions may be U- E d3ikM Mk-JP ]
i k
estimated as above.in a second stage using
where Mijk is the quantity of g
the instrument 1j Yj. In principle, a trade
country i consumed in country j. Good k
17Disregarding bias, the procedure for solving out
is a different commodity in each country
the parameters of the m( ) and F( ) functions are es- due to differentiation. The elasticity of sub-
sentially the same as in Section II. The only new factor stitution is a = l/(I + p). Expenditure shares
is the presence of f(dij). If we adopt the log-linear
derived from such a utility function are
form, (16) assures us that any constant term it pos-
sesses is cancelled out (i.e., if f (dij) = kddg'1, the kd(Al) 0ijk ikPik)_0
term would not appear in the general constant term
of the estimator of(16)). The constant term kd can be
(A I ) e ijk - E E ik 1,(Pk)IA_
identified by noting that
where Oijk is the traded-goods expenditure
Mij Y +lNikN 1
share of country j for good k of country i,
(e) M - Y4$y+MNii N kddlA and P,jk is the price of good k from country
Equation (a) of fn. 9 becomes i landed in country j. The denominator of
(Al), when raised to the power l/(I - a),
(a') kmk,0 kd = M[ Mi;+ Mi,n] Y II+I Y+y gives the "true cost-of-living" index for the
j=l
CES function. The demand for imports is
N (N+ ^ N)d

Equations (a'), (e), as well as (b) and (c) of fn. 9 can


(A2) Miik = Oijk+j Yj I
ijk
be solved for all constant term estimates. Other dis-
tance functions will require other identifying restric- Derivations are standard, so omitted.
tions. Assume now that the transit cost factors

This content downloaded from 147.96.1.236 on Sun, 25 Feb 2018 00:50:58 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 69 NO. I ANDERSON: GRA VITY EQUA TION 115

are based on two components. The first is The gravity equation run on the stochastic
tik, a tax on good k of country i levied version of (A8) omitting the square bracket
by all countries in the group. The second is term has a chance of reasonably small bias
a transit cost factor, common to all goods in the estimator if there is little variation in
and dependent on distance, h(dij). the square bracket term as we move across
i and j. Note that with free trade prices of
(A3) ilk = tikh (dij) unity:
Pik

Define the "free trade" share: E6 E .(tik) I h (dij) i -


(A9) g> a = i k
(A4) (A4)
e - ik.k
0ik i3~~~ik Pi'k
Oi E 00a p! -a i k

i k
The denominator of the square bracket is a
Using (A3) and (A4) in (A 1) and (A2) the weighted sum of h(dij) - acrossj for a given
demand equation can be written i. The numerator is a weighted sum of
h(dij)-6 across i for a given j. Changin
origin points i and destination points j may
(A5) M~ik = Oi k tikh(di)]]
well create changes which wash out (as in
the related square bracket term of (16) in
the text). This is more likely for countries
ik E ik Ptikh (d geographically distributed in a polygon
ik ik ti di
(and impossible for countries distributed on
a line). We might thus hope to gain more
in efficiency than we lose in bias by estimat-
The denominator of the large square ing the stochastic form of (A8) omitting
bracket term is a weighted average of the the bracket term. The parameters of the
transit cost factors, and equals a transit m( ) and F( ) functions can be identified
cost true cost-of-living index for country j as in the text, and the instruments /j 1
raised to the power 1 - a. Denote this as used to attack the stochastic form of the
gjci. Simplifying (A5) and using the demand con- equation (A5'). Note that in esti-
vention that free trade prices are unity: mating (A5') we might again appeal to the
lack of variation in gJ-a to produce simpler
(A5') Mijk = Oik9g( -O)(tikh(dij)) aci4j Y}
estimation techniques capable of producing
The trade balance requirements are asymptotically "unbiased" estimates of a.
Other alternatives include approximation
(A6) mii= Y T Oikgj(I a)
of gj in the numerator of (A8) with a
Laspeyres traded-goods price index, and
.(tikh (dij) O a j Yi
full non-linear estimation of the stochastic
Aggregate trade flows between i andj are
form of (A8).
(A7) Mij = j1Yjg-(l`) h(di) Oik
k
tik
The gravity equation substitution replaces REFERENCES
IkOiktik in (A7) with miqi&Y/2gjjYj. The
proper substitution yields N. D. Aitken, "The Effect of the EEC and
EFTA on European Trade: A Temporal
(A8) Mij = -(- a) Cross-Section Analysis," Amer. Econ.
Rev., Dec. 1973, 63, 88 1-92.
E gj -ah (dii) -aj
H. B. Chenery, "Patterns of Industrial
Growth," Amer. Econ. Rev., Sept. 1960,
EY[ 50, 624-54.

mj iYab jYi [h( i) A. R. Gallant, "Three Stage Least Squares


oI Estimation for a System of Simultaneous,

This content downloaded from 147.96.1.236 on Sun, 25 Feb 2018 00:50:58 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
116 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 1979

Non-Linear, Implicit Equations," J. titative International Economics, Boston


Econometrics, Feb. 1977, 5, 71-88. 1970.
P. Isard, "How Far Can We Push The Law , "The Commodity Composition of
of One Price?," Amer. Econ. Rev., Dec. International Trade in Manufactures:
1977,67,942-48. An Empirical Analysis," Oxford Econ.
Edward E. Leamer and Robert M. Stern, Quan- Pap., Nov. 1974, 26, 350-74.

This content downloaded from 147.96.1.236 on Sun, 25 Feb 2018 00:50:58 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

Você também pode gostar