Você está na página 1de 18

26

Cultural and Creative


Industries
David Hesmondhalgh

The term cultural industries has been cir- analysis associated with the cultural industries
culating in cultural analysis and policy for approach, and that unqualified use of the
many years and has more recently been former now signals a considerable degree
joined by another version of the same phrase: of accommodation with neoliberalism. But
creative industries. There is understandable simply to accuse creative industries policy of
confusion about the relationships between complicity with neoliberalism is not enough.
the two terms, and an objective of this How might we critique creative industries
chapter is to reduce bewilderment in this policy and its theoretical underpinnings? In
area. To address such questions is more the final section of the chapter, I briefly
than just an exercise in semantics, however. explore one avenue of criticism, involving the
The two phrases emerge from quite different nature of work in these expanding industries.1
theoretical lineages and policy contexts. And,
for all the considerable difficulties of scope
and definition that they raise, it is clear THE CULTURAL INDUSTRIES
that both concepts refer to a domain that IN THEORY
no serious cultural analysis can afford to
ignore: how cultural goods are produced A common misconception about the term
and disseminated in modern economies and cultural industries is that its use implies
societies. A second objective of this chapter is an adherence to Adorno and Horkheimer’s
linked to the importance of that domain. I aim critique of ‘the Culture Industry’(1977/1944).
to assess how various theoretical traditions It is more accurate to think of the term as
associated with these terms understand the an attempt to pluralize and sociologize the
relations between culture and economy, and conception of cultural production in Adorno
between meaning and production. My main and Horkheimer’s brilliant but flawed essay,
claims are that the term ‘creative industries’ and to question some of the simplifications
represents a refusal of the forms of critical arising in the adoption of the idea by student

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 552 552–569
CULTURAL AND CREATIVE INDUSTRIES 553

radicals and others in the 1960s/1970s coun- I have distinguished between, on the one
terculture. The French sociologist Bernard hand, a tradition of North American political
Miège, for example, introduced a collection economy of culture, exemplified in the work
of his translated essays in 1989 by outlining of Herbert Schiller, Noam Chomsky, Edward
the main limitations, from his perspective, of Herman and Robert McChesney, and on
the culture industry idea: its failure to see how the other, the cultural industries approach,
technological innovations had transformed introduced above. The latter tradition is
artistic practice; its paradoxical emphasis more nuanced than the former, more able to
on markets and commodities rather than deal with contradiction, and with historical
on culture as an industry, as a process of variations in the social relations of cultural
production with limitations and problems; and production, and most importantly of all, it
the implication in the term ‘culture industry’ provides – and indeed is founded upon – an
that analysts were addressing a unified field analysis of the specific conditions of cultural
governed by one single process, rather than a industries. This is significant because it means
complex and diverse set of industries compet- that the cultural industries approach has been
ing for the same pool of disposable consumer able to offer explanation of certain recurring
income, time, advertising revenue and labour. dynamics, rather than polemically bemoaning
However, there is another distinction crucial the processes of concentration and integration
to understanding the term. The term ‘cultural that are a feature of capitalist production –
industries’ was not just a label for a sector including media production.
of production, it was also a phrase that came Drawing upon industrial economics, cul-
to signify an approach to cultural production tural industries writers such as Garnham
based on these and other principles, developed outlined the problems of capital accumulation
by Miège and other French sociologists, but distinctive to that sector. Their definition
also by influential British analysts, notably was restricted to those industries that use
Nicholas Garnham. characteristic forms of industrial production
This cultural industries approach was and organization to produce and disseminate
connected to a broader set of approaches to symbols. This was very much centred on the
culture that had come to be known as political media. The problems of accumulation they
economy of culture. Political economy in its identified included the especially high risks
widest sense is a general term for an entire associated with capital investment in this area,
tradition of economic analysis which differs which in turn derived from the difficulty, even
from mainstream economics by paying much in cases where substantial promotional and
greater attention to ethical and normative marketing budgets were available, of pre-
questions. The term is prefaced with the word dicting which products (whether individual
‘critical’ by analysts who wish to differen- films, TV programmes or books) or creators
tiate their work from conservative versions. (performers, musicians, writers, etc.) would
Critical political economy approaches to the achieve success. All capitalist production
media and culture developed in the late 1960s involves risk to a greater or lesser degree,
amongst sociologists and political scientists but there was a substantial case for believing
concerned by what they felt were increasing that the cultural industries were riskier than
concentrations of communicative power in most. The cultural industries sociologists
modern societies – whether in the form of state forefronted other important features too.
control or business ownership. Proponents Cultural goods had relatively high production
and opponents of political economy of culture costs, because each recording, each film,
often portray the field as a single unified each book, is a kind of prototype, involving
approach but it is more complicated than considerable amounts of investment of time
that. In other work, building on Vincent and resources, even at the cheaper, low-
Mosco’s important overview (Hesmondhalgh, budget end. However, reproduction costs
2007: pp. 33–37; Mosco, 1995: pp. 82–134), are usually very low. This high ratio of

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 553 552–569
554 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CULTURAL ANALYSIS

production to reproduction costs means that In contradistinction to some versions of


big hits are disproportionately profitable in critical political economy of culture, and
cultural production, which helps explain such to a great deal of left discourse about
phenomena as ‘the blockbuster syndrome’, media production, the cultural industries
where massive amounts of money are spent approach avoids portraying cultural producers
in order to generate a mega-hit which can as monolithically powerful actors. Instead,
subsidize a company’s (inevitable) misses. there is an emphasis on contradiction and
Another feature of many cultural industries complexity. This arguably makes it more
is the tendency for the cultural commodities applicable to interventions in public policy
they produce, not to be destroyed in use, but to than some other critical approaches. Unlike
act as what economists call ‘public goods’ – many of the economistic approaches that
goods where the act of consumption by one have come to dominate policy formation in
individual does not reduce the possibility recent years, however, the cultural industries
of consumption by others. This public good approach does not lose sight of issues of power
tendency creates particular problems for and inequality. I trace some of the ways in
cultural producers concerning how to control which the idea of the cultural industries has
the circulation of their goods. The recent been applied in the next section.
furore over digitalization of content, heard
most loudly in the debates over the sharing
of music files over the Internet (sometimes THE CULTURAL INDUSTRIES
known in the early 2000s as the ‘Napster’ IN POLICY
phenomenon after the most famous early file-
sharing site), is a manifestation of this feature The first impact of the cultural industries idea
of the cultural industries. in public policy was through the auspices
According to cultural industries ana- of UNESCO, which produced a substantial
lysts, capitalists seeking profits from culture volume on the cultural industries in 1982
respond in various ways to these various (UNESCO, 1982). Miège produced a report
problems of accumulation in the sector. To on ‘Problems which the development of
counteract these conditions, many cultural national and international cultural industries
industries build up a repertoire or list of presents for artistic and intellectual creation’
products, in the hope that the hits will cancel for that organization in 1983. Here the con-
out the inevitable failures. Because it is hard text was international inequality in cultural
for consumers to know what kinds of plea- resources, exacerbated by the formidable
sures will be available from cultural products investment in culture being undertaken by
in advance of experiencing them, cultural Western businesses (an issue to which we
industries use ‘formatting’ (Ryan, 1992) in shall return). The most lasting legacy of
order to identify products with particular stars, the term ‘cultural industries’ in government
or as particular genres, or as part of a serial. policy, however, has been in local rather than
In order to counteract the public good nature international cultural policy.
of most cultural products, cultural businesses In advanced industrial countries after
and governments try to impose artificial World War II, government cultural subsidy
scarcity, through the careful control of release tended to go mainly to the ‘classical’,
schedules, and via limitations on copying legitimated arts, the principal exceptions
(copyright law is crucial in this respect). In being public broadcasting and film. There
particular, the cultural industries approach were various struggles to include more groups
emphasized the importance of control of in the ambit of funding, in the interests of
circulation – the distribution and marketing democratization (see Looseley, 2004, on the
of products as opposed to their creation. This French version of this). In the UK, for exam-
was the crucial nexus of power in the cultural ple, funding for the ‘fine arts’ was gradually
industries. expanded to the arts, and then to include

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 554 552–569
CULTURAL AND CREATIVE INDUSTRIES 555

traditional crafts such as pottery and ‘folk’ and finance’ ought to be redirected towards
arts. In the 1970s, there were ‘community arts’ broadcasting, the ‘heartland of contemporary
movements, and in the 1980s an increasing cultural practice’, towards the development
emphasis on multiculturalism. As a result of libraries (the recipient of over 50 per cent
of such battles, the content of subsidized of all public expenditure on culture) and in
‘legitimated’ culture has shifted over time: for providing loans and services to small and
example, arts cinemas came to be subsidized medium-sized cultural businesses in London
alongside the opera and regional theatre for the marketing and dissemination of their
houses. One of the reasons that Jack Lang products (Garnham, 1990: p. 166).
became an internationally famous Minister There was a second major element to
of Culture in the 1980s and 1990s was that GLC cultural industries strategy, which saw
he attempted to extend French cultural policy public investment in this sector as a means to
funding to forms previously excluded, such as economic regeneration. As Garnham pointed
rock, hip hop and raï (Looseley, 2004: p. 19). out in a later retrospective (2001), this had
The seminal introduction of the concept of no necessary connection to the quite separate
the cultural industries to cultural policy in argument about shifting the focus of policy
Britain represented a more radical revision of from the artist to the audience. It was also less
cultural policy than this democratic spreading novel, in that the use of cultural initiatives
of arts funding. This took place at the left-wing to boost the image of cities was under way
Greater London Council (GLC) from 1983 elsewhere (Bianchini and Parkinson, 1993).
until the Council’s abolition by the British Such policies were often directed towards the
Conservative government in 1986. The GLC’s boosting of tourism and/or retail in an area,
cultural industries policy was directed against or towards making an area attractive as a
elitist and idealist notions of art but it also location for businesses, rather than towards
was a challenge to those activists and policy- the democratization of cultural provision. In
makers who had concentrated on expanding the late 1980s and 1990s such strategies
the field of arts subsidy to include new groups. boomed and spread across the world. Notable
Instead, it was argued by some at the GLC, cases included Glasgow’s remarkable success
cultural policy should take full account of in becoming European City of Culture for
the fact that most people’s cultural tastes and the year 1990. Expensive flagship projects
practices were shaped by commercial forms often based around adventurous architecture
of culture and by public service broadcasting. proliferated, the best-known of which was
The aim was not to celebrate commercial probably the Guggenheim Museum in Bilbao,
production but simply to recognize its cen- opened in 1997, which succeeded in making
trality in modern culture. One key position post-industrial Bilbao a tourist attraction.
paper (written by Nicholas Garnham, and Such projects have been controversial locally,
reprinted in Garnham, 1990) argued that, but voices of criticism are rarely heard
rather than on an artist-centred strategy internationally.
that subsidized ‘creators’, policy should be Because the GLC was abolished in 1986,
focused on distribution and exhibition – its cultural industry policies were never
the reaching of audiences. This argument implemented in London. Nevertheless, local
reflected the emphasis on the centrality of cultural policy under the banner of the cultural
circulation in the cultural industries tradition industries was to have a big impact over the
of political economy, and the importance following decade. In many cities, cultural
of thinking about the distinctive character- industries policies became bound up with
istics of primarily symbolic production and broader strategies to use culture for urban
consumption, as opposed to other forms regeneration. But the rise of local cultural
(see above). The practical implications of industries policy, initially in the form of
such thinking, according to Garnham’s paper, ‘cultural quarters’in post-industrial cities, was
were that ‘debates, organizational energy not entirely a result of the appeal of GLC’s

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 555 552–569
556 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CULTURAL ANALYSIS

pragmatic anti-idealist egalitarianism. In fact, written for the think tank Demos, for example,
in many cases, the idea of cultural industries Kate Oakley and Charles Leadbeater (a figure
policy chimed with a fast-growing desire in associated with the GLC, who by the late
the 1980s and 1990s to think about all areas 1990s was closely linked to the British ‘New
of public policy, including culture and media, Labour’ project personified and led by Tony
in terms of a return on public investment. The Blair) outlined their view that entrepreneurs in
key context here is the steady rise and general the cultural industries provided a new model
acceptance of neoliberalism. of work and a key basis for local economic
Neoliberalism is a word that is sometimes growth, in that their local, tacit know-how –
used too easily and too glibly. But it is still a ‘a style, a look, a sound’ – showed ‘how cities
useful term to describe an underlying rationale can negotiate a new accommodation with the
for government policy which proposes that global market’ (Leadbeater and Oakley, 1999:
‘human well-being can best be advanced p. 14). The view that independent cultural
by liberating individual entrepreneurial free- production might be connected to wider
doms and skills within an institutional frame- movements for progressive social change,
work characterized by strong private property implicit in at least some of the GLC work,
rights, free markets, and free trade’ (Harvey, was by now being steadily erased, in favour
2005: p. 2). Cultural industries policy was of a view much more compatible with
founded on a recognition, ultimately derived contemporary British neoliberalism.
from a properly sophisticated reading of A very important further connection was
Marx, of the ambivalence of markets. This with new developments in arts policy,
linked up with an increasing questioning, as whereby institutions increasingly sought to
a result of broader sociocultural changes, of legitimize their funding on the basis of its
the legitimacy of ‘high cultural’ forms. In contribution to a somewhat uncomfortable
this context, the use of money to promote and potentially contradictory mixture of
‘ordinary’ culture was seen as anti-elitist – economic and social goals. An influential
and this contributed to the popularity of though controversial report by economist
cultural industries policies with many left- John Myerscough (1988), for example, put the
wing councils in Europe. The problem was cultural industries together with the arts, and
that, by the 1990s, as neoliberalism emerged analysed how they contributed to job creation,
triumphant, recognition of the importance of tourism promotion, invisible earnings and
cultural markets could soon be turned, in urban regeneration (see Belfiore, 2002, for
practice, into an accommodation with the a survey of arts policy developments in this
market, as the critical elements in the original domain in the UK). Alongside such develop-
GLC vision were lost. The roots of such ments, many arts policy-makers also sought to
policies in a more hopeful early 1980s context, justify arts subsidy on the basis that the arts,
based on bottom-up, grassroots interventions, and the cultural industries increasingly linked
gave a democratizing sheen to policies with to them in policy discourse, could contribute
very different aims. to combating social exclusion – a new term
So it was that in the 1990s, the notion of which spread like wildfire through European
the cultural industries or the cultural sector social policy in the 1990s. Some analysts
became increasingly attached, in a new era see social exclusion as a term which allows
of local and regional development policy, to those who use it to avoid consideration of
the goals of regeneration and employment deep-seated structural inequalities, including
creation. It was the second element of GLC class (see, for example, Levitas, 1998). These
policy that was often emphasized, not the developments were to have an important
first, now bound up not only with culture-led effect at the national policy level, as we
urban regeneration strategies, but also with an shall see.
increasing emphasis on entrepreneurialism, in This is not to say that all such local
the private and public sectors. In a pamphlet cultural industries policies were ineffective,

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 556 552–569
CULTURAL AND CREATIVE INDUSTRIES 557

that they all represented an accommodation of miles from Sydney and other urban areas
with neoliberalism, or with new centrist further south. They acknowledge that the
forms of policy. In some cases, policy-makers effects of such an association on employment
with a genuine desire to promote new and and economic activity are very hard to ascer-
interesting forms of cultural activity within tain, because of the perennial data problems
an area, and to provide support for strug- in this area. But they say that the asso-
gling entrepreneurs and practitioners, could ciation’s campaigns (keeping venues open,
persuade local government to provide funding putting on events, getting better remuneration
by talking about the regenerative possibilities for musicians, publicizing activity through
of cultural industries development. In some awards, and so on) helped to encourage
cases (for example, in Sheffield, in the young aspiring creative workers to stay,
north of England) such policies were able and thereby encouraged a sense that there
to support local infrastructures, to the lasting might be an interesting and rewarding cultural
benefit of symbol creators who wanted to life in the region. In other words, funding
work in the city (see Frith, 1993). But the such grassroots cultural industries institutions
economic and social effectiveness of local may have other, less directly economic but
cultural policies oriented towards the cultural nevertheless positive benefits.
industries remains controversial. It surely
made sense to emphasize the importance
of the cultural industries to a news and THE RISE OF CREATIVITY: CITIES,
entertainment hub city such as London, and CLUSTERS AND UK NATIONAL POLICY
such a policy direction may have had some
coherence in some smaller but substantial By the mid-1990s in Europe, two related
cities where the cultural industries have some concepts had begun to grow out of cultural
growing presence, but in other places the quarter policies, each of which was the
idea that investment in the cultural industries subject of a great deal of policy interest:
might boost local wealth and employment has creative cities and creative clusters. These
proven more problematic. Mark Jayne (2004), terms represent an important shift in the
for example, has written about the difficulties policy vocabulary surrounding the cultural
a local council had in developing an effective industries. The former idea was strongly asso-
cultural industries development policy in ciated with the Comedia consultancy group.
Stoke-on-Trent, in the English Midlands, a In Comedia booklets and policy documents
city with an overwhelmingly working-class (for example, Landry, 2000), creativity was
population. The issue of class is significant presented as the key to urban regeneration
here. Much of the burgeoning policy discourse and the main reason given was that ‘the
(and associated academic literature) seems industries of the twenty-first century will
implicitly to portray working-class popula- depend increasingly on the generation of
tions as regressive, as holding back cities from knowledge through creativity and innovation
entering into competition with the thriving matched with rigorous systems of control’
metropolises of the West. This has led some (Landry and Bianchini, 1995: p. 12). In this
commentators to wonder about the dangers of new creativity discourse, television, software
foisting inappropriately metropolitan policies and theatre were examples of such industries,
on predominantly working-class or rural but so was dealing in stocks and shares – and
places. they all needed creative cities to help them
Nevertheless, cultural industries policies thrive. A number of examples of creativity
have made a contribution to people’s lives in local planning and policy were offered by
in ‘unlikely’ areas. Chris Gibson and Daniel Landry and Bianchini, including the culture-
Robinson (2004) have written about a small led urban regeneration strategies referred to
entertainment industry association on the far above. How these were to induce creativity
north coast of New South Wales, hundreds in a city’s inhabitants was not made clear.

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 557 552–569
558 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CULTURAL ANALYSIS

But by the turn of the century, the cultural of innovation and creativity, and finding a
industries were being thoroughly incorporated new use for old buildings and derelict sites.
into a more general notion of creativity as a Mommaas notes that while some clustering
boon to a city’s ills. strategies are limited to artistic-cultural activ-
The idea of creative clusters has been ities, most of them incorporate many other
even more significant in local policy than leisure and entertainment elements – bars,
that of creative cities. The concept of the health and fitness complexes and the like.
business cluster is derived from the work of Development strategies based on the cul-
US economist Michael Porter, which attempts tural industries have proliferated across the
to explain how nations and regions gain world in the late 1990s and early 2000s. It
competitive advantage over others. An impor- cannot be automatically assumed that such
tant element, which distinguishes it from strategies are entirely about a dubious form of
older theories, such as that of the nineteenth- gentrification. They need to be assessed case
century economist Alfred Marshall, of why by case and it remains important to distinguish
firms from the same industry tend to gather between top-down versions of such strategies,
in the same places, is its emphasis on the which come close to simply making cities
notions of innovative entrepreneurialism and more accommodating for business-people
competitiveness fetishisized in neo-liberal who want a funky lifestyle, and bottom-up
discourses of the ‘new economy’ (Martin approaches which take account of the needs
and Sunley, 2003). This has made ‘business of people across a range of social classes
clusters’ a hugely influential concept in and ethnic groups. Nevertheless, it seems to
national and regional government policy be the case that the democratizing intent in
across the world. Unsurprisingly perhaps, in the original GLC strategy by this stage of
the late 1990s, policy-makers concerned with cultural industries policy had become deeply
the development of the cultural industries submerged.
adapted the term by linking it to the rising Cultural policy analyst Justin O’Connor
cult of creativity in management, business has recently reflected on this latest stage in
and government and using the term ‘creative local cultural industries strategy (manifested
clusters’. in initiatives across much of the world). He
For Hans Mommaas (2004: p. 508) ‘cul- seeks to correct a number of misconceptions in
tural clustering strategies represent a next what he sees as an overly celebratory literature
stage in the on-going use of culture and the concerning the insertion of local – especially
arts as urban regeneration resources’. Once urban – sites of cultural production into the
all major cities had developed their festivals, global circulation of cultural products. One
major museums and theatre complexes in is the view that clusters of local cultural
the culture-led urban regeneration boom of producers derive their success from creativity
the 1990s, the action moved on to creating and other forms of local, tacit knowledge
milieux for cultural production. However, like (including the genius loci). According to such
‘business cluster’, the creative cluster is an views, which can be found in the work
idea built on a shaky conceptual foundation. of the Comedia consultancy and elsewhere,
Mommaas distinguishes between a number of cities and regions can gain competitive
discourses, which have tended to be merged advantage because such knowledge cannot
together in policy discussions of the benefits easily be codified and therefore transferred.
of creative clusters, and which in his view are In fact, says O’Connor, successful clusters
in danger of undermining and contradicting are increasingly predicated not so much on
each other. These include promoting cultural the much-vaunted ‘creativity’ but on access
diversity and democracy, place-marketing in to a range of formal knowledges, about
the interests of tourism and employment, global markets, about larger companies and
stimulating a more entrepreneurial approach about distribution networks. To miss this,
to the arts and culture, a general encouraging says O’Connor, is to miss the reality of local

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 558 552–569
CULTURAL AND CREATIVE INDUSTRIES 559

policy: few of the agencies set up to help (for example, DCMS 1998, 2001) included
nascent cultural industries have this kind of the industries labelled the ‘cultural industries’
knowledge (O’Connor, 2004: p. 139). But by the political-economy cultural industries
O’Connor is making a broader point too. The analysts (essentially, the media – see above)
emphasis on using ‘creativity’ and urbanity but also dance, visual arts and the more craft-
for the competitive advantage of cities risks based activities of jewellery-making, fashion
going beyond a reconciliation of economics and furniture design. This made it possible to
and culture to being an annexation of the latter link these subsidized sectors to the supposedly
by the former (O’Connor, 2004: p. 146). booming commercial creative industries of
music and broadcasting. It also, crucially,
included computer software, which made it
National creative industries policy
possible to present the creative industries
By the late 1990s, the term ‘creativity’ had sector as a much larger and more significant
spread to the national policy level in the part of the economy than would otherwise
UK. Creative industries is a concept that has have been possible.2
since been widely adopted in the spheres of According to Garnham, this broad defini-
cultural policy and higher education. Its first tion in turn had two valuable policy conse-
major policy use appears to have been by the quences for the interest groups involved. First,
British Labour government elected in 1997, it enabled software producers and the major
though there were important precedents in cultural-industry conglomerates to construct
other countries, notably the Australian Labor an alliance with smaller businesses and with
government’s Creative Nation initiative of cultural workers around a strengthening of
1994. In Britain at least, one basis for the intellectual property protection. Crucial here
adoption of the term ‘creative industries’ was the way that the defence of intellectual
was that it allowed cultural policy-makers property became associated with ‘the moral
(whether concerned with arts, crafts or film prestige of the “creative artist” ’ (Garnham,
production) to legitimize their concerns at 2005: p. 26). Second, it enabled the cultural
the national level. This was an attempt to sector to use arguments for the public support
repeat at the national level the strategy of of the training of creative workers originally
linking ‘the arts’ to the cultural industries, developed for the ICT industry. This argument
so that even these most refined of activities in turn had much wider implications in that it
could be made to seem part of economic pushed education policy much more strongly
development, the sine qua non of most in the direction of a discourse of skills, on the
government policy in the era of neoliberalism. basis that future national prosperity depended
However, national creative industries policy upon making up for a supposed lack of
goes further than this. creative, innovative workers. The result for
Nicholas Garnham (2001: p. 25; see also Garnham is that UK creative industries policy
Garnham, 2005) has identified two major is more than ever based on an ‘artist’-centred
claims implicitly made by the mobilization notion of subsidy, rather than an audience-
of the term ‘creative industries’ in the British oriented policy of infrastructural support – the
context: that the creative industries are the very opposite, in other words, of the original
key new growth sector of the economy, both GLC vision.
nationally and globally; and that they are The key point here is that while the terms
therefore the key source of future employment ‘cultural industries’ and ‘creative industries’
growth and export earnings. For Garnham, superficially share a rejection of forms of cul-
the use of the term ‘creative’ achieved a tural policy grounded on subsidy for the fine
number of goals with regard to these claims. arts, and a concern with the specific dynamics
In the first instance, it allowed a very broad of symbolic production and circulation, the
definition. Various documents issued by the terms – in the Northern European context at
UK Department of Culture, Media and Sport least – tend to denote very different modes

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 559 552–569
560 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CULTURAL ANALYSIS

of theoretical policy analysis. Those who that the Beijing Party Committee adopted
prefer the term ‘cultural industries’ tend to be the term ‘cultural and creative industries’ for
much more sober in their claims regarding its development strategy in December 2005.
the role of culture or creativity in modern Such a conjoined use is likely to become more
economies and societies, and, as we shall see, common in many non-European contexts.
considerably more sceptical about the benefits But for all these complexities, it remains the
of marketization in the domain of culture, than case that many non-European governments
what we might call the creativity or creative have looked to Northern European policies
industries theorists. for inspiration as they seek ways to expand
In the 2000s, policy using the terms their cultural or creative industries – and
cultural industries and creative industries that the terms cultural industries and creative
has spread across much of the world, both industries represent quite different lineages.
at the national and sub-national (local or
regional) levels. There has been a relentless
flow of mapping documents and development CREATIVITY AND CREATIVE
strategies. There is no space here to trace INDUSTRIES THEORY
in any detail the many and complex ways
in which the terms have been taken up In the next section, I will look at the
outside Northern Europe. Some governments work of cultural researchers who are broadly
have followed the ‘British model’ of creative advocates of the kinds of creative industries
industries in terms of definition and policy policy delineated above; I then proceed to
orientation. Some have preferred the term examine attempts to critique the idea of the
‘cultural industries’ even while pursuing creative industries.
policies more akin to what, based on the These policy developments have meant that
dominant Northern European uses, I am here in recent years there has been a rising tide
calling ‘creative industries policy’. Issues of of academic interest in creativity and the
translation and of local context mean that creative industries. ‘Creativity’ is an even
the terms have quite different connotations looser word than culture and there can be
from Europe. The People’s Republic of China little doubt that this has enabled a number
(PRC) provides one significant example. The of analysts to put forward the kinds of
16th Congress of the Chinese Communist claims summarized by Garnham, regarding
Party in 2002 declared the development the role of cultural production in modern
of cultural industries (wenhua chanye) as economies. Policy consultant and journalist
a key task in the tenth Five Year Plan. John Howkins, for example, claimed in
Jing Wang (2004: p. 16) explains that an influential and widely read book that
wenhua chanye has a very different set ‘the creative economy will be the dominant
of connotations than its English equivalent, economic form in the twenty-first century’
because chanye contains a double reference (Howkins, 2001: p. vii). Howkins sustained
to chanquan (property ownership) and shiye this claim by defining the creative economy
(public institutions). The nearest equivalent to and the creative industries as those involved
‘creative industries’(chuangyi gongye), Wang in intellectual property. This allowed him to
felt, lacked these connotations, and diverted include not only those industries based on
attention away from crucial issues about copyright, which is the basis of the cultural
stock-market flotation and privatization and industries as they are most usefully defined (as
towards a less immediately relevant agenda essentially the media industries – see above),
of small and medium-sized enterprises, and but also those industries that produce or deal in
artistic creativity (rather than innovation). In patent. This meant that massive sectors such as
policy discussions in China, the English term pharmaceuticals, electronics, engineering and
‘creative’ is often preferred. Nevertheless, chemicals could be added into ‘the creative
Desmond Hui (2006: pp. 317–319) reports economy’ mix. Even the impossibly nebulous

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 560 552–569
CULTURAL AND CREATIVE INDUSTRIES 561

categories of trademark and design industries and Stuart Cunningham have explained their
were incorporated. Howkins was right to adoption of ‘creative industries’ (Hartley and
stress the importance of intellectual property Cunningham, 2001) as a key term in cultural
in modern economies, across both symbolic policy – and indeed in cultural education.
and scientific domains, but he extrapolated First, they say, it offers an opportunity to
from this to make dubious claims about move beyond the elitist wastefulness of arts
a transition to a new economy based on subsidy. Second, it moves beyond limitations
creativity. in the concept of cultural industries which in
Perhaps the most ardent treatment of the their view (a mistaken one in my opinion) is
role of creativity in modern economies has a term associated with the old arts-oriented
come from the US academic and policy form of cultural policy. For them, by contrast,
consultant Richard Florida. Florida makes the term creative industries fits with the
the cheering assertion that while most tran- political, cultural and technological landscape
sition theories tend to see transformation of globalization, the new economy, and the
as something that is happening to people, information society. Echoing writers such as
in fact society is mostly changing because John Howkins, creativity and innovation are
we want it to, and the driving force of presented as the basis of the new economy.
these desired changes is ‘the rise of human But governments need to look beyond science
creativity as the key factor in our economy and engineering conceptions of innovation,
and society’ (Florida, 2002: p. 4). For Florida, say Hartley and Cunningham. Policy needs
the new centrality of creativity has led to a to combine the promotion of this growing
change in the class system itself, with the sector of local economies with the fostering
rise of ‘a new creative class’, comprising an of creative urban spaces. Education needs
astounding 30 per cent of all employed US to change too: arts and humanities faculties
citizens: a creative core of people in science should be reoriented towards training students
and engineering, architecture and design, in the production of content.
education, arts, music and entertainment; and Cunningham and Hartley were writing
then an outer group of creative professionals a manifesto for policy-makers and higher
in business and finance, law, health care and education managers. Terry Flew, also at QUT,
related fields. As will be clear from this, the has provided a fuller rationale for an emphasis
inflated claims about creativity again derive on creative industries in both cultural and
from lumping together a very diverse set educational policy (here I concentrate on one
of activities. But such claims clear the way piece – Flew, 2005). Flew questions, from a
for Florida to address himself to policy- perspective informed by Foucauldian govern-
makers. In a version of the Comedia argument mentality theory, the emphasis on citizenship
about creative cities, Florida says that creative amongst social democratic policy-makers and
people want to live in creative cities, and academic advocates of reform. For Flew,
if cities want to attract these often wealthy ‘there is a need for caution in too readily
and influential creative people to live, and invoking cultural citizenship as a progressive
to spend their hard and creatively earned cultural goal’ (Flew, 2005: p. 244) because
money on local taxes and local services, then citizenship conceptions underestimate the
governments will need to foster ‘a creative degree to which culture has been used by
community’ in their cities. states as part of top-down nationalist projects,
Florida is without doubt the most important and the degree to which rights have involved
academic popularizer and legitimator of exclusions as well as reciprocal obligations
the idea that creativity is central to new between state and subject. Flew asserts that
economies. A more substantial attempt to such policies – for example, in post-war
ground this idea has emerged from a group of France – have also tended to neglect the com-
researchers at Queensland University of Tech- mercial sector in favour of elitist arts subsidy.
nology in Brisbane, Australia. John Hartley What is more, globalization, the rise of new

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 561 552–569
562 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CULTURAL ANALYSIS

media technologies such as satellite and the may be unwise to opt too quickly in favour
Internet, and the increasing incorporation of of a strongly market-oriented system over a
culture into economic life mean a new set of ‘top-down nationalism’ which is portrayed in
challenges for policy institutions. In Flew’s monolithic terms, characteristic of much glob-
view, rather than protecting national and local alization theory, as a force for oppression and
content, the aim should be to promote the exclusion. Third, Flew shows the influence of
ability of a nation to create content, in a way post-structuralist cultural studies, by focusing
that avoids ‘top-down nationalism and pre- on questions of difference and identity, to the
ordained conceptions of cultural value’ (Flew, exclusion of systemic economic processes.
2005: p. 251). Rather than grounding cultural There is a lack of attention to the way capitalist
policy in an opposition to the market or in markets repeatedly (though not in any pre-
cultural protectionism, Flew offers the Open defined way) work with other processes to
Source software movement as an alternative produce inequalities of access and outcome –
paradigm, based on the decentralizing force in the domain of culture, as in many other
of the Internet and on new conceptions of aspects of society.
the public interest, where the state acts as
a guarantor of competition, innovation and
pluralism, rather than a buttress against the CRITIQUING CREATIVE INDUSTRIES
market, and the idea is to let a million POLICY AND THEORY
multicultural and globalized publics bloom,
rather than to advocate particular directions I have focused here on the work of a group
for cultural policy. of academic researchers based in Queensland
Such an account raises some difficult because they provide the most coherent
issues. First, Flew and other advocates of attempt to delineate what one might call a
new conceptions of the public interest place centrist or accommodationist position with
great faith in the democratizing impact of regard to government policy on the creative
the Internet; but there are good reasons to industries. What I mean by this is that they
wonder whether the Internet can validly be broadly accept the position underlying the
seen in this way: including, not least, marked most influential forms of creative industries
inequalities in access, both within individual policy: that the creative industries are a
nation-states and between nations and regions. key new growth sector of economies, both
Second, although the idea of a policy that nationally and globally; and that they are
would move beyond the dubious imposition therefore the key source of future employment
of cultural value is likely on its surface to growth and export earnings. The expansion
be attractive to anyone but the most ardent of local cultural markets is therefore seen
cultural conservative, the problem of aesthetic as the best way to combine both economic
value will not simply go away. If the role and cultural well-being. As I write, however,
of cultural policy (and arts and humanities there is an increasing interest in developing
education) is to act as an R&D wing of critiques of the notion of the creative
the creative industries – which is the QUT industries as it operates in contemporary
group’s explicit goal – then it may well be policy discourse. In this next section, I want
that it is the market’s (i.e. in this case, the briefly to consider some versions of such
cultural or creative industries) conceptions critique, in order to assess how effectively
of value which will prevail. Like those of they question developments in the role of
nation-states, these values are multiple and cultural production in modern societies. My
contradictory, and indeed this is something main concern here is theoretical – with
emphasized by cultural industries theory. But criticism focused on the underlying principles
in a context where massive corporations still and assumptions of policy. First, though, it
control the circulation and dissemination of must be recognized that theory is always, to
culture (even in the era of the Internet) we a greater or lesser degree, based on empirical

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 562 552–569
CULTURAL AND CREATIVE INDUSTRIES 563

assumptions, whether stated or not; and that been to focus on the question of creative or
therefore some of the empirical assumptions artistic labour, which Healy draws attention
underlying creative industries theory need to, above. There is certainly no space in
scrutinizing. the present context to address the detailed
Kieran Healy (2002) has identified a empirical and quantitative work that has been
number of questions that might be asked about done on these labour markets (see Menger,
the role of creativity in the new economy 1999, for a very useful survey) but Ruth
as identified by writers such as Howkins Towse (1992) has provided a neat summary
and Florida. In particular he separates out of the findings of a wide range of studies
four claims concerning why the relationships of artistic labour markets. These have the
between the so-called creative sector and the following features, says Towse. Artists tend
new economy might matter to policy-makers: to hold multiple jobs; there is a predominance
of self-employed or freelance workers, work
• Claim 1: The ‘creative sector’ will continue to grow,
is irregular, contracts are shorter-term, and
justifying more policy research in this area. This there is little job protection; career prospects
is the easiest claim to defend, says Healy, but it are uncertain; earnings are very unequal;
establishes little in itself. What kind of policies? artists are younger than other workers;
Can there be any shared policy agenda amongst and the workforce appears to be growing.
the very varied interests involved? By ‘artistic’, Towse means the subsidized
• Claim 2: The creative sector is a miner’s canary for arts sector, but these features would seem
the wider economy because of its uncertain labour also to apply very much to artistic (and
markets, flexible collaboration and project-based informational) labour in the cultural and
work. But, Healy asks, is the project work of a creative industries. If that is so, then policies
project-based stage actor really relevant to those
that argue for a radical expansion of these
of a project-based systems administrator? Is the
industries under present conditions, without
artistic labour force a good model given problems
of labour markets there? attention to the conditions of creative labour,
• Claim 3: Creativity in general is becoming risk fuelling labour markets marked by
increasingly important to competitiveness. This, irregular, insecure and unprotected work.
says Healy, is not established, and demand for This in turn suggests that cultural labour
different kinds of creative people will be very might indeed be one important way in which
unequal across different industries and sectors. creative industries policy (and theory) might
• Claim 4: The so-called ‘creative class’ is intensely be criticized.
interested in cultural goods of many kinds, so cities In what follows, I will focus on three
should invest in culture. As Healy says, this is ways in which labour has become a part
unlikely to be uniform.
of a critical analysis of cultural policy
under the sign of the creative industries:
Healy’s scrutiny of the empirical claims the idea of a ‘new international division of
underlying creative industries discourse cultural labour’; the focus on creative work in
is useful. However, such scrutiny leaves autonomist Marxism; and a more sociological
untouched a deeper set of questions approach that helps to show some of the
concerning the way in which cultural limitations of even the most sophisticated
production operates in modern economies, political economy critiques. My emphasis
and this involves the status of culture itself, is on the theoretical and political problems
in relation to society and economy. What plaguing these critiques. At the moment, it
does the boom in creativity and the creative seems to me, serious attention to cultural work
industries tell us about the relations between represents something of a gap in the analysis
culture, society and economy at the beginning of creative and cultural industries. Critiquing
of the twenty-first century? One avenue for some of the critiques of cultural work may
critiquing these developments (not the only help to construct a more secure foundation for
one, but there is limited space here) has both theory and policy.

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 563 552–569
564 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CULTURAL ANALYSIS

CREATIVE LABOUR AS THE BASIS FOR The implication is that state policies are failing
A CRITIQUE OF CREATIVE INDUSTRIES to set up their own dynamic bourgeoisies,
POLICY but instead remain ‘locked in a dependent
underdevelopment that is vulnerable to disin-
A new international division vestment’ (Miller et al., 2005: p. 140). Miller,
of cultural labour? Wang and Govil recognize that responses
from US-based cultural workers to the loss
In numerous publications since the early of income and benefits involved in such
1990s, the US-based academic Toby Miller, offshoring of audio-visual production can
sometimes with collaborators, has developed sometimes descend into a chauvinistic Yanqui
the idea of a new international division of cultural nationalism. But they argue that there AQ: Sould the
cultural labour, which he abbreviates to NICL. is some reason behind US cultural workers’ heighlighted
This concept is adapted from the Marxian idea problems: the threat to their livelihoods, the be Miler et al.?
of a New International Division of Labour loss of local US culture (as legitimate a
(or NIDL).3 This purported to analyse the concern as the arguments made in support of
emergence of a new capitalist world economy, national cinemas, say Miller et al., though this
involving massive movements of capital from may be arguable) and the massive control of
developed countries to low-cost production corporations over their destinies.
sites in developing countries, exploiting a Miller, Wang and Govil’s treatment helps
huge global reserve of labour. Such mobility expose ways in which policies aimed at
of capital clearly had implications not only for boosting national creative industries can
the power of labour, but also for the capacity affect workers elsewhere. It shows how
of national democratic governments to act in nationalism can feed exploitation, insecurity
the interests of its populations. Controversies and casualization. These seem to me to be
over the idea of the NIDL rest on the degree important issues for any analyst concerned
to which such movements of capital really with questions of equality and social justice
represent a new feature of contemporary with regard to culture. And yet somehow the
capitalism. But how does this idea get trans- concept of the NICL does not seem to add
lated into the cultural domain? In the latest much theoretical value to a consideration of
version of the NICL idea, which appears in cultural labour. What, for example, distin-
the book Global Hollywood 2 (Miller, Govil, guishes the division of cultural labour from
McMurria, Maxwell and Wang, 2005) there other divisions of labour? To what extent is
seem to be four main manifestations of the this ‘new’ division of labour really new? And
phenomenon: the purchase of, or partnership if it is really new enough to merit that epithet,
with, non-US firms by US corporations and what dynamics drove it? When and under
financial institutions; the use of cheaper sites what conditions did it emerge? The NICL
overseas for animation; the harmonization seems to work more as a rhetorical device
of copyright law and practice; and run- intended to draw attention to exploitation
away production – the practice of shooting and injustice, rather than as a theoretical
Hollywood films overseas. Miller and his co- concept addressing complex dynamics and
authors on the chapter on NICL (Wang and contradictions. While such rhetorical devices
Govil) concentrate overwhelmingly on the can be useful, for a theoretical understanding
latter, outlining the ways in which various of cultural work adequate for grounding
national governments seek to attract such critique of creative industries policy, we will
runaway productions (all the more so, under need to look elsewhere.
the creative industries policy that is now
spreading through various countries). They
Autonomist Marxism
do so not only for the local employment
that location shooting provides, but also for In recent years, an attractive option for many
the potential secondary effects of tourism. intellectuals seeking theoretically informed

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 564 552–569
CULTURAL AND CREATIVE INDUSTRIES 565

critique of developments in contemporary computer-driven forms of immaterial labour).


capitalism has been autonomist Marxism, Because wealth creation takes place through
most famously the work of Michael Hardt such cooperative interactivity, ‘immaterial
and Antonio Negri, in their books Empire labour thus seems to provide the potential
(2000) and Multitude (2004). These books for a kind of spontaneous and elementary
offer an ambitious and very sweeping account communism’ (p. 294).
of economic, political and social change. It is this combination of rampantly
This includes, in Empire, considerations of optimistic Marxism, combined with a post-
changes in work, including reflections on structuralist concern with questions of sub-
the concept of immaterial labour – ‘labor jectivity and affect, that has helped to make
that produces an immaterial good, such as Hardt and Negri’s work so popular amongst
a service, a cultural product, knowledge, contemporary left intellectuals. On the basis
or communication’ (Hardt and Negri, 2000: of their work alone, the notion of immaterial
p. 290) – drawing upon the earlier work of labour could not be the basis of a serious
Maurizio Lazzarato. For some analysts, the critique of the creative industries. But the
concept of immaterial labour, directed as it is autonomist Marxian tradition they have both
towards the production of culture, knowledge drawn upon and radically popularized does
and communication, offers promising terrain have the advantage of drawing attention to
for a critical analysis of forms of work some important ambivalences in the growth
associated with the cultural and creative of creative or cultural labour encouraged
industries. (or demanded) by creative industries policy.
For Hardt and Negri, the introduction of Hardt and Negri’s ambivalence seems too
the computer has radically transformed work. polarized, founded on an opposition between
Even where direct contact with computers is the potential for commonality in networked
not involved, they say, the manipulation of forms of communication, and the insecurity
symbols and information ‘along the model of of workers undertaking immaterial labour.
computer operation’ is extremely widespread. These ambivalences are explored tentatively
Workers used to act like machines, now but with more regard for the specifics of policy
they increasingly think like computers. They institutions, in an article by Brett Neilson
modify their operations through use, and and Ned Rossiter (2005) on the concepts
this continual interactivity characterizes a of precarity and precariousness. For Neilson
wide range of contemporary production. and Rossiter, immaterial labour (and variants
The computer and communication revolution upon it) contain ‘potentialities that spring
of production has transformed labouring from workers’ own refusal of labour and
practices in such a way that they all subjective demands for flexibility – demands
tend towards the model of information and that in many ways precipitate capital’s
communication technologies. This means a own accession to interminable restructur-
homogenization of labouring processes. In ing and rescaling’ (Neilson and Rossiter,
this respect, Hardt and Negri are pessimistic 2005: p. 1). The term they use for this
about the ‘informationalization’ of the econ- state is precarity, ‘an inelegant neologism
omy. But they also discern another face of coined by English speakers to translate the
immaterial labour, involving the affective French precarité’. The term refers to many
labour of human contact and interaction. different forms of ‘flexible exploitation’,
Here they seem to have in mind caring and including illegal, seasonal and temporary
health work, heavily gendered, and much employment; homeworking, subcontracting
analysed by feminists. Such affective labour, and freelancing; so-called self-employment.
they claim, produces social networks and But the sense of the term extends beyond
communities, and cooperation is immanent to work to encompass other aspects of life
such labouring activity (and also, it seems, in a including housing, debt and social relations.
typical moment of incoherence, to other more Importantly, precarity is not a term used

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 565 552–569
566 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CULTURAL ANALYSIS

exclusively by academics; it has been used antagonistic to incorporation as abstract


widely by social movements as the basis of labour (which, in Ryan’s Marxian framing,
events and campaigns directed against the is the capitalists’ prime concern because
insecurity and casualization characteristic of this determines exchange-value). Capitalists
modern forms of work – including the decline lengthen the working day or intensify the
of welfare provision. Neilson and Rossiter work process to achieve a relative increase
in effect accuse creative industries policy of in the unpaid component of abstract value
neglecting and effacing both sides of this (surplus value). Abstract and concrete labour
precarity. One side is the precarious and are therefore in contradiction. Technology
insecure conditions faced by most workers, generalizes the concrete labour in the work
and absent from government policy. The other process in many industries, but not in cultural
is the complexity and promiscuity of actual industries. For Ryan, therefore, the artist,
networks of cultural production, reduced in as historically and ideologically constituted,
‘mapping documents’ to value-chains and ‘represents a special case of concrete labour
clusters. which is ultimately irreducible to abstract
value’ (Ryan, 1992: p. 44). Art must always
appear as unique, and so ‘artistic workers …
A sociology of creative labour
cannot be made to appear in the labour process
Autonomist Marxism’s greatest weakness is as generalized, undifferentiated artists’ (Ryan,
that it lacks an empirical engagement with the 1992: p. 44). More than that, artistic labour
specifics of cultural production. It might be demands an even more identifiable specificity.
thought that sociologies of cultural production They must be engaged as ‘named, concrete
might fill this gap. The problem is that, while labour’.
there have been many studies of individual For Ryan, the consequence of this con-
industries, there have been very few sociologi- tradiction is a certain relative autonomy
cally informed attempts to understand cultural for creative workers, with stars getting
production as a whole (see Hesmondhalgh, considerable freedom. In his view, this also
2005, for a survey). The most in-depth study helps fuel the irrationality, or at least the
of work in the cultural industries (as opposed arationality, of the creative process. For
to studies of working in a particular industry, capitalists, artists represent an investment in
such as television) is provided by Bill Ryan, variable capital in a way that consistently
in his book Making Capital from Culture threatens to undermine profitability. This also
(1992). Ryan’s perspective here is strongly leads, according to Ryan, to contradictions
influenced by the cultural industries version in the cultural commodity itself, whereby
of political economy outlined earlier, but ‘commoditization of cultural objects erodes
he analyses organizational dynamics in far the qualities and properties which constitute
greater detail than writers such as Garnham them as cultural objects, as use-values, in
and Miège, using a Weberian framework. the first place’, because it undermines the
A Marxian influence is apparent in the way quest for originality and novelty that gives
that Ryan bases his account on a historical the art product its aura of uniqueness. For
understanding of the relations between artistic Ryan, capital’s response is to rationalize
creativity and capital. For Ryan, capital cannot cultural production, both at the creative stage
make the artist completely subservient to and the circulation stage. Indeed, most of
the drive for accumulation. Because art is his book is framed as an examination of
centred on the expressive individual artist, the extent to which capital has succeeded
artistic objects ‘must’ appear as the product in achieving such rationalization. This is
of recognizable persons; the concrete and achieved at the creative stage through ‘for-
named labour of the artist is paramount matting’, and at the circulation stage through
and must be preserved. Artists appear to the institutionalization of marketing within
capital as the antithesis of labour power, corporate production, in order to produce

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 566 552–569
CULTURAL AND CREATIVE INDUSTRIES 567

a more controllable sequence of stars and young fashion designers, and other empirical
styles. studies, McRobbie notes (in Foucauldian
Ryan’s account of methods of rational- vein) the way in which notions of passion for,
ization provides a helpful way to explain and pleasure in, work serve as disciplinary
certain recurring strategies of capitalists in devices, enabling very high levels of (self-)
the cultural sector, and he offers an impres- exploitation. She also notes the extremely low
sive examination of these strategies across levels of union organization in most cultural
different industries. However, Ryan’s strong industries.
emphasis on rationalization as a response
by capitalists to the irrationality produced
by the art/capital contradiction leads to CONCLUDING COMMENTS
some limitations in his approach. Relatively
autonomous work, generated by the art-capital Ross and McRobbie’s work represent impor-
contradiction, is implicitly portrayed as a tant openings, because they join theoretical
progressive force, and rationalization is seen sophistication with empirical sociological
as something imposed by capitalists upon analysis of the specific discourses of creativity
this freedom. But what if creative autonomy and self-realization in particular industries.
is itself a significant mechanism of power There is room, in my view, to combine
within certain forms of work – including their approaches with historical analysis of
much creative work in the cultural industries? changing discourses of creative labour, and
This would have significant implications with the sensitivity of the cultural industries
for considering the way creative industries approach to the specific conditions of cultural
policy seems to offer a certain freedom capitalism. Such a synthesis would allow for
and self-realization for workers, but in fact a critique of arguments for the expansion of
offers this freedom under certain power- creative industries, at the local, national and
laden conditions. And it is a question raised international levels. This is not the only pos-
not only by the cultural industries, but by sible route of critique. It might be allied, for
developments in a wide range of work in example, to criticisms of prevailing notions
contemporary capitalism. While relentless, of intellectual property at work in the cultural
physically exhausting and highly routinized industries (and there has been no space here
work remains a feature of a great deal of work, to explore such potential links). A coherent
an important and growing stratum of jobs and empirically informed critique of cultural
purports to offer what Andrew Ross (2003) work under contemporary capitalism might
has called a ‘humane workplace’ and self- help to prevent the danger in recent policy
realization through more autonomous forms developments – that the original visions of
of labour. Writing about work in the IT sector reform that motivated the cultural industries
(a form of work which, as we have seen, is idea might be permanently distorted and even
often unhelpfully blurred with artistic labour inverted. While creative industries policy
in the notion of the creative industries), Ross and theory share with cultural industries
claims that, in the eyes of a new generation of versions an emphasis on the specific dynamics
business analysts in the 1980s, Silicon Valley of making profit from the production and
‘appeared to promote a humane workplace dissemination of primarily symbolic goods,
not as a grudging concession to demoralized it tends to work with loose and sometimes
employees but as a valued asset to production’ dubiously broad definitions of ‘creativity’.
(Ross, 2003: p. 9). Angela McRobbie (2002) And, as I have explained in this chapter,
has addressed these dynamics specifically policy and theory using the term ‘creative
with regard to the British Labour Party’s dual industries’ tend to be based on arguments
endorsement both of the creative industries which all too often come close to endorsing
and of hard work as the basis of social inequality and exploitation associated with
well-being. Drawing upon her own work on contemporary neoliberalisms.

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 567 552–569
568 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CULTURAL ANALYSIS

NOTES Cultural Sector. London: Policy Studies Institute.


pp. 445–458.
1 Because this is intended as an overview of Garnham, N. (2005) ‘From cultural to creative industries:
the idea of the cultural industries, this chapter an analysis of the implications of the “creative
inevitably draws upon material published in the industries” approach to arts and media policy making
two editions of my book The Cultural Industries in the United Kingdom’, International Journal of
(Hesmondhalgh, 2002 and 2007). However, the
Cultural Policy, 11(1): 15–30.
argument has been substantially developed from that
material.
Gibson, C. and Robinson, D. (2004) ‘Creative networks
2 This of course raises the wider question of in regional Australia’, Media International Australia,
how to measure the changing role of culture, or 112: 83–100.
of the cultural industries, in modern economies (see Hardt, M. and Negri, A. (2000) Empire. Cambridge:
Hesmondhalgh, 2007: chapter 6). Harvard University Press.
3 By far the best-known formulation of this idea Hardt, M. and Negri, A. (2004) Multitude. Cambridge:
is The New International Division of Labour (Fröbel, Harvard University Press.
Heinrichs and Kreye, 1980). Hartley, J. and Cunningham, S. (2001) ‘Creative
industries: from Blue Poles to Fat Pipes’, in
Malcolm Gillies (ed.), The National Humanities and
REFERENCES Social Sciences Summit: Position Papers. Canberra:
Department of Education Science and Training.
Adorno, T. and Horkheimer, M. (1977/1944) ‘The Harvey, D. (2005) A Brief History of Neoliberalism.
culture industry: enlightenment as mass deception’, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
in J. Curran, M. Gurevitch and J. Wollacott (eds), Mass Healy, K. (2002) ‘What’s new for culture in the new
Communication and Society. London: Edward Arnold. economy?’, Journal of Arts Management, Law and
pp. 349–383. Society, 32(2): 86–103.
Belfiore, E. (2002) ‘Art as a means of alleviating Hesmondhalgh, D. (2002/2007) The Cultural Industries.
social exclusion. Does it really work? A critique 1st and 2nd edns. London and Thousand Oaks,
of instrumental cultural policies and social impact CA: Sage.
studies in the UK’, International Journal of Cultural Hesmondhalgh, D. (2005) ‘The production of media
Policy, 8(1): 91–106. entertainment’, in J. Curran and M. Gurevitch
Bianchini, F. and Parkinson, M. (eds) (1993) Cul- (eds), Mass Media and Society, 4th edn. London:
tural Policy and Urban Regeneration. Manchester: Hodder Arnold.
Manchester University Press. Howkins, J. (2001) The Creative Economy. London:
DCMS (1998) ‘Creative industries mapping document Allen Lane.
1998’. London: UK Department of Culture, Media and Hui, D. (2006) ‘From cultural to creative industries:
Sport. strategies for Chaoyang District, Beijing’, Interna-
DCMS (2001) ‘The creative industries mapping doc- tional Journal of Cultural Studies, 9(3): 317–331.
ument 2001’. London: UK Department of Culture, Jayne, M. (2004) ‘Culture that works? Creative industries
Media and Sport. development in a working-class city’, Capital and
Flew, T. (2005) ‘Sovereignty and software: rethinking Class, 84: 199–210.
cultural policy in a global creative economy’, Landry, C. (2000) The Creative City. London: Earthscan.
International Journal of Cultural Policy, 11(3): Landry, C. and Bianchini, F. (1995) The Creative City.
243–260. London: Demos.
Florida, R. (2002) The Rise of the Creative Class. Leadbeater, C. and Oakley, K. (1999) The Independents.
New York: Basic Books. London: Demos/ICA/The Smith Institute.
Frith, S. (1993) ‘Popular music and the local state’, Levitas, R. (1998) The Inclusive Society? Basingstoke:
in T. Bennett et al. (eds), Rock and Popular Music. Palgrave.
London: Routledge. pp. 14–24. Looseley, D. (2004) ‘The development of a social
Fröbel, F., Heinrichs, J. and Kreye, O. (1980) The exclusion agenda in French cultural policy’, Cultural
New International Division of Labour. Cambridge: Trends, 50: 15–26.
Cambridge University Press. Martin, R. and Sunley, P. (2003) ‘Deconstructing
Garnham, N. (1990) Capitalism and Communication. clusters: chaotic concept or policy panacea?’, Journal
London: Sage. of Economic Geography, 3(1): 5–35.
Garnham, N. (2001) ‘Afterword: the cultural commodity McRobbie, A. (2002) ‘From Holloway to Hollywood:
and cultural policy’, in S. Selwood (ed.), The UK happiness at work in the new cultural economy?’

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 568 552–569
CULTURAL AND CREATIVE INDUSTRIES 569

in P. du Gay and M. Pryke (eds), Cultural Economy. and unstable networks’, Fibreculture, 5. Retrieved
London and Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. pp. 97–114. 10 May 2006 from http://journal.fibreculture.org.
Menger, P-M. (1999) ‘Artistic labor markets and O’Connor, J. (2004) ‘ “A special kind of city knowl-
careers’, Annual Review of Sociology , 25: 541–574. edge”: innovative clusters, tacit knowledge and the
Miège, B. (1989) The Capitalization of Cultural “creative city”’, Media International Australia, 112:
Production. New York: International General. 131–149.
Miller, T., Govil, N., McMurria, J. Maxwell, R. and Ross, A. (2003) No-Collar: The Humane Workplace
Wang, T. (2005) Global Hollywood 2. London: British and its Hidden Costs. Philadelphia: Temple University
Film Institute. Press.
Mommaas, H. (2004) ‘Cultural clusters and the post- Ryan, B. (1992) Making Capital from Culture. Berlin and
industrial city: towards the remapping of urban New York: Walter de Gruyter.
cultural policy’, Urban Studies, 41: 507–532. Towse, R. (1992) ‘The labour market for artists’, Ricerche
Mosco, V. (1995) The Political Economy of Communica- Economiche, 46: 55–74.
tion. London and Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. UNESCO (1982) The Cultural Industries. Paris: UNESCO.
Myerscough, J. (1988) The Economic Importance of the Wang, J. (2004) ‘The global reach of a new
Arts in Britain. London: Policy Studies Institute. discourse: how far can “creative industries”
Neilson, B. and Rossiter, N. (2005) ‘From precarity travel?’, International Journal of Cultural Studies,
to precariousness and back again: labour, life 7(1): 9–19.

[15:57 10/12/2007 5038-Bennett-Ch26.tex] Paper: a4 Job No: 5038 Bennett: The Sage Handbook of Cultural Analysis Page: 569 552–569

Você também pode gostar