Você está na página 1de 4

Demand Cross Elasticities and ‘Offset Effects’

J Glazer, Boston University, Boston, MA, USA, and Tel Aviv University, Tel Aviv, Israel
TG McGuire, Harvard Medical School, Boston, MA, USA
r 2014 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

Glossary Sufficient statistic In welfare analysis, when a sufficient


Offset effects When use of one service ‘offsets’ or reduces statistic is available, no data are informative about a welfare
use of another. effect.

Introduction The article begins with a brief review of some of the em-
pirical literature on offset effects, and then considers the issue
The typical analysis of health insurance and service use con- from the standpoint of welfare economics and insurance
siders coverage for a single aggregate commodity, ‘health care.’ design.
It is natural to extend the analysis to more than one service,
raising a number of issues in health insurance design. Fun-
damentally, two covered services can be substitutes or com- Empirical Literature Cross Elasticities
plements. ‘Offset effects,’ a term common in the empirical
literature, refers to the substitute case, when use of one service Much of the empirical research on cross elasticities in health
‘offsets’ or reduces use of another. The main insight regarding care has focused on drugs. Ellison et al. (1997) studied
optimal insurance with multiple services is straightforward: cephalosporins, a class of anti-infectives, using IMS monthly
When one service substitutes for another covered service, the time series data from 1985 to 1991, and found significant
increase in demand from insurance generates an efficiency elasticities between some therapeutic substitutes. More re-
gain from the decreased use of the other covered service. The cently, Ridley (2009) investigated cross-price elasticities for
reason for this is that the other service is itself insured and antiulcer drugs and drugs to treat migraines using data for 3
therefore to a degree ‘overused.’ The under appreciated subtlety million people from a large pharmacy benefit manager (PBM)
in this result is the role of coverage for the ‘other’ service. in the early 2000s. He found large effects on demand when
Without coverage and overuse, there is no efficiency gain/loss drugs differed in the co-payment from other drugs in
with a change in demand for the other service. The role of their class.
coverage emerges in the analysis of multiple services, and has A particularly interesting case of a cross elasticity has
important implications for the way ‘offset effects’ should be emerged in statins, used to treat high cholesterol. In June
measured and interpreted. 2006, the second largest-selling statin, Zocor, became available
Concern about multiple services and substitutability and as generic simvastatin. Statin drugs had very high sales. In
complementarity in insurance design need only be concerned 2004, Zocor was the fifth largest selling drug worldwide in
with relationships with other covered services. Other services, terms of dollar sales, and another statin, Lipitor, was the
if these are not part of the insurance plan even if they are worldwide leader among all drugs from any class greater than
health care services, are irrelevant for questions of optimal $12 billion of sales annually. In response to the availability of
insurance. For example, suppose coverage for a certain pre- generic simvastatin, managed care plans moved Lipitor to
scription drug for pain offsets use of over-the-counter an- higher (less favorable) tiers (Aitken et al., 2008 p. W157). One
algesics. Because these are not insured, there is no inefficiency PBM moved Lipitor to tier 3 in January, 2006 in anticipation
associated with their use, and any ‘offset’ in the use of over- of generic simvastatin, and saw more than 40% of patients
the-counter drugs is irrelevant for insurance design. switch from Lipitor to a lower-tier statin (Cox et al., 2007).
Coverage for the ‘other good’ plays a role in the empirical Among those with co-payment differences of $21 or more,
literature studying cross effects in demand. A large literature in 80% switched.
health economics and health services research tests for ‘offset It is typical in this literature to measure the ‘offset effect’
effects.’ The most active area for current research is on the cross by the effect on total spending not just covered or plan
effect of coverage for prescription drugs. Drug coverage is spending on the ‘other service.’ For example, Shang and
relatively new and variable. Furthermore, effective drug treat- Goldman (2007) use Medicare Current Beneficiary Survey
ment for many, particularly chronic illnesses, might reason- (MCBS) data from 1992 to 2000 to show that extra spending,
ably be expected to prevent/offset the need for other forms measured by plan plus consumer medical costs, on drugs use
of care. induced by Medigap coverage, is more than offset by re-
A related question is insurance coverage for ‘prevention,’ ductions in total health care spending. Hsu et al. (2006)
health care that affects the probability of illness. The argument compared medical spending for Medicare beneficiaries with a
for coverage for preventive services is similar to the offset ar- cap on drug coverage to those without a cap at Kaiser Per-
gument, and rests on the presence of coverage of the service manente of Northern California before Medicare Part D.
for the illness that would be prevented. Drug spending was 28% less in the capped group but other

Encyclopedia of Health Economics, Volume 1 doi:10.1016/B978-0-12-375678-7.00803-8 155


156 Demand Cross Elasticities and ‘Offset Effects’

categories of expenditures were higher and total spending for for each unit of service i, then the individual demands service i
all care was not significantly different between the groups, to satisfy:
implying a near dollar-for-dollar offset in total costs. Gaynor
Bi ðx1 ,x2 Þ ¼ ci i ¼ 1,2 ½1
et al. (2007) studied the effect of increases in co-payments
charged for drugs among private employees on total (plan Let R denote the plan premium paid by the enrollee. As-
plus consumer) spending. Increases in nondrug spending, suming the plan makes zero profit, the premium is
largely in outpatient care, offset $0.35 of each dollar saved in
Rðc1 ,c2 Þ ¼ ð1  c1 Þx1 þ ð1  c2 Þx2 ½2
drug costs. An exception to the singular focus on total
spending is the paper by Chandra et al. (2010), finding that where (x1,x2) are given by eqn [1].
the savings in costs due to higher co-payments for drugs were The individual’s total utility from the plan is thus
partly offset by higher spending on hospital services among
U ðc1 ,c2 Þ ¼ Bðx1 ,x2 Þ2c1 x1 2c2 x2 2Rðc1 ,c2 Þ ½3a
retired state employees in California. They tracked offsets by
payer because a primary (Medicare) and secondary (em-
where (x1,x2) are from eqn [1] and R is from eqn [2].
ployer-provided supplemental) shared in offsets unequally.
Substituting for R to recognize that the individual pays for
Approximately 20% of the cost savings from higher cost
services by a combination of the cost sharing and the
sharing for physician services and drugs was ‘offset’ by higher
premium:
costs of hospitalization overall, with the offset concentrated
among those with a chronic illness. Interestingly, as the U ðc1 ,c2 Þ ¼ Bðx1 ,x2 Þ2x1 2x2 ½3b
authors point out, in the CalPERS case, this offset largely
takes the form of a negative fiscal externality from the Cal- Consider now what happens to utility (welfare) eqn [3b] if
PERS supplemental policy (which saves from the elevated co- the plan were to change the co-payment for service 2:
payments) to Medicare (which pays most of the costs of q Uðc1 ,c2 Þ q x1 q x2
hospitalization). ¼ ðB1  1Þ þ ðB2  1Þ
q c2 q c2 q c2
The implicit logic in offset papers is that if total medical
costs fall due to an increase in coverage, then the change in
q x1 q x2
¼ ðc1  1Þ þ ðc2  1Þ ½4
coverage is welfare improving (i.e., ‘pays for itself’). This article q c2 q c2
argues that change in total medical spending, meaning the
The second equality follows from eqn [1].
sum of plan and patient out-of-pocket spending, is not the
Suppose co-payment for service 2 is reduced. If
right measure of the economic value (or cost) of a change in
q x1 =q c2 40, there is an offset effect and consumption of x1
insurance coverage due to offset effects. Rather, changes in
falls with this change. What happens to welfare? Equation [4]
health plan costs alone measure the economic value of savings
tells us how to value the offset. Reversing the sign of eqn [4] to
due to reductions in the use of other services. Applying
get an expression in terms of plan shares, when co-payment
methods reviewed by Chetty (2009) and Glazer and McGuire
for service 2 goes up (down), utility of the individual goes up
(2012) showed that a ‘sufficient statistic’ for evaluating the
(down) if and only if eqn [5] holds:
welfare effect of change in coverage for one that is good is the 2 3
change in total plan-paid costs less the change in costs trans-
6 q x1 q x2 7
ferred to/from consumers. They derived an elasticity rule for 4ð1  c1 Þ þ ð1  c2 Þ 5o0 ½5
when the offset effects of an improvement in coverage in- q c2 q c2
Offset effect Own-price effect
creases welfare.
A simple argument shows why total costs are not the right The intuition for this result is the following: The second
welfare measure of an offset effect. Suppose the plan covers just term on the left-hand side of the inequality captures the
one service, ‘health care,’ and an increase in coverage of health inefficiency in consumption induced by the reduction in co-
care increases a consumer’s total expenditures on health care. payment for service 2. With health insurance, the marginal
The consumer budget constraint implies that spending on some benefit of health care is less than the marginal cost
other noncovered services has to fall. This ‘offset’ says nothing (B2 ¼ c2o1), and the extra consumption of x2 due to the
about efficiency because coverage expansions are always exactly reduction in co-pay creates additional welfare loss. In the
‘offset’ in this trivial sense. What if the other affected spending conventional analysis of optimal health insurance, this
were on another form of health care that was minimally cov- welfare loss is weighted against the risk spreading gain to
ered in the plan, say for 1% of costs with consumers paying find the optimal co-payment, c2. The first term on the left-
99%? Logically, token coverage cannot imply that the full hand side in eqn [5] is the offset effect due to the change in
spending change as an offset should be counted. consumption (in this case reduction) of x1. Just as with the
own-price effect, benefits and costs both matter in valuing
welfare of any offset effect. The 1ðq x1 =q c2 Þ part is the re-
A Model of Offsets in Health Insurance duction in total cost from the change in x1 and, because
B1 ¼ c1, the c1 ðq x1 =q c2 Þ part is the loss in benefits. Thus,
Suppose a health plan covers services 1 and 2. Quantity of the net welfare measure of offset effects is plan’s savings:
each received by a representative individual in the plan is x1 ð1  c1 Þq x1 =q c2 :
and x2 measured in dollars. Benefits to the individual are Changes in (consumer’s) welfare to changes in plan costs
B(x1,x2), where BiZ0, Biio0, i ¼ 1,2, with subscripts indicating can now be related. From eqn [2] it is known that when co-
partial derivatives. Letting ci denote the co-payment charged payment for service 2 changes, the change in the plan costs is
Demand Cross Elasticities and ‘Offset Effects’ 157

given by In eqn [9], e12 is the cross and e22 is the own-price elasticity
q Rðc1 ,c2 Þ q x1 q x2 with respect to c2. The RHS of eqn [9] is positive and equal to
¼ ð1  c1 Þ þ ð1  c2 Þ  x2 ½6 the ratio of plan paid costs for service 2 to service 1. The
q c2 q c2 q c2
following rule can now be stated: For a decrease in c2 to im-
Equation [4] for changes in welfare, and eqn [6] for prove welfare, the goods must be substitutes (e1240); and the
changes in plan costs, are the same except for the presence of ratio of the absolute values of the cross to the own-price
x2, the cost shifting effect of a change in c2, a transfer ultim- elasticity must exceed the ratio of the plan paid costs for the
ately paid by the consumer in any case. Using eqns [4] and [6] two services.
a rule for a welfare change, in terms of changes in plan-paid The offset rule for welfare is simple to apply. Suppose it is
costs, can be stated. known that the own-price elasticity of drugs is  1.0 and the
cross-price elasticity for hospital services is þ 0.2. If the
plan paid drug costs are less than 20% of the plan-paid hos-
Rule for Welfare Effects pital costs, an improvement in coverage for drugs improves
welfare.
The welfare effect of a change in coverage is equal to minus the Attention to plan rather than total cost can change the
change in plan costs net of the cost-shifting effect of the cov- tenor of the policy implications of offset effects, particularly
erage change. for drug coverage where plan shares are relatively small.
Proof. From eqns [4] and [6] the result is Turning to some results in significant recent offset papers il-
q Uðc1 ,c2 Þ q Rðc1 ,c2 Þ lustrates the quantitative importance of the plan-cost per-
¼   x2 ½7 spective. Comparing the change in total costs for drugs and
q c2 q c2
hospitals, Chandra et al. (2010, p. 208) found that a decrease
This rule for welfare effects constitutes, in Chetty’s (2009) in coverage for drugs reduced total drug costs by $23.06 per
term, a ‘sufficient statistic’ for welfare evaluation of health member per month, but increased total hospital costs by only
insurance changes. The measure, change in plan costs less cost $7.23 – the offset amounted to only a 1:3 ratio of hospital cost
shifting, is equal to the welfare change, and thus yields an ‘if increases to drug cost savings, and in the authors’ judgment
and only if rule’: Welfare goes up if and only if plan costs less was ‘unlikely to be enough’ to reverse the perceived value of
transfers go down. the co-payment increase. However, taking the plan rather than
The rule brought out in this article can be used to interpret total cost perspective it can be said that because drugs are
the existing logic of the offset literature which focuses on total covered at roughly 50% and hospital cost at 100%, the offset
costs, plan paid plus patient paid, and concludes that an im- ratio doubles, to approximately 2 to 3. It should be noted here
provement in coverage for good 2 is worthwhile if it ‘pays for that the California change studied in Chandra et al. (2010)
itself’ in savings on good 1. Consider a reduction in c2 that also involved increases to outpatient co-pays, which are ig-
decreases use of covered good x1 (an offset effect). Suppose the nored in this illustrative example. These increases also saved
improvement in coverage for x2 ‘pays for itself’ in the sense money, making the offset ratio 1:5. By ignoring this other
that the reduction in the total cost of x1 exceeds the increase in benefit change in this discussion, it is, in effect, assumed that it
plan costs for x2. This rule tells us that this condition is neither is the drug coverage change that causes the offset.
necessary nor sufficient for an increase in welfare. It is not
necessary because the cost-shifting effect of the change in c2 is
disregarded for welfare. It is not sufficient because it is not Final Comments
total costs that measure the value of the offset, but plan-paid
costs. Instead of looking for a coverage improvement to ‘pay In applied policy research, offset effects played an important
for itself,’ the following simple rule, expressed in terms of role in the discussion about the design of optimal health in-
demand elasticities for when an improvement in coverage surance for mental health treatment, and more recently they
improves welfare via an offset effect, is proposed. do so in the case of coverage for drugs. Most public and private
plans cover drugs, but the coverage is partial in the sense that a
drug formulary typically excludes many drugs, and for those
A Simple Rule for When Offsets Increase Welfare drugs that are covered, the percent paid by the plan is much
less than for other health care services. Interestingly, the co-
Welfare goes up with a decrease in c2 (improvement in cov- payment for generic drugs is often so high that it exceeds
erage) when the partial derivative in eqn [4] is negative, or the acquisition cost to the health plan. The ideas in this article
alternatively about valuing offset effects have the most current direct ap-
q x1 q x2 plication to the question of coverage for drugs. If health
ð1  c1 Þ 4  ð1  c2 Þ ½8 insurance markets worked perfectly, competition would maxi-
q c2 q c2
mize welfare of the representative consumer, implying the
Putting this in elasticity form and dividing through by – e22 efficiency issues discussed here would be taken care of in
(a positive number), the criterion for a welfare improvement competitive equilibrium. Health insurance markets are fraught
with a decrease in c2 becomes with sources of market failure, however, such as moral hazard,
adverse selection, imperfect competition, externalities due to
e12 ð1  c2 Þx2 the participation of multiple insurers, as well as concerns
 4 ½9
e22 ð1  c1 Þx1 about equity. In many cases there can be little assurance that
158 Demand Cross Elasticities and ‘Offset Effects’

market forces alone will lead to optimal coverage, leaving a Chandra, A., Gruber, J. and McKnight, R. (2010). Patient cost-sharing,
role for calculations of the type illustrated here. hospitalization offsets in the elderly. American Economic Review 100(1),
193–213.
The major limitation of this rule for offsets and model
Chetty, R. (2009). Sufficient statistics for welfare analysis: A bridge between
setup generally, stems from the assumption that quantity is structural and reduced-form methods. Annual Review of Economics 1, 451–487.
determined by the equality of marginal benefit to the con- Cox, E., Klukarni, A. and Henderson, R. (2007). Impact of patient and plan design
sumer/patient and patient co-payment. Although the standard factors on switching to preferred statin therapy. The Annals of Pharmacotherapy
demand model is widely applied in theoretical and empirical 41, 1946–1953.
Ellison, S., Cockburn, I., Grilichres, Z. and Hausman, J. (1997). Characteristics of
health care research, it is also seriously questioned as a basis demand for pharmaceutical products: An examination of four cephalosporins.
for describing the outcome of patient–provider interactions. RAND Journal of Economics 28(3), 426–446.
Effective physician agency on behalf of the patient would be Gaynor, M., Li, J. and Vogt, W. B. (2007). Substitution, spending offsets, and
consistent with this approach, but it is acknowledged that the prescription drug benefit design. Forum for Health Economics and Policy 10(2),
1–31.
marginal benefit–marginal cost equality is still a strong as-
Glazer, J. and McGuire, T. G. (2012). A welfare measure of ‘offset effects’ in health
sumption. Relatedly, health economists doubt whether con- insurance. Journal of Public Economics 96, 520–523.
sumer demand should be interpreted as marginal benefit Hsu, J., Price, M., Huang, J., et al. (2006). Unintended consequences of caps on
when assessing the efficiency of changing coverage. Per- Medicare drug benefits. New England Journal of Medicine 354(22), 2349–2359.
spectives from ‘value-based insurance design’ and behavioral Ridley, D. (2009). Payments, promotion and the purple pill. Fuqua School of
Business, Duke University, unpublished.
economics both question the conventional welfare framework Shang, B. and Goldman, D. P. (2007). Prescription drug coverage and elderly
for assessing the efficiency cost of added coverage for a service. medicare spending, NBER working paper 13358. Available at: http://
www.nber.org/papers/w13358 (accessed 26.07.13).

See also: Efficiency in Health Care, Concepts of. Evaluating


Efficiency of a Health Care System in the Developed World. Resource Further Reading
Allocation Funding Formulae, Efficiency of. Value-Based Insurance
Duggan, M. (2005). Do new prescriptions pay for themselves? The case of second-
Design generation antipsychotics. Journal of Health Economics 24(1), 1–31.
Gibson, T. B., Mark, T. L., Axelsen, K., et al. (2006). Impact of statin copayments
on adherence and medical care utilization and expenditures. American Journal of
Managed Care 12, SP11–SP19.
References Goldman, D. P., Joyce, G. F. and Karaca-Mandic, P. (2006). Varying pharmacy
benefits with clinical status: The case of cholesterol-lowering therapy. American
Aitken, M., Berndt, E. and Cutler, D. (2008). Prescription drug spending trends in Journal of Managed Care 12(1), 21–28.
the United States: Looking beyond the turning point. Health Affairs 28(1),
W151–W160.

Você também pode gostar