Você está na página 1de 168

Executive 1. Power sector 2. Wholesale 3. Distribution networks 4.

Conclusions and
Summary transition market design and distributed resources recommendations

VARIABLE RENEWABLE ENERGY


ADAPTING MARKET DESIGN
TO HIGH SHARES OF
© IRENA 2017

Unless otherwise stated, material in this publication may be freely used, shared, copied, reproduced, printed and/or
stored, provided that appropriate acknowledgement is given of IRENA as the source and copyright holder. Material
in this publication that is attributed to third parties may be subject to separate terms of use and restrictions, and
appropriate permissions from these third parties may need to be secured before any use of such material.

978-92-9260-025-9 (PDF)

Citation: IRENA (2017), Adapting market design to high shares of variable renewable energy.
International Renewable Energy Agency, Abu Dhabi

ABOUT IRENA
The International Renewable Energy Agency (IRENA) is an intergovernmental organisation that supports
countries in their transition to a sustainable energy future, and serves as the principal platform for
international co-operation, a centre of excellence, and a repository of policy, technology, resource and
financial knowledge on renewable energy. IRENA promotes the widespread adoption and sustainable
use of all forms of renewable energy, including bioenergy, geothermal, hydropower, ocean, solar and
wind energy, in the pursuit of sustainable development, energy access, energy security and low-carbon
economic growth and prosperity.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
This report has been directed by Salvatore Vinci and Rabia Ferroukhi (IRENA) and has been authored by: Ignacio
Pérez-Arriaga, Tomás Gómez, Carlos Batlle, Pablo Rodilla, Rafael Cossent, Ignacio Herrero, Inés Usera, Paolo
Mastropietro (Comillas Pontifical University), Salvatore Vinci (IRENA); with the contribution of: José Pablo Chaves,
Binod Prasad Koirala (Comillas Pontifical University); Federico Boschi; Bishal Parajuli (IRENA).

The report benefited from input and review of experts: Pedro Linares (Comillas Pontifical University); Matthew
Wittenstein (International Energy Agency); Marco Foresti (ENTSO-E); Christian Redl (Agora-Energiewende); Lori
Bird, Jenny Heeter (NREL); Luiz Augusto Barroso (Empresa de Pesquisa Energética); Ruud Kempener (European
Commission); Luca Lo Schiavo, Massimo Ricci (AEEGSI); Hannelore Rocchio; Henning Wuester, Sakari Oksanen, Paul
Komor, Alvaro Lopez-Peña, Divyam Nagpal, Michael Taylor, Emanuele Taibi (IRENA).

For further information: publications@irena.org.


This report is available for download from www.irena.org/publications

DISCLAIMER
This publication and the material herein are provided “as is”. All reasonable precautions have been taken by IRENA
to verify the reliability of the material in this publication. However, neither IRENA nor any of its officials, agents, data
or other third-party content providers provides a warranty of any kind, either expressed or implied, and they accept
no responsibility or liability for any consequence of use of the publication or material herein.

The information contained herein does not necessarily represent the views of the Members of IRENA. The mention of
specific companies or certain projects or products does not imply that they are endorsed or recommended by IRENA
in preference to others of a similar nature that are not mentioned. The designations employed and the presentation
of material herein do not imply the expression of any opinion on the part of IRENA concerning the legal status of any
region, country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of frontiers or boundaries.
F O R E WO R D

T
he world has embarked upon a major energy transition which is bringing
about profound changes in the ways electricity is produced, distributed, and
consumed.

Renewable energy is at the centre stage of this transition. Fuelled by decreasing


costs and improving technologies, renewable energy deployment has grown at
an unprecedented pace. Each year, renewable power capacity additions set a new
record, with over 160 GW added in 2016 alone.

Still, the energy transition needs to happen faster for the world to meet key
sustainable development and climate goals. The change will not happen merely
with adjustments to the existing energy system, but through a paradigm shift across
economies, societies and communities.

Accelerating this transition requires a rethinking of electricity markets in many Adnan Z. Amin
aspects, a key one being the adaptation of their design and operation to support Director-General
higher shares of variable renewables –solar and wind energy – as well as distributed International Renewable
power generation. Energy Agency
In this context, this report presents the latest knowledge on the different options
for the adaptation of liberalised electricity markets. Building on case studies
from advanced markets, it identifies policy and regulatory measures needed to
accommodate variable and decentralised renewables, while ensuring high standards
of efficiency, reliability and environmental stewardship.

The report highlights that regulations governing the electricity market must adapt
to rapidly evolving needs and conditions in a timely manner. Enhanced flexibility for
future power systems is an essential consideration. Electricity markets need to be
re-designed to integrate all available resources, reward flexibility, and promote long-
term investment. Modular, decentralised power generation requires new approaches
to network regulation, advanced grid management methods and innovative metering
technologies.

Power sector regulation and renewable energy policy must work in tandem. They
must reflect each country’s circumstances, ensuring reliable services at reasonable
prices while sharing system costs and benefits fairly and equitably.

“Adapting Market Design to High Shares of Variable Renewable Energy” offers


recommendations for the entire power supply chain, from wholesale markets and
system operations to distribution networks and end users. ADAPTING
MARKET DESIGN
I am confident that this report will prove useful, particularly as policy makers and TO HIGH SHARES OF
regulators strive to transform the world’s power systems to achieve a sustainable VARIABLE RENEWABLE
energy future for all. ENERGY
A Renewable Energy Roadmap
R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y M A R K E T A N A LY S I S : L AT I N A M E R I C A

TABLE OF CONTENTS

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10

01 POWER SECTOR TRANSITION. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

1.1 The energy transition and its implications for the power sector. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

1.2 Power sector organisation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

1.3 Renewable energy impact on the power sector operation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24


1.3.1 System impacts of variable renewable energy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25

1.3.2 Market impacts of variable renewable energy. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26

1.4 Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

02 WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32


2.1 Introduction. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
2.1.1 Electricity markets, products and time frames. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
2.1.2 Why rethink the market now. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35

2.2 Short-term markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38


2.2.1 Time frames of markets, dispatches and prices. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40
2.2.2 Locational granularity of prices and schedules. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
2.2.3 Bidding formats: fitting new necessities and resources. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52
2.2.4 Pricing and clearing rules. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58
2.2.5 Rethinking reserve requirements and procurement. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63

2.3 Balancing markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67


2.3.1 Balancing responsibility and imbalance settlement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68
2.3.2 Balancing products. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70
2.3.3 Reserve markets and pricing of the products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75

2.4 Long-term support mechanisms. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75


2.4.1 Generation adequacy mechanisms and RES integration. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77
2.4.2 RES promotion mechanisms and wholesale market integration. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83

2.5 Conclusions and recommendations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .89

03 DISTRIBUTION NET WORKS AND DISTRIBUTED ENERGY RESOURCES . . 90


3.1 Introduction. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91

3.2 Advanced solutions for distribution network planning and operation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93



3.2.1 Proactive grid connection approach and long-term network planning. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
3.2.2 From reinforcement-based solutions to an active network operation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98
3.2.3 Paving the way through demonstration and pilot projects. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100
3.2.4 Conclusions and recommendations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104

4
3.3 Advanced regulation to encourage innovation
and efficient distributed generation integration. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104

3.3.1 S
 hort-term measures to mitigate the impact of high levels
of distributed generation on distribution revenues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106
3.3.2 Guidelines for smarter distribution regulation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107
3.3.3 Conclusions and recommendations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111

3.4 Self-consumption: tariffs and metering. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 112



3.4.1. Net-metering policies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113
3.4.2 Self-consumption and the missing money problem. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115
3.4.3 Short term solutions to tackle the missing money problem. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117
3.4.4 Towards a new tariff design approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117
3.4.5 The importance of metering arrangements. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121
3.4.6 Additional policy considerations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121
3.4.7 Conclusions and recommendations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 122

3.5 Future role of distribution companies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 123


3.5.1 Moving from network managers to market facilitators and system operators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124
3.5.2 Advanced metering to enable demand response and competitive retail markets. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 128
3.5.3 Distributed storage and ownership models. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131
3.5.4 Business models for the deployment of electric vehicle charging infrastructure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 135
3.5.5 Conclusions and recommendations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 138

04 LESSONS LEARNT AND POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140


4.1 Wholesale market design . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141

4.1.1 Adapting short-term market design. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 142
4.1.2 Improving long-term signals without ruining short-term ones. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 144

4.2 Distribution networks and distributed energy resources. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 145


4.2.1 Adapting regulation under high shares of distributed generation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 145
4.2.2 Encouraging distribution companies to act as system operators. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 147
4.2.3 Enabling distribution companies to act as neutral market facilitators. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 148
4.2.4 Promoting sustainable development of self-consumption and demand response. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 149

REFERENCES. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154

A PPENDIX: EUPHEMIA,

THE PAN - EUROPEAN MARKET CLEARING ALGORITHM . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 164

5
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

LISTS OF FIGURES, TABLES AND BOXES

LIST OF FIGURES Figure 2.5 Example of schedule adjustments


in intraday market. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
Figure 1.1 Levelised cost of electricity Figure 2.6 Time frame of European intraday markets. . 45
for utility-scale power
(ranges and averages), 2010 and 2016 . . . . 20 Figure 2.7 Intraday trading arrangements
across Europe. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46
Figure 1.2 Energy installation costs and cycle life
of battery storage technologies, Figure 2.8 The time frame of US real-time markets. . . 48
2016 and 2030. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
Figure 2.9 Average German system imbalance
Figure 1.3 Solar PV installed capacity within for every minute of the day during
California Solar Incentive (CSI) program the year 2011. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
against the evolution of average
cost of solar PV capacity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 Figure 2.10 Approximation of the realized load
and forecast errors on intraday markets. . . 50
Figure 1.4 Traditional power sector organisation
with a vertically integrated utility in each Figure 2.11 Simulation of suitable zones for zonal
territorial franchise. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 pricing in Europe (maximum wind). . . . . . . . 51

Figure 1.5 Competition wholesale market Figure 2.12 Annual total of physical cross-border flows
and regulated distribution companies in the CWE region and at the German
acting also as retailers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 borders in 2016 (in TWh). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53

Figure 1.6 Fully liberalized power sector Figure 2.13 Monthly volumes of netted imbalances
with competition at wholesale for all IGCC members for the imbalance
and retail level with bilateral contracts. . . . . 24 netting process. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54

Figure 1.7 Weekly wind and solar production Figure 2.14 Evolution of the activation of the minimum
in Germany . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25 income condition and wind production. . . . 57

Figure 1.8 Hourly net load ramps for different Figure 2.15 Pricing and clearing in the presence
penetration levels of solar PV. . . . . . . . . . . . . 26 of lumpy bids . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61

Figure 1.9 Wind and solar PV forecasting Figure 2.16 Result with the ISO model approach. . . . . . . 61
for Belgium. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27 Figure 2.17 Result with the EU PX model approach. . . . . 61
Figure 1.10 Wind forecasting error evolution in Spain . . 28 Figure 2.18 Sample of TSO’s actions to ensure
Figure 1.11 Flexibility sources and the cost involved . . . 29 the availability of reserve resources. . . . . . . 64

Figure 1.12 System and thermal production cost Figure 2.19 Operating reserves demand curve. . . . . . . . . 65
for increasing solar penetration Figure 2.20 Price adder as a function of the energy
in a thermal-dominated system . . . . . . . . . . 30 price for different reserve levels. . . . . . . . . . 66
Figure 1.13 Electricity production and spot prices Figure 2.21 RES balancing responsibility. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70
November 2016 in Germany . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31
Figure 2.22 Standard characteristics
Figure 2.1 VRE generation and the need of balancing products. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71
for flexibility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35
Figure 2.23 Available ramping capacity with
Figure 2.2 European power systems with and without flexibility reserve products. . . . 72
(or in the process of implementing)
capacity mechanisms. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37 Figure 2.24 Conventional regulation signal (blue)
and the faster regulation D signal (yellow). . 73
Figure 2.3 Market clearing price and market clearing
volume setting in electricity auctions. . . . . . 38 Figure 2.25 Updated benefits factor curve to optimise
operations under all system conditions. . . . . 73
Figure 2.4 Short-term market time frames:
An overview . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41

6
L I S T S O F F I G U R E S , TA B L E S A N D B OX E S

Figure 2.26 Annual gross aggregated electricity Figure 3.15 Process for avoiding TFO congestion
production from gas-fired, solar and wind using flexibility in the distribution grid. . . . 128
electricity plants in the European Union. . . . 77
Figure 3.16 One-line diagram of PNM’s battery
Figure 2.27 Coincidence of solar energy with storage pilot project. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132
peak demand in Colorado. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79
Figure 3.17 Framework proposed by the Italian
Figure 2.28 Reference price settlement periods. . . . . . . 86 regulator to decide upon the role
of distribution companies
Figure 3.1 Effect of energy storage to mitigate in storage ownership . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 133
the impact of PV penetration
on distribution costs. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94 Figure 3.18 Network of Tesla Motor’s superchargers
across North America. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 136
Figure 3.2. Expected network investments in
Great Britain to accommodate Figure 3.19 Contractual relationship between
low-carbon technologies connected actors involved in electric mobility . . . . . . . 137
to the distribution network under
different planning scenarios (2012-50). . . . 94 Figure A.1 Linked block orders. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165

Figure 3.3 Examples of map-based information Figure A.2 Characteristics of pumped hydro
for potential DG connections methodologies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 166
in the United Kingdom. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97

Figure 3.4 DER integration map in California LIST OF TABLES


(Southern California Edison). . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97
Table 2.1 Bid sessions for intraday market in Italy. . . . 43
Figure 3.5 Impact of DG on distribution voltage
control strategies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99 Table 2.2 Typical multipart offer structure
in ISO markets. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
Figure 3.6 Distribution of budget per country
and smart grid application in Europe, Table 2.3 Energy-weighted average energy
considering only demonstration and price adder (and online reserve price). . . . . 66
deployment projects. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 101
Table 3.1 Overview of smart grid pilots in India. . . . . 103
Figure 3.7. Cumulative annual budget of smart
Table 3.2 General guidelines for a smarter
grid projects in Europe, 2002-14 . . . . . . . . . 102
distribution regulation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109
Figure 3.8 Categorisation of US smart grid
Table 3.3 Net-metering cap at the utility
demonstration projects by type . . . . . . . . . 103
level in California (March 2016). . . . . . . . . . . 117
Figure 3.9. Sample daily load profile for a plastic
Table 3.4 Major services that DER
manufacturing company with
may provide to DSOs and TSOs . . . . . . . . . . 126
self-consumption from PV. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113
Table 3.5 Current and future TSO-DSO interactions . 127
Figure 3.10 Net-metering policies across
the United States in July, 2016 . . . . . . . . . . . 114 Table 3.6 Smart metering cost-benefit analysis (CBA)
in Germany (left) and the United Kingdom
Figure 3.11 PV production in the European Union
(right). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 130
in 2014 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115
Table 3.7 Summarised benefit-cost analysis
Figure 3.12 Possible effects of traditional regulatory
of PNM’s battery storage pilot project . . . . 132
approach in the presence of high shares
of DER . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116 Table 3.8 Proposed storage targets for IOUs
in California (MW installed per year). . . . . . 134
Figure 3.13 Influence of pricing signals on PV and storage
investment decisions Table A.1 Bidding formats and description . . . . . . . . . 165
Figure 3.14 Treatment of prosumers’ excess energy
across the United States in July, 2016. . . . . 118

7
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

LIST OF BOXES Box 2.20 Cross-border participation in European


Capacity Remuneration Mechanisms. . . . . . . 82
Box 2.1 The Major Difference Between Box 3.1. Network investments and
US and EU Market Designs. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39 advanced solutions to integrate
distribution generation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94
Box 2.2 Short-term electricity market
timeline in Italy. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43 Box 3.2. Regulatory mechanisms to handle
a large number of DG connection
Box 2.3 Intraday markets and schedule
applications. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96
adjustments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
Box 3.3. Network information disclosure
Box 2.4 Intraday markets and forecast accuracy. . . 50
for new DG connections. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97
Box 2.5 Market integration
Box 3.4. The need for a more active network
in the European Union . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
management: voltage control with DG. . . . 99
Box 2.6 Bidding formats in the US ISO market:
Box 3.5. Non-firm distribution network
Multipart offers. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
access as a means to prevent
Box 2.7 Bidding formats network constraints . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100
in European power exchanges . . . . . . . . . . . . 56
Box 3.6: Digitalization and cooperation between
Box 2.8 Empirical evidence of the growing role energy and telecom regulators. . . . . . . . . . . 105
of complex conditions and block bids in EU
Box 3.7 Regulatory reforms to encourage the
power exchanges: the case of Spain. . . . . . . 57
adoption of innovative grid technologies and
Box 2.9 Illustrating the need for uplifts. . . . . . . . . . . . 59 solutions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107

Box 2.10 Uplifts: an increasingly relevant Box 3.8 Examples of self-consumption benefits
problem in some US systems . . . . . . . . . . . . 60 for commercial end users. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113

Box 2.11 Illustrating the difference between Box 3.9 Key terms related to self-consumption
the US and EU pricing and clearing. . . . . . . . 61 and net-metering. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114

Box 2.12 TSO’s actions to ensure the availability Box 3.10 Simulation of investment decisions
of reserve resources . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64 in PV and storage under different
pricing schemes. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118
Box 2.13 Techno-economic Analysis of the Impact
of Implementing the ORDC in Texas Box 3.11 Market-based earnings and new roles
(Backtesting for Years 2011 and 2012). . . . . 66 of utilities in New York . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125

Box 2.14 Utility solar PV plant’s ability Box 3.12. Balancing generation and demand with
to provide ancillary services to the grid. . . 68 distributed flexibility. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126

Box 2.15 Defining the characteristics of balancing Box 3.13. The benefit-cost analysis
products: The European approach. . . . . . . . . 71 of a grid-connected storage system. . . . . . 132

Box 2.16 Defining innovative products for batteries Box 3.14. Business models and drivers
in the United States. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73 for electric vehicle public charging
in the United States. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 136
Box 2.17 Wind penetration in Brazilian
long-term auctions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79 Box 3.15 Charging service model according
to the European Directive 2014/94/EU
Box 2.18 Renewable participation on Alternative Fuels Infrastructure. . . . . . . . 137
in PJM’s reliability pricing model. . . . . . . . . . 80
Box A.1 The complexity of bidding some
Box 2.19 Renewable participation in ISO resources with existing formats:
New England’s Forward Capacity Market. . . 81 the case of storage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 166

8
A B B R EA
VBI AT
B RI O
EVNISAT I O

ABBREVIATIONS

AEEGSI Autorità per l’Energia Elettrica ISO-NE Independent System Operator


il Gas e il Sistema Idrico of New England
AFID Alternative Fuels Infrastructure KWH Kilowatt hour
AMI Advanced metering infrastructure M2M Machine-to-machine
ANM Active network management MI Intra-day market (Italy)
BAU Business-as-usual MISO Midcontinent Independent System
ARRA American Recovery and Reinvest- Operator
ment Act MV Medium voltage
BF Benefit factor MWH Megawatt hour
BRP Balancing responsible party NEG Net excess generation
CAISO California Independent System NEM Net energy metering
Operator NYISO New York Independent System
CAPEX Capital expenditures Operator
CEER Council of European Energy Regu- OFGEM Office of Gas and Electricity Markets
lators OMS Outage management system
CPO Charging point operator OPEX Operational expenditures
CPUC California Public Utilities Commis- ORDC Operating reserves demand curve
sion PJM Pennsylvania Jersey Maryland Inter-
CRM Capacity remuneration mechanism connection
DER Distributed energy resources PLM Peak load management
DG Distributed generation PNM Public Service Company of New
DLMP Distribution locational marginal price Mexico
DSIRE® Database of State Incentives for PQM Power quality management
Renewables and Efficiency® PV Photovoltaic
DSO Distribution system operator PX Power exchange
EV Electric vehicle RES Renewable energy sources
EU European Union REV Reforming the energy vision
FACTS Flexible Alternating Current Trans- RIIO Revenues = Incentives + Innovation
mission System + Outputs
FIT Feed-in tariffs RPI Retail price Index
FRR Frequency restoration reserve RPM Reliability pricing model
GW Gigawatts TOTEX Total expenditure
ICT Information and communication TOU Time-of-use
technology TSO Transmission system operator
IEA International Energy Agency US United States
ISGAN International Smart Grid Action VIU Vertically integrated utility
Network
VRE Variable renewable energy
ISO Independent system operator
VOLL Value of lost load

9
EXECUTIVE
SUMMARY
E XECUTIVE SUMMARY

BACKGROUND AND KEY MESSAGES


The world is undergoing an accelerated energy •• Distributed energy resources improve the resil-
transition, one driven by environmental, techno- ience of the electricity system during extreme
logical, social, and economic drivers. The ways in weather events and unscheduled technical fail-
which electricity is produced, transported, and ures.
consumed are essential to this transformation, •• Distributed energy resources allow consumers
and will undergo profound changes over the next to take on a more active role within the power
several years. These changes include the pro- system.
gressive adoption of low-carbon technologies,
To realise the positive contributions of renew-
including through the increased deployment of
ables regulation and electricity market design
variable renewable energy the decentralisation of
must adapt to changing conditions. The share of
generation, driven by the growing availability and
variable renewable energy has grown substan-
reduced costs of distributed-energy resources;
tially in some countries and there is an ongoing
increases in regional inter-connection and mar-
process of rethinking the future design of elec-
ket integration; and consumer responsiveness
tricity markets to make them compatible with
enabled by information and communication tech-
ambitious renewable-energy targets.
nologies.
To support the ongoing discourse, this report
High shares of variable renewable energy have
is primarily targeted at stakeholders from lib-
been successfully integrated into the power
eralised electricity markets with large shares of
system in several advanced markets, at rates
variable renewable energy, and provides a set
well above 30% of the generation mix. Variable
of policy and regulatory recommendations to
renewable energy can contribute to its own inte-
facilitate continued deployment. The recommen-
gration in the system and bring multiple benefits:
dations address different activities in the power
•• Technological innovation allows variable re- supply chain from wholesale markets and sys-
newable energy technologies to provide ancil- tem operations to distribution networks and end
lary services, ultimately contributing to system users. Many different contexts and regulatory
flexibility and reliability. frameworks are considered, although examples
•• Distributed energy resources reduce energy are drawn mainly from North America and Eu-
losses, peak demand and the need for network rope. The recommendations are broadly appro-
reinforcements under certain conditions. priate for power systems with organisational
•• Variable renewables can contribute to meet models that are similar to the ones analysed here:
peak demand by providing capacity to the sys- liberalised electricity markets with high shares of
tem, essentially allowing them to participate in renewables.
capacity mechanisms.

11
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

ES
These recommendations are based on sound 1.REFORMING WHOLESALE ELECTRICITY
regulatory principles and reflect the complex MARKETS TO ENCOURAGE FLEXIBILITY
inter-relationships of activities and stakeholders
across the power sector. The overarching goal 1.1 Adapting short-term markets
is to assist policy makers and regulators to take The presence of high shares of variable renewable
timely action to facilitate the energy transition. energy increases the uncertainty in the prediction
of market conditions and network constraints.
The analysis is divided into two main sections. The
Consequently, the time and locational granularity
first part addresses the integration of variable re-
of market signals should be increased with rise in
newable generation within wholesale electricity
variable renewable energy levels. The design of
markets. It recommends reinforcing the design
short-term energy markets should be enhanced
of short-term markets (day-ahead and intra-day
and refined at all levels, including timelines, bid-
markets), balancing markets, and long-term in-
ding formats, clearing and pricing rules, and their
vestment signals. Adapting short-term markets
integration with reserves and regulation markets.
requires improving temporal and spatial granu-
Some recommended reforms include:
larity, increasing the details of bidding formats,
and strengthening the link between energy and •• Increase time granularity by making trading
reserve markets. Adapting balancing markets intervals shorter and closer to real time. As
involves redefining traded products, recognising generation variability increases, market sig-
the contribution of variable renewables to grid nals should be made more time-specific and
stability, and avoiding dual-imbalance pricing. gate-closure times reduced to reveal the flex-
Long-term mechanisms, which guide genera- ibility of resources that can respond quickly
tion expansion according to the strategic view to fast-changing conditions. This can be done
of government, should allow mature renewable through continuous trading, discrete intra-day
technologies to compete with other generation auctions or a combination of both.
technologies and to ensure that both renew- •• Increase locational granularity by using zonal
able-energy support and capacity mechanisms or nodal prices. The increased deployment of
are designed to minimise distortion in electricity variable renewable energy, particularly wind,
markets, while taking into account the environ- may result in a constrained transmission net-
mental externalities, and the need for further work. Markets must reflect such network con-
renewable energy development. straints. Zonal pricing is a simplified approach
to address this, but it comes at the expense of
The second part of this analysis addresses the
market efficiency, particularly in regional mar-
regulation of distribution networks and the design
kets. Zonal pricing works well when transmis-
of retail tariffs to allow for smarter distribution
sion congestions are structural and systematic,
systems and increasingly active network users. It
and when predefined price zones are easy to
recommends incentivising distribution companies
determine accurately. However, variable renew-
to adopt a more active role in network planning
able energy can alter power-flow patterns sig-
and operation, and implementation of smart grids.
nificantly, thus exacerbating the limitations of
The report also emphasises the importance of de-
zonal pricing. In this context, nodal pricing can
coupling distribution remuneration from the vol-
often provide better operation and investment
ume of energy distributed, and shifting the goal
signals but may be harder to implement.
of regulation solely from investment adequacy to
•• Reform wholesale-market bidding formats to
also include a broader set of performance indica-
incorporate increased detail in the representa-
tors. The report recommends promoting self-con-
tion of generation and demand characteristics.
sumption through cost-reflective retail tariffs and
With higher variability, and given the need to
supporting advanced metering technologies.
fully exploit flexibility from storage or demand
Distribution companies should adopt new roles as
response, it is important to rethink and reform
market facilitators and distribution system oper-
the bidding formats used by participants in en-
ators, interacting more closely with other agents
ergy markets to submit their bids. These need
such as suppliers, aggregators and transmission-
to go beyond simple price-quantity bids and
and independent-system operators.

12
E XECUTIVE SUMMARY

move toward advanced schemes that allow explored. When service providers with different
market participants to hedge against increas- response capabilities compete to provide the
ingly variable short-term market conditions same balancing product, performance-based
and to better represent the characteristics of remuneration can help avoid defining too many
demand response and storage. reserve products and markets, and can also re-
•• Adapt existing pricing and market clearing duce overall reserve requirements.
rules. Current pricing and clearing rules either •• Avoiding dual-imbalance pricing. Because du-
focus on minimising the cost of economic dis- al-imbalance pricing does not exactly reflect
patch at the expense of having uplift payments the costs of imbalance, it distorts real-time
outside the market, or on providing uniform price signals. Although portfolio aggregation
payments to all market agents at the expense can mitigate the deviation risks that renewable
of higher complexities. The right balance ought producers face when dual-imbalance pricing is
to be met according to the policy priorities in applied, the practice still provides a competi-
each context. tive advantage to larger companies over small
•• Strengthen the link between energy and re- providers and distributed energy resources.
serves markets. This imperative reflects an im- Where it is applied, responsibility for balancing
portant key fact: supplying one of them implies supply should be assigned to each generation
modifying the ability of power plants to pro- unit to prevent competitive disadvantages.
vide the other. Strengthening this link involves
co-optimising energy and reserve procurement 1.3. E
 ncouraging long-term investment
both in day-ahead and shorter-term energy Long-term support mechanisms, including ca-
markets. Where that is difficult, frequent mar- pacity or adequacy mechanisms and support
ket sessions for the procurement of reserves schemes for renewables, are widely used to guide
could be organised, aligned with the timelines generation investments according to country
of energy markets. Furthermore, system opera- policy priorities. When these policy interventions
tors should abandon inflexible reserve require- are deemed necessary, the following guidelines
ments and implement new solutions to procure should be followed: first, as far as technically
and price reserves according to the actual value possible, mature renewable technologies should
they provide to the system. compete with other generation technologies,
even in capacity markets. Second, both renew-
1.2. Adapting balancing markets able-energy support and capacity mechanisms
Redesigning of balancing markets is essen- should be designed to minimise distortions of
tial for the effective and efficient integration electricity markets.
of variable renewable energy. Existing rules
•• Renewables should be allowed to participate
should be reviewed to ensure that they reward
in generation-adequacy mechanisms. Renewa-
flexibility and to facilitate the effective use of
ble generation can be a valuable contributor to
all resources.
system adequacy, especially in power systems
•• Redefining balancing products. To the extent with a high share of conventional (i.e. reser-
possible, balancing energy should be procured voir-based) hydropower. Therefore, regulations
from the most economic resources available in should avoid introducing systematic technol-
real time, even if those resources do not acquire ogy-specific market-entry barriers, and allow
longer-term commitments in day-ahead or oth- renewable technologies, including variable re-
er reserve markets. Furthermore, upwards and newables, to participate in generation-adequa-
downwards reserves should be two distinct cy mechanisms on a level playing field, where
products. and when it is technically possible.
•• Facilitating variable renewable energy contri- •• Capacity mechanisms do not necessarily sub-
bution to grid stability. To efficiently exploit all stitute for support mechanisms. Long-term
available flexibilities, including those offered by support mechanisms should be designed in
renewables, new reserve products should be a coherent way to ensure that the incentives

13
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

ES
provided through renewable-energy support A first-come-first-served approach can mean
schemes account for possible remuneration higher connection costs for later applicants due
earned in the capacity market (as well as in to reinforcement requirements. It also results in
other markets). inefficient grid development due to economies
•• Economic support for renewables should be of scale. Therefore, co-ordinated approaches
market compatible. Where policy makers con- should be explored such as working in batches
sider offering economic support for renewable per network area.
technologies, this should be done in a way that •• Disclosure of grid condition information. Infor-
is compatible with markets. Several designs for mation disclosure obligations should be levied
support schemes are available, all of them offer- on distribution companies such that new DG
ing advantages and disadvantages. A balance units have information on the condition of the
must be found between optimal investment in- grid for a point of connection. Publishing the
centives and market compatibility, determined available generation-hosting capacity allows
according to policy priorities. Mixed approach- DG promoters to estimate whether their appli-
es may be explored to achieve a compromise cation will be successful and determine which
solution. location will result in lower connection charges.
Ultimately, this facilitates the integration of DG.
•• Remunerate distribution companies based on
2. FOSTERING SMARTER DISTRI- their active grid management. Large penetra-
BUTION SYSTEMS AND MORE tions of DG introduce complexities in distribu-
ACTIVE NETWORK USERS
tion planning since the location of DG units can
2.1. Adapting distribution systems be highly uncertain. Integrating DG efficiently
requires active network management as an al-
The efficient deployment of high levels of dis-
ternative to conventional grid reinforcements,
tributed energy resources, including distributed
such as solving network constraints in real time,
generation (DG), demand side management
or close to it. Regulation should promote this
and small-scale storage, requires innovative ap-
transformation. One important way to do that
proaches to planning and operating distribution
is to require utilities to submit detailed business
networks. Conventional grid access and connec-
plans based on cost-benefit methodologies as
tion rules and practices should be adapted ac-
part of the remuneration process.
cordingly and smart-grid technologies deployed.
•• Enable advanced forms of contracting be-
•• Rethinking planning for DG. Grid connection tween distribution companies, generators
has traditionally followed a “fit-and-forget” and consumers. Active network management
approach, i.e. reinforcing the grid as much as requires the development of smarter grids as
necessary to prevent any operational problems. well as closer interaction between all relevant
This is a safe and robust strategy and requires actors. The latter can be achieved through flex-
very low levels of network monitoring. But as ible connection contracts that limit curtailment
DG penetration levels increase such an ap- of generation or demand in exchange for some
proach can be costly, especially in areas with form of compensation or under specific condi-
high concentrations of DG, and can cause long tions. As the presence of DER grows, more ad-
lead times for connecting new DG sources. vanced forms of contracting flexibility services,
Therefore, regulators should gradually abandon such as bilateral agreements or market-based
the “fit-and-forget” approach as DG penetra- approaches, could be implemented.
tion levels grow, and rethink network planning •• Promote smart grids. Technology risks, and the
and grid connection. absence of economic incentives, prevent the
•• Co-ordinated approach to grid connection. development of smarter distribution grids. Pol-
Grid-connection application processes should icy and regulation should promote and support
be reviewed to speed up DG connection and innovation, implementation of pilot projects,
to allocate grid capacity more efficiently. the exchange of lessons learned, and the shar-

14
E XECUTIVE SUMMARY

ing of best practices. The creation of public-pri- Rethinking the remuneration of distribution
vate collaborative networks and the definition companies. As the penetration levels of distribut-
of knowledge sharing and information disclo- ed energy resources increases, greater changes
sure obligations can facilitate information ex- to current regulatory approaches are required.
change. The regulation focus should shift from short-term
cost reductions to the promotion of long-term
2.2. P
 romoting long-term efficiency efficiency. Distribution companies should also be
Distribution regulation has conventionally focused encouraged to implement innovative grid plan-
on promoting adequate investment levels and ning and operation solutions (i.e. smarter distri-
short-term efficiency gains, while controlling the bution grids). This involves:
quality of service. This approach works well with
•• The focus of regulation should shift from
stable and predictable grid technologies and net-
ensuring that companies invest sufficient-
work users. However, conventional remuneration
ly in networks to assessing grid operators
formulas and cost-assessment methodologies
based on their performance, as measured
are less optimal as the presence of distributed
by an extended set of indicators. Those in-
generation increases. With moderate distributed
dicators could include customer satisfac-
energy resource penetration levels, the poten-
tion, grid-connection lead times, the carbon
tially negative effects of distributed generation
footprint or available distributed generation
can be mitigated with a few regulatory tweaks.
hosting capacity. When these indicators can
Nevertheless, efficiently integrating high shares
be objectively measured and controlled by
of distributed energy resources requires a major
the distribution companies, incentive (and
regulatory overhaul.
penalty) mechanisms can be implemented.
Decoupling distribution volumes from energy •• The required novel methods of managing the
volumes. Cost-assessment methods generally network reduce the need for investment in dis-
applied to determine allowed revenues of dis- tribution assets but increase operational ex-
tribution companies are usually unable to accu- penditures. Traditional regulatory approaches
rately quantify the impact of distributed energy discourage novel methods if distribution com-
resources on network costs. To compound this panies are remunerated mostly based on their
situation, distribution remuneration usually capital investment. Incentive systems should
depends on the volume of energy distribut- reward both operational and capital expendi-
ed, which DG (and some forms of demand side tures of distribution companies.
management) dminishes. As a result, distributed •• Regulatory benchmarking, a method of de-
generation, self-consumption or energy-efficient termining remuneration for distribution com-
measures may translate into a reduction in rev- panies, usually relies on past information. It
enues without a corresponding drop in costs. implicitly assumes that future developments
To mitigate such a negative impact, distribution will follow a similar trend. This assumption is
revenues should be independent of the volume questionable in a context requiring innova-
of energy distributed. This decoupling of revenue tion. Hence, cost-assessment methodologies
essentially consists of adjusting network tariffs should increasingly rely on forecasted data
ex post so that distribution companies recoup ex- and well-justified investment plans submit-
actly the allowed revenues. Moreover, if cost-as- ted by the regulated companies.
sessment tools are unable to capture the impact •• Promoting efficient investment in distribution
of DG on distribution costs, economic compensa- networks requires adopting a long-term per-
tion on top of conventional revenue allowances spective given the long life of the assets and
may be necessary to account for it. the time required before innovation yields
benefits. Regulators should progressively ex-
tend the length of the regulatory period to
incentivise distribution companies to pursue

15
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

ES
long-term efficiency. Remuneration formu- of self-consumption and to stimulate end users’
las should be more flexible to accommodate demand response, including distributed storage.
possible uncertainties in such a dynamic en- Economies of scale and standardisation are im-
vironment. This may include the introduction portant when deploying advanced meters.
of profit-sharing schemes and automatic-ad- •• The changes that advanced power systems are
justment factors. experiencing are strictly interlinked with the
power system digitalization. The evolving role
2.3. Improving tariffs and metering of information and communication technolo-
Self-consumption and the adoption of distributed gies for the efficient management of the power
storage behind the meter can yield benefits for system calls therefore for a close cooperation
both end-users and the power system as a whole. between electricity and telecommunication
Therefore, regulation should actively promote regulators.
self-consumption by adopting a cost-reflective
design for retail tariffs and supporting the roll out 2.4. Encouraging the new roles
of advanced metering technologies. of distribution companies
As the energy transition evolves, a growing share
•• High levels of self-consumption may negative-
of the resources needed to ensure secure and
ly impact the financial viability of distribution
flexible system operations will be connected at
utilities and the recovery of fixed power-system
the distribution level. In this new environment,
costs. Such issues become more prevalent in
distribution companies must bridge the gap be-
markets with high shares of renewable sources
tween flexibility providers (i.e., distributed gen-
supported by net-metering policies since they
erators, responsive demand and aggregators),
implicitly value the energy injected into the
markets and transmission/independent system
grid at the retail electricity price. To keep up
operators. To do this, they should adapt their
with these developments, regulations in many
planning and operational practices accordingly
systems have limited individual or aggregate
and play new roles as market facilitators and dis-
installed capacity, reduced the period of time
tribution system operators.
over which energy injections can offset energy
withdrawals, and changed the structure of retail •• Regulation should allow distributed energy re-
tariffs and compensation rules. However, these sources to participate in upstream energy and
do not provide a real long-term solution for juris- ancillary services, particularly when these re-
dictions with high penetration of active agents. sources become widespread. Distribution com-
•• The sustainable development of high levels of panies should facilitate this participation and
on-site generation in mature liberalised markets carry out activities such as ex ante technical
entails adoption of self-consumption schemes validation, to ensure that no constraints arise in
with hourly netting intervals, or even shorter. In the distribution grid, and ex post verification of
addition, retail tariffs should be cost reflective. the provision of the services.
They should be based on the value of electricity •• To facilitate well-functioning retail markets and
at each time and location, the individual contri- the participation of distributed energy resourc-
bution of the network users to network costs, es in wholesale markets, it is critical that mar-
and a charge to recover other regulated costs ket agents have transparent and non-discrim-
so that the economic signals sent by energy inatory access to metering data. This might
and network charges are not distorted. be seen as a conventional task of distribution
•• Advanced-metering infrastructure should be companies, but concerns arise when a metering
installed so that adequate locational and time data manager, traditionally a local distribution
granularity in the tariffs can be communicated company, is also a market participant. In this
to end consumers. Electronic meters capable context, alternative models for data manage-
of recording bidirectional energy flows every ment could be explored, such as creating a new
few minutes are needed for the development regulated entity responsible for data manage-

16
E XECUTIVE SUMMARY

ment (central hub) or opting for a decentralised charging points as part of the regulated asset
approach. There is no consensus on the most base may imply that rate payers would be sub-
appropriate model, but regulations must al- sidising EV users. To avoid such problems, other
ways ensure non-discriminatory access to data policy alternatives might be adopted to provide
and protect consumers’ privacy, particularly the initial policy push.
after the deployment of advanced metering. •• Distributed storage will be another game
•• Distribution companies should make use of dis- changer in the power sector, also for its po-
tributed energy resource flexibilities by active- tential to supply grid-support services. For
ly integrating with the resources connected to this reason, distribution companies may seek
their grids. Ad hoc regulatory mechanisms such to own and operate storage devices. However,
as non-firm connection agreements, bilateral unbundling provisions could rule this possibility
agreements or local markets may be necessary. out since storage operators may wish to pro-
Regulators should clearly define the respon- vide other services under competition to obtain
sibilities of distribution companies, especially a positive business case. Thus, exemptions on
where a distribution company belongs to a ver- the unbundling obligations may be considered
tically-integrated company in a context of retail in some cases. In others, distribution compa-
competition. nies may be entitled to contract services with
storage operators through auctioning.
2.5. Facilitating the development
of infrastructure for storage
and electric vehicles
The development of electric mobility requires
careful regulation of the contractual relationship
between the various actors involved: electrici-
ty distribution operators, electricity suppliers,
charging point operators, mobility service pro-
viders, and electric vehicle (EV) drivers.

Distribution companies will play a key role in the


deployment and operation of new grid-edge in-
frastructure such as public EV charging stations,
or distributed storage. The major regulatory
question is whether to consider them part of
the business model of distribution companies or
open them to competition. The former can collide
with unbundling rules and lead to a suboptimal
utilisation of these technologies, while the latter
may make it harder for distribution companies to
benefit from their potential contribution to grid
planning and operation.

•• Market forces alone may not be able to foster


the development of public charging infrastruc-
ture. Policy makers may have to kick-start the
infrastructure development, for example by
giving distribution companies responsibilities.
However, this may be challenging. On the one
hand, unbundling rules may prevent distribu-
tion companies from selling electricity to elec-
tric-vehicle users; on the other hand, treating EV

17
POWER
SECTOR
TRANSITION
P OW E R S E C TO R T R A N S I T I O N

1.1 THE ENERGY TRANSITION AND and the building and industry sectors must use
ITS IMPLICATIONS FOR THE POWER more electricity in their heating and cooling pro-
SECTOR cesses.

The global energy transition is underway, driv- The increased electrification of end energy uses
en by ambitions to improve energy security, ad- will take place in the midst of several other ma-
dress environmental impacts, and achieve uni- jor trends that are also shaping the future of the
versal energy access. The transition will involve power sector, including: 1) the integration of pow-
a fundamental rethinking of the way energy is er systems into larger entities at regional or su-
produced, distributed and consumed which will pranational levels, seeking more efficiency and
bring changes to the way societies operate and a reliability; 2) the increased interplay between
wide range economy-wide benefits. The political the power sector and adjacent ones, such as gas,
commitment to the energy transition is reflected and information and communication technology;
in the adoption of the Sustainable Development 3) the spectacular cost reduction and technology
Goals, and the ratification of the Paris Agreement. improvement in promising technologies, which
could become disruptive, especially electricity
The adoption of renewable energy technolo-
storage; and 4) the increasing presence of dis-
gies is a key pillar of the energy transition. Over
tributed energy resources (DER), which include
the past decade, as the technologies have ma-
distributed generation, demand response, dis-
tured and costs decreased (Figure 1.1), their de-
tributed storage and other devices.
ployment has grown at a tremendous pace in the
power sector. In fact, for the past five years, re- Energy storage is viewed to be the next game
newables capacity additions have exceeded ad- changer in the power sector. IRENA forecasts
ditions of conventional power capacity. Looking show that the cost of energy services from bat-
forward, mainly because of the potential of so- tery electricity storage will continue to decline
lar and wind technologies, the power sector will due to reductions in the installed costs and im-
play an important role in the energy transition. provements in battery technology performance
To achieve climate targets, part of the transpor- (Figure 1.2).
tation sector has to switch to electrical mobility,

19
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

1
Figure 1.1 Levelised cost of electricity for utility-scale power (ranges and averages), 2010 and 2016

400

350
Weighted
250 average
USD/MWha

200

150

100 Fossil fuel


cost range
50

0
2010 2016 2010 2016 2010 2016 2010 2016 2010 2016 2010 2016 2010 2016
Biomass Geothermal Hydropower Solar PV Solar Thermal Offshore Onshore
Wind Wind

Note: a) MWh: megawatt-hour. b) All costs are in 2016 USD. Weighted Average Cost of Capital is 7.5% for OECD and China
and 10% for Rest of World.
Source: IRENA, 2017a

According to most scenarios, future investment a crucial role in the transition to a more decen-
in power generation will be dominated by RES tralised system, thereby shaping the electric grid
worldwide. Among RES investment, wind and of the future. For example, advanced meters can
solar technologies would represent the highest allow real-time pricing and fully automated bill-
shares. In particular, the use of decentralised so- ing. With over 12 million smart meters, California
lar photovoltaics (PV) is expected to rise sharp- has reached close to 100% penetration, enabling
ly, due to the significant cost reductions and the consumers and utilities to access added function-
support of policies. The technology has already alities.
reached significant penetration levels in some
The European Union also has an ambitious pro-
cases. In California, for instance, around 2 GW
gram for deployment of smart meters in mem-
of distributed solar PV has been installed. Figure
ber states before 2020. Italy pioneered a com-
1.3 shows the growth of installed solar PV capac-
plete installation of advanced meters more than
ity between 2007 and 2015 under the California
a decade ago. Of course, what matters is not the
Solar Incentive program and the corresponding
physical existence of these meters, but taking full
observed reduction in average installation cost
advantage of their potential. Concerns related to
during this period.
the availability of abundant online information

−− Changing role for consumers and utilities about each individual network user, such as pri-
vacy, must also be addressed.
The transition is not driven by cost reduction
alone. Another relevant factor is the more active Under this new paradigm of decentralised re-
role of consumers, enabled by the possibility of sources and customer engagement, new busi-
generating their own electricity and by the de- ness models and commercial strategies are
ployment of new technologies, such as advanced emerging. With the rise of distributed generation,
meters or load automation systems. Better in- individuals and communities have greater con-
formed and more responsive consumers will play trol on generation and consumption of energy.­­

20
P OW E R S E C TO R T R A N S I T I O N

Figure 1.2 Energy installation costs and cycle life of battery storage technologies, 2016 and 2030

2030 2030
Titanate ZnBr Flow

12,000
Cycle life (equivalent full-cycles)

10,000
2016 2016
Titanate ZnBr Flow
8,000 2030
2030
NaS
LiFePO4 2030
6,000 NMC/LMO
2016
NaS
4,000 2030 2030
NCA VRLA

2030
2,000 2016 2016 Flooded LA
LiFePO4 NMC/LMO 2016
2016 VRLA 2016
NCA Flooded LA
0
1,100 1,000 900 800 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0
Energy installation cost (USD/kWh)

Flooded LA VRLA NCA NaS NMC/LMO LiFePO4 ZnBr Flow Titanate

Note: T
 itanate: Lithium Titanate; ZnBr Flow: Zinc-Bromine; NaS: Sodium Sulphur; NMC/LMO - Nickel Manganese Cobalt Oxide (NMC) /
Lithium Manganese Oxide (LMO); LiFePO4: Lithium Iron Phosphate; NCA: Lithium Nickel Cobalt Aluminium; VRLA:
Valve regulated lead-acid; Flooded LA: Flooded lead-acid
Source: IRENA, 2017b

For example, 35% of Germany’s RES installation is −− Power system integration


owned by citizens, whereas the aggregated share Together with the structural and ownership trans-
in total distributed generation capacity of the big formations associated with the rising presence of
four incumbent utilities, namely E.ON, RWE, Vat- decentralised resources, other important drivers
tenfall and EnBW, is only 5% (BEE, 2014). of change can be observed in the power sector.
The increasing share of RES is affecting the ca-
pacity factor of fossil fuel power plants. Accord- Figure 1.3 Solar PV installed capacity within Califor-
ingly, several incumbent utilities changed their nia Solar Incentive (CSI) program against the evolu-
roles and strategies for their energy business- tion of average cost of solar PV capacity
es. In September 2013, RWE, Germany’s largest
power producer, decided to depart radically from 12 1,800
its traditional business model based on large-
CSI installed capacity (MW)

1,600
10
scale thermal power production and to become
Average cost ($/W)

1,400
8 1,200
a service company, increasingly acting as proj-
1,000
ect enabler, operator and system integrator of re- 6
800
newables. Similarly, at the end of 2014, E.ON an- 4 600

nounced that it is spinning off conventional power 2


400
200
plants to focus on RES, distribution network and 0 0
customer solutions. RWE and E.ON illustrate the 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015

strategies of traditional industry to adapt to the


Source: California Solar Statistics, 2016
power sector transformation.

21
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

1
The integration of power systems into increasing- the long-term financial viability of the power sys-
ly large markets is one. Power pools encompass- tem. Although several countries have successfully
ing several electric utilities under traditional reg- incorporated a large share of variable renewable
ulation were created in the United States during energy (VRE), over 30% of total electricity gener-
the 1970s, and they have evolved into the present ation, without compromising the reliability of the
regional markets, known as regional transmission electricity supply, achieving the energy transition
organisations and run by independent system involves changes at many levels.
operators.
One of these is the adaptation of liberalized elec-
In the European context, electricity and gas mar- tricity markets to efficiently accommodate even
kets form a pillar of the regional energy policy. higher shares of VRE.
European electricity market liberalisation, which
began in the 1990s, represents one of the most 1.2 Power sector organisation
extensive cross-­jurisdiction reform of the elec- This section briefly describes the main activities
tricity sector involving integration of distinct in the power supply chain and discusses the dif-
state-level or national electricity markets (CEEPR, ferent possible organisational approaches that
2005). may be found worldwide.

Today, national and regional day-ahead, intraday Broadly speaking, the electricity supply chain can
and balancing markets are under reform to cre- be divided into four distinct activities: genera-
ate single platforms where all European market tion, transmission, distribution and retailing. Un-
players can trade the different energy products, til recently, power generation has usually taken
subject only to the limitations of cross-border in- place in large centralised power plants located far
terconnection capacities.1 away from the load centers. Therefore, transmis-
sion grids are necessary to transport electricity
Since the early 1990s, Latin American countries
over long distances. In the downstream segment
have launched diverse initiatives to increase in-
of the power system, distribution networks sup-
terconnection capacities and to create integrat-
ply electricity locally from the transmission sub-
ed regional electricity markets. Mercado Eléctrico
stations to end consumers. The traditional role of
Regional, the Central American electricity market
distribution companies as network operators and
(MER), is a present reality, having formally be-
suppliers of electricity to consumers is being re-
gun operations in 2013. Another initiative is the
visited because of the need to integrate growing
Interconnected Andean Electricity System SINEA
levels of distributed generation (DG) and to fa-
which is in the process of creating a sub-regional
cilitate retail market competition and consumers’
electricity market, including Colombia, Ecuador,
demand response. Lately, some countries are lib-
Peru and Bolivia.
eralising the retail segment with the goal of pro-
Other examples are the well-established Aus- moting efficiency.
tralian National Electricity Market, the six inde-
The traditional boundaries between transmission
pendently operated regional markets in China
and distribution systems were largely driven by
and the four power pools in Sub-Saharan Africa,
the different functions these networks fulfilled
which are still under establishment.
within the power system. On the one hand, trans-
The decentralisation and growing penetration of mission grids have conventionally had a decisive
RES are bound to transform the power sector. impact on the system generation dispatch and its
While some challenges remain, favorable policies efficiency, as most generation was connected to
and regulations can bridge the gap and avoid them. On the other hand, the main role of distri-
technology lock-ins that prevent the achievement bution networks has traditionally been to bring
of a suitable low carbon path. These policies in- the electricity to the end consumer while ensuring
clude those that reduce barriers, promote invest- adequate levels of continuity of supply. However,
ments, create a fair level playing field and ensure these boundaries, both at the network (physical

22 1. http://www.acer.europa.eu/electricity/regional_initiatives/Pages/default.aspx
P OW E R S E C TO R T R A N S I T I O N

asset) and system operation (their use) levels, are made by the VIUs under the approval of the cor-
evolving with the progressive decentralisation of responding agency, considering both generation
dispatchable resources (DG, demand response, and transmission network expansion as a whole,
distributed storage). whereas medium-term and short-term operation-
al decisions are made on the basis of cost minimi-
Furthermore, power systems need to be man-
sation and a centralised cost-based dispatch. This
aged as a whole so that security of supply is en-
power sector structure is illustrated in Figure 1.4.
sured over both the short and long term. Pow-
er system planning and operation comprise a
chain of sequential decisions, ranging from gen- Figure 1.4 T
 raditional power sector organisation
eration capacity expansion and transmission net- with a vertically integrated utility in
work planning in the long term to short-term de- each territorial franchise
cisions such as the dispatch of generation units
and the utilisation of reserves. Besides technical
constraints, these decisions must be guided by
Generation
economic considerations so that social welfare is
maximised, i.e., this is a cost minimisation subject
to prescribed reliability targets. The main differ-
ences in power system management lie in how
the responsibilities of the different decisions are Transmission

allocated among stakeholders.


System

−−  Different power sector structures


Operation

Distribution
A salient feature of the energy transition will be
the integration of growing shares of RES into the
power system. The policy and regulatory adap- Retailing

tations that are required to achieve this affect all


the segments of the electricity supply chain and
Note: Each colour represents a vertically integrated utility
vary depending on the existing structure of the
power sector. The essential differences among
these alternatives correspond to the allocation Some countries have opened up their power sys-
of decision-making among stakeholders and the tems to allow new entrants – known as indepen-
degree of liberalisation and restructuring intro- dent power producers (IPPs) – in the generation
duced in the segments of the electricity chain segment. This change in paradigm may be moti-
(Batlle and Ocaña, 2013). vated in response to the difficulties faced by pub-
licly owned incumbents to finance new invest-
The traditional power sector paradigm relies on
ments in generation and/or by the will to make
centralised decision-making by vertically inte-
possible the development of RES or combined
grated utilities (VIUs), owning both generation
heat and power facilities. The contracts signed
and network assets, with the obligation to supply
by incumbents with IPPs, allow them to recover
end consumers within their territorial franchises.
their generation costs (fixed and variable) and in-
In this context, the state has a predominant role
clude provisions concerning their duties and ob-
since VIUs are either publicly owned companies,
ligations (e.g., reliability level, ancillary services,
or privately owned firms subject to some sort
audits, etc.).
of cost regulation and supervision by a govern-
mental agency. In some countries, privately and In the markets where restructuring and liberali-
publicly owned companies coexist and are both sation has taken place, it usually started by in-
subject to the same traditional cost-of-service troducing competition into the generation sector
regulation. Investment decisions are centrally at the wholesale level. This implies allowing new

23
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

1
entrants to compete with the previous incum- at the retail level. In some systems, the right to
bent generation company, oftentimes a national freely choose a supplier has been established for
company owning strategic resources (e.g., hydro- all consumers at once; while in others, it has been
power), or splitting up the previous incumbent progressively introduced, starting from the larg-
generation firm into a few smaller generation est consumers to the smallest residential ones.
companies allocated to private investors through Regulated default tariffs are frequently made
auctioning processes. These generation compa- available for those consumers who do not wish to
nies then sell their production through the inter- shop around for a supplier or who are temporarily
mediation of a market operator via some sort of without a contract.
spot-trading platform, where participation is fre-
Lastly, some countries have decided to go be-
quently mandatory, and the resulting wholesale
yond the model based on a single compulsory
electricity prices are passed through to consum-
market operator or an ISO by allowing the agents
ers by the distribution companies (see Figure 1.5).
to establish bilateral contracts with one another.
The function of operating the market can either be
Thus, generators and retailers (or large consum-
carried out by an entity independent of the sys-
ers) may freely sign bilateral agreements, with
tem operator (transmission system operator plus
the organised spot markets simply being another
market operator model), or by a separate market
alternative. This model is depicted in Figure 1.6.
operator. In the former circumstance, the agent in
charge of system and market operation is usually 1.3 R
 enewable energy impact on the
referred to as an Independent System Operator power sector operation
(ISO). Contrasting the need to centralise the op-
This section describes the main reasons why a
eration of the system and the network expansion
large penetration of VRE imposes the need to
under a single entity, under the supervision of the
adapt the design of power markets. While the im-
regulatory authority, the transmission grid is fre-
pact that high shares of these sources have on
quently owned by one or more different agents.
the operation of electricity systems has already
Some countries that have liberalised their elec- been assessed in the literature (e.g. NREL 2013a;
tricity markets have also introduced competition Holttinen et al., 2013), international experiences

Figure 1.5 C
 ompetition wholesale market and regu- Figure 1.6 Fully liberalised power sector with com-
lated distribution companies acting also as petition at wholesale and retail level with
retailers bilateral contracts

Generation Generation

Transmission
Transmission

System Market Operator


ISO Operation System
Operation

Distribution Distribution

Retailing Retailing

24
P OW E R S E C TO R T R A N S I T I O N

can illustrate the particular operational charac- complementarity (due to inverse correlation) be-
teristics of wind and solar, and the way they can tween wind and solar production.
affect both short-term operation and long-term
We shall distinguish two different characteristics
planning in liberalised contexts.
of VRE that present challenges for their integra-
1.3.1 System impacts of variable tion: variability and limited resource predictabil-
renewable energy ity. These characteristics make solar and wind
completely different resources when it comes to
VRE technologies, in particular wind and solar,
market integration.
present unique characteristics that have signifi-
cant impacts on the power system.
−− Variability
−− Seasonality and complementarity The challenge associated with variable resourc-
es is the increased need for flexibility, including
The variability patterns of wind and solar heav-
ramping requirements to keep the system bal-
ily depend on the climatological characteristics
anced depending on resource availability. Figure
of each system. The assessment of the season-
1.8. shows the hourly ramps (in GW/hour) that
ality in variable energy resources production al-
have to be met in the Electric Reliability Coun-
lows discovering correlations among different re-
cil of Texas (ERCOT) system under different solar
sources, as well as with demand. In Germany, for
penetration scenarios. Solar production is useful
instance, peak demand takes place during winter,
to reduce morning ramp needs since it is well cor-
mainly due to the demand corresponding to elec-
related with the morning demand peak, however,
tric space heating. Figure 1.7 depicts the annual
a large amount of solar production shifts the net
variation of wind and solar PV production in Ger-
load peak and steep ramps to the evening. This
many. While solar PV production is greater during
highlights the importance of sending accurate
summer, wind production is higher during win-
(i.e. time sensitive) price signals that can drive in-
ter. Consequently, wind production is positively
vestment to efficiently integrate high penetration
correlated with demand, but there is also certain
levels of renewables.

Figure 1.7 Weekly wind and solar production in Germany

Weekly Production: Solar year 2014

1.5
TWh

1.0
0.5

1 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48 52

Weekly Production: Wind year 2014

2.5
2.0
TWh

1.5
1.0
0.5

1 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48 52

Source: Burger, 2014

25
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

1
Figure 1.8 Hourly net load ramps for different penetration levels of solar PV

2
GW/h

-2

-4

-6
5 10 15 20 25
Hours

No PV PV 6GW PV 18GW PV 36GW

Source: MIT, 2015

−− Predictability tions close to the demand could offset demand


growth, reduce peak load and allow distribution
Another characteristic is related to resource pre-
dictability. Wind may be relatively unpredictable, companies to defer grid enforcements. However,
as shown in Figure 1.9 which shows an example RES not located near the demand could lead to
from Belgium. This example depicts the week- the need for further investments in transmission
ahead and day-ahead forecasts versus the actu- networks and sometimes cause network conges-
al measured production. The forecast accuracy tion. This highlights the need to reinforce the grid
improves when it is made closer to real time. As as well as to send location-specific price signals in
seen in Figure 1.9 also shows that PV forecasting liberalised markets.
is more accurate than wind forecasting.
1.3.2 M
 arket impacts of variable
Much progress has been made in recent years on renewable energy
wind forecasting tools; Figure 1.10 shows the ex- The impacts of a large penetration of VRE on lib-
perience of the Spanish power system, for exam- eralised power systems, and specifically on pro-
ple, where the accuracy of wind forecasts has dra- duction costs and market prices, heavily depend
matically increased since 2008. on the characteristics of the generation mix. In

−− Geographical dispersion
particular whether the generation mix is energy-
or capacity-constrained; and its degree of flexi-
Another relevant characteristic of RES, which bility.
makes them different from conventional thermal
generation, is that the generation assets are lo-
cated where abundant resources are available,
sometimes leading to dispersed installations
or to generation assets being relatively distant
from demand centres. In specific cases and if the
right regulations are in place, dispersed installa-

26
P OW E R S E C TO R T R A N S I T I O N

Figure 1.9 Wind and solar PV forecasting for Belgium

1,000

750
MW

500

250

0
1/09 2/09 3/09 4/09 5/09 6/09 7/09 8/09 9/09
Time Horizon
Wind forecasting Measured & Upscaled Day-ahead forecast Week-ahead forecast

2,500

2,000

1,500

1,000
MW

500

0
8/07 9/07 10/07 11/07 12/07 13/07 14/07 15/07
Time Horizon
Solar PV forecasting Measured & Upscaled Intraday forecast Day-ahead Forecast

Source: ELIA, 2016

Capacity-constrained versus energy- Energy-constrained systems, on the contrary, are


constrained systems (system adequacy) characterised by a value of peak demand sig-
In capacity-constrained systems, scarcity prob- nificantly lower than installed capacity, and only
lems arise when there is not enough installed constrained when the system runs out of avail-
capacity available (MW) to satisfy demand at a able energy. These are typically hydro-dominat-
given moment due to, for instance, forced out- ed systems with large reservoir capacity, but
age of thermal plants. These systems cannot sat- they also include gas-constrained systems (e.g.,
isfy the peak demand but could certainly have subject to potential gas transmission constraints.
enough energy available to satisfy demand on a These systems can meet the peak demand but
given day. The largest portion of the capacity mix the challenge in these systems is to supply the to-
in these systems is usually conventional thermal tal amount of energy required (in megawatt-hour
generation. terms).

These represent the two extremes, but sys-


tems can also be both capacity- and energy-­
constrained at the same time.

27
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

1
Figure 1.10 Wind forecasting error evolution in Spain

25
% Mean Absolute Error / Average production

20

15

10

0
1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 39 41 43 45 47
Predictions horizon, hours
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015

Source: REE, 2016

Flexible versus inflexible systems is called the merit order effect, which tends to de-
(system operation) crease wholesale prices.
A flexible system, meaning a system where gen- In inflexible thermal-dominated systems, signifi-
eration can deal both with short-term variability cant penetration of VRE (especially PV) increases
and limited predictability with a moderate impact the cycling requirements of conventional thermal
on production costs, is due to the availability of plants. The change in the net load shape will force
different possible resources. Figure 1.11 shows a plants to change their output more often to meet
qualitative representation of the cost associated ramps of net demand, and to start up and shut
with different sources of flexibility. down frequently. This context is illustrated in Fig-
An inflexible generation mix involves a significant ure 1.12, from a simulation of different solar pen-
increase in costs in the short term when genera- etration levels in the ERCOT system. Initially solar
tion needs to follow a variable and unpredictable production can reduce total short-term system
net load shape (i.e. demand minus VRE genera- costs and thermal generation costs (fuel costs),
tion). This is typically the case of systems rely- but as solar penetration increases, thermal units
ing on old thermal plants originally envisioned operation is affected by the cycling, thus increas-
to produce base-load. Again, systems can be in-­ ing its cost.
between these two ‘extremes’. Therefore, the total thermal cost will generally de-

−− Impact on spot prices


crease (for its associated production decreases),
but the production cost of thermal plants gener-
The short-term impact of VRE on prices is larg- ating, and therefore setting the market prices in
er in inflexible, thermal-dominated systems. Vari- some hours, may increase. This can translate into
able renewables that very low or even zero vari- two impacts on energy prices: the first effect leads
able costs tend to displace the most expensive to lower average prices; the second effect may be
variable cost units, thus changing the marginal sharper and higher prices during a reduced num-
price of the generated power of the system. This ber of hours because of increased cycling.

28
P OW E R S E C TO R T R A N S I T I O N

Figure 1.11 Flexibility sources and the cost involved

Involuntary Load Chemical Storage


Shedding

Transmission
Expansion

Coal Ramping
Residential Transmission
Demand Response CT and CCGT Reinforcement Pumped Hydro
Gas Ramping Storage
Strategic
Cost

RE Curtailment
Advanced Network Thermal Storage
Expanded Balancing Joint Market
Operation Management
Footprint/Joint Hydro Ramping
System Operation Industrial &
Increased Ancillary
Commercial Demand
Service Liquidity
Sub-hourly Response
Scheduling and Improved Energy
Dispatch Market Design
RE Forecasting Option costs are system-dependent
Grid Codes
and evolving over time

SYSTEM FLEXIBLE
MARKETS LOAD NETWORKS STORAGE
OPERATION GENERATION

Type of Intervention

Source: Miller, 2015

29
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

1
Figure 1.12 System and thermal production cost for increasing solar penetration in a thermal-dominated system

Total Short-term Production Cost Average Thermal Producion Cost


10.2
10.0 41
9.8
Merit Order Effect Cycling
9.6 40
9.4

USD/MWh
Billion USD

9.2 39
9.0
8.8 38
8.6
8.4 37
8.2
0 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 0 6 12 18 24 30 36 42
Solar PV penetration Solar PV penetration
(% peak demand) (% peak demand)

Source: MIT, 2015

The impact that increasing VRE penetration will put below a minimum technical output may cause
have on short-term prices can be mitigated in flex- negative prices to appear. This problem is more
ible, energy-constrained systems. Hydropower, acute in inflexible, capacity-constrained power
for instance, can easily provide the much-needed systems (IADB, 2014). These issues will be ana-
flexibility to the system and contribute to absorb lysed in detail in chapter 2, which provides rec-
the steep ramps in the net load. The same hap- ommendations on how to adapt the wholesale
pens if there are other forms of flexibility, as dis- market design for the efficient integration of high
cussed in the previous section. level of VRE.

−− Impact on price convergence and volatility 1.4 Conclusions


As mentioned above, in some cases the output This chapter has outlined the fundamental role re-
of VRE may be difficult to predict. Large devia- newable energy technologies will play in achiev-
tions in day-ahead and intraday forecasts cause ing the energy transition. The power sector is at
a divergence between day-ahead and intraday the forefront of the transition with renewables ca-
prices. In some cases, this price divergence can pacity growing at a tremendous pace, outpacing
be very large, as in the example of Figure 1.13, those of conventional energy sources. The grow-
where an unexpected increase in wind availabil- ing deployment of VRE technologies and rise in
ity caused a sudden drop in electricity prices in distributed generation are some of the factors
intraday markets. Furthermore, intertemporal that are driving the transition in the power sec-
production constraints coupled with the inability tor. VRE already accounts for a large share of the
of many thermal generators to reduce their out- electricity mix in several markets. Further accel-
erating the transition, while ensuring high stan-
dards of economic efficiency and technical reli-
ability, requires supportive policy and regulatory
measures.

30
P OW E R S E C TO R T R A N S I T I O N

Figure 1.13 Electricity production and spot prices, November 2016 in Germany

80.00 200.00

70.00 175.00

60.00 150.00

50.00 125.00

Price (Euro/MWh)
40.00 100.00
Power (GW)

30.00 75.00

20.00 50.00

10.00 25.00

0.00 0.00

-10.00 -25.00

-20.00 -500
01.11 15.11. 17.11. 20.11. 20.11. 24.11. 26.11. 29:11. 30.11.
09:53 17:26 01:00 08:33 16:06 23:40 07:13 23:00
Date
Import Balance Conventional > 100 MW Wind Solar Day Ahead Auction Intraday Continuous
(right axis) Average Price (right axis)

Source: Fraunhofer ISE, 2016

For the sustainable development and greater re-


newable energy deployment, adequate measures
are needed to adapt the market design to ad-
dress system level impacts associated with vari-
ability, resource predictability and geographical
dispersion, and market level impacts that include
effects on spot prices. Indeed, embracing and
supporting the energy transition will bring a wide
range of economy-wide benefits, in addition to
positive impacts on the environment and energy
security.

The remainder of this report mainly focuses on


adapting policy and regulations for two ele-
ments of an advanced liberalised power system
– wholesale market and distribution networks. It
analyses the key impacts of variable and distrib-
uted renewables for each element and provides
recommendations for policy makers and regula-
tors in relevant markets.

31
WHOLESALE
MARKET
DESIGN
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

2.1. INTRODUCTION As a consequence, and as reviewed in Chapter 1,


the original configuration and functioning of pow-
The electricity market designs implemented to
er systems worldwide is changing, and will con-
date, with their strengths and weaknesses, are
tinue to change in the near future.
the results of gradual adaptations to the physical
characteristics of each particular power system. All these transformations are taking place at a
Although no two market designs are alike – for no very fast pace. Adapting market designs to re-
two power systems are completely alike – elec- alize the maximum benefits of existing and new
tricity markets have been traditionally tailored to resources is a formidable challenge.
a context in which grid-connected, large-scale
This chapter reviews several important issues re-
power plants supplied electricity in response to a
lated to the design of electricity markets, issues
relatively easy-to-forecast, passive demand. Until
that need to be reconsidered in today’s new set-
recently, electricity demand has been assumed to
ting. In doing so, it analyses three time frames: 1)
be highly inelastic and mainly dependent on tem-
long term; 2) day ahead and intraday and 3) very
perature and expected economic activity.
short term (close to real time).

−− The reconception of power systems


is recasting wholesale market designs
2.1.1. E
 lectricity markets, products
and time frames
Before the power industry reached a consensus
Electricity markets comprise all the commercial
on how to most efficiently implement electricity
transactions involving energy as well as other
markets, new driving factors for change put cur-
complementary products related to the supply of
rent market designs into question. Worldwide,
electricity (e.g., ancillary services, reliability prod-
electricity systems are experiencing one of the
ucts traded in capacity mechanisms, etc.).1
most profound transformations in their history.
To deepen the current transition, power systems Procuring products aside from energy is essential
need to integrate large amounts of variable re- to ensure that the delivery of electricity is suffi-
newable generation resources (often distributed). ciently secure and of adequate quality. The num-

1. This general overview is based on Batlle (2013).

33
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
ber of these complementary products and their •• In the day-ahead market – covered in Section
exact definition vary from one system to another. 2.2 – trading takes place one day before the
Notwithstanding, energy and ancillary services delivery of electricity. Market members sub-
are jointly produced; they are not typically jointly mit their bids and offers, and a clearing algo-
procured, as energy procurement is left to mar- rithm determines the market price for each
ket participants whereas the system operator is settlement period (e.g., for each hour) of the
in charge of ancillary services’ procurement. As following day and the cleared quantities. It is
we shall see later, there are alternative ways to in this time frame where the largest fraction of
integrate ancillary services and energy procure- operating reserves is often acquired. After the
ment. day-ahead, and before real-time delivery of
electricity, there are intraday markets or other
Energy and electricity-related products can be
mechanisms that allow rescheduling units. The
traded in various time frames, depending on the
reasons for this rescheduling are diverse and
particular market. For example:
depend on market design characteristics.
•• Energy, the most basic product traded on elec- •• The focus of Section 2.3 is on the markets re-
tricity markets, can be procured from the very lated to the close-to-real-time actions of the
long term to real time, through either physical system operator (more specifically, operations
or financial contracts. carried out by the system operator after the
•• The system operator may acquire ancillary ser- last market gate closure2). It is during this time
vices (e.g., operating reserves that are used to frame when the detailed design of energy and
ensure a continuous match between demand reserves products becomes more relevant. A
and supply, even in case of contingency) in dif- proper design is crucial to provide accurate
ferent time frames (including long-term, day- price signals in the very short term, and this
ahead and intraday, depending on the market). will play a fundamental role in unlocking all the
•• Reliability products (i.e., products that assure flexibility already available in power systems
the physical availability of an adequate quan- while also providing efficient long-term signals.
tity of resources in the system needed to run •• Finally, in Section 2.4, we focus on those mech-
it safely without having to curtail demand) are anisms generically oriented towards directly
usually procured over the long term; subse- supporting the long-term development of the
quent markets may also allow the adaptation power sector. Capacity mechanisms, or any oth-
of buying and selling positions. er mechanism designed to guarantee the ade-
•• Renewable energy support mechanisms can quacy of the system, are introduced to achieve
provide long- to short-term incentives for the the reliability target defined by the regulator.
production of renewable energy. Reliability products traded in these mecha-
nisms may be very diverse, reflecting the diver-
It is not always easy to clearly separate the three
sity of scarcity conditions in different systems.
time frames discussed here for short-, very-short-
Also, the procurement process varies (e.g.,
and long-term markets. All electricity markets are,
centralised versus decentralised approaches)
to some extent, coupled. The most relevant prod-
according to the structure of the power sector.
ucts that are usually traded within each time frame
On the other hand, RES support schemes aim
will be discussed. The analysis will start with short-
at achieving a renewable penetration target. In
term markets, i.e., day-ahead (DA) and intra-day
this case, different designs are possible, each
(ID) markets because, in most power systems, the
one with its pros and cons, as analysed in detail
day-ahead market serves as a reference for all the
in the second part of Section 2.5.
others. Later, the very- short-term (balancing or
real-time markets) and the long-term market de-
sign (focusing on capacity mechanisms and RES
support schemes) will be discussed.

2. T
 he last gate closure is the moment until which market agents can modify their own programmes on the markets without
the intervention of the system operator.

34
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

In the remainder of this section, we introduce the Variable and small-scale generation on the sys-
reasons why increasing penetration levels of re- tem dispatch requires flexibility (Holttinen et al.,
newables (utility scale and distributed) call for 2013; Graichen, 2015), which, among other mea-
revisiting wholesale market design in liberalised sures, calls for a larger amount of dispatchable
power systems for all time frames. resources capable of dealing with changing sit-
uations, whose operation is to be based on fast-
2.1.2. Why rethink the market now er and more accurate markets. Figure 2.1 illus-

−− The need to rethink short-term and


very-short-term markets today
trates the rising need for flexibility as variable
generation increases across different renewable
penetration scenarios in the US Western Inter-
connection. Three technologies are selected to
Variable and small-scale generation and represent three different types of operating re-
demand response solutions call for faster and gimes: coal plants (base load), combined cy-
more accurate short-term markets. cles (mid-load) and gas turbines (peakers). An
increasing penetration of RES technologies re-
More than in any other kind of market, trading in sults in a higher “capacity started” among peak-
power markets is largely conditioned by the laws ing units (Panel a), a decrease (even if not ho-
of physics. The deployment of variable and dis- mogenous) in the number of hours that a plant
tributed renewables may complicate the efficient is online each time it is started (Panel b) and an
management of markets if adequate adapting increase in the number of ramps required, not
measures are not put in place. Designing power only from peakers, but also from base-load units
markets then, involves an ongoing search for the (Panel c) – three effects that clearly highlight the
right balance between economic and engineering growing need for flexibility.
efficiency, between what is desirable and what is
feasible.

Figure 2.1 VRE generation and the need for flexibility

Scenarios
NoRenew TEPPC HiWind HiMix HiSolar

(a) (b) (c)


Capacity started (GW)

Hours online per start

Numbers of ramps

300 90,000
1,000

200 60,000

500
100 30,000

0 0 0
Coal Gas CC Gas CT Coal Gas CC Gas CT Coal Gas CC Gas CT

( a) Capacity started
(b) average number of hours online per start
(c) total number of ramps for different plant types per year in different scenarios of RES penetration
Note: T
 he scenarios simulated are: no renewables (0% wind, 0% solar); Transmission Expansion Planning Policy Committee (TEPPC
9.4% wind, 3.6% solar); High Wind (25% wind, 8% solar); High Solar (25% solar, 8% wind) and High Mix (16.5% wind, 16.5% solar).
Power plant types are coal plants (base load), gas combined cycles (mid-load) and gas combustion turbines (peakers). Results
depend on the technical parameters assigned to each technology and are specific to the Western Interconnection.
Source: Adapted from NREL, 2013a

35
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
The format of the bids in day-ahead markets im- of balancing products and the pricing of reserves
plemented to date has traditionally been tailored (see Section 2.3).
to the prevailing generation mix in each particu-
lar context. The vast majority of relevant dispatch −− The need to revisit long-term
investment signals
decisions have been one-sided (no demand re-
sponse was expected except in very extreme sit-
uations) and could be mostly closed in the day- Long-term regulatory mechanisms (including
ahead horizon. Something analogous happens capacity and RES support ones) need to be
with the definition of reserves products and the designed to minimise market distortions and
functioning of close-to-real-time markets. to encourage full integration of all resources.
However, prevailing resources are rapidly chang-
ing. The development of renewable energy According to economic theory, perfect compet-
sources (RES) has fostered the proliferation of itive markets lead to the most efficient results,
distributed generation, giving rise to a signifi- both in the short and in the long term. In real cas-
cant number of new small-scale agents and busi- es, however, the presence of market failures im-
nesses that need proper accommodation in the plies that this ideal outcome is often not reached.
market. In addition to this and in parallel, en-
abling information and communication technolo- When there is no way to fix these failures to al-
gies are increasingly allowing demand to receive low the market (left to its own devices) to achieve
more precise market signals and to react to them, the welfare-maximising outcome, some addition-
which will empower consumers to play a major al regulatory mechanisms can help the market
role in the energy transition. In this new context, meet this goal. These mechanisms may look to
there is growing consensus around the fact that reinforce the short- and/or long-term signals that
short-term and very-short-term3 markets need to agents perceive in order to improve system secu-
be improved and adjusted to meet future needs. rity of supply or may seek to incentivise certain
technologies (e.g., wind or solar).
The major refinements needed depend to a large
extent on the particular type of market design Capacity remuneration mechanisms
in place. To simplify, there are two main ways of No consensus has been reached yet regarding
conceiving short-term electricity markets (Bat- instruments for the remuneration of capacity. A
lle, 2013): the US Independent System Operator good number of markets, mainly on the the Amer-
(ISO) approach and the Target Model for the Eu- icas (Batlle et al., 2015) opted to implement a di-
ropean electricity market.4 verse array of explicit capacity mechanisms from
the outset, while in other regions (Europe is the
The short-term market design elements consid-
paradigmatic example), this was not initially the
ered pivotal to the current transition include the
case.5 However, several countries in Europe have
time frame of markets, bidding formats, clearing
now implemented, or are in the process of imple-
and pricing rules and the integration of energy
menting capacity mechanisms (ACER, 2013; AC-
and reserve markets (see Section 2.2).
ER-CEER, 2016a), as also evidenced in Figure 2.2.6
In very-short-term markets, the design elements
in need of revision are the definition of balanc-
ing responsibility (for conventional and RES gen-
eration), the imbalance settlement, the definition

3 Balancing markets in the European Union and real-time markets in the United States.
4 As defined by CACM Guideline (Commission Regulation 2015/1222) and draft Electricity Balancing Guideline.
5 Although all sorts of implicit regulatory safeguards have been applied indirectly in order to guarantee the security of supply
in these energy-only markets.
6 The European Commission has highlighted the need to use a harmonised adequacy assessment methodology, in order to avoid the
design of CMs at country level to be a potential threat to to the development of the internal energy market. For further details, see
the Winter Package released on 30 November 2016 (https://ec.europa.eu/energy/en/news/commission-proposes-new-rules-con-
sumer-centred-clean-energy-transition).

36
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

The deployment of RES has been argued by some ditional plants. Indeed, in a competitive electrici-
as the new and key factor to justify the need for ty market – given the standardised nature of the
the implementation of capacity mechanisms. The product – the market price is equal to the margin-
argument more commonly raised is that high al cost of serving an incremental unit of demand.
volumes of variable renewables in markets with Therefore, as long as there is enough capacity to
overcapacity are driving down short-term prices serve the demand, market price cannot exceed
and load factors of conventional generation. This the marginal variable cost of the system. Because
makes it more difficult to forecast the frequency electricity cannot be stored economically, only
of scarcity events that, in a competitive “energy when capacity is scarce with respect to demand
only” market, are the ones that allow for the re- can prices surge over variable cost, contributing
covery of the fixed costs of non-incentivised tra- to the recovery of fixed costs.7

Figure 2.2 European power systems with (or in the process of implementing) capacity mechanisms

No CM (energy only market) CM proposed/under consideration CM operational

Strategic reserve
(since 2007)

Strategic reserve
Strategic reserve (since 2004)-gradual
(since 1 november 2014) phase-out postponed 2025

Capacity auction
Strategic reserves
(since 2014-first delivery
(Envisaged in 2017)
in 2018/19)

Strategic reserve
Capacity payments
(from 2016 on, for 2 years,
(since 2007) considering
with possible extension
reliability options
for 2 more years)

Capacity requirements Strategic reserves


(certification started
1 April 2015)
Reliability options
(the date for the first auction
Capacity payments has not been set. First
(since 2008) delivery of contracted
Tendering for capacity capacity is expected in 2020)
considered but no plans

Tender
Capacity payments (since November 2013)
(since 2010 partially
suspended between May
2011 and December 2014) New Capacity Mechanism
under assesment by DG
COMP (Capacity payments
from 2006 to 2014)

Note: I n Germany, there are three (envisaged) schemes: Climate Reserve, Network Reserve and a Strategic Capacity Reserve. The
first is not considered to be a CM; the second could be, and the third is a CM. The Strategic Capacity Reserve is envisaged to
be implemented in 2017, if the necessity is demonstrated. The envisaged CM in Poland for after 2016 includes generation units
tendered by the TSO, which would definitely have been decommissioned by the end of 2015. This scheme has the characteristic
of a Strategic Reserve CM.
The term “country” as used in this material also refers, as appropriate, to territories or areas.
Source: Adapted from ACER-CEER, 2016a, based on NRAs (2016) and European Commission’s report on the sector inquiry into CMs
(2016).

7. “ In an energy-only market, the signal for investment relies on high prices that materialize in moments of excess demand (these
are called scarcity prices and moments of excess demand are scarcity scenarios): whenever there is a scarcity scenario, prices are
allowed to rise so that generators start earning ‘scarcity rents’ that are high enough to cover their fixed costs of capital and induce
new investment/new entry in the market. […]” see European Commission, 2015a.

37
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
In this context, many stakeholders have ques- for generation adequacy and renewable devel-
tioned whether short-term market prices alone, opment. The goals are to send proper long-term
even if regulations allow market prices to reach signals, to avoid interfering and distorting market
very high levels in scarcity events, are a reliable functioning as much as possible, and to encour-
enough signal to encourage adequate capacity in- age the integration of all resources.
vestments. In fact, the need to reinforce long-term
signals does not arise only from RES deployment
2.2. SHORT-TERM MARKETS
itself, but also from the regulatory uncertainty
(e.g., around the kind of support to be provided in
the future) around deployment and the effects of Short-term energy market design needs to be
this uncertainty on wholesale markets. enhanced and refined at all levels, particularly
RES support mechanisms timelines, locational granularity of prices,
bidding formats, clearing and pricing rules
For many years, there has been a consensus on
and integration with reserves.
the need to implement long-term RES support
mechanisms because of the market’s inability to
internalise a number of externalities. However, Short-term auctions are the core of electricity
RES support mechanisms, and therefore RES in- wholesale markets. At these auctions, bids by
vestments, have not always benefited from stable generators and consumers are matched with the
remuneration frameworks. This lack of regulato- textbook objective of determining not just who
ry predictability, among other factors, affects the sells and who buys, but also market clearing pric-
decisions of potential RES investors (and also the es (for each time interval in the auction timeline
decisions of investors in conventional generation scope and for both market sides: generation and
technologies). demand) – that is, as described in figure 2.3, the
price at which demand equals supply, and no
A discussion on whether the need for such mech-
more demand is willing to purchase and/or sup-
anisms in each particular context is justified or
ply willing to sell. These short-term electricity
not falls outside the scope of this study. Here, the
prices are essential since they represent the ref-
focus is on providing recommendations about
erence for the longer-term markets (which help
how to design these support mechanisms, both
drive the system expansion).

Figure 2.3 Market clearing price and market clearing volume setting in electricity auctions

$/MWh

DEMAND SUPPLY

Market
clearing
price

Market MWh
clearing volume

38
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

In electricity markets, trades concern an underly- erator. But the two approaches are increasingly
ing commodity which is subject to many complex converging and promise to continue doing so.
physical constraints (operation, network, security,
etc.). Different approaches to dealing with these −− Short-term
considered
market design elements to be re-
physical complexities have resulted in (some-
times significantly) different market designs. We have pointed out that the recent proliferation
of resources with new characteristics has raised
In practice, as briefly analysed in Box 2.1, there
concerns regarding the need to improve the cur-
are two main approaches to accounting for all
rent market design. Among the different design
these physical constraints: the US and the Euro-
features of short-term markets, we focus here
pean Union (EU) models. The major difference
on those that we believe deserve more attention
between the two is the degree of separation be-
from stakeholders and policy makers:
tween the market operator and the system op-

Box 2.1 The major difference between US and EU market designs

The major difference between US and EU market designs requirements set by the ISO (e.g., different types of re-
is the degree of separation between the roles of market serves) can be co-optimised and priced along with en-
operator and system operator. In certain jurisdictions, the ergy.
role of the system operator is less pervasive than in oth-
ers, under the argument that the system operator func-
−− At the other extreme, the model currently used in most
European member states, which we can call the EU pow-
tion should be limited to ensure reliability in an attempt
er exchange (PX) approach, originally aimed at a simpler
to maximise the range of the market. The debate on allo-
consideration of the physical reality along with a major
cation of responsibilities between the market and the sys-
decoupling of the system operator’s responsibilities and
tem operator has been central since the outset of market
the spot market functioning. Historically, European Pow-
restructuring (see, for instance, Hogan, 1995).
er Exchanges were designed as financial platforms for
The predominant models implemented in US markets and agents to buy/sell energy with the supposed objective of
in force in the majority of EU member states – with some maximising liquidity, in an attempt to isolate (as much as
exceptions, including Ireland until very recently (CER, possible) this trading from the complexities of the net-
2014) and Poland (Siewierski, 2015) – represent two dif- work. In line with this separation between the market and
ferent views on whether or not to carry out this separa- the system operators, the European approach tends to
tion. allow generators to bid on a portfolio basis (aggregated
bids from different facilities of the same company). 8
−− In the United States, the integration of physical con-
straints in the clearing process and the involvement of −− In a nutshell, as will be discussed throughout the chap-
the independent system operator (ISO) in the markets is ter, the influence of the system operator to determine the
probably as significant as is possible. The ISO oversees real-time scheduling throughout the entire process is, in
both activities, market and system operation, not only practice, reflected in a number of basic design elements,
from an institutional perspective, but also from the op- for example, the point in time at which the last gate clo-
erative standpoint, as energy trades are jointly cleared sure is set (i.e., the moment until which market agents can
with the electricity system security procedures. This is modify their own programmes without the intervention
considered necessary, not only to reliably operate the of the system operator), the integration of the physical
system, but also to guide market agents towards the op- constraints in the clearing process, the amount and di-
timal dispatch (from the system operator’s perspective, versity of reserves defined by the system operator and
taking into account technical and reliability constraints). the mechanisms to acquire them, or even the role of the
This model revolves around the concept of bid-based, se- system operator as aggregator and balancing party re-
curity-constrained economic dispatch (SCED), where the sponsible for RES.

8. D
 espite being the major trend in Europe, portfolio bidding is not allowed in some European systems, including, for instance,
in Spain and Portugal.

39
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
•• The time frame of markets, both for energy and 2.2.1. T ime frames of markets,
reserves, which is fundamental to allow market dispatches and prices
mechanisms to respond quickly to fast-chang-
ing conditions.
As variability increases, the time specificity of
•• The locational granularity of prices and sched-
produc ts traded in the markets needs to be
ules.
increased. This leads to the need for better-
•• The so-called bidding formats. i.e., the way
adapted and more flexible market timelines.
generators are allowed to submit their offers in
the market (not only in the day-ahead but also
closer to the real-time markets). One central element of the short-term market de-
•• How markets are cleared and settled, i.e., how sign that needs to be revisited to better accom-
it is determined who produces and who con- modate RES is the time frame of the energy and
sumes and at what price. reserve markets. The time frame of the system
•• How to define and procure operational reserves, operator’s actions (i.e., reliability-related pro-
and particularly how to guarantee that the mar- cesses involved in the delivery of electricity) also
ket reflects the interdependence between the needs reconsideration.
energy and reserve products, especially under
The design of market time frames is mainly in-
conditions of scarcity.
fluenced by the physical and technological char-
Some of these design features are relatively new acteristics of the power system. Since the outset
(e.g., the need to adjust the market timeline to of the electricity market liberalisation, there has
fit the new flexibility requirements or the need to been a general consensus (with some exceptions)
define new bidding formats), while other refine- that, in thermal-dominated systems, it is conve-
ments (for example, the need to revisit clearing nient to implement a day-ahead energy market
and pricing rules) target deep-rooted efficiency and also day-ahead reserve markets. Energy and
issues that have been acknowledged for years, reserves can be procured: 1) within the same auc-
but whose effect has been exacerbated by the tion mechanisms or 2) by means of different and
new market conditions. sequential mechanisms.

Although most of the previous design elements For a short-term energy market, one day is suffi-
of short-term markets are related to some ex- cient to both forecast demand consumption with
tent, for the sake of clarity, we will try to deal with reasonable certainty and to schedule thermal
them one at a time and separately. plants’ commitments. Meanwhile, for a hydro-
power-dominated (energy-constrained) system,
the economic dispatch and the resulting prices
can be calculated over larger horizons (e.g., on a
weekly basis, as done in Brazil). This is evidence
of the significant role that electricity systems’
technological characteristics play in deciding op-
timal time frames.

40
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

From the day-ahead market to real time, addi- market, where resources are purchased or sold
tional markets and mechanisms are needed to al- by the system operator (which is the counterpart
low agents to adapt their programmes to chang- of all transactions). As described later, in the Eu-
ing conditions. Increasing shares of wind and ropean model, there are intraday markets where
solar generation, in particular, result in increas- energy products are traded directly between
ing volumes of intraday trading necessities, and market players.
the need to adjust production schedules to the
The first difference between both schemes in
most recently updated forecasts. This requires
the short term lies in the way operating reserves
the market time frame to adapt to fully exploit
(generation capacity readily available to the sys-
the potential of variable renewable resources.
tem operator for solving contingencies) are pro-
Figure 2.4 offers an overview of market time cured:
frames in the US and European contexts. This
•• In the case of ISO markets, reserves are usually
representation is simplified for clarity and main-
procured simultaneously with the energy mar-
ly focuses on the most relevant differences be-
ket (in the US ISO’s terminology, they are often
tween the two paradigms.
co-optimised).
The figure indicates when each process takes •• In Europe, operating reserves are organised by
place and the time scope covered. For example, the system operator after9 the energy market
the day-ahead market in Europe takes place in results are known. Therefore, the procurement
the morning of the day prior to electricity deliv- is sequential in this case. (The drivers and im-
ery (operating day – 1) and covers all 24 hours of plications of this alternative are discussed in
the delivery day (operating day). Figure 2.4 also Section 2.2.5.)
specifies whether the process is an energy mar-
ket, where products are traded directly between
market players, or a system operator’s centralised

Figure 2.4 Short-term market time frames: An overview

Operating Day -1 Operating Day

Day Ahead
Energy Reliability Unit
ISO model

(& Reserve) Commitment Trading/Operating horizon


Market (ISO dispatch correction)

System Operator’s Market (Real-Time Market [RTM])

Day Ahead Day Ahead Ancillary


Energy services (Reserve
Trading/Operating horizon
procurement, Congestion
European model

Market
management...)

Intraday Energy Markets

System Operator’s Market (Ancillary and Balancing Markets)

0:00 Day D
Energy Markets: traded directly between market players System Operator’s centralised markets Trading/Operating horizon

9. Reserve resources can also be procured prior to the day-ahead energy market through longer-term agreements
(e.g., through monthly tenders/auctions).

41
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
After the day-ahead market and the reserve pro- correct their deviations without any type of in-
curement process(es), the system operator takes tervention from the system operator. After that
actions to ensure the reliability of the system. The point in time, the final binding production sched-
timing and scope of these actions are similar in ule is determined for all participants, and only the
both contexts.10 These actions are needed after system operator can adjust any deviation. The
the day-ahead market because this market does timing of the last gate closure represents the di-
not account for all the physical complexities of viding line between markets and pure system op-
the power system. As mentioned above, in the EU erations.
case, this lack of detail is partly the consequence
•• In Europe, the last opportunity for a market
of decoupling the system operator’s responsi-
agent to change its schedule in hour h (or in a
bilities from the functioning of the spot market,
market time period x), without the system op-
isolating as much as possible the energy trading
erator’s intermediation, is the closure of the last
from the complexities of the network-constrained
intraday market session in which energy can be
dispatch model. This separation comes at a cost,
traded for that delivery period h (see following
which is the appearance of potential infeasibilities
section on intraday settlements), see Box 2.2.
that have to be later solved by the system opera-
•• In the United States, this dividing line between
tor. In the United States, although the objective is
markets and purely system operations is slight-
to include all the details in the energy market pro-
ly different. Once the day-ahead market closes,
cesses, it is still found that today, “the full alter-
the ISO calculates the so-called reliability unit
nating current representation of the transmission
commitment (RUC), which corrects the sched-
system cannot currently be explicitly included
ule for the day after. The ISO first clears the
in the market software despite the use of state-
day-ahead market and develops the necessary
of-the-art computational tools” (FERC, 2014c).
corrections. It checks either for eventual trans-
Some operational and reliability considerations
mission constraints that could not have been
remain impossible to incorporate into the day-
fully captured by the security-constrained eco-
ahead market process. As a result, the system
nomic dispatch optimisation model, or seeks
operator also needs to undertake some follow-up
to adjust cleared bids to the ISO’s forecast of
actions in US electricity markets.
load and RES production or as a result of the
Apart from the previous issues, which are analysed co-optimisation of both the energy and reserve
in subsequent sections, there are three fundamen- markets (see Section 2.2.5). In principle, mar-
tal design decisions related to the time frame of ket agents are not supposed to re-adapt their
markets: 1) the definition of the time threshold bids from that point on, so to some extent this
within which bids have to be presented in intr- would be the gate closure. However, market
aday energy markets and beyond that only the agents, under certain specific and well-justified
system operator can take action/dispatch re- circumstances, are allowed to update their day-
sources through its centralised (balancing) mar- ahead offers. This reoffering period may end a
ket (the so-called last market gate closure or sim- few hours to a few minutes before real time.
ply the gate closure); 2) the timeline and format
The increased uncertainty on real-time opera-
of intraday energy markets (run by the market
tions, partially as a result of the growth of vari-
operator in the European Union and by the ISO in
able renewable energy, is stimulating this de-
the United States) and 3) the settlement period.
bate. And again, the discussion revolves around
These designs are discussed next.
the boundaries between the market and the sys-

−− Reoffering period and gate closure tem operator’s competencies. As discussed in


the next subsection, in principle, widening the
Until the so-called last gate closure, market
scope of the market provides market agents with
agents are allowed to balance their positions and

10. Although some ISOs integrate several reliability processes into the day-ahead market, as discussed in Section 2.2.5.

42
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

incentives to do their best to minimise their im- ity. Therefore, having the gate closure away from
balances. This can be of utmost relevance as RES real time would be preferable to faciliate the task
penetration rises since allowing market agents of the system operator and to reduce system se-
to update their offers closer to real time would curity costs. In deciding the point in time when
improve the accuracy of their forecasts. (Miller, market participants have the last opportunity to
2015)11 On the other hand, forcing the transmis- change their schedule, benefits (from a RES pro-
sion system operator (TSO) to operate too close ducer point of view) and costs (from the system
to real time could require procuring reserve re- operation point of view) should be compared.
sources in larger amounts and/or of higher qual-

Box 2.2 Short-term electricity market timeline in Italy

Day-ahead market tion are made known by 12.55 p.m. on the day before the
day of delivery. The MGP’s auction selects bids and offers
In the day-ahead market, electricity is traded one day be-
based on economic merit-order criterion, taking into ac-
fore the operating day. In a wholesale market, electricity
count transmission capacity limits between zones.
can be traded day-ahead bilaterally (over-the-counter
trading) or on the day-ahead power exchange. Intra-day market
In Italy, the day-ahead-market, called the MGP, is an auc- The intra-day market (MI) allows market participants to
tion market, not a continuous-trading market. Bids and modify the schedules defined in the MGP by submitting
offers can be submitted to the MGP beginning at 8:00 additional supply offers or demand bids. The MI takes
a.m. on the ninth day before the day of delivery until 12:00 place in seven sessions: MI1, MI2, MI3, MI4, MI5, MI6 and
p.m. on the day before the day of delivery (Day — 1), when MI7. The schedule of each MI is as shown in the Table 2.1.
the auction process begins. The results of the MGP aucº-

Table 2.1 Bid sessions for intraday market in Italy

MI session Opening time Closing Time Result

MI 1 12.55 pm (Day -1) 3.00 pm (Day -1) 3.30 pm (Day -1)

MI 2 12.55 pm (Day -1) 4.30 pm (Day -1) 5 pm (Day -1)

MI 3 5.30 pm (Day -1) 11.45 pm (Day -1) 00.15 am

MI 4 5.30 pm (Day -1) 3.45 am 4.15 am

MI 5 5.30 pm (Day -1) 7.45 am 8.15 am

MI 6 5.30 pm (Day -1) 11.15 am 11.45 am

MI 7 5.30 pm (Day -1) 3.45 pm 4.15 pm

Source: Gestore mercati energetici, 2017.

11. But this may be relevant for thermal plants too since it would allow them to update thermal generation offers so they can represent
intraday changes in gas market prices.

43
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

−− Intraday settlements
2
(see also Box 2.4). Intraday markets produce pric-
Intraday markets in Europe perform two relevant es used to settle the incremental changes execut-
functions. First, as shown in Box 2.3, they allow ed in each market.
generators to make incremental adjustments to In the United States, ISOs perform intraday ad-
their energy schedules (resulting from the day- justments according to updated forecasts on the
ahead market), which improves the efficiency of evolution of the system (mainly related to load
the initial day-ahead programme. This can miti- forecasts and generation forced outages). These
gate the potential inefficiency of the day-ahead actions are adapting to a larger penetration of re-
dispatch due to the limitations of the European newable energy sources. These processes are not
bidding formats (see Section 2.2.3). Second, they equivalent to European intraday markets in one
recover the balance between demand and sup- key aspect: generally, no intraday price signals
ply if the forecasted system conditions change. are calculated in the United States associated with
For example, intraday markets are fundamental to these actions. This way, the US intraday actions do
accommodate renewable energy forecast errors, not establish binding economic transactions (for
and most European intraday markets have recent- they do not produce binding prices). All deviations
ly been modified to improve their performance

Box 2.3 Intraday markets and schedule adjustments

Intraday markets are useful platforms to accommodate markets and which, also due to the impossibility of sub-
possible forecast errors (e.g., on demand or on renew- mitting multi-bid offers, could be technically unfeasible.
able energy production) as well as to modify the produc-
The need for intraday markets is closely linked to the fact
tion’programs of thermoelectric power plants (as shown
that deviations from programs (imbalances) are penal-
in Figure 2.5), defined as a result of day-ahead energy
ised. The intraday market therefore helps reduce the risk
of imbalances.

Figure 2.5: Example of schedule adjustments in intraday market

Unit X production program, Unit Y production program,


as defined in day-ahead market (MWh) as defined in day-ahead market (MWh)

20,000 30,000
25,000
15,000
20,000
10,000 15,000
10,000
5,000
5,000
0 0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24

Unit X production program, as changed in Unit Y production program,


intraday market (MWh) as changed in intraday market (MWh)

20,000 30,000
25,000
15,000
20,000
10,000 15,000
10,000
5,000
5,000
0 0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24

44
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

from the day-ahead programme are settled later tlement system in ISO markets dilutes these sig-
at the real-time price,12 i.e. the price that represents nals since all deviations are settled at the real-time
the value of the electricity in real time (taking into price. The important role of intraday markets and
account the actual condition of the system), cal- signals has also been confirmed by other analy-
culated every five minutes through a unit-commit- ses on market design. For example, the Interna-
ment-like model (similar to the one used for the tional Energy Agency (IEA, 2016) pointed out that
day ahead but with updated information). “transparent intraday prices are necessary to in-
form all market participants about the cost of serv-
Ideally, generators deviating from the day-ahead
ing the next megawatt”, and also that “the design
programme should receive signals representing
in North America could be further improved by
the cost associated with the deviations. These
providing greater transparency of the evolution of
costs can be lower if deviations are known in ad-
locational prices during the intraday timeframe”.
vance. For example, a renewable energy source
having a lower output than anticipated in the
day-ahead forecast could require other resources
−− Continuous
in Europe
versus discrete intraday markets

to fill the gap. If the deviation is known only a few


European intraday markets, pending a unified de-
minutes before real time, this deviation will likely
sign (XBID project), have been implemented by
require fast-start units or expensive flexible gen-
Member States using two methods: 1) discrete
erators, but if notified several hours in advance,
auctions, in which auctions are called at specific
the operator has enough time to adjust the out-
predefined times (Figure 2.6, upper part) and 2)
put of inflexible resources more economically.
continuous trading, in which bids can be submit-
Intraday prices in Europe capture the different ted and matched at any time before gate closure
value in times of deviations, while the two-set- (Figure 2.6, lower part).

Figure 2.6 Time frame of European intraday markets

Operating Day -1 Operating Day


Day Ahead Energy Market
Day
Ahead
EU Intraday Markets: Auction vs Continuos trading

Intraday Energy Market (IM)


Intraday Auctions

Market
IM1
IM2
IM3
IM4
IM5
IM6
IM7
TSO’s Ancillary and Balancing Markets
Day Ahead Energy Market
Day
Intraday Continuos Trading

Ahead Intraday Energy Market (IM)


Market

IM1

IM2

TSO’s Ancillary and Balancing Markets

0:00 Day D
Energy Market Bidding Energy Market Bid Selection Intraday Energy Market Bidding Period
period and Bid Selection
Trading horizon Energy Market Process TSO’s Market Process Input for TSO’s market

12. The day-ahead and the real-time markets make up the so-called two-settlement system.
45
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
As shown in figure 2.6, auctions provide for dif- Flexibility versus liquidity
ferent times for bid submission and selection, Calling auctions at specific, predefined times
whereas with continuous trading, bids can always provides market agents with limited flexibility to
be submitted, and once submitted, they can be change programmes since the market can only
selected at any time. As a consequence, intraday capture these changes at the subsequent auc-
auctions have different sections open at the same tion. From a flexibility point of view, this is less of
time, each collecting different bids and with its an issue if auctions are held frequently.
own results, even though the trading horizon can
partially overlap. Intraday continuous trading, in- The potential advantage of discrete auctions is
stead, is characterised as having just one session that they may provide higher liquidity since they
at a time, with a shortening of the trading horizon concentrate transactions reflecting all the accu-
(i.e., of the hourly products that can be traded) mulated events since the last session. Clearly,
as time passes. increasing the frequency of these auctions may
negatively affect their liquidity. Discrete auctions,
Figure 2.7 presents the intraday market designs therefore, need to be configured depending on
implemented across different European pow- the system characteristics, and they need to en-
er systems, which are based on two criteria: 1) sure sufficient liquidity.
whether these markets are continuous or auc-
tion-based and 2) which entity owns the trad- On the other hand, continuous trading provides
ing platform used to carry out those transactions greater flexibility (since trading is possible at any
(i.e., is the ownership based on a power exchange time). However, as is the case with too frequent
[PX], TSO or bilateral?). discrete auctions, continuous trading may result
in insufficient liquidity.
Each of the two above-mentioned alternatives
(i.e., continuous and auctions) has the following
characteristics, advantages and disadvantages.

Figure 2.7 Intraday trading arrangements across Europe

Spain Poland:
Auction

Italy physical

Germany:
15 min auction
Poland:
financial

UK
Continuous

Germany

The Kingdom of Netherlands

Bilateral Exchange - based TSO - based redispatch

Source: Adapted from Neuhoff et al, 2015

46
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

Pricing cross-border capacity es in the level of consumption/production from


in continuous markets RES are managed through regulation resources).
Debate continues as to whether intraday auc- However, the product traded in energy market is
tions can more efficiently price the cross-border standardised in the sense that it is assumed that,
transmission capacity compared to continuous in order to comply with the commitment to sup-
trading. The major problem is that in a continu- ply/withdraw the energy sold/purchased in the
ous trading context, cross-border transmission market – i.e., in order to be balanced – it is suf-
capacity is allocated on a first-come, first-served ficient to do so “on average” within predefined
basis; this does not allow scarcity to be properly temporal windows, named settlement periods
priced in transmission. In other words, transmis- (also referred to as trading periods) that are typ-
sion capacity is allocated little by little at a zero ically one hour long. It is the TSO’s role to assure
price until it becomes congested (and at that pre- that the system is continuously balanced; to do
cise moment, there is no more available spare ca- so, all balancing resources have to divide up in
pacity to allocate). sub-periods (e.g. 15 or five minutes) their previ-
ously assumed production commitments. Then
A potential solution: hybrid design the TSO in the balancing and ancillary services
A hybrid design, combining a flexible continuous markets negotiates changes in their net produc-
market with a number of discrete auctions with tion level in each of those sub-periods (or dis-
concentrated liquidity, may represent a suitable patch periods), and this updated program will
trade-off. The question is: to what extent can determine the final schedule based on which un-
adding auctions to continuous intraday trading balancing penalties are applied.
actually improve the performance of the market?
Given that for balancing resources (typically ther-
In Germany, the implementation of an addition- mal power plants) it is more efficient to produce
al local intraday auction (called at 3:00 p.m.) to at a constant level, they will try to uniformly dis-
complement continuous trading is assessed by tribute the planned output of a settlement peri-
Neuhoff et al. (2016). The analysis shows how od through the different sub-periods. This means
trading volumes, liquidity and market depth13 in- that the higher the demand (or the RES produc-
creased after the auction’s implementation. This tion) volatility within a settlement period, the
is in line with previous observations showing more actions the TSO will have to implement to
that liquidity in European power markets based balance the system. Thus, as the RES production
on continuous intraday trading (e.g., in the cen- quota increases, it becomes more important to
tral western states) is lower than in markets hav- reduce the size of the settlement period for VRE
ing auction-based intraday trading (e.g., Italy and plants as well.
Spain).
The length of the settlement period is particularly
These discrete auctions can be called either at relevant for trades close to real time. This is why
specific predefined times or upon the occurrence we first discuss the role of the settlement period
of particular events (e.g., a forced outage of a in the very-short-term markets and then extend
large plant, a high forecast error, etc.). the discussion to the day-ahead market.

−− Settlement and dispatch period Settlement period in intraday


and very-short-term markets
A safe and reliable system requires that ener-
gy supply always equals energy demand. As the In the United States, the real time market produc-
demand, as well as the production from renew- es five-minute dispatch instructions (Figure 2.8),
able sources, continuously fluctuates over time, and prices are also computed every five minutes.
the (marginal) cost of producing electricity varies However, all ISOs, except the New York Indepen-
almost continuously (even though small chang- dent System Operator (NYISO), have traditional-

13. M
 arket depth is the market’s capability to sustain large market orders without affecting the market price. It can be measured
as the amount of electricity that is offered at certain prices during certain time periods.

47
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
Figure 2.8 The time frame of US real-time markets

Operating Day - 1 Operating Day

Day Ahead
Reliability Unit
Energy
Commitment
ISO model

(& Reserve) Trading/Operating horizon


(ISO dispatch correction)
Market

System Operator’s Market (Real-Time Market [RTM])

0:00 Day D

RTM

5 minutes
RTM
RTM
RTM
RTM
RTM

Energy Markets: traded directly between market players System Operator’s centralized markets Trading/Operating horizon

ly calculated average hourly prices to settle re- of reserve needs and use – long periods create
al-time transactions to simplify the metering and systematic deviations as a consequence of artifi-
settlement process. This simplification is widely cially breaking a continuous and smooth demand
viewed as relatively inefficient, and the Federal into discrete steps. Figure 2.9 shows the system
Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) recently imbalance in Germany for every minute of the
issued Order 825 (FERC, 2016) requiring all ISOs day during 2011. Imbalance deviations are larger
to settle energy transactions in the real-time mar- around the end and the beginning of each hourly
ket in five-minute intervals. period. These leaps around full hours can also be
observed in grid frequency (see Weißbach and
Recent concerns regarding the integration of re-
Welfonder, 2009). As previously mentioned, this
newable generation (due to short-term variabil-
is due to the fact that, conventionally, the pro-
ity, as discussed earlier) had already motivated
duction/consumption programs are uniformly
sub-hourly settlements in some US ISOs – such
distributed during the settlement (or dispatch)
as in the California Independent System Oper-
period, whereas the actual demand and produc-
ator (CAISO), where 15-minute settlements are
tion changes continuously within each settlement
already implemented; or in the Midcontinent In-
period.
dependent System Operator (MISO) and the
Independent System Operator New England As a consequence of this inefficient use of re-
(ISO-NE), where currently changes are being im- serves, Germany opted to reduce the settlement
plemented. However, taking into consideration period in intraday trading down to 15 minutes, i.e.
that “a movement to sub-hourly settlements may at time when VRE production and demand can
be costly and difficult to accomplish in a short pe- be better predicted (see box 2.4), though some
riod of time” (PJM, 2015b), the FERC allows addi- EU systems still use longer settlement periods in
tional time for full implementation of this reform. intraday markets. The intraday market is usually
aligned with the balancing market, where TSOs
Dispatches and prices are less granular in Europe-
charge for imbalances between supply and de-
an systems. Using long settlement periods (e.g.,
mand, measured in 15-minute intervals (Germany,
one hour) has relevant consequences in terms

48
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

Figure 2.9 Average German system imbalance for every minute of the day during the year 2011

1,000

500
(Mean) [MW]

-500

-1,000

-1,500

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23
Time (Hours of the day)

Source: Adapted from Hirth and Ziegenhagen, 2015

the Kingdom of Netherlands, and Italy for quali- its Day-Ahead market could significantly increase
fied units), 30-minute intervals (France, the Unit- the computational time” (NYISO, 2015). Other
ed Kingdom) and hourly intervals Italy, Poland and ISOs do not see clear advantages: “ISO-NE be-
Spain for non-qualified units) (Neuhoff et al., 2015). lieves that the potential benefits of sub-hourly
settlements in the day-ahead market are differ-
The European Commission (2016a) has recently
ent, and likely to be much smaller than in the re-
proposed a regulation explicitly requiring market
al-time market.” The potential drawbacks include
operators to allow trading energy in intervals as
those noted by MISO (2015): “Due to the imper-
short as the imbalance settlement periods (i.e.,
fect knowledge of real-time net load or unex-
aligning intraday and balancing markets), which
pected outages one day ahead, scheduling at the
is at 15-minute intervals in all Member States.
sub-hourly level may actually worsen the consis-
While this proposal will improve granularity in
tency and cost-efficiency than scheduling at the
electricity markets, its projected implementation
hourly level with some robustness”.
date – January 2025 – is not very ambitious.
In the European context, the above-mentioned
Settlement period in the day-ahead market
European Commission (2016a) proposal requires
A more debated topic is whether subhourly set- the use of 15-minute intervals in both the day-
tlements should be used in day-ahead markets. ahead and intraday markets. This measure will
CAISO (2015) sees many advantages in doing have the positive effects of increasing granular-
so: “Among the possible benefits of sub-hourly ity in wholesale markets and aligning electric-
settlements in the day-ahead market are align- ity products from the day-ahead market with
ing unit commitment decisions between the day- the balancing market (therefore preventing in-
ahead and real-time timeframes, […] improve efficient arbitrage opportunities). The poten-
forward scheduling of variable energy resources tial drawbacks of sub-hourly settlements found
and help align the CAISO ramping requirements in ISO markets (mainly, excessive computational
with resource operating characteristics”. Howev- complexity) should also be expected in Europe,
er, a more granular day-ahead market could re- although the use of 15-minute intervals (instead
quire excessive computational complexity; for of five minutes) may alleviate the challenge.
example, “The NYISO has concerns that imple-
menting sub-hourly commitment scheduling in

49
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
2.2.2. Locational granularity of prices
Box 2.4 Intraday markets and forecast accuracy
and schedules
Market participants submit their offers in the day
ahead market based on their assumption of the ac-
High shares of VRE deployment, particularly
tual system conditions and on their forecasts for re-
wind, might lead to an increasingly constrained
newable energies. As the time of delivery approach-
transmission system. It is reasonable to assume
es, the accuracy of renewable generation forecasts
increases (see figure 2.10 upper part). The intraday
that zonal pricing mechanisms may lead to
market enables market participants to better reflect
higher inefficiencies with high penetration
these forecasts in their positions. levels of VRE, both in the short and in the long
run, compared to nodal pricing.
Moreover, quarter-hourly products are traded in
the intraday market which enable a better approx-
imation of the real demand ramps and variable A number of regulatory options address the is-
renewable energy than the hourly products at the sue regarding the allocation of limited transmis-
day-ahead market. This is especially important since sion capacity for transactions among players un-
imbalance settlement periods are on a quarter-hour- der normal market conditions.14 These options fall
ly basis. Figure 2.10 (bottom part) shows the differ- into two main groups: pricing algorithms that in-
ence between hourly and quarter-hourly products volve a detailed representation of the transmis-
and their accuracy in representing actual feed-ins. sion network, and those that consider a simplified
one (this is true for all market segments, even if
Figure 2.10 Approximation of realized load different approaches can be used for each seg-
and forecast errors in intraday markets ment):

•• Nodal pricing applies security-constrained eco-


Day-ahead Intraday
forecast error forecast error nomic dispatch to derive locational margin-
al prices – i.e., the prices paid for the energy
Forecast / realization

consumed or generated at a given transmission


node (a substation or any other element that
creates a discontinuity in the grid). Nodal ener-
gy pricing provides an accurate description of
the technical and economic effects of the grid
Time on the cost of electricity. It implicitly includes
Day-ahead forecast Intraday forecast Actual realization the effect of grid losses and transmission con-
gestion, internalising both effects in a single
Hourly products 15-min products value (monetary unit per kilowatt hour [kWh])
that is different at each system node. Therefore,
Feed-in / load

nodal prices are perfectly efficient signals for


economic decisions concerning the short-term
operation of generation and demand since they
correctly convey the economic impact of losses
and constraints at all producer and consumer
Time
locations.
Source: Adapted from TenneT, 2017
•• With zonal pricing, the power system is ad-
ministratively divided into zones, within which
little congestion is expected. Price differentials
reflect only transmission congestions consid-
ered relevant by the regulator or the system
operator. Different degrees of spatial resolution
are possible (France and Germany feature only
one price zone, while Italy has ten). Accurately

14. S
 ee, for example, Rivier et al. (2013).

50
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

defining stable zones is not a straightforward must withdraw from the system and which are
task. Zones do not match national borders and to be included. Energy removed to solve a net-
can change hour by hour alongside the chang- work constraint may be paid at the respective
ing supply/demand equilibrium. An example is agent’s bid price (if a specific bid related to the
provided in Figure 2.11, where the effect of wind constraint-solving mechanism is in place), at the
output on zone definition is shown. opportunity price (the energy market price less
the price of the agent’s bid in the energy market)
With zonal pricing (as with single-node ap-
or not at all. When additional energy is request-
proaches that consider an entire grid as a single
ed, it is normally paid at the respective agent’s
node), a re-dispatch may be necessary to solve
bid price.
congestions (this is true for all market segments).
In the (supposedly) few cases in which grid con- The pros and cons of nodal and zonal pricing have
straints are detected, the system operator re-dis- long been debated by experts and policy mak-
patches the system, determining which players ers. Several issues are to be taken into account

Figure 2.11 Simulation of suitable zones for zonal pricing in Europe (maximum wind)

500 N

400 N

W 300 E

00 200 E
100 E

Maximum wind No wind

10 28 46 64 82 100
Energy price at nodal level (Euro/MWh)

Source: Adapted from Neuhoff, 2015

51
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
when estimating the benefits of these two ap- RES and the efficiency of locational granularity
proaches: the efficiency of the resulting price sig- The planning process in liberalised electricity sys-
nals (both in the short and long term), the com- tems may be more difficult than within vertically
putational burden and implementation costs, the integrated utilities because decisions about gen-
hedging complexity and the impact on the liquid- eration expansion are the result of market forces
ity of long-term markets and geographical con- influenced by policies and regulations rather than
sumer discrimination. In usually congested elec- centralised planning.
tricity networks, the benefits from nodal pricing
seem to outweigh the disadvantages (Neuhoff When generator build times are shorter than
and Boyd, 2011). On the other hand, in densely those for transmission, planners are forced to ei-
meshed grids, where power flows are easily pre- ther anticipate new generation and build poten-
dictable and significant congestion infrequent, tially unnecessary infrastructure or wait for firm
zonal pricing does little to affect the efficiency of generation plans before starting the process,
the resulting price signals. At the same time, larg- thereby potentially discouraging investment in
er bidding zones are believed to increase liquid- new generation. Since, in the vast majority of cas-
ity and competition, and zonal prices represent es, it takes much longer to plan, get approval for
a more stable signal for investors and tend to be and build a high voltage transmission line than it
less discriminatory for consumers. does to plan and build a wind farm or solar gen-
erating facility, transmission reinforcements are
Nonetheless, many arguments used to support often significantly delayed.
zonal pricing are questionable. In nodal markets,
financial transmission rights can provide produc- Furthermore, in the case of wind, for example, the
ers the long-term hedge required to sell their best and most efficient sites to develop projects
productions in forward markets to operators lo- are clustered around certain geographical areas.15
cated elsewhere in the system; at the same time, Therefore, unless (and until) transmission scales
end-consumer tariffs can be calculated using any at the rate of the new RES generation build, the
geographical granularity, i.e., averaging nodal transmission system will be increasingly con-
prices, if the regulator considers this necessary strained around these areas, requiring more ac-
for the sake of equity, which prevents exposing curate network representation. In this context, a
some end users to higher local prices. Probably shift towards a more detailed spatial resolution
the most relevant obstacles to the implementa- in the wholesale market, and therefore the use of
tion of nodal pricing arise from institutional and nodal prices, may represent a useful solution.
governance issues. In the United States, market
2.2.3. B
 idding formats: fitting new
integration is challenging because of the required
necessities and resources
co-ordination among different institutions and
harmonisation among diverse regulations. The
challenge is even greater when market integra- A large deployment of VRE requires more
tion must take place across different countries, as complex bidding formats to guarantee an
in the European Union (see Box 2.5) efficient economic dispatch. Bids may need
to include an explicit representation of
Next, we briefly discuss how, in most real-world
technical constraints, as done, for instance,
cases, a high penetration of variable generation
in the US ISO market model.
resources may aggravate the potential inefficien-
cy of zonal pricing.
As illustrated in this chapter, the variability and
partial unpredictability of the increasing amounts
of RES that are being deployed in power sys-
tems increases complexity and uncertainty in the
short-term scheduling process.

15. R
 elevant examples of onshore wind include Texas, where most of the wind mills are located in the west; Germany in the north and
Romania in the southeastern region of the country, close to the Black Sea. Obviously the problem of geographical location is even
greater in the case of offshore wind.

52
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

Box 2.5 Market integration in the European Union

Market integration is a key driver to promote overall effi- To promote efficient cross-border trades, seven European
ciency and foster competition in the EU electricity market. Power Exchanges developed an initiative (price coupling
of regions, or PCR) to develop a single price coupling
The EU electricity market consists of a number of inter-
solution to be used to calculate electricity prices across
connected markets. A deep coordination among them is
Europe and efficiently allocate cross-border capacity on
needed to maximize the efficiency obtainable through
a day-ahead basis.
cross border trade between market areas, given the avail-
able interconnection capacity. It must be noted that market integration is an issue not
just with regard to energy markets, but also with refer-
Figure 2.12 shows electricity flows between EU markets
ence to the actions TSOs have to take to maintain the
in the Central Western European (CWE) region, driven by
system secure.
the corresponding cross-border trades, in 2016.

Figure 2.12 Annual total of physical cross-border flows in the CWE region and at the German borders in 2016
(in TWh)

NO
4.2

SE 1.1
0.3

DKW DKE 0.8


0.9 1.7

3.6 1.8

9.1
GB 0.1 1.2
NL PL
8.7 0.3
7.7 14.8
DE
1.1
1.8
BE
4.4 6.4
CZ
11.2
5.1
7.6
FR 3.9
2 10.4
15.7
AT

1.6
CH 1.1

Source: Adapted from TenneT, 2017

Figure 2.13 shows the increase in inter TSO imbalance consisting of 11 TSOs, the largest imbalance netting co-
netting – which in turn corresponds to a reduction of the operation in Continental Europe. On 2 February 2016, the
balancing actions required to maintain the systems secu- French TSO RTE joined the IGCC. As shown in Figure 2.13,
rity – made possible by a deeper inter TSO cooperation. inclusion of this large Load Frequency Control Block has
To be more precise, figure 2.13 shows the results of the resulted in a significant increase of the netted volumes.
International Grid Control Cooperation (IGCC) currently

53
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2 Figure 2.13 Monthly volumes of netted imbalances for all IGCC members for the imbalance netting process

2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

500

400

300
GWh

200

100

0
January
February
March
April
May
June
July
August
September
October
November
December
January
February
March
April
May
June
July
August
September
October
November
December
January
February
March
April
May
June
July
August
September
October
November
December
January
February
March
April
May
June
July
August
September
October
November
December
January
February
March
April
May
June
July
August
September
October
November
December
AT BE CH CZ DE DK FR NL

Source: Adapted from TenneT, 2017

Short-term markets are nothing but tools that aim we find two major approaches to the bidding for-
to help both market agents and system operators mat design: 1) the more complex ISO bidding for-
approach this objective in the most efficient way mat (used in the United States) (see Box 2.6), and
by optimising economic risk management for the 2) the simpler PX format (used in the European
former and achieving short-term reliability and Union).
security levels, a responsibility of the latter.
ISO bidding format and increasing penetration
In this context, the format of the bids that mar- levels of RES
ket agents can use influences the ultimate mar- In the US, in principle, increasing the penetration
ket outcomes. The alternatives and the flexibility of RES need not significantly impact the com-
made available to market agents when building plexity of the format applied to existing resourc-
their bids is central to allowing them to reflect es since the model is already based on complex
their true costs and the physical constraints of and detailed (multipart) offers. That being said,
their generation units on the energy market. Bid- enhanced modelling software, made possible by
ding formats differ from one market to another, developments in computing technology, has al-
and they can range from a simple price-quantity lowed a progressive increase in modelling detail
hourly bid (indeed, 24 price-quantity hourly bids) (O’Neill et al., 2011).
to a complex declaration of technical and eco-
nomic constraints. Where the model has to be further refined is in
integrating new resources, particularly those
While the optimal design of bidding formats has with characteristics that differ from the status
been an open question since the creation of elec- quo. This calls for a larger number of bidding
tricity markets, it has recently been revealed as a formats tailored to the needs of these new re-
critical subject that needs to be revisited. Again, sources. For example, in the relevant case of de-

54
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

Box 2.6 Bidding formats in the US ISO market: multipart offers

Independent system operators (ISOs) require generators ling a conventional generator, with the aim of defining the
to submit multipart offers aimed at representing the de- economic dispatch in the most efficient way.
tailed operational (and opportunity) costs and also the
Other bidding formats have also been implemented for
technical constraints of their generating units. Table 2.2
different types of resources, such as multistage resources
lists several typical offer components used while model-
(combined cycles), intermittent generation, pumped-stor-
age hydropower units and other storage units.

Table 2.2 Typical multipart offer structure in ISO markets

Operating costs Technical constraints

Energy offer curve MW, $/MW Economic min MW

Piecewise linear or stepwise linear function Economic max MW


with multiple MW/Price pairs
Ramp rate MW/hour

No-load offer $/hour Min/max run time hours, min

Min downtime hours, min

Start-up offer $ Notification time hours, min

Available for different types of start-ups Cooling time hours, min


(hot/intermediate/cold)
Start-up time hours, min

Note: Small storage, typically electrochemical storage, is in many cases only allowed to provide secondary frequency
control reserves (regulation).

mand response, as pointed out, for example, by lar demand. This was simpler to predict in a pow-
Liu et al. (2015) “the bidding system does not al- er sector with stable and predictable dispatches,
ways provide a mechanism as an alternative to but it becomes quite risky when the high pene-
the price-quantity bid format for consumers to tration of variable technologies can unpredict-
express their willingness to adjust consumption, ably alter the price.
particularly in response to price signals”. For in-
The main obstacle to creating more complex bid-
stance, an industrial consumer may need a cer-
ding formats is the computational complexity of
tain number of consecutive hours of supply, but
the associated optimisation model. This limiting
is willing to shift this period according to the mar-
factor is not as relevant to the EU model.
ket price. This willingness cannot be expressed as
a simple quantity-price bid during each hour; it The EU power exchange approach: the complex-
needs a complex bid format. ity of prioritising simplicity

A similar difficulty is related to the consideration As pointed out in the beginning of this chapter,
of storage technologies, as uneconomical sched- most European markets were designed with the
ules can often occur using current bidding for- explicit aim of reducing – as much as possible
mats. For example, they often have to define ex – the intervention of the system operator. Con-
ante (before knowing the market prices) both the current aims include: releasing market agents
periods when they want to act as producers and from the need to buy and sell through a com-
those when they want to procure energy as regu- pulsory pool (a market model that centralises all

55
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
trades and covers its costs through fees to mar- The main goal of the new bidding formats is to
ket agents), decoupling the format of bids from allow PX participants to hedge their risk against a
plants’ technical characteristics (costs and con- wrong estimation of market conditions (and thus
straints), and postponing as much as possible the minimise the risk of being scheduled in ways that
market gate closure.16 imply additional costs), while at the same time
ensuring that auctions are transparent and com-
Day-ahead markets in European power exchanges
petitive. This allows market agents to build strat-
were originally, and at least in theory, envisioned
egies that somehow internalise the potential im-
as simple electricity auctions, where most agents
pact of the physical and economic constraints of
would submit price-quantity offers and bids.
their portfolios in a more effective way than just
The reality is not as straightforward. For simple through simple price-quantity bids.
bids to be utilised in a context where the laws of
Early on, the use and impact of these complex
physics play such a strong role, market agents
and block bids was rather irrelevant. A simpler
must anticipate the resulting dispatch and inter-
approach was thought to ensure greater trans-
nalise all operational costs and constraints, a task
parency of clearing results. Today, the uncertain-
that, to be properly fulfilled, requires that market
ty that market agents face when building their
conditions be possible to predict (the lower the
bids has significantly increased, mainly due the
size and diversity of the portfolio of plants each
higher shares of variable renewable energy, and
market agent manages, the harder this task).
therefore the use of complex and block orders is
The increasing penetration of RES has increased on the rise (see Box 2.8).
uncertainty in the dispatch, making accurate
It is often argued that an increase in uncertainty
predications more difficult. This calls for bidding
and a lack of more accurate bidding formats are
formats that allow for greater complexity and re-
not necessarily problems if sufficiently liquid and
duce the burden for market agents. In response,
thus efficient intraday market sessions follow the
as seen in the Box 2.7, each PX has progressively
day-ahead market auction. Certainly, as we have
incorporated so-called block orders and semi-
seen, the role of intraday sessions is relevant to
complex orders, (rather than the multipart for-
allowing market agents additional resources to
mats used in the US ISOs).17 readapt the schedules resulting from the day-
ahead market clearing, but this argument is not
Box 2.7 Bidding formats in European without challenges.
power exchanges On one hand, the algorithmic complexity of the
European power exchanges use the EUPHEMIA mar- EU clearing mechanism does not handle large
ket-clearing algorithm in their day-ahead market to amounts of block bids well, the reasons for which
support the different bidding formats used by each will be reviewed in the next section. On the oth-
market operator. Simple bids can be used in all bid- er hand, market agents may in the future need
ding areas, but depending on the market operator, to combine increasing amounts of block orders
agents can represent some operational constraints in order to reliably represent their characteris-
and economic conditions using block orders or tics and hedge against different potential sce-
complex conditions (see Appendix: EUPHEMIA, the narios (see Appendix). This has led the current
pan-European market clearing algorithm). approach to be questioned since the number
Block orders basically entail an all-or-nothing con- of block orders can become impractical. In oth-
straint, representing the willingness of an agent to er words, properly hedging against all potential
sell/buy some amount of electricity at a given price, market outcomes may require bidding on an ex-
but only if this amount can be sold/bought fully. Ad- tremely large number of block orders. For this
ditionally, several block orders can be combined to reason, one of the root principles of EU PX is be-
create more complex products. ing reconsidered: the key idea is whether the al-
gorithm performance may be improved by us-

16. These and related aims are particularly apparent since the implementation of the New Electricity Trading Agreements.
17. I n some cases, the block and complex conditions were already implemented in the initial market design.

56
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

Box 2.8 Empirical evidence of the growing role of complex conditions and block bids in EU
power exchanges: the case of Spain

Figure 2.14 illustrates how, even in a power market with a It can be argued that when the amount of offers reject-
relatively large amount of hydropower reservoir resourc- ed by the algorithm becomes large, the efficiency of
es, the impact of complex conditions (in this case the the market results can be put into question. A market
minimum income condition, or MICa) increased alongside clearing based on multipart offers (as in the US ISOs)
wind penetration (Vázquez et al., 2014). The graph shows probably would not reject (all of) those bids and would
how, until 2005, the Spanish market cleared and behaved minimise the overall cost of supply. Indeed, multipart
as a simple auction; the number of offers rejected during offers allow producers to properly represent the tech-
the clearing process because of the MIC condition was nical constraints and the cost structure of the different
types of plants. Conversely, block bids seek to allow
close to negligible. Starting from 2006, however, due to
for only an extremely simplified representation of
the increased penetration of wind resources and the con-
those constrains, precisely with the risk of completely
sequent increased variability in the daily dispatch (more
rejecting the offers of some plants that, if they could
cycles and ramps for thermal units), the MIC conditions
offer multipart offers, would have been cleared for an
started being activated much more frequently. Many bids
efficient subset of hours. In recent years, the number
were rejected since the total income did not reach the
of complex conditions used by agents has remained
specified minimum.
relatively constant (PCR-ESC, 2015).

Figure 2.14 Evolution of the activation of the minimum income condition and wind production

Rejected energy through MIC activation (peak hour)


30
20
GWh

10
0
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Daily Wind Production

300
200
GWh

100
0
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Source: Adapted from Vázquez et al., 2014


a. As defined by the Spanish market operator, OMIE “sellers may include, as a condition governing the electricity sale bids they submit for
each production unit, that the bid in question is only to be considered submitted for matching purposes if the seller obtains a minimum
income. The minimum income required shall be expressed as a fixed amount in €, and as a variable amount expressed in €/MWh”
(Omel, 2001).

57
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
ing resource-­specific bidding formats that would These characteristics hold only under certain as-
only require one (multipart) offer per resource, in sumptions, including the absence of economies
line with the ISO approach already reviewed. of scale in generation and the absence of “lumpy
decisions” (Hogan and Ring, 2003), stemming,
As pointed out at the beginning of this section,
for instance, from “lumpy costs” (e.g., start-up
one alternative – recently supported in PCR-ESC
costs) or “lumpy constraints” (e.g., all-or-nothing
(2015) – is to resort to multipart offers. This ap-
commitments or minimum outputs).19 In reality,
proach involves greater complexity than blocks
electricity markets present multiple and unavoid-
or complex orders, but it is preferable if the multi-
able lumpy decisions.
part offer is able to replace multiple blocks. How-
ever, the EUPHEMIA provider has pointed out In the US ISO model, multipart offers contain
that including such a bid would involve a signifi- both lumpy costs and lumpy constraints. In the
cant change in the market design and pricing and EU contexts, simple bids do not introduce “lumpy
clearing rules, a design element which will be an- decisions” but block bids and other complex con-
alysed in the next section. ditions do. Thus, it is mathematically impossi-
ble to find uniform prices that support the wel-
2.2.4. Pricing and clearing rules fare-maximising solution (Scarf, 1994).

Practical implementation of marginal pricing


More complex markets require modifications therefore includes modifications that accord
to clearing and pricing models. more or less priority to the two above-mentioned
Of the two main approaches to pricing rules objectives. Two real-world examples follow.
and clearing – those of the US ISO (dispatch-
•• Optimal-dispatch-based (marginal) prices: The
based pricing plus discriminatory pricing) and
volumes accepted on the market are those of
the EU PX (price-based dispatch) – the best
the welfare-maximising solution (optimal dis-
option might be some point in between.
patch). However, a discriminatory pricing rule
must be applied to guarantee cost-recovery.
The key economic theory at the basis of electric- Marginal prices (e.g., hourly) are calculated, but
ity market designs is marginal pricing remunera- some agents may have to pay/receive an addi-
tion for generation. Under this principle, at each tional lump sum (uplift) to avoid cleared bids
point in time, electricity is supposed to be valued that would be at a loss if only marginal prices
at the marginal cost of producing (or not con- were considered. This approach sacrifices effi-
suming) an additional unit of energy. Ideally, this cient price signals for short-term operational
has two benefits: efficiency.
•• Uniform-(marginal)-price-based dispatch: A
•• First, the marginal price supports the welfare
uniform pricing rule constraint is imposed;
maximising solution.18 That is to say, accepted
i.e., all transactions in a given period (e.g., an
bids are sufficiently compensated, and rejected
hour) are settled at the same price. The level
bids are not profitable at the marginal price.
of (uniform) market prices in the various hours
•• Second, settling the transactions of all agents
of the day must therefore be such as to include
at the same price (uniform pricing) sends an ef-
– not necessarily in a perfect way – the impact
ficient signal for bidding true costs and for op-
of lumpy constraints and costs. This price con-
timal investment over the long term (the main
straint requires that the market solution deviate
argument in favour of the energy-only market
from the most efficient (social welfare maxim-
approach to ensure resource adequacy).
ising) dispatch.

18. Ventosa et al. (2013) define welfare maximisation as the “overall minimisation of system costs while respecting reliability and
environmental objectives and constraints.” See the same source for the economic formulation of social welfare in the power sector
context.
19. More exactly, the problem is the presence of non-convexities in the optimisation problem (the maximisation of the social welfare).
These non-convexities arise, for instance, from the discrete “jumps” in the cost function of thermal plants, which have a constant
variable cost, but only if a fixed start-up cost is incurred at the beginning of the commitment period.

58
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

Uplifts are unavoidable elements of the dis-


Box 2.9 Illustrating the need for uplifts
patch-based pricing system required to support
A plant submits an offer to the independent system the welfare-maximising dispatch. The underlying
operator (ISO), including its variable cost per mega- problem is the fact that not all costs incurred are
watt hour (MWh), along with other costs such as embedded in uniform market prices, which alters
start-up and no-load costs. Once the plant has been the correct signals. 20
committed, its variable costs and the variable costs
of other committed resources are the basic drivers of The problem with energy uplifts
the marginal price and the dispatch level of the unit. Resorting to uplifts not only prevents prices from
Absent other constraints (such as ramps), when the
reflecting the full cost of the serving load, but its
price is greater than the variable cost, the resource associated cost has to be somewhat arbitrarily al-
is dispatched at the maximum output, and when the located to energy consumers. Currently, the up-
price is less than the variable cost offer, the plant is lift calculation involves only the generation side
either shut down or operated at its economic min- of the market, taking advantage of the fact that,
imum (depending on whether it makes sense eco- because of demand-side inelasticity, it can be de-
nomically to de-commit the resource). termined ex post and then socialised. In a context
of active demand participation, the uplift alloca-
This setting illustrates two clear situations where the
tion should be incorporated in the market-clear-
market price may not be sufficient for the unit to re-
ing process to be consistent with the demand
cover its short-term operation cost:
side as well.
−− If the unit is marginal, then the price is equal to its As already mentioned in the previous section,
variable cost, and the unit will not recover its start-
up and no-load costs. one of the effects of RES penetration in electric-
ity markets is the increasing need for complex
−− If the unit is committed but dispatched at the eco- bidding formats, which aggravate the pricing
nomic minimum, then the price is lower than its vari-
problem. In the ISO context, this problem has re-
able cost (since the unit is not marginal), and the
cently attracted a lot of attention (see Box 2.10),
variable cost is not fully recovered through the mar-
and ISOs are undergoing design improvements
ket price.
aimed at reducing uplift. Proposed solutions at-
In these cases, and others, the resource needs to re- tempt to internalise all costs in market prices as
ceive an uplift payment in order to be dispatched at much as possible – in other words, to approach
the optimum level, as determined by the ISO, with- uniform pricing. This represents the increasing
out losing money. importance of short-term market signals needed
for efficient generation investment and the de-
velopment of demand-side resources (Hogan,
Next, we analyse the challenges involved in each
2014).
particular approach and possible solutions being
explored today. Pricing and clearing in the European Union:
Uniform-price-based pricing approach
Pricing and clearing in the United States:
The optimal-dispatch-based pricing approach Although one of the claimed objectives of the EU-
PHEMIA clearing algorithm is the maximisation of
In the United States, the ISOs first calculate the
social welfare, the algorithm considers two ma-
optimal dispatch and then compute prices based
jor rules to be fulfilled that condition the clearing
on the marginal cost of the system. On the basis
process and thus the corresponding associated
of these prices, uplifts are calculated to compen-
social welfare:
sate generators incurring costs above the revenue
earned through market prices. See Box 2.9 for an •• The single marginal pricing rule entails that uni-
illustrative example based on Bresler (2014). form market prices (without uplifts) must suf-
fice to compensate all accepted bids.

20. T
 his is instrumental, in theory, to leading long-term market decisions towards the optimal capacity expansion
(see Herrero et al., 2015).

59
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
Box 2.10 Uplifts: an increasingly relevant problem in some US systems

The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) initi- system constraints make necessary subsequent redis-
ated a docket to improve price formation among US inde- patches commanded by the ISO (FERC, 2014b).a
pendent system operators (ISOs). This docket identifies
While uplift cannot be completely eliminated, it can be
uplift as a major problem (FERC, 2014a):
largely reduced with appropriate market design, as stat-
“Use of uplift payments can undermine the market’s ed by Pope (2014):
ability to send actionable price signals. Sustained
“Uplift is a symptom rather than a cause of price
patterns of specific resources receiving a large
formation problems, though, and efforts to improve
proportion of uplift payments over long periods of
pricing should focus on correcting the causes”.
time raise additional concerns that those resources
are providing a service that should be priced in the
Such causes are varied, and the solutions will affect very
market or opened to competition”.
diverse parts of the market, but, undoubtedly, a key el-
ement is the method used to compute prices. A widely
Uplifts can occur for many reasons; the three primary
debated solution is the so-called extended location-
ones in ISO markets are: 1) the operating costs of some
al marginal pricing, which in the literature is known as
resources are not reflected in prices (the case reviewed
Convex-Hull pricing (Gribik et al., 2007). Essentially, this
in Box 2.9); 2) inflexible resources, such as the so-called
method would produce hourly prices that better reflect
block-loaded units, are committed and 3) unmodelled
the full cost of producing electricity (e.g., internalising the
start-up and no-load costs).

a. Inefficient price distortions become particularly evident for the case of block-loaded (or fixed-block) units, which are those that only
operate economically at full load. Fast-start gas turbines generally lie in this category. When these units are committed, other units
have to be dispatched down to accommodate the full output of block-loaded units. If block-loaded units are treated as non-dispatcha-
ble by enforcing a minimum economic output constraint, they cannot set marginal prices and, therefore, require uplift payments to
recover their operational costs.

•• Simple bids are given preferential treatment offs, and in the European context, uniform pricing
(over complex and block bids): if the market is considered an objective worth the loss in short-
price is above a simple bid price, the bid always term cost efficiency (or, more generally, welfare
has to be fully accepted (in the terminology maximizing). One of the advantages of uniform
used by EU PXs, “simple bids cannot be para- pricing is that demand and generation interact on
doxically rejected”). the market in equal terms, and it is not necessary
to define rules to allocate uplift that would inevi-
In the presence of “lumpy decisions”, these two
tably send inefficient signals.
rules make the market-clearing results deviate
from those obtained in the US ISO model. Box 2.11 The European approach does, however, present
(based on Olmos et al., 2015) offers an example some problems that compromise the sustainabil-
of how these two rules may affect market results ity of this model, namely: 1) the complexity of
and divert them from those obtained in the US the algorithm limits the amount of complex and
ISO model. The example is based on a block-load- block orders that can be handled in practice; 2) a
ed plant. As was noted in Box 2.10, inflexible re- certain lack of transparency in the algorithm be-
sources are among the major reasons why uplift ing used; and 3) the inability of some units to set
is needed in the United States. the market price.

The European market-clearing mechanism makes Computational complexity


the short-term dispatch of generation units devi- One of the major practical downsides of the EU
ate from the welfare-maximising dispatch. As ar- approach is that integrating clearing and pricing
gued before, however, this is a matter of trade- in one step is inevitably a problem harder to solve

60
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

Box 2.11 Illustrating the difference between the US and EU pricing and clearing

Consider a one-hour market setting and an inflexible block


type of plant. To illustrate how lumpy decisions are dealt Figure 2.16 Result with the ISO model approach

with in the EU and US approaches, it is useful to consider


the market setting represented in Figure 2.15.

Within the generation bidding curve (in blue), we introduce

$/MWh
a block order (dotted line). This is an all-or-nothing type of
bid that is either completely matched or completely reject-
ed. The marginal price is the cost of supplying a marginal Welfare
increment in demand, and it corresponds to the variable
cost of the margin unit, i.e., the unit in the position of sup-
Indivisible
plying such marginal increment. Because of the block-order Pa
condition, the bid represented with a dotted line will never
be marginal, for it cannot “marginally” supply an additional
MW
MWh of demand due to its inflexible nature.

In the EU Price Coupling of Regions (PCR), EUPHEMIA


Figure 2.15 Pricing and clearing in the presence
also seeks to maximise the welfare, but at the same time
of lumpy bids
it has to comply with the two rules previously outlined:
the uniform market price (no uplifts allowed) and the full
acceptance of simple bids if the bid is below the market
price. Since the indivisible block needs a price equal to or
$/MWh

above its offer to be accepted, it is not possible to par-


tially accept any simple bid below that price. As a conse-
Indivisible quence, the algorithm rejects the block order. This leads
All-or-nothing block
to the dispatch depicted in Figure 2.17: the most expen-
sive bid cannot be accepted because it exceeds the price
of the demand bid. Therefore, only part of the demand
will be supplied, and the price is set by the partially ac-
cepted demand bid. As can be observed by comparing
MW Figures 2.16 and 2.17, welfare is much lower with the sec-
ond clearing approach.
In the United States, the welfare-maximising dispatch re-
quires reducing the production of a cheaper flexible plant
to make room for the indivisible bid. Since the indivisible Figure 2.17 Result with the EU PX model approach
bid cannot be marginal, the price in the market is set by a
lower-price bid (Pa in Figure 2.16). With such a price, the
block-loaded plant would not recover its short-term pro-
ductions costs. Thus, the need for an uplift. In the figure,
$/MWh

the orange horizontal line represents the price of the de-


mand bid (a single inflexible demand bid is considered). As
explained in Ventosa et al. (2013), the social welfare can be Welfare
represented as the area contained between the cleared de-
mand curve and the cleared offer curve (green area in the
Indivisible
figure 2.16).

MW

Source: Olmos et al., 2015

61
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
than the economic dispatch problem followed by “The effect of defining an order as a block is
an ex post price (van Vyve, 2011). that the order cannot then be a full price mak-
er. Rather, block orders may impose a bound on
This led some PXs in the precoupling era to lim-
the range of prices possible while the price be-
it the amount of block orders that could be used.
ing set would still need to come from the simple
Further developments in computing and solving
order or complex order curves. This is because
techniques allowed for an increase in the num-
the decision to execute the order is an integer
ber of block bids that could be handled, as well
decision (i.e., the order is executed or not ex-
as the introduction of new block bid formats. The
ecuted) and the decision on whether to accept
increasing use of these formats is, however, threat-
a block occurs before the price determination
ening the sustainability of this approach.
sub-problem. The bound created by the last ac-
Transparency cepted block order would function to affect the
The EUPHEMIA algorithm has to deal with a diffi- price (by limiting possible values) but could not
cult combinatorial problem: deciding which com- directly set this price”.
plex and block orders are accepted and which are “This was discussed with the PCR ALWG rep-
rejected. How EUPHEMIA accepts and rejects the resentative, APX, who confirmed that without
orders is reason for debate. It is difficult to justify the blocks setting the price, the price could only
why some orders are rejected by the EUPHEMIA be set by other price makers, i.e., simple orders
algorithm when the prices would not allow them or complex orders, or the price indeterminacy
to be accepted at a loss (these are the paradox- rules of EUPHEMIA”.
ically rejected blocks, or PRBs; for example, the
indivisible block in Figure 2.17 is rejected even if The European approach requires simple enough
the clearing price is higher than its offer). In PCR- bids to ensure the price is representative of sys-
ESC (2015), the Market Parties Platform (MPP) tem costs. In a scenario where most bids are
pointed out that: “There may exist false PRBs: re- block orders, the market price will not accurately
jected in-the-money blocks that could have been indicate the marginal cost of meeting the load.
accepted and result in a better (higher welfare) Trends in US and EU pricing rules:
solution. MPP asks for more transparency on op- towards a hybrid solution?
timality, to prove the absence of false PRBs”.
The problems highlighted in US and EU pricing
This is linked to the computational complexity rules share the same primary causes and could
problem, which has led to a complicated clear- therefore benefit from similar solutions. To some
ing algorithm. The public documentation of the extent, the novel pricing methods discussed
market-coupling algorithm (PCR PXs, 2016) is in the US ISO context can be seen as a middle
not completely detailed. The joint response of ground between the reviewed US and European
ACER and the Council of European Energy Regu- approaches.
lators (ACER-CEER, 2015) to the European Com-
While the trend in the United States is to advance
mission’s Consultation on a new Energy Market
towards a hybrid solution, this possibility is gen-
Design stated: “We would particularly like to see
erally ignored in Europe, where current efforts
clearer rules and greater transparency around
concentrate on improving the computational
the market coupling algorithm (EUPHEMIA)”.
performance of EUPHEMIA in order to cope with
Not all units can set the market price the increasing number and complexity of the bids
According to the authors’ best interpretation of that are used. However, it seems that more rad-
the public description (PCR PXs, 2016), the Euro- ical solutions may be needed to decidedly solve
pean pricing rule also suffers one of the pricing the complexity issue. In this respect, three long-
problems we have seen in the US model: inflex- term solutions are pointed out in PCR-ESC (2015):
ible block bids cannot set the market price. This
is confirmed by the thorough analysis carried out
by Eirgrid et al. (2015), who stated:

62
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

•• Reduce the amount of block types and other Although operating reserve requirements are a
complex products allowed per participant and regular requisite in electricity systems, defining
market (bidding zones). these requirements for security reasons is a clear
•• Reduce the range of products treated in EU- but well-accepted intervention of the central
PHEMIA. planner (the system operator in this case). The
•• Relax the uniform price requirement (accept system operator (See Box 2.12) needs to ensure
that the result has more than one price per bid- the availability of a certain level of operating re-
ding zone and time period). serves to tackle unpredictable short-term events
and avoid forced curtailment or cascading fail-
Among these, only the last one really tackles the
ures in the system.
root of the problem. In this regard, one of the
alternatives being discussed is proposed in van Two interdependent products
Vyve (2011), whose model resembles the ISO The values (prices) of reserves and energy are
approach in that it uses the welfare-maximising mutually dependent. The fact that generation
solution and compensates committed units at a plants can offer one or the other product links
loss through uplifts. the value of reserves with the opportunity cost
of providing energy, and the other way around
2.2.5. Rethinking reserve requirements
(Stoft, 2003).
and procurement
Because of this interdependence, if the objective
is to provide accurate short-term price signals, it
System operators need to implement new
must be taken into consideration that both the
solutions to improve the reserves supply
requirements and the procurement mechanism
function in such a way that they are priced
(co-optimised or not) for operating reserves mat-
according to their real value.
ter.
At the same time, energy and reserve markets
need to be properly connected in order to As discussed by Hogan (2013), in the face of effi-
allow the former to reflect the actual value of ciency, this calls for two relevant conditions in the
the latter. market design:

•• A proper definition of the operating reserve de-


Short-term energy markets produce dispatch in- mand curve (ORDC) is needed. Roughly speak-
structions that are very close to the actual deliv- ing, the ORDC needs to account for the real
ery of energy. However, the final power plants’ value that any amount of reserves has for the
output or the demand consumption can deviate system.
from these commitments. This calls for last ad- •• Energy markets have to reflect the opportunity
justments during real-time operation, which can cost of providing reserves and potential scar-
either be made automatically or by command of cities in the reserve product in such a way that
the system operator using different types of op- the prices of the two products maintain a stable
erating reserves (also referred to simply as re- and transparent linkage.
serves). We next analyse these two desirable require-
An operating reserve is defined by NERC (2015) ments.
as “that capability above firm system demand re- The operating reserves demand curve (ORDC)
quired to provide for regulation, load forecasting
System operators usually define a minimum con-
error, equipment forced and scheduled outages
tingency requirement for reserves. Below this
and local area protection” and is typically divided
minimum level of reserves, the load would be
under primary, secondary and tertiary frequency
curtailed to ensure that the reserve target is met.
control.
Usually, these quantity requirements are pro-
cured through market mechanisms. The demand

63
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
Box 2.12 TSO’s actions to ensure the availability of reserve resources

One of the actions undertaken by the system operator in Similar functions in US systems are carried out by the ISO
the ancillary services markets is to buy (sell) power from through the reliability unit commitment, where the ISO
(to) specific power plants to ensure the availability in the adjusts the day-ahead market’s schedules to take into ac-
system of sufficient spare resources capable of rapidly re- count its load forecast and all security constraints, includ-
sponding to dispatch orders in real time, so as to maintain ing the availability of adequate backup resources.
the system balanced (see Figure 2.18 for sample).

Figure 2.18 Sample of TSO’s actions to ensure the availability of reserve resources

Day-ahead (+intraday) results


PMAX PMAX

PMIN PMIN
PU1 PU1
PMAX TSO ancillary PMAX
Sold by TSO
services market
PMIN PMIN
PU2 PU2

PMAX PMAX

PMIN PMIN
PU3 PU3
Purchased by TSO
UP3 not running at all
Enough fast
Post day-ahead Post TSO’s ancillary
No reserve response
energy market service’s market
reserve

PU = Production Unit

curve in such a market is completely inelastic, 21 This minimum requirement and its value has been
i.e., a demand bid is put for the entire quantity long debated in the literature. Stoft (2003), for
(equal to the contingency requirement) at a price instance, says in this respect: “Operation reserves
equal to the value of lost load (VOLL). This means requirements, though based on sound princi-
that the willingness to pay for each MW of reserve ples, are rules of thumb that vary from one con-
up to the minimum contingency level is set to the trol area to another. Is it possible that each mega-
VOLL, while above this level, the marginal value watt of operational reserve is worth U.S.$10 000
of any additional MW is typically set to zero. The up to the requirement, but the next megawatt is
price for the operating reserve is then set accord- worth nothing? Is it possible that there is no limit
ing to supply bids from market agents. The in- on what the system operator should pay to meet
elastic demand bid on the reserve market reflects the last megawatt of the requirement?”
the priority that system operators assign to secu-
Resorting to first principles, probably what is
rity over economic efficiency, potentially leading
more questionable is the zero value above the
to over-procurement of operating reserves.
minimum contingency level. As described by Ho-

21. An inelastic demand does not change its consumption behaviour depending on the price. In the reserve market, the price almost
never reaches the VOLL level. Thus, in normal operations, reserves are procured up to the contingency level, no matter if their price
is 10 or 1 000 USD/MWh.

64
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

gan (2014), whenever there is in real time a forced in most US ISOs’ day-ahead markets. However,
load curtailment, the value of having available ad- the co-optimisation is not always carried out in
ditional amount of reserves (above the minimum the real-time market segment, where it is proba-
contingency requirement) would correspond to bly more important.
the VOLL during that period.
This is the case in ERCOT, where the market in-
At any previous time frame, such value would cludes co-optimisation of energy and reserves to
be probabilistic (based on the expectation of re- clear the day-ahead market, while the real-time
ducing the potential curtailment). In other words, market does not. This lack of co-optimisation has
the value of an increment of operating reserves led to the connection between the ORDC and the
would be the VOLL, but now multiplied by the energy market being implemented through the
probability that these additional reserves help re- second-best approach – that of using a price ad-
duce the curtailment. der to the energy price. This price adder aims at
replicating, approximately, the outcome of co-op-
This leads to an ORDC that has the shape of a
timisation (Hogan and ERCOT, 2013).
loss of load probability (LOLP) function, at least
above the minimum contingency level, as shown Figure 2.20, from ERCOT (2014), illustrates how
in Figure 2.19. the adder works and how it depends on the re-
serves available and the energy market price.
The effect of using such a curve would increase
On the one hand, the price of reserves depends
the price of reserves, and since the energy and
on the quantity of reserves procured: the higher
reserve prices should be “connected” in properly
the price, the lower the quantity, with the price
functioning markets, the energy price would also
being USD 9,000/MWh for reserve levels below
increase. This connection is further explored next.
2,000  MW. On the other hand, the adder that
Designing the market to allow energy prices “connects” the price of energy with the price of
to reflect the opportunity cost reserves will depend on the gap between the pric-
of providing reserves es of both products, and will therefore depend
The co-optimisation of energy and reserves is the on the level of reserves and the price of energy.
textbook solution that results in the appropriate This way, for a reserve level below 2,000 MW and
valuation of energy accounting for the oppor- an energy price of USD 9,000/MWh, the adder
tunity cost of providing reserves (and the other would be close to zero (for the energy price is
way around). This is the approach implemented already reflecting the non-served energy price).

Figure 2.19 Operating reserves demand curve

12,000

VOLL
9,000
Price of Reserves (USD/MWh)

8,000

6,000

4,000

2,000

0
0 2,000 4,000 6,000 8,000
Available reserves (MWs)

Source: Adapted from ERCOT, 2014

65
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
Figure 2.20 Price adder as a function of the energy However, for a reserve level below 2 000 MW and
price for different reserve levels an energy price of USD 2 000/MWh, the adder
will be USD 7 000/MWh.
$9,000 4,000
It is important to note that the value of the adder
$8,000 3,500 depends on the level of reserve available. Indeed,
$7,000 3,000 the adder’s goal is to properly price the energy
$6,000
2,500 sold in the day-ahead market. It requires taking
$5,000
2,000 into account the system’s scarcity, which in turn
$4,000
1,500
depends on the available reserve margin once ex-
$3,000
pected demand is satisfied. Therefore, the value
$2,000 1,000
of the adder grows at the shrinking of the avail-
$1,000 500
able reserve to reflect the higher risk of having to
$- -MW
unintentionally disconnect the load.
$ Energy $ Adder Reserves MW
Box 2.13 summarises the results of the backtest-
Source: Adapted from ERCOT, 2014 ing (involving years 2011 and 2012) carried out in
Texas to assess how energy prices would have
changed had this operating reserve demand

Box 2.13 Techno-economic analysis of the impact of implementing the ORDC in Texas
(Backtesting for years 2011 and 2020)

“The Public Utility Commission of Texas (PUCT) request- “The back cast analysis shows that the energy-weighted
ed that ERCOT perform a back cast of an interim pro- average energy price increases over a range of $7/MWh
posal that intended to be a more appropriate method of to $26.08/MWh in 2011 and $1.08/MWh to $4.5/MWh in
pricing reserves. The back cast approximated the pricing 2012. This range results from different parameter settings
outcomes and estimated what the market impacts may that were used in the back cast. The back cast results for
have been if the solution devised had been in place for the the average energy price increase with minimum contin-
years 2011 and 2012”. gency levels (X) of 1375 MW and 1750 MW are presented
in Table 2.3. At the minimum contingency level, scarcity
prices achieve the maximum allowed value”.

Table 2.3 Energy-weighted average energy price adder (and online reserve price)

Energy-weighted average price Energy-weighted average price


increase with X at 1375 MW (S/MWh) increase with X at 1750 MW (S/MWh)
VOLL
2011 & 2012 2011 & 2012
2011 2012 2011 2012
combined combined

$5000/MWh 7.00 1.08 4.08 12.03 2.40 7.28

$7000/MWh 11.27 1.56 6.48 19.06 3.45 11.35

$9000/MWh 15.54 2.05 8.87 26.08 4.50 15.42

Source: Hogan and ERCOT (2013).

66
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

curve been implemented with a co-optimisation 2.3. BALANCING MARKETS


of energy and reserves (Hogan and ERCOT, 2013).

In the European Union, as introduced above, Properly designing balancing markets


there is a separation between energy markets is essential to ensure that:
and reserves markets. As briefly illustrated in the
1) A
 ccurate incentives for flexibility are
next section, they are sequential markets where
offered
agents can (and indeed do) withhold capaci-
ty from the energy market (though including in 2) All resources can effectively participate
their bids the opportunity costs of providing re- in offering their flexibility potential to
serves in the ancillary service market) to provide system operators.
reserves. 22 This way, one market ideally reflects
the opportunity cost of providing the other ser-
In the previous section, we discussed a multitude
vice. Unfortunately, in real life, the information is
of issues related to day-ahead and intraday mar-
not perfect, and undesired deviations from an ef-
kets and introduced the concept of gate closure.
ficient outcome are likely.
After gate closure, the system operator must en-
Co-optimisation, although representing the first- sure overall system security and stability in real
based approach, would embody a major institu- time, which calls for an instantaneous (in the or-
tional challenge in the European Union today and der of seconds) matching of electricity supply and
so is not a realistic alternative. demand. Although RES obviously add complexi-
ty to this challenge, practical experiences have
The main problem with the EU approach is relat-
shown how power systems can be safely oper-
ed to the timeline of the procurement of reserves.
ated in real time with large levels of renewable
While there are frequent markets to procure and
production, provided that the system is prepared
sell energy, reserve markets are not so frequent.
for this. The question today, however, is how to
Typically, reserves are procured in a single ses-
ensure this real-time security in the most efficient
sion, whose lead time varies from country to
manner to better integrate large volumes of RES.
country (month ahead, week ahead, day ahead,
In this respect, there is a total consensus on the
etc.). This lack of frequent markets for reserves is
key role of properly designing balancing markets
a major drawback, preventing the effective con-
and mechanisms.
tribution and participation of many RES and dis-
tributed energy resources (DER). Furthermore, Technological innovation allows variable renew-
procuring reserves exclusively in the long term able energy technologies to provide ancillary ser-
may be inefficient because it does not allow for vices, ultimately contributing to system flexibili-
the complementarity between reserves and en- ty and reliability (See Box 2.14). A well-designed
ergy to be properly considered. balancing market should give incentives to all
types of resources, including conventional gen-
eration, demand and RES, to offer their flexibility
potential to system operators. Nonetheless, the
regulation governing the provision of these ser-
vices, hampers RES generators and DER from de-
livering them.

This section characterises the essential elements


of balancing services and markets with a direct
impact on the adequate integration of RES and
DER resources, also highlighting best practices
in their design. The section is divided into three
parts: 1) the imbalance responsibility and settle-

22. I n some EU markets the sequence is the other way around – reserves are procured before the energy.

67
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
the EU context, the unit for settling the total net
Box 2.14 Utility solar PV plant’s ability to provide
imbalances is known as the balancing responsi-
ancillary services to the grid
ble party (BRP). The imbalances from the pro-
The technical capabilities of utility-scale PV plants gramme declared at gate closure are measured
to provide ancillary services have been known for and charged to these BRPs.
a number of years. Such features have also been
recently proven in commercial settings. A recent
In the words of ENTSO-E (2014), “in a liberalised
study on a 300 MW PV plant carried out by CAISO, market, the market players have an implicit re-
NREL, and First Solar shows that the solar unit per- sponsibility to balance the system through the
formance was able to meet the frequency regula- balance responsibility of market participants, the
tion response usually provided by natural-gas-fired so called Balance Responsible Parties or BRPs. In
peaker plants. This is another demonstration of the this respect, the BRPs are financially responsible
contribution that utility-scale solar farms, equipped for keeping their own position (sum of their in-
with advanced inverters and software controls, can jections, withdrawals and trades) balanced or to
offer to smooth out grid fluctuations, enhance sys- help restore system imbalance over a given time-
tem flexibility and reliability, and reduce needs in frame”.
spinning reserves.
The allowed aggregation level for measuring im-
Source: CAISO, 2017
balances conditions the quantities that are sub-
ject to imbalance charges (since imbalances with-
in the BRP in opposite directions compensate
ment, 2) the definition of the balancing products
each other). The criticality of the aggregation lev-
and 3) the design of markets for procuring bal-
el will be explained later, as it is very much related
ancing reserves and their pricing and remunera-
to the adopted pricing scheme.
tion schemes.
Imbalance settlement
2.3.1. B
 alancing responsibility
The other element that completes the imbal-
and imbalance settlement
ance charges is the price to be applied. There are
two major price schemes that can be applied to
Dual imbalance pricing does not reflect BRPs for their net imbalances: the single- and du-
imbalance costs and therefore distorts the al-pricing schemes.
real-time price signal.
In the single imbalance pricing scheme, imbal-
How to define balancing responsible parties ances are always settled at prices representing
(BRPs) is a contentious issue when coupled the procurement costs of the balancing services
with a dual imbalance pricing scheme. used by the system operator. This is the approach
When dual imbalance pricing is applied, followed in the United States23 and some EU sys-
portfolios to conform to a BRP gives a tems (e.g., Germany). With this mechanism, the
competitive advantage to large companies and price that the BRP pays when it is short and the
introduces entry barriers to small providers. price the BRP receives when it is long are the
same for each point in time and space, and it is
determined by the price of the balancing ser-
Balancing responsibility vices. This way, settling imbalances results in a
The imbalance responsibility and the imbalance zero-sum operation for the system operator.
settlement are two of the most important and
Sometimes, it is pointed out that the single im-
controversial cornerstones of balancing mecha-
balance pricing scheme can lead to speculative
nism design.
behaviour where BRPs may seek to deviate in real
Imbalances are measured and settled at different time to be remunerated for helping the system.
aggregation levels depending on the system. In System operators fear this potential behaviour

23. T
 his is true, at least, for small imbalances. For large imbalances, depending on the system, there are additional, explicit penalties.

68
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

because, although it may help balance the system, A dual imbalance pricing penalises imbalanc-
it can also result in a situation where the TSO has to es, but a generation company can avoid imbal-
balance two imbalance origins: the original imbal- ance charges by compensating the (positive or
ance and the “speculation imbalance” if the BRP’s negative) imbalance with another plant within
imbalance estimation is wrong (SWECO, 2015). its BRP. 24 This gives a competitive advantage to
large companies in comparison to smaller ones,
The dual imbalance pricing scheme seeks to
and can effectively create a barrier to small DER
avoid the previous problem by reinforcing the in-
providers and aggregators.
centives to prevent deviations from the gate clo-
sure programme. This scheme applies an addi- If dual imbalance pricing cannot be avoided, the
tional penalty, on top of the price representing BRP should be defined on a unit-by-unit basis, so
the balancing procurement costs, if the BRP de- as not to create these competitive disadvantages.
viation is opposite to grid needs. For example, if
The reference market to measure imbalances
the BRP is short on production when there has
been a negative system imbalance in real time, Imbalances in the real-time operation are usually
the BRP will not only pay the costs of the balanc- measured with respect to the programme com-
ing services used by the system operator, but also mitted at the gate closure (roughly speaking, the
a penalty. This pricing scheme avoids speculative last intraday opportunity in Europe and the re-
behaviours, for, on average, the losses when pe- al-time market in the United States).
nalised will not compensate the profits when the There may be, however, additional penalties for
imbalance helps the system. This scheme also deviating in real time from the programmes de-
provides incentives, beyond the true short-term clared in previous market sessions, for example,
costs, to accurately forecast intermittent produc- for deviating from the day-ahead programmes.
tion at the gate closure. Using other markets can help allocate some sys-
There is a growing consensus that if the imbal- tem costs. Operating reserves are often procured
ance price does not exactly reflect imbalance precisely to deal with potential deviations from
costs, this distorts the real-time signal to agents the day-ahead market. This is the approach of the
and, therefore, may not provide correct incentives cost allocation design implemented in some US
to encourage flexibility (Olmos et al., 2015). That systems, such as the Pennsylvania Jersey Mary-
being said, if speculative behaviour is seen as a land Interconnection (PJM). Such cost allocation
real threat, there is a second-worst alternative to provides additional incentives to provide accu-
dual imbalance pricing, which is not allowing par- rate programmes in the day-ahead time frame,
ties to speculate under strict regulatory supervi- although it makes intermittent resources less
sion. Such an approach is not recommended if it competitive.
ends up artificially limiting market agents’ range Balancing responsibility for RES
of action.
Traditionally, variable RES generation has been
Defining balancing responsible parties when exempted from balancing responsibility in many
coupled with dual imbalance pricing countries. The main reason for exempting RES
Defining BRPs is a contentious issue when cou- from this responsibility, and socialising these
pled with a dual imbalance pricing scheme (if a costs, has been to encourage RES generation by
single imbalance pricing is in place, the level of further reducing investor risk.
aggregation allowed does not interfere with mar- In the United States, the FERC issued Order
ket signals). 890 (FERC, 2007) that, among other things, re-
vamped the energy imbalance provisions in Or-
der 888. Order 890 basically provides a pro-
gressive scheme by which larger imbalances pay

24. H
 owever, depending on the mix available in the BRP, paying the imbalance charges may be more economical than self-
compensating the imbalance.

69
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
larger imbalance charges, but also establishes and consumption, and dual pricing for conven-
softer conditions to protect RES. 25 tional generation.
Reducing investor risk at the expense of distort- 2.3.2. Balancing products
ed shortterm signals was considered an accept-
able trade-off when RES volumes were small. But
as volumes of variable RES generation increase, When designing balancing products,
these aspects may become significantly hard to it is helpful to:
control. For this reason, there is a growing con- · Define innovative products to unlock new
sensus on the need to make RES increasingly flexible resource potential,
responsible for their imbalances. This is an im-
· Give different price signals to resources
portant step towards the greater integration of
performing differently,
variable RES.
· Separate the procurement of, balancing
Despite this global trend, there are still some coun- energy, upward reserves and
tries that do not expose RES producers to balanc- downward reserves,
ing responsibility (See Figure 2.21 on EU countries).
· To the extent possible, avoid limiting
participation based on size or technology
Figure 2.21 RES balancing responsibility

Significant barriers to the participation of DER


Balancing responsibility for RES
and RES in balancing markets can be found in the
Country Balancing responsibility
details of product definition. To properly under-
Belgium Yes
stand this issue, it is helpful to review how bal-
Denmark Yes
ancing products are defined. Three criteria are
Croatia No
relevant: 1) whether it is a capacity- or an ener-
France No gy-based product; 2) whether it involves an up-
Germany FIP Only ward or downward balancing capacity/energy or
Ireland Partly not and 3) the time parameters involved.
Italy Partly Balancing capacity and balancing energy
Poland Yes
Balancing capacity gives TSOs the possibility of
Portugal Yes
activating a certain amount of balancing energy in
Spain Yes
real time. This refers only to capacity reserved in
Sweden Yes
advance for its subsequent use in real time.
Source: European Commission, 2016b Balancing energy, on the other hand, refers to the
actual variation of generation/consumption used
In several market designs, the calculation and in real time to fix imbalances.
pricing of imbalances may differ among conven-
Upward and downward balancing products
tional generation, consumption and renewable
generation. Some countries, such as Italy, have Upward balancing products are procured to com-
opted for applying single pricing for variable RES pensate a lack of generation in real time (or an
excess of consumption).

25 FERC Order 890 requires that imbalances of less than or equal to 1.5% of scheduled energy (or up to 2 MW) be netted monthly
and settled at the transmission provider’s incremental or decremental cost. Imbalances between 1.5% and 7.5% of scheduled
energy (or between 2 MW and 10 MW, whichever is larger) are settled at 90% of decremental costs and 110% of incremental costs,
respectively. Imbalances greater than 7.5% (or 10 MW, whichever is larger) would be settled at 75% of the system’s decremental
cost for overscheduling imbalances or 125% of the incremental cost for underscheduling imbalances. Intermittent resources, how-
ever, would be settled at 90% of decremental costs and 110% of incremental costs for imbalances greater than 7.5% or 10 MW (PJM,
2013). Apart from the previous regional applying regulation, additional RES exemptions can be implemented in each particular
system. For example, under NYISO’s market rules, if a variable generation resource is scheduled a day ahead, the resource must
buy or sell deviations at real-time locational marginal prices. However, for up to 3 300 MW of installed wind and solar capacity,
this generation is exempt from undergeneration penalties when its output differs from that scheduled in real time during uncon-
strained operations.

70
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

Downward balancing products are products pro- Box 2.15 shows some time parameters that are
cured to compensate an excess of generation used to define the standard characteristics of the
in real time (or a lower-than-programmed con- different products in the EU context (in the Unit-
sumption). ed States the parameters are similar).

Type of response (time parameters) Once the previous characteristics have been dis-
In order to deal with disturbances, the system op- cussed, we focus on considerations to be taken
erator usually makes use of three types of bal- into account in the design of balancing products
ancing products in a sequential process based on to ease the integration of RES and DER (Olmos
successive layers of control (ENTSO-E, 2014). The et al., 2015; NREL, 2016). Subsections that follow
names of these products vary by region: draw recommendations for such design.

•• Primary (US) or frequency containment reserve Innovative products to unlock flexible resources
(EU) The definition of new reserve products is a major
•• Secondary (US) or frequency restoration re- discussion in the United States and in the Euro-
serve (EU) pean Union, both to unlock existing flexibility and
•• Tertiary (US) or replacement reserve (EU) also to allow new flexible resources to efficient-

Box 2.15 Defining the characteristics of balancing products: The European approach

Transmission system operators (TSOs) have to define at quested power of the TSO. It is expressed in seconds if
least the following standard parameters in accordance the bid is not divisible and expressed in megawatts per
with the Network Codes on Electricity Balancing and second (MW/s) if the bid is divisible.
Load Frequency Control and Reserves (LFC-R) to allow
Full delivery period: the sum of [3] ramping period; [5]
minimum and maximum duration of delivery period and
[6] deactivation period.
Figure 2.22 Standard characteristics of balancing
products −− [3] Ramping period: (as described above).
Quantity
−− [5] Minimum and maximum duration of delivery period:
the time during which the balance service provider de-
livers the full requested power to the system.

4 −− [6] Deactivation period: the time from the start of phys-


ical deactivation of the unit until the full instruction MW
has been delivered; expressed in seconds if the bid is
Time
1 not divisible and MW/s if the bid is divisible.
2 3 5 6
Minimal duration between the end of deactivation period
and the following activation, which allows time to recover
Full Activation time
(from LFC-R) the capacity to provide the service once again.

Other characteristics are as follows.


Full Delivery Period
Divisibility: The minimum divisible unit of balancing en-
ergy expressed in MW for the divisibility of volume and
the exchange of balancing products (see Figure 2.22). expressed in seconds for the divisibility of the delivery
period.
Full activation time: The sum of [2] preparation period
and [3] ramping period. Validity period: The period defined by a beginning time
(hh:mm) and an ending time (hh:mm), when the bid could
−− [2] Preparation period: time required prior to delivery of be activated. The validity period is at least the full deliv-
the first megawatt (MW).
ery period.
−− 
[3] Ramping period: time when the bid is physically ac-
Mode of activation: Manual or automatic.
tivated, delivers the first MW and approaches the re-
Source: ENTSO-E, 2014

71
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
ly participate in electricity markets. The penetra- provide more efficient signals and result in an
tion of RES technologies increases the need for overall more economic system operation. The ex-
fast-ramping reserves, so this discussion is sup- perience of defining new products for which bat-
posed to become more important in the future. teries can provide fast-responding reserves has

For example, pioneered by CAISO (Galiteva and been successful in PJM (see Box 2.16).
Casey, 2015), there is a growing trend in the Unit- Different price signals
ed States to consider introducing requirements
In many US systems, it was usual to have differ-
for “flexibility reserves”. As pointed out, these
ent resources following regulation signals with
flexible reserves encompass a family of products
varying performance, but all equivalently clear-
that do not (yet) have a universal definition.
ing on the market under the same remuneration
In CAISO and MISO, flexibility reserve products (Benner, 2015). This was detected as a major con-
are typically designed to better prepare the sys- straint on new resources capable of providing
tem for expected and unexpected ramping, not better responses since that extra value was not
to resolve energy or capacity shortfalls. acknowledged on the market. FERC Order 755
(FERC, 2011), a performance-based regulation,
Some simulations (Krad et al., 2015) suggest that
changed this by measuring performance with a
these products will keep more resources available
standard metric and ranking the clearing based
in advance of ramping events (see Figure  2.23,
on performance and benefits.
which shows how the available fast-ramping ca-
pacity increases when flexibility products are The implementation of the performance-based
traded) and likely reduce scarcity price spikes as- regulation has been slightly different from one
sociated with ramping shortfalls. ISO to another, but in general, it has removed dis-
crimination against flexible resources, enabled
energy storage resources to profitably provide
Figure 2.23 Available ramping capacity with regulation services, and reduced regulation re-
and without flexibility reserve products
serve costs (Xu et al., 2016).

Separation of balancing capacity and balancing


7
energy products
6
When balancing capacity and balancing energy
5
Ramp [MW/5 min]

products are procured jointly, only the balancing


4
service provider having sold balancing capacity
3 can provide balancing energy in real time to the
2 system operator. Examples of markets with this
1 design include the Spanish and the Danish auto-
o matic frequency restoration reserve (FRR) mar-
kets, and the German automatic and manual FRR
106.4 106.6 106.8 107 107.2 107.4 markets.
Time [h]
The joint procurement of balancing capacity
With flex Without flex
and balancing energy products is often ineffi-
Source: Adapted from Krad et al., 2015 cient because it does not reveal the benefits of
the most-cost-efficient resources in real time. But
New, flexible resources may need new product what is even more important is that it limits the
definitions. This is the case, for instance, with bat- potential participation of renewable producers
teries, which can offer a quick response but can- and other DER participants.
not retain the response for long periods of time. In general, the procurement of capacity products
A new product designed to unlock battery poten- is carried out well before real time, so the system
tial can be compatible with current mechanisms, operator can ensure in advance the availability of

72
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

Box 2.16 Defining innovative products for batteries in the United States

Following FERC Order No. 755 (FERC, 2011), the Pennsyl-


vania Jersey Maryland Interconnection (PJM) implement- Figure 2.24 Conventional regulation signal (blue)

ed a performance-based regulation. Resources providing and the faster regulation D signal (yellow)

frequency regulation are remunerated based on their


performance – how fast and accurately they respond to
PJM’s signals. Faster and more accurate resources receive
higher compensation.

PJM now has two separate signals. Conventional genera-


tion resources follow a traditional slower signal (Reg A).
Faster resources, such as batteries, follow a dynamic or
fast-responding signal (Reg D). 1 Hour

This separate fast regulation signal (Reg D) was de- Conventional regulation signal Faster regulation-D

signed to provide zero net energy required over a time


Source: PJM, 2013
period shorter than one hour (see Figure 2.24). Thus, this
product is energy neutral, meaning that the accumulat- tice, this calls for defining a rate of substitution between
ed signal will converge back to zero after a short time. traditional Reg A resources and dynamic Reg D resources
The implementation of this new signal removes a serious or, in other words, comparing the value of fast moving re-
obstacle to the participation of energy storage in PJM’s source‘s regulation with that of traditional reserves.
regulation market.
This has been carried out by means of the so-called ben-
This new market design uses two separate payments – efits factor (BF) curve (Figure 2.25). This curve expresses
one for capacity and one for performance. As of April the equivalence of both types of reserves and depends on
2015, there are several energy storage resources par- the amount of fast reserves procured. The x-axis represents
ticipating in PJM’s regulation market. Regulation D was the percentage of total reserves covered through fast-regu-
developed specifically for energy storage devices with lation reserves, while the y-axis represents the relative value
limited storage capabilities with respect to the maximum of these fast reserves with respect to conventional reserves.
capacity. (For example, lithium ion batteries typically op- As shown in the BF curve, the first MW of fast reserves (0%
erate to a 4:1 MW:MWh ratio.) That said, other technolo- in the x-axis) is worth 3 MW of slow reserves (y-axis). How-
gies can also provide such services (since 2014, hydro- ever, if the amount of fast reserves increases, this equiva-
electricity can qualify for Regulation D). lence lowers (even down to zero, for 40%).

The major challenge associated with defining different As also shown in the figure 2.25, the BF curve had to be
products updated recently because the equivalence acknowledged
during its early implementation proved to be too gener-
The major problem with this design is how to define the re-
ous and was leading to suboptimal results.
quirements for both types of regulation services. In prac-

Figure 2.25 Updated benefits factor curve to optimise operations under all system conditions

Updated Benefits 3

Factor Curve 2.5


Benefits Factor

New Benefits Factor Curve


2
Current Benefits Factor Curve
1.5
Cap for ‘Excursion’ Hours (26.2%)
1

Resources will be New Reg-D Cap (40%)


0.5
assigned unit specific
BF down the BFcurve, Performance Adj. MWs
as today 0 (offer MW* Preformance Score) -
0% 7% 14% 21% 29% 36% 43% 50% 57% 64% 71% MW and % of Regulation Requirement
(700MWs)
0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 500

Source: Adapted from PJM, 2013

73
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
sufficient resources to deal with real-time imbal- It is also an inefficient design, given that pow-
ances. For instance, in Spain, balancing capacity er systems, especially those with significant RES
is procured one day before real time; in Germa- penetration, can have very different require-
ny and Austria, balancing capacity is guaranteed ments for upwards and downwards reserves in a
one week before real time. In the case of intermit- given period.
tent renewable generators, committing capacity
Bid size requirements
within those time frames is a clear barrier that
can hamper their participation for all intents and A minimum bid size is often imposed for partic-
purposes (they cannot forecast their production ipation in balancing mechanisms. Such a thresh-
accurately in such a time frame, as seen in Sec- old is commonly introduced for the sake of sim-
tion 2.2 of this chapter). plicity and in order to maintain the computational
effort of clearing the market at an acceptable
A more efficient option is to decouple capac- level. However, depending on the minimum size
ity and energy provision. It is more efficient to requirement, smaller resource providers may be
procure, in advance, exclusive capacity from dis- prevented from participating. This is particular-
patchable units (and to ensure that those bal- ly true if, concurrently, the aggregation of indi-
ancing service providers providing capacity are vidual units’ offers (to comply in aggregate with
obligated to offer the amount sold on the balanc- minimum bid size) is not allowed. Even if a re-
ing energy market, perhaps by including a price duction of the size requirement would make the
threshold for them). At the same time, all resourc- market clearing more complex, it may effective-
es, including those with no balancing capacity ly increase the participation of RES and demand
committed, may participate in the balancing en- resources.
ergy market. This way, a variable RES unit, which
cannot sell balancing capacity much before real In Germany, the minimum bid size is 1 MW; in Bel-
time without incurring a high risk, would be able gium, 4 MW; and in the the Kingdom of Nether-
to sell surplus energy production (above fore- lands, 5 MW. The highest minimum bid size is that
casts) as balancing energy. implemented in Spain, which is 10 MW.

Examples of this design include the Belgian and Technology-specific products


the Dutch automatic and manual FRR markets The only prerequisites to providing a product
and the Danish manual FRR market. should involve objective technical evaluations
and tests. Allowing only certain technologies to
Separation of upwards and downwards reserves
provide a product, or similarly, not allowing cer-
In some systems, the reserve capacity product tain technologies to offer one (as is the case for
links the amount of upwards and downwards re- RES and DER on many markets) reduces compe-
serve capacity that has to be provided in what tition and the efficiency of the overall dispatch.
is sometimes called the “regulation band”. The
Spanish, Italian and the Danish system operators By the same token, the aggregation of resourc-
procure this band reserve product for the FRR es should be allowed to participate as long as
balancing capacity. compliance with the objective requirements is
demonstrated.
The definition of a single product for providing
upwards and downwards reserve imposes clear
barriers to the participation of renewable genera-
tors since the (opportunity) costs incurred by RES
for providing upwards reserves are much higher
than those for providing downwards reserves.

74
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

2.3.3. R
 eserve markets and pricing then the solution should not be to change the
of the products pricing rule but rather to fix the situation (or re-
turn to a regulated provision of the service).
When sufficient competition can be ensured, Marginal prices may be more volatile, but they are
and when products are homogeneous, the correct signals that reflect the real-time value
balancing services should be priced based on of flexibility and give the right incentives to the
pay-as-cleared schemes. resources that can respond to these price signals.
If market power is a problem, relying on a Furthermore, marginal prices provide efficient
market mechanism might not be enough. long-term incentives.

As was analysed in Section 2.2.5, most Europe- 2.4. L ONG-TERM SUPPORT


an systems do not procure energy and reserves MECHANISMS
in a fully co-optimised way. In the United States, Long-term mechanisms refer to those regulatory
meanwhile, the procurement of these products is instruments whose purpose is to guide genera-
usually co-optimised. The efficiency of one or the tion expansion according to the strategic view of
other process has already been analysed. governments and regulators. This strategic view
In some cases, the provision of a service (typical- includes capacity (or adequacy) mechanisms and
ly primary regulation) is obligatory and not remu- support mechanisms for RES.
nerated, while secondary regulation capacity and In general, generation capacity mechanisms and
additional upward regulation capacity are pro- some RES support mechanisms provide investors
cured through market mechanisms. with an additional and/or more stable remunera-
The pricing of balancing products can either be tion. However, there has been a major difference
based on pay-as-cleared or pay-as-bid mecha- between them. Conventional generation tech-
nisms. In many cases, the procurement is bilateral nologies could be financially viable in a well-de-
and so, by definition, these products are pay-as- signed and fully functional energy-only market,
bid. In other cases, pay-as-bid has been imple- i.e., they would be able to recover their total pro-
mented (and average reserve pricing) with the duction costs, including a suitable rate of return
objective of mitigating market power and reduc- on investment. 27 On the other hand, in the ab-
ing the volatility of prices. Moreover, pay-as-bid sence of a proper internalisation of environmental
clearing rules are mandatory when the products/ externalities, until very recently, some RES have
services procured by the TSO in a specific auc- not been competitive enough to be financially vi-
tion are not adequately homogeneous in terms able in electricity markets, either energy only or
of quality, location and time. Indeed, the adop- with generation adequacy instruments. As a re-
tion of a marginal pricing rule requires that the sult, they have historically needed an additional
market has been segmented into homogeneous support mechanism. Nonetheless, this does not
products/services and that a relation of substitu- automatically imply that they should be banned
tions among the different products has been es- from general capacity adequacy instruments, as
tablished. discussed in Section 2.4.1.

In general, the market price should be calculated Next, we introduce the capacity (or adequacy)
applying the marginal pricing. 26 If it is believed mechanisms and the support mechanisms for
that the market is prone to market power abuse, RES and later review the recommended trends in
their design today.

26. When it is impossible to separate the different products in groupings of similar products
(because of different qualities or times of negotiation), the use of pay-as-bid rules is justified.
27. This does not necessarily mean that in the absence of a fully active demand, the levels of reliability
achieved might not reach those desired by the regulator.

75
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
Long-term capacity mechanisms Support mechanisms for RES
A combination of market and regulatory failures Many of the most promising forms of RES once
is often believed to threaten the long-term se- faced significant barriers to growth, ranging from
curity of supply. If this is the case, to the extent their high capital cost and perceived risks to a
possible, the failures should be identified and re- market and regulatory structure designed to ac-
moved to allow the energy-only market to work commodate conventional fossil-based genera-
and give proper long-term incentives. From an tors. Policy makers to date have recognised that
investment perspective, long-term markets and in order to boost their deployment and eventually
long-term price signals are as important as prop- compete on the energy market, RES needed spe-
erly functioning short- and very-short-term mar- cific support policies.
kets (European Commission, 2015b). 28 Well-func-
Regardless of the mechanism to which RES re-
tioning long-term markets are a prerequisite for
sources finally have access, it is important that
a fully functional energy market. 29 Long-term
renewable technologies are exposed to market
hedging products are relevant for all market par-
signals as much as possible in order to achieve
ticipants and particularly essential for indepen-
their actual integration in power systems. They
dent non-vertically integrated agents.
can still receive economic support if needed, but
A liquid and efficient forward market helps pro- they should be increasingly required to partici-
vide optimal long-term price signals about fu- pate in all the segments of the market, including
ture market expectations. This, in turn, promotes the short and long term, and thus be responsive
long-term security of supply in a market-compat- to all market signals.
ible manner. Despite this essential role, well-func-
The ideal RES support framework should allow
tioning long-term markets do not happen sponta-
and foster this participation in the market, and
neously in electricity markets, and this represents
should take into consideration the revenues ob-
one of the major market failures affecting the
tained by renewable plants in all the markets (in-
long-term security of supply.
cluding energy, capacity and other services), in
In comparison with an energy-only framework, order to calculate the incentive required to make
long-term support mechanisms can help in re- the investment attractive and to make it available
ducing the investment risk premium. In the ab- to the project developer.
sence of well-functioning long-term markets, a
There are two main aspects to consider here: 1)
capacity remuneration mechanism can, in some
as far as technically possible, and taking into con-
cases, result in lower, but more stable, income for
sideration their specific characteristics, mature
generators.
RES technologies should increasingly participate
In this section, we analyse how the regulatory in all electricity markets and be exposed to the
design of these mechanisms should evolve and same incentive mechanisms as any other gener-
adapt to the future scenario, in which high pene- ation technologies (including capacity markets)
tration levels of renewables and DER are expect- and 2) if RES need technology-oriented support,
ed. It is important to bear in mind the experience the corresponding long-term mechanism should
accumulated over the past two decades in the be designed so that any distortion of the electric-
regulation of market mechanisms for generation ity markets is minimised.
supply and RES support instruments. Today, the
major objective of regulatory design must be to
improve the performance of these support mech-
anisms while minimising their impact on the cor-
rect market signals.

28. We refer here to time horizons between one and 15 years.


29. T
 his involves long-term energy markets and also long-term carbon markets
(e.g., the role of a properly designed emission trading scheme is fundamental in the EU context).

76
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

2.4.1. Generation adequacy of variable renewable technologies (and, in some


mechanisms and RES integration cases, generation overcapacity), hampers in-
vestments as much as uncertainty regarding the
long-term deployment of these resources (due
RES technologies should be allowed
to regulatory uncertainty as regards long-term
to participate in generation adequacy
planning and to uncertainty of learning curves).
mechanisms and be exposed to their market
This is certainly the case in those systems where
signals.
RES support policies have been unpredictable
because they did not stick to any consistent en-
The penetration of renewable energy technolo- ergy policy plan.
gies in power systems is often argued to be one
On the other hand, renewable technologies also
of the key reasons for the implementation of a
represent a valuable resource for security of sup-
generation adequacy mechanism. This is espe-
ply (Gouveia et al., 2014):
cially the case in Europe, where this penetra-
tion has already reached significant shares. RES, •• Regional markets can help manage fluctuations
whose installation has been driven, so far, by pol- in their electricity production by increasing
icy support, are claimed to depress prices in the the geographical scope and thus reducing the
short-term electricity market (Moreno et al., 2012; probability of a concurrent lack of renewable
Reuter et al., 2012). Furthermore, RES technol- energy. Developments in storage technologies
ogies have caused a significant decrease in the can also reduce these fluctuations on a smaller
load factors of many conventional plants, as can scale for each unit or plant.
be observed in Figure 2.26. These combined ef- •• Renewable sources may complement other en-
fects, together with their increased short-term ergy resources, and RE technologies construc-
volatility, are often claimed as major reasons be- tion time may be significantly shorter than that
hind the need for capacity mechanisms. However, of other technologies, as previously discussed
this is not completely correct. (Barroso and Batlle, 2011).
•• The cost of RES technologies, especially that
Increased price volatility in the short term, or the
of wind and solar PV, is swiftly decreasing, and
reduction of average prices due to the installation

Figure 2.26 Annual gross aggregated electricity production from gas-fired,


solar and wind electricity plants in the European Union

GWh
700,000
600,000
500,000
400,000
300,000
200,000
100,000
0
1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

Natural Gas Wind Solar

Source: Adapted from ACER-CEER, 2016b

77
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
these technologies are already, or will soon be, short-term market, as the remuneration is thought
able to compete with conventional technolo- to complement wholesale market revenues. 30
gies in several electricity markets.
In this context, the short-term variability of some
Depending on the type of technology and the de- renewables does not impede them from con-
sign of the mechanism, renewable technologies tributing to system reliability. Obviously, once
could also be able to participate in generation they are installed, their non-dispatchable nature
adequacy mechanisms, thus also competing with does not leave much room to manage them in
conventional technologies in the capacity market. the short run, but if proper incentives are imple-
Nonetheless, the ability of some RES technolo- mented, the investment process can be oriented
gies – like wind and solar PV – to contribute to to maximise system reliability (for example, by
the security of supply and to help relieve scarcity opting for those RES technologies or those sites
conditions is generally lower per unit of installed whose resources are positively correlated with
capacity than for conventional technologies. The the net needs of the system). If they are able to
RES contribution depends on the specific condi- deliver, on average, their expected contribution in
tions of the power system where they are locat- the medium term, they permit the saving of water
ed and on the typology of scarcity conditions, as in the reservoirs, regardless of the daily or hourly
analysed next. schedule of their production. Their participation
in a generation adequacy mechanism can there-
Variable generation in energy-constrained
fore be beneficial (see Box 2.17).
and capacity-constrained systems
In energy-constrained systems, e.g., in hydro- In capacity-constrained systems, scarcity condi-
power-dominated countries, the coverage of the tions arise because there is not enough installed
instantaneous peak load is not an issue, and scar- capacity available to meet the load at a given
city conditions are more related to dry seasons moment. Aggregating all the hours, the system
that could last for months. The system could cer- could certainly have enough energy available
tainly satisfy peak demand, but it would be un- to satisfy demand on a given day (more than
able to supply demand during the remaining enough prouction capacity in off-peak hours),
hours of the day/week. In this context, rationing but it lacks installed and available capacity to sat-
takes place due to a lack of available energy, not isfy peak demand. This type of potential scarcity
capacity. This situation is quite common, for ex- condition is found in many European and North
ample, in Latin America. Brazil is the paradig- American power systems and has prompted op-
matic example, with its huge hydropower facili- erators of these systems and market participants
ties and multiyear storage capability. It must be to model the very-short-term time frame in great
kept in mind, then, that in an energy-constrained detail. Generation adequacy mechanisms are also
system, the reliability product procured in a ca- focused on this time frame, which can be easi-
pacity mechanism is not capacity. For example, ly observed in the reliability product design. Es-
in some power systems in Latin America (as in pecially in the most recently introduced capacity
Brazil, Chile or Peru), generation adequacy mech- remuneration mechanisms (CMs31) – for example,
anisms take the form of long-term electricity auc- the British capacity market or the pay-for-perfor-
tions in which the reliability product is energy, or mance reform of the Forward Capacity Market
a call option on future energy (as in Colombia). of ISO-NE) – the reliability provider is required
In some cases, these auctions somehow “sub- to deliver its contribution during stress events.
stitute” for the energy market (as investors are These may be identified by the system operator
fully hedged from the fluctuations of short-term either at short notice (e.g., four hours in advance
market prices); in other cases (e.g., Colombia), in the United Kingdom) or no notice at all (the
the auctions let agents trade electricity on the case of the so-called “shortage events” in the
Forward Capacity Market).

30. See Maurer and Barroso (2011) for details.


31. C
 apacity remuneration mechanism is the term used in the EU context to refer to long-term security of supply mechanisms.
In the US context, the term resource adequacy mechanism is used instead.

78
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

Figure 2.27 Coincidence of solar energy with peak


Box 2.17 Wind penetration in Brazilian
demand in Colorado
long-term auctions

Brazil is a typical example of an energy-constrained 14,000 700


system. Its market is organised around different 12,000 600

Solar Generation (MW)


kinds of long-term electricity auctions, which de- 10,000 500

Net Load (MW)


termine the majority of the economic flows, leaving 8,000 400
only minor settlements to the short-term market. 6,000 300
These tenders also represent the generation ade- 4,000 200
quacy mechanism used in this country. 2,000 100
0 0
The outstanding participation of wind energy in the 1 12 24 36 48 60 72
Brazilian auctions has been celebrated worldwide
Base case net load Net load with PV PV
for the low prices offered by this technology. These
prices are related to the very high capacity factors Source: Adapted from NREL, 2013b
considered in the project planning, which range
from 30% to 60%. This high capacity factor not only
describes the amount of energy that each unit can This information can be used to define de-rating
sell in the long-term auction, but it also represents factors that constrain the amount of capacity that
its expected contribution to generation adequacy. RES can trade in a capacity mechanism, thus lim-
In fact, in the scarcity conditions foreseen in Brazil, iting the remuneration they can receive from it.
the variability of wind power does not impede these
plants’ contribution to system reliability. A well-designed regulatory framework for RES
development should be able to allow renewable
Also, Brazil’s penalties for underperformance reflect
participation in CMs in capacity-constrained sys-
the need for guaranteeing that enough energy is
tems, leaving to investors the definition of their
available during the year, more than that required to
risk-hedging strategy and the decision of wheth-
cover the peak load. The penalties are also for delays
er to enter into CM contracts or not (see Box 2.18).
in the construction of plants. Once installed, a minor
settlement is carried out every year, but the main Generation adequacy and interactions with RES
penalty scheme is represented by a cumulative four- support mechanisms
year performance assessment (IRENA, 2015), which
As has been mentioned, the debate over wheth-
clearly reflects the time dimension of the generation
er or not to isolate RES from market signals (and
adequacy problem in Brazil.
to what extent) has been intense. 32 The ineffi-
ciencies derived from reduced wholesale mar-
ket exposure were assumed to be outweighed by
In this context, the variability of renewable pro-
a reduction of investors’ risks. However, as RES
duction is an issue because if the RES are not
penetration has increased, the maturity of RES
available at the very moment when the system
technologies has reached a level that allows these
stress occurs (e.g., due to a lack of wind or so-
plants to be largely exposed to market mecha-
lar radiation), then they cannot contribute to re-
nisms. At the same time, the impacts of a lack of
ducing the shortage. The contribution of variable
market integration on the broader power system
RES to capacity mechanisms in capacity con-
have become more difficult to ignore.33
strained systems has to be evaluated using spe-
cific, well-known and widely available methods In principle, CMs should allow RES of all types to
(for solar and wind capacity values, see NREL participate in any kind of generation adequacy
(2013b;  2008); Figure 2.27). Statistical analyses mechanisms. This is already taking place in Bra-
can be used to calculate the likely production zil, where generation adequacy mechanisms are
from RES during the expected scarcity periods. a component of the income of RES. RES technol-

32. For example, in Europe the debate was around whether to use feed-in tariffs, tradable green certificates or auction-based mecha-
nisms – see, for instance, Butler and Neuhoff (2008).
33. See Fraunhofer ISI (2015) for a discussion of the growing impact of negative prices on European wholesale power markets.

79
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
Box 2.18 Renewable participation in PJM’s reliability pricing model

The Pennsylvania Jersey Maryland Interconnection (PJM) qualification phase prior to the auction. These factors,
is a large interconnected (capacity-constrained) pow- lower than those in the Brazilian case, represent the ex-
er system in the United States, whose generation mix is pected contribution of these units during scarcity con-
mainly based on conventional thermal plants. Its gener- ditions in the PJM. Since these conditions are related to
ation adequacy needs are covered through a capacity short-term shortages, the likelihood of RES resources be-
market called the reliability pricing model (RPM). RPM ca- ing available at the specific time when scarcity occurs is
pacity providers, selected through centralised auctions, estimated to be low.
commit to be available whenever the system operator
As for penalties, a capacity remuneration mechanism
requires their contribution to solve scarcity conditions.
reform being implemented in the PJM (as well as in the
In the 2017/18 RPM base residual auction, the main pro- ISO New England), inspired by the “pay-for-performance”
curement process of this mechanism, 803 MW wind pow- principle (see Mastropietro et al., 2015a, for details), in-
er plants and 116 MW solar resources were cleared (PJM, troduces severe penalties for underperformance. It is not
2014). On average, wind and solar units were assigned clear how this will affect renewable participation in future
a 13% and 38% capacity factor, respectively, during the auctions.

ogies started being cleared in specific renewable electricity rationing. This side of the mechanism
auctions, but they also ended up being selected is now being reinforced through the implemen-
in conventional long-term electricity auctions for tation of performance incentives. If the capaci-
new energy. As analysed in the next subsection, ty mechanism design is robust and the reliability
this convergence is not yet complete, and some product is technology neutral, RES participation
rules still need to be harmonised. in system reliability would be acknowledged –
and RES would be exposed to an economic sig-
Meanwhile, in capacity-constrained systems, re-
nal that prompts them to be available when the
newable energy technologies have so far partic-
system most needs them. If specific renewable
ipated in CMs to only a limited extent. In many
energy technologies/sources are technically able
countries, regulators decided that RES, which
to compete with other resources on a level play-
were already receiving some other kind of incen-
ing field, relevant renewable power plants should
tive (grants, feed-in tariffs [FiTs], etc.), were not
not be favoured, either through their exemption
eligible for the capacity mechanism remuneration.
from penalties or through overgenerous recog-
This was the case, for example, in the UK’s Capaci-
nition of firm energy/capacity. If RES units have
ty Market (DECC, 2014). The rationale for this deci-
to compete with conventional technologies, they
sion is that the capacity mechanism remuneration
should be subject to the same rules. RES support
represents an investment incentive. Renewable
mechanisms are not incompatible with this ap-
technologies, for which investment is already be-
proach. As mentioned above, the ideal RES sup-
ing incentivised by some sort of RES support
port scheme would deduct the estimated reve-
mechanism, are therefore not eligible since they
nues obtained by the renewable plant on all the
do not need further investment support.
markets, including the energy and capacity mar-
This argument misses the main point that we are kets, from their total costs. This would be done to
making here – that RES technologies need to be calculate the incentive required to make the in-
exposed to market signals. They should be in- vestment attractive, and to make it available to
tegrated into the wholesale market as much as the project developer, without spending unnec-
possible. Capacity mechanisms provide not only essary funds.
an investment incentive, but they are supposed
However, in real markets, several factors can
to provide market agents with incentives to fos-
complicate this simple theoretical discussion.
ter the availability of committed resources during
According to some stakeholders, if “subsidised”
scarcity conditions, with the objective of avoiding

80
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

Box 2.19 Renewable participation in ISO New England’s Forward Capacity Market

ISO-New England pursues generation adequacy through “protect” the capacity market from excessive renewable
its Forward Capacity Market. This mechanism has been participation, which could depress capacity prices, the
recently reformed to introduce stronger penalties for un- regulator introduced specific offer review trigger prices
derperformance (FERC, 2014d). for renewable technologies, which apply to all renewable
bids exceeding 200 MW in each auction. These trigger
Renewable penetration may grow significantly in the next
prices are intended to prevent uneconomic or subsidised
few years (wind represents 42% of generation project
new entries from distorting market prices by setting a
proposals). According to ISO-NE (2015), state subsidies
price floor below which new entrants must demonstrate
for renewable resources will put downward pressure on
their costs or withdraw from the capacity auction.
energy-market prices, but the capacity market will help
balance the revenue needs for conventional resources. To

renewable technologies are allowed to take provision can heavily impact the overall effective-
part in the capacity market, it may be difficult ness of the scheme in achieving its objectives. 34
to guarantee that they do not depress prices in
If renewable and conventional technologies have
capacity auctions (as they have already done in
to compete for the provision of generation ade-
the day-ahead market in some power systems).
quacy, they have to be at the same level. When
This concern is further described in Box 2.19,
possible, no discrimination should exist in the
which focuses on ISO-NE’s experience.
definition of the reliability product, and the same
The justification for the floor described in Box commitment should be required from all reliabili-
2.19 is flawed. The objective of a capacity mecha- ty providers, regardless of technology.
nism is not to compensate all generators for their
Two design elements must be carefully consid-
investment cost, no matter the resulting mix and
ered in order to avoid discrimination between re-
reserve margin in the system. Instead, the aim is
newable and conventional technologies. The first
to provide investors with incentives – when need-
is the performance incentive to which reliability
ed – to ensure that a capacity level that maxi-
providers are exposed, i.e., the penalty for un-
mises the social benefit is installed. If there is an
derperformance. The second is the methodology
excess of capacity due to wrong investment de-
used to calculate the firm energy/capacity that
cisions, generators will see the prices depressed
resources are allowed to trade in the generation
in the short and medium term. In such a context,
adequacy mechanism. Without a proper harmon-
they will most likely ask for a higher capacity re-
isation of these contract provisions, competition
muneration to ensure total cost-recovery. But
between renewable and conventional technolo-
note that, in this case, the remuneration should
gies will be distorted. This could seriously impact
be close to zero since no additional incentives are
the effectiveness of the generation adequacy
needed to ensure reliability.
mechanism in attracting investment and in guar-
Rules to be harmonised in capacity mechanisms anteeing reliable electricity supply.
When signing a contract in the framework of a Regional market context
generation adequacy mechanism, power resourc-
The importance of exploiting the synergies be-
es are committed to providing a certain reliability
tween RES development and regional market in-
product, which is defined in detail in the contract
tegration has already been underlined. Increas-
provisions. The design of the reliability product
ing the geographical size of the market helps
represents a cornerstone for the generation ad-
manage fluctuations in RES electricity produc-
equacy mechanism. Minor changes in a specific
tion, reducing the probability of a concurrent

34. Batlle et al. (2015) identify the main design elements of the reliability product.

81
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
lack of renewable energy. Furthermore, regional et al. (2015b), the basic requirement is to open
market integration permits a co-ordinated plan- CMs to cross-border participation. If resources
ning of generation infrastructures that exploits are allowed to trade their reliability in all capacity
the available renewable resources as efficiently mechanisms within the regional market, regard-
as possible. 35 less of their point of connection (that being the
only obvious constraint in the interconnection ca-
A well-functioning regional market, however,
pacity), they can still locate optimally. That said,
should encompass all time dimensions, including
some sort of co-ordination between the neigh-
generation adequacy. In this respect, differenc-
bouring TSOs will always be necessary (for exam-
es in adequacy mechanism choices coupled with
ple, to avoid one plant selling the same product in
a lack of co-ordination can undermine regional
different systems).
market integration. International integration of
national CMs is currently a major challenge (Per- This discussion is particularly relevant to the Eu-
ner, 2015). ropean Union, where the regional market integra-
tion process is advanced. The EU experience is
The implementation of different national CMs
to achieve a range of diverse reliability targets described in Box 2.20.
does not impede the optimal exploitation of re-
gional resources but requires a minimum level
of co-ordination. As mentioned by Mastropietro

Box 2.20 Cross-border participation in European Capacity Remuneration Mechanisms

In the European Union, market integration efforts have (2015b) highlighted that one main barrier to such partici-
focused until now on the security and the economic effi- pation is related to mistrust in the fulfilment of article 4.3
ciency of short-term time frames, i.e., the day-ahead and of the Security of Supply Directive (2005/89/EC), which
operation markets. Long-term, capacity remuneration states that “Member States shall not discriminate be-
mechanisms are being introduced with little co-ordina- tween cross-border contracts and national contracts”. In
tion. Their design seems to rely almost exclusively on the order to include generation from a neighbouring system
domestic generation mix in the corresponding Member in a capacity mechanism, the transmission system oper-
State, with the main objective of maintaining a reliable and ator of the country launching the CM must be sure that,
self-sufficient power system. Obviously this is at odds with during scarcity conditions, the foreign resources are able
a regional concept of the security of generation supply. to fulfil their physical supply commitment linked to the
capacity mechanism. Nonetheless, most electricity laws
This concern has been clearly expressed by all EU institu-
and national network codes in force in the Member States
tions, including in the recent consultation document from
still contain clauses that maintain that exports to other
the European Commission (European Commission, 2015c)
countries will be interrupted in case of a domestic emer-
which claims that mechanisms to ensure generation ade-
gency of supply.
quacy should be open to all capacity that can effectively
contribute to meeting the required reliability level, includ- This barrier can be removed only through greater co-or-
ing capacity from other Member States. Nonetheless, CM dination among system operators, who should commit
designs implemented or proposed so far in the European to fulfilling the Security of Supply Directive through the
Union (DECC, 2014; RTE, 2014; AEEG, 2011) do not allow modification of national (and regional) network codes
explicit cross-border participation. Mastropietro et al. and operation procedures.

35. Obviously, this implies the existence of a regional transmission network with the adequate cross-border interconnection capacity
and a regional transmission expansion strategy capable of following the evolution of the generation mix and the need for further
interconnections. This relevant topic, however, exceeds the scope of this section, which is focused on electricity markets, and thus
on activities open to market competition.

82
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

2.4.2. R
 ES promotion mechanisms and the two methods are similar in that they decou-
wholesale market integration ple actual production from the support price and
therefore do not interfere with short-term market
RES technologies may continue to require signals.
economic support. This support should Capacity-based mechanisms are characterised
become more market compatible. Several by several key design features that affect mar-
design options exist. A balance must be found ket compatibility. Four such features are outlined
between optimal investment incentives below.
and market compatibility.
Design feature 1:
Support payment, amount and timing
Many of the most promising forms of RES have
An obviously critical initial decision in any sup-
in the past years faced significant barriers to
port scheme is the overall size of the payment:
growth, ranging from their high capital costs
how much support does a project need to earn
and perceived risks to a market and regulatory
in the various segments of the market (includ-
structure designed to accommodate convention-
ing energy, capacity and other services)? There is
al fossil-based generators. In several countries,
significant risk in the decision, as an overly gen-
policy makers recognised that in order to boost
erous payment can lead to overinvestment in re-
RES deployment with the objective of eventual-
newable generation. On the other hand, too small
ly competing on the energy market, RES need-
an incentive may fail to attract sufficient invest-
ed to be promoted with specific economic in-
ment. One of the design features that affects this
centives. The cost of renewable technologies has
issue is the timing of the support payment, which
been progressively decreasing over the past few
can either be calculated ex ante or ex post.
years. Soon these units may be (and in some cas-
es already are) able to compete with convention- Most capacity-based support is determined ex
al technologies without the need for economic ante based on the expected cost of a particular
support. In some countries, however, incentives generation technology (as in Spain) or on the ac-
for renewables are still needed while the environ- tual cost of the project (as in the United States
mental externalities that RES mitigate are not in- with the Investment Tax Credit). Alternatively, the
ternalised in the market prices. size of the incentive payment can be determined
ex post based on actual costs and observed rev-
This section discusses the three major RES sup-
enues from the market. For example, if energy
port scheme classifications, namely capaci-
market prices turned out to be lower than ex-
ty-based mechanisms, production-based mech-
pected, an ex post capacity incentive could be
anisms and support mechanisms for prosumers,
adjusted to ensure RES plants are able to recover
and their compatibility to wholesale market inte-
their fixed costs.
gration.
Providing support upfront has the advantage of a
−−  Capacity-based mechanisms low administrative burden (it requires only a sin-
In purely capacity- or investment-based support gle transaction) and also rewards the best-per-
mechanisms, a remuneration is provided on a forming projects – the windiest/sunniest sites will
per MW installed basis (i.e., there is no energy or have an easier time covering any revenue short-
availability contract involved). These payments falls on the energy market and will therefore have
are intended to cover the difference between a an easier time attracting investors. On the other
plant’s upfront investment costs and any market hand, calculating the incentive ex post makes it
revenues. While the choice of paying based on easier to guarantee a certain level of cost-recov-
installed capacity or project cost has important ery, regardless of external factors, such as market
consequences, depending on the policy goals, prices or plant location.

83
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
Design feature 2: project relative to a reference facility. This has the
Choice of reference plant effect of distributing support costs to where they
Closely related to the timing issue is selecting a are needed: the projects in the best (windiest) lo-
reference plant for calculating the size of the ca- cations have their incentive reduced since they
pacity payment. The first decision is between us- are earning above-average market revenues,
ing the actual cost of a project versus using a ref- while projects in suboptimal locations receive a
erence cost, derived from a “typical” plant. The premium incentive to ensure they are able to re-
ITC in the United States is an example of the for- cover their investment costs (Purkus et al., 2015).
mer, while support schemes in Spain, Germany Design feature 4:
and Russia are examples of the latter (IFC, 2013). Minimum performance requirements
Paying based on actual costs is straightforward One of the consistent criticisms of capacity-based
and incurs a low administrative burden, but all mechanisms is that they do not motivate effec-
else equal, this approach risks providing incen- tive system design, efficient component selection
tives for overpriced and underperforming proj- (high-efficiency panels/turbines) or regular main-
ects. The use of a reference facility helps over- tenance once the project is operational (Hoff,
come these problems by creating a benchmark; 2006). These risks can be mitigated by attach-
if a developer can build a plant with a lower cost ing minimum performance requirements to the
or a higher performance than the reference plant, incentive and then adjusting or even withholding
then it will have higher profits, thus creating a part of the payment subject to conditions (which
natural incentive for higher-quality projects. could include any sort of locational signal).

Developing reference plants involves estimating These tactics require ongoing performance mon-
capital costs and production hours. However, re- itoring, which increases administrative costs, but
lying on reference plants can be problematic if the upside can be substantial in terms of higher
there are too few of them, or if the regulator fails and longer-lived production from quality systems.
to properly diversify them depending on the pol-
In addition to performance monitoring, or perhaps
icy objectives. Spain has addressed this problem
as an alternative, regulators can impose minimum
by defining some 1 276 different reference plants,
standards for component efficiency or system de-
diversified by technology, size, location and con-
sign. It can be challenging, however, for regulators
struction date (Barquín, 2014).
to maintain reasonable standards in light of rap-
Design feature 3: idly evolving technology. Furthermore, there is a
Frequency of support payment risk of regulatory overreach as innovative technol-
Capacity-based support can be delivered either ogies and design approaches may be restricted in
as a one-time lump-sum payment or through a their development if they do not meet the admin-
series of periodic payments. One-time payments istratively determined criteria.
are potentially advantageous as they can be con- Assessment of market compatibility
cluded in a single interaction, reducing the ad-
In general, capacity-based support mechanisms
ministrative burden on both the developer and
are highly compatible with a market-oriented
the government counterparty. On the other hand,
power generation sector. They avoid the mar-
periodic payments are more flexible as total com-
ket distortions of production-based schemes
pensation may be adjusted over time. This can be
by decoupling payment and performance. They
a useful feature for controlling policy costs and
also come with their own set of potential risks
limiting windfall profits, or conversely, for keep-
that need to be managed, such as an unstable
ing an underperforming project profitable.
investment environment, incentives flowing to
Germany uses periodic payments to support low-quality projects and inflexibility to evolving
wind generators, which are adjusted over sev- market conditions.
eral years depending on the performance of the

84
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

Many, though not all, of these risks can be mit- to either remunerate any and all output, or pro-
igated through incorporation of specific design vide support only up to a certain limit. For ex-
features. The risk of under- or overpaying can ample, premiums for wind production could be
be reduced by using reference plants, diversified restricted to a benchmark number of hours (e.g.,
based on key performance criteria such as plant 2 000) after which any production receives only
location and size. Differentiating payments by re- the market price. This has the effect of limiting
source quality also supports economically viable windfall payments to developers in resource-rich
development of diverse sites and avoids inflated areas, while still creating incentives to site proj-
payments to developers in resource-rich areas. ects in the best locations.
The risk of payments flowing to poor-perform-
Design feature 2:
ing projects can be reduced by attaching mini-
Type of support for production
mum performance requirements. Finally, paying
out the incentive over time rather than in a single Once quantity is established, the next key deci-
lump sum leaves room for program administra- sion is the type of production support. This can
tors to adjust the level of payment in response to generally be classified based on how the pay-
changing market conditions. ment is determined: whether it is: 1) not tied to
the energy market; 2) tied to the energy market
−− Production-based mechanisms or 3) tied to a separate market.
Production-based remuneration schemes are Production incentives that are not based on a
characterised by periodic payments based on a market are administratively defined, typically ei-
generator’s actual production and, in some cas- ther through a calculation of the levelised cost of
es, the market price. By tying payment to perfor- energy or by auction. Once the incentive level is
mance these schemes create an incentive to max- established, RES generators enter into a contract
imise energy production, meaning developers for a certain number of years and are paid on a
naturally prefer the windiest/sunniest locations, per-kilowatt-hour basis for any production re-
the most efficient components and the best sys- gardless of demand. FiTs are the prime example
tem designs. of this type of flat, out-of-market approach. They
The same cannot be said for the impact of pro- have been historically effective because they cre-
duction support on operating behaviour. While ate an environment of high investor confidence
the operating decisions of wind and solar are due to the elimination of market price risk. How-
simplified compared to their thermal counter- ever, from a pure market design perspective, they
parts due to their intermittency and zero vari- are the least compatible with markets: generators
able cost, decisions such as shutting down in the are insulated from market signals and are there-
presence of negative prices, or scheduling main- fore more likely to create distortions, such as con-
tenance during off-peak times, are not driven by tinuing to produce even when prices are negative.
price signals coming from wholesale energy mar- Support mechanisms tied to the energy market
kets. Furthermore, linking support payments to require generators to sell their production on the
production adds a second signal that may cause wholesale market and then provide a premium
generators to change their behaviour, resulting in on top of the market price. These schemes are
potentially distortive impacts across the broader broadly classified as feed-in premiums, though
market. they have a variety of alternative names de-
Production-based support mechanisms are char- pending on the design details. These schemes
acterised by two key design features, as follows. are “market integrated” by nature, as generators
are exposed to price signals and tune their op-
Design feature 1: erating decisions accordingly. However, this does
Amount of production receiving support not eliminate the potential for market distortions
The first key decision in the design of produc- completely, as RES generators may still have an
tion-based schemes is the quantity of genera- incentive to continue producing in the presence
tion to support. Regulators can essentially decide of negative prices – at least until negative pric-

85
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

2
es exceed the size of the premium. The extent of average of market prices (e.g., hourly), then gen-
these distortions critically depends on how the erators are continually “topped up” to the strike
premium is calculated and whether it is fixed or price and are thus well-insulated from market vol-
“sliding”: atility. The support mechanism functions like a FIT
and generators receive signals to produce until
•• Fixed premiums are defined in advance and
prices exceed the negative of the strike price; in
therefore expose generators to the same lev-
fact, regardless of when they produce and of the
el of market volatility and price risk as any
market price at that time, their revenue is always
other market participant. The production tax
reset to the strike price. At the other extreme, if
credit in the United States, the “green bonus”
the reference price is based on a long-term aver-
in the Czech Republic and a similar scheme in
age (e.g., yearly), then the premium is more sta-
Slovenia are all examples of fixed premiums
ble on an hour-by-hour basis, and the mechanism
(Fraunhofer ISI, 2014).
sends signals equivalent to a fixed premium, ex-
•• Sliding premiums are calculated ex post as the
posing generators to market volatility and price
difference between a strike price (which reflects
risk. In this case, the generator does have a pref-
the long-term price needed to recover fixed
erence for producing at high-price hours. In prac-
costs) and a reference price (which reflects in
tice, many countries choose a middle ground, bal-
some way the payment received by participat-
ancing revenue certainty with market exposure.
ing through the electricity markets). By contin-
Germany, for example, calculates reference prices
ually correcting total payment to a fixed strike
based on a monthly average while Finland uses a
price, a sliding premium provides a high level of
three-month average (RES-LEGAL, 2015). These
revenue certainty while still exposing producers
different approaches are represented graphically
to market prices in real time.
in Figure 2.28.
The duration of the settlement period for apply-
Finally, the sliding premium may be implement-
ing the reference price is a critical factor condition-
ed as a purely financial contract, as in the case
ing the behaviour of generators (Huntington et al.,
of the United Kingdom’s Contract for Differences.
2016). If the settlement is based on a short-term

Figure 2.28 Reference price settlement periods

Strike Price

ce
Market Pri

Premium based on
long-term average Medium-term average Short-term average

Premium
renumeration

Market
renumeration

Effective Price Signal

Source: Adapted from Huntington et al., 2016

86
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

Under this arrangement, generators are still Attempts to limit distortions through market de-
“topped up” when reference prices are below sign “fixes” may create new problems. Banning
strike prices (which is most of the time), but are negative prices outright removes the channel
forced to pay back the difference when refer- through which base-load plants might contin-
ence prices exceed strike prices (peak days). This ue operating, by effectively paying renewable
works because generators still have an incen- generators to shut down. Another option is to
tive to produce as prices are above their variable force RES generators to shut down when pric-
cost, but their revenue is effectively capped at es are negative and simply pay them when they
the strike price. are available. However, this creates a dangerous
“cliff-edge” effect where generators are high-
A third alternative for production-based schemes
ly sensitive to small changes in market prices:
is to tie premiums to an entirely separate mar-
plants could suddenly switch between a desire to
ket where the value of renewable generation is
run at full output and access premium payments
determined by the demand for it. These mecha-
when prices are above zero and to turn off and be
nisms are broadly categorised as “quota obliga-
paid upon their availability when prices are below
tions” linked with “tradeable green certificates”.
zero. These oscillations could disrupt the broader
While quota schemes expose producers to the
energy market and complicate system operation
efficiency of market prices, they provide less rev-
(DECC, 2012).
enue certainty for investors. Price floors are com-
monly introduced to address this (NREL, 2011), Production-based schemes will always suffer
but by guaranteeing a minimum value for the from this fundamental tension between market
premium quota, these schemes may cause some integration and limiting distortions because, one
market distortions as traditional feed-in premi- way or another, they alter the price signals from
ums. Even a well-functioning certificate market is the energy market.
not immune to these problems. In a market with
relatively stable prices (e.g., Sweden) generators −− Specific support mechanisms for prosumers
may still find it in their interest to produce when Prosumers are electricity customers who both
prices are zero or slightly negative, knowing that consume and produce electricity. 36 The pros and
they can still sell their production in the certifi- cons of support mechanisms for generators, as
cate market for a profit. described in the previous section, are equally
applicable to generation from prosumers. Sup-
Assessment of market compatibility
port mechanisms for prosumers have the add-
Fixed premiums expose generators to efficient ed dimension of interaction with the retail tariff.
market signals and introduce limited distortions, Depending on the metering technology and ar-
but they come at the price of reduced revenue rangement, production can net consumption and
certainty. Sliding premium schemes attempt to reduce consumption tariff payments. When vol-
provide greater revenue certainty but create the umetric tariffs are bundled, prosumers have the
potential for negative price distortions as genera- opportunity to reduce or avoid non-energy costs,
tors bid up to the negative of the strike price. Cer- such as taxes, policy costs or network charges.
tificate schemes are often perceived as the most This aspect has a more significant impact when
“market compatible” since market signals and pre- prosumers are allowed to “bank” production
mium determination are fully decoupled, but the credits and apply them as negative consumption
risk introduced by the certificate market can be at a later date.
significantly higher. Measures to reduce that risk,
such as price floors, transform the scheme to one
that functions like a traditional fixed premium.

36. This topic is addressed here from the perspective of these mechanisms’ compatibility with overall market functioning. In partic-
ular, we look at potential distortions introduced by the inappropriate design of support mechanisms. Chapter 3 will tackle these
issues again from the perspective of their impact on the distribution network and the design of distribution and retail tariffs.

87
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

market can act as a basis for valuing grid injec-

2
The metering technology plays an important role
tions, thus providing a more efficient long-term
in these support mechanisms. Meters must be bi-
price signal (EURELECTRIC, 2015).
directional, therefore providing the possibility to
distinguish between consumption and produc- Design feature 2:
tion. Furthermore, smart meters with measure- Value of net excess generation
ment intervals that are aligned with the intervals Net excess generation (NEG) refers to any pro-
of the wholesale market allow the market value duction not consumed on-site and not converted
of both injected and consumed energy to be de- to production credits to be treated as negative
termined separately. This is especially relevant consumption. In net-metering schemes, NEG ex-
when the two profiles are not aligned – for ex- ists only when on-site production exceeds con-
ample, with on-peak production (solar) and off- sumption over the course of the netting period.
peak consumption (a night-oriented residential Schemes that do not allow banking of production
profile). This also helps manage imbalances and credits effectively treat all grid injections as NEG.
attributes imbalance costs more fairly (Eurelec-
tric, 2015). The value of NEG influences both the operating
and investment decisions of prosumers. If NEG is
The remainder of this section focuses on two key valued at or above the retail rate, the incentives
design features of support schemes for prosum- are equivalent to net metering: customers are in-
ers: namely the parameters of the netting period, different to their rate of self-consumption. This
and the value of excess generation. can also lead to the oversizing of generation as-
Design feature 1: sets. On the other hand, if NEG is valued below
Length and timing of netting period the retail rate, customers have a direct incentive
to increase their rate of self-consumption and tai-
The netting period refers to the window between
lor the size of the generation systems accordingly.
meter readings when customers can apply gener-
ation credits to their bill, effectively “netting out” Assessment of market compatibility
their consumption. The longer the netting period, In any arrangement that allows for self-consump-
the greater the potential subsidy since consumers tion, prosumers will have the opportunity to
have more opportunity to use generation credits avoid paying the retail rate, and any associated
to offset their consumption. Shorter netting peri- network costs. Many schemes allow prosumers to
ods, combined with a lower rate for excess gener- carry their production credits forward and “net
ation, create incentives for prosumers to increase out” their consumption at a later time. From a
their rate of self-consumption. pure market perspective, schemes that do not al-
Most states in the United States use an annual low the “banking” of production credits, or those
netting period, though some, like Alaska, allow that minimise the netting period, lead to fewer
credits to be carried forward indefinitely. Two distortions. Of course, this depends on whether
utilities in California, PG&E and SDG&E, recent- the design of the network tariffs takes advantage
ly proposed shortening the netting period from of the pattern of injections and withdrawals of
yearly to monthly in an effort to control support the network users.
costs and reduce cross-subsidisation of custom- Rather than allowing the banking of production
ers with solar production (PG&E, n.d.). Most EU credits, support for prosumers may be delivered
countries, including Belgium and the Kingdom of by adjusting the value of NEG. As long as the value
Netherlands, , also use an annual netting period. remains below the retail rate, customers will have
Denmark uses a very short hourly netting period incentives to make both efficient operating (in-
(European Commission, 2015c). creased self-consumption) and investment deci-
The timing of the netting period is another im- sions (proper sizing), leading to fewer market dis-
portant dimension: by aligning the period with tortions and greater overall efficiency. But the only
the trading interval of the wholesale market, the fool-proof approach is a complete redesign of the
retail tariffs, as discussed in the next chapter.

88
WHOLESALE MARKET DESIGN

2.5. CONCLUSIONS Also, the balancing segment must be reformed


AND RECOMMENDATIONS if RES resources are to become responsible for
their imbalances. Balancing products should be
In this chapter, we saw how wholesale market de-
revised to unlock the potential of all flexible re-
sign will have to evolve in the near future to ef-
sources. Balancing capacity and balancing ener-
ficiently integrate large shares of RES and DER.
gy should be two separate products, procured
The short-term market is probably the segment at different stages. Resources not cleared in as
that requires the most adjustment. As many char- balancing capacity may be allowed to provide
acteristics of the power sector become more vari- balancing energy if they can do it efficiently. Up-
able, the time granularity of market signals has to wards and downwards reserves should be pro-
be increased. Market time frames must be adapt- cured separately too since some resources may
ed and become more flexible. be able to provide one product but not the other.
Minimum-size requirements should be avoided to
In terms of location, the deployment of variable
the largest extent possible so as not to discour-
technologies is likely to increase congestion on
age RES and DER participation.
the transmission network, which may exacerbate
the potential disadvantages of zonal pricing when In the long term, we saw how capacity (or, more
compared with nodal pricing. Nodal pricing pro- generally, generation adequacy) mechanisms are
vides more accurate operation and investment climbing regulatory agendas in many liberalised
signals, and its drawbacks in terms of long-term power systems. RES technologies can represent
market liquidity and end-consumer discrimina- a valuable opportunity for system adequacy. De-
tion may be reduced through financial transmis- pending on the characteristics of the power sys-
sion rights and a proper tariff design. tem (especially on the share of hydropower in
the generation mix), the variability of some RES
A large deployment of renewable resources also
technologies may not be an obstacle for these re-
requires more complex bidding formats, if an ef-
sources to provide reliability products efficiently.
ficient economic dispatch is to be guaranteed.
Bids may need to include an explicit representa- For this reason, RES resources should be allowed
tion of most of the technical constraints of power to participate in generation adequacy, and also to
resources. Also, bids may be tailored to certain be exposed to the corresponding market signals,
products, such as those coming from demand re- which may result in the development of technol-
sponse. ogies or strategies that maximise the availability
of RES units during scarcity conditions. Harmoni-
There are two key approaches to clearing bids and
sation is called for in many areas, especially in the
setting a price: that of the US ISO (dispatch-based
calculation of a firm’s energy/capacity and in the
pricing plus discriminatory pricing) and the EU PX
application of penalties for underperformance.
(price-based dispatch). The best option might be
some point in the middle. An optimum clearing Finally, RES participation in capacity mechanisms
methodology would find a balance between: 1) does not directly imply the elimination of any oth-
uniform prices that may oversimplify the problem er form of RES support scheme. These two reg-
and result in potential economic inefficiencies ulatory instruments can coexist – the only strong
and 2) large uplifts that may distort the efficient requisite being that the incentive provided by the
price signal. support scheme account for the remuneration
earned on the capacity market.
In the very-short-term, new solutions must be
found to improve the reserve demand function, RES support mechanisms may be designed in
increasing its elasticity to price. At the same time, several ways. The key question is whether to pro-
the linkage between energy and reserve markets vide the incentive based on the capacity installed
has to be enhanced in order for an energy market or the energy produced. Also in this regard, a bal-
to properly reflect the value of reserves. ance must be found between optimal investment
incentives and minimal market distortions.

89
DISTRIBUTION
NETWORKS AND
DISTRIBUTED ENERGY
RESOURCES
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

3.1 INTRODUCTION service cost may no longer be valid. The distribu-


tion system operator need to adopt advanced, in-
Over the past decade, distribution networks have
novative approaches to managing the distribution
experienced the connection of an increasing
grid. The active management of networks will help
number of distributed energy resources (DER),
solve network constraints and reduce relative-
most of it distributed generation (DG), but also
ly costly network reinforcements. This approach
active demand response.1 In the near future, elec-
requires distribution companies to interact more
tric vehicles and distributed storage will have a
closely with their network users and to deploy ad-
substantial presence in several systems. The cur-
vanced network technologies, which will play a
rent – and anticipated – growth of DER demands
crucial role in future power systems. The transition
new approaches to operating and planning distri-
towards smarter distribution networks should be
bution networks, and the regulation of distribu-
initiated through policies and regulations promot-
tion and retail activities.
ing innovation and demonstration projects. Sever-
What are the major challenges anticipated? For al mechanisms have been used around the world
the time being, most changes will be on the DG to help distribution companies efficiently integrate
side. A high presence of DG may increase un- growing levels of DER through more active grid
certainty around distribution networks’ remu- planning and operation. Examples of these mech-
neration since the methods that regulators have anisms and of relevant demonstration projects are
traditionally employed to estimate an efficient discussed in Section 3.2.

1. D
 istributed energy resources (DER) consist of small- to medium- scale resources that are connected mainly to the lower voltage
levels (distribution grids) of the system or near the end users and are comprised of three main elements: distributed generation,
energy storage and demand response. Demand response (DR), also known as demand-side management (DSM) or energy demand
management (EDM) refers to the possibility to shift energy loads around in time. The management of small end-users must be
achieved automatically at the user level, which requires online communications. In this regard, smart meters represent a key
enabling technology of demand response. Distributed generation (DG) is a generating power plants serving a customer on-site, or
providing support to a distribution network, and connected to the grid at distribution level voltages. For the purpose of this report,
the technologies used for distributed generation are renewable energy technologies.

91
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
New regulatory approaches are needed for metering technologies are adopted. Section 3.4
the remuneration of distribution networks. The discusses the negative consequences of inap-
method currently used by most regulators relies propriate tariff structures in combination with
on some multiplicative factor – validated by ex- self-consumption policies and discusses some
perience – applied to the volume of distributed measures that regulators and policy makers have
electricity. The network charges applied to the implemented to tackle such challenges. Several
end-consumer are also, typically, volumetric, i.e., guiding principles for a truly cost-reflective tar-
proportional to the amount of consumed ener- iff design and the sustainable development of
gy. However, with high presence of DG, revenues self-generation on consumers’ premises are pro-
may fall – both the total amount determined by vided in this section.
regulators and that collected through the appli-
Last but not least, owing to the presence of DER
cation of network tariffs. This is in large part be-
in their grids and the flexibility these services may
cause self-generation implies a smaller amount
provide, distribution companies will need to take
of distributed electricity. In order to mitigate the
on new roles as market intermediaries and sys-
potential financial impact of this on distribution
tem operators. This transformation means that, in
utilities, some regulators have started to imple-
the near future, distribution companies will need
ment mechanisms that decouple the amount of
to interact more closely with DER, which will be
allowed revenues from the volume of delivered
at least partly dispatchable. In this new context,
energy. Also, some compensate companies for
DER will provide services both to a distribution
the incremental network costs. However, these
company itself and to upstream stakeholders and
short-term measures are not enough. More must
markets. Since the distribution companies will
be done to determine efficient cost levels and to
need to act as mediators in these transactions,
incentivise the degree of innovation required to
e.g., performing technical validation or verifica-
integrate high shares of DG efficiently. Profound
tion of service delivery, the traditionally simple
regulatory changes are required to encourage
interactions between distribution companies and
the deployment of more active grid planning and
system operators – whether independent system
operation. The regulatory changes to support DG
operators (ISOs) or transmission system opera-
integration and to promote long-term efficiency
tors (TSOs) - ought to be revisited in order to en-
are discussed in Section 3.3.
sure the efficient and secure operation of a large-
The development of generation on consum- ly decentralised power system. Thus, to some
ers’ premises for self-consumption presents im- extent, distribution companies may become to
portant benefits both for end users as well as retail markets and DER what transmission sys-
for the distribution grid. However, as a result of tem operators are to wholesale markets and cen-
tariff structures that do not adequately reflect tralised generation. Moreover, as part of their
the true costs that each network user imposes newly acquired roles, distribution companies may
on the system and outdated metering technol- be required to deploy new types of infrastructure
ogies, self-consumption, especially when com- – such as advanced metering infrastructure (AMI),
bined with net-metering policies, may jeopardise energy storage or electric vehicle (EV) charging
the financial viability of the system. Acknowledg- stations – that do not fall within their convention-
ing this, regulators have already started to apply al core activities. Section 3.5 addresses the new
mechanisms to mitigate the problem in the short roles to be adopted by distribution utilities as sys-
term. However, the fundamental issues will not be tem operators and market facilitators, including
solved until cost-reflective tariffs and advanced in the deployment of infrastructure.

92
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

3.2 ADVANCED SOLUTIONS FOR work costs (investment, maintenance and ener-
DISTRIBUTION NETWORK gy losses cost) compared to a business-as-usual
PLANNING AND OPERATION approach (see, for example, Cossent et al., 2011).
Box 3.1 summarises the results of analyses aim-
ing at quantifying the effect of DG deployment
A growing penetration of distributed energy on network costs, the level of investments to ac-
resources, particularly distributed generation, commodate DG integration as well as the savings
requires innovative approaches to distribution that might be achieved through innovative tech-
network planning and operation. nologies (such as storage) and more active net-
work operation.
The presence of generation in distribution net- Policy makers all over the world acknowledge
works is beneficial, thanks to the fact that DG is that not co-ordinating the development of DER
located near end-consumers. It can partially off- and distribution grids is inefficient:
set demand growth, reduce peak load and allow
distribution companies to defer grid reinforce- “Thus far, there has been limited incorporation
ments or reduce energy losses. However, in many of demand response and energy efficiency into
cases the absence of locational network charges, distribution system planning efforts, and very
as well as policy design, do not encourage effi- little incorporation of distributed generation.
cient operating decisions regarding generation […] System planners are appropriately conser-
location. And even if the correct locational sig- vative, and inclined to consider only resources
nals were sent, operators can make operating that are well known and can be relied upon […]
decisions based on many other factors. Thus, in These challenges, however, should not preclude
practice, DG is not necessarily located close to consideration of available, feasible, and cost-ef-
the loads or operated efficiently. Moreover, its fective DER solutions as part of any distribution
production is largely variable and may not coin- system planning efforts” (New York DPS, 2014:
cide with times when local demand is highest. 2 14–15).
Thus DG production does not necessarily take “[R]egulatory frameworks shall enable distribu-
place where and when it is most needed from a tion system operators to procure services from
network perspective. resources such as distributed generation, de-
Another issue to consider is that distribution mand response or storage and consider ener-
companies rarely rely on DER to optimise net- gy efficiency measures, which may supplant the
work planning – and reap its potential benefits. need to upgrade or replace electricity capacity
Instead, they usually follow a so-called fit-and- and which support the efficient and secure op-
forget approach to DG connection, which con- eration of the distribution system” – Proposal
sists of reinforcing the grid at the time of con- for a revised Electricity Directive, Art. 32.1 (Eu-
nection in such a way that any future operational ropean Commission, 2016b).
problem is prevented. This means that network To achieve these goals, distribution utilities should
capacity by itself must be sufficient to cope not adopt a more active role in distribution network
only with peak demand conditions, but also with planning and operation. Implementing advanced
peak net generation, even if these conditions only solutions often requires utilities to take the risks
last for a few hours per year (Eurelectric, 2013). inherent in using new technologies. Pilot projects
Consequently, distribution costs can actually in- ought to be encouraged through funding mech-
crease significantly due to the connection of DG. anisms that partly hedge distribution companies
Several studies have demonstrated that the im- against these risks. This would help ensure that
plementation of active network management suitable solutions are available when needed.
helps lower the impact of DG on distribution net-

2. T
 he coincidence in time of local generation and demand is a key factor determining the impact of DG/RES on the distribution
network. For instance, solar PV production may yield significant benefits in areas dominated by commercial consumers with a
significant air-conditioning demand. However, it is not possible to draw general conclusions about DG impacts since these depend
on many factors, such as location, season, the year load composition, etc.

93
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3 Box 3.1 Network investments and advanced solutions to integrate distribution generation

Figure 3.1 presents the outcome of a study assessing the


influence of photovoltaics (PV) on distribution network
In 2011, the UK Department of Energy and Climate Change
and the energy regulator – the Office of Gas and Electric-
cost and energy losses for 12 prototype networks. These ity Markets (OFGEM) – created the so-called Smart Grids
networks were constructed using a distribution network Forum for public authorities, industry representatives and
planning model, called reference network model, and stakeholders to exchange ideas about the future of their
corresponding to different reference locations across the energy networks. Among other initiatives, a forum study
United States, selected based on solar radiation levels and evaluated the future investment that distribution net-
population density. The vertical axis shows the increase works need to accommodate expected DER by the year
in network costs driven by solar PV, relative to a scenario 2050 under different scenariosa (EA Technology, 2012).
without DG. The horizontal axis measures PV penetration Figure 3.2 shows how, under all the scenarios, the consid-
levels, defined as the share of the annual electricity de- eration of smart grid investments (either in a top-downb
mand supplied by local solar generation. In addition, the or incrementalc approach) yielded much lower costs than
contribution of energy storage to the mitigation of PV in- a business as usual (BAU) strategy. The vertical axis rep-
tegration costs is evaluated for different values of a stor- resents the net present value of expected network costs
age factor. This parameter represents the reduction in DG throughout the period 2012–50 quantified by means of a
peak injection achieved by the storage system. A value distribution-planning model for a set of scenarios. Each
of zero means that there is no reduction in the maximum scenario displayed in Figure 3.2 corresponds to a differ-
annual power injection, whereas a value of one indicates ent penetration level of low-carbon technologies (solar
that storage fully offsets PV injections. The results show PV, heat pumps and electric vehicles).
that when storage reduces the peak PV production seen
by the grid, significant amounts of PV can be connected Figure 3.2 Expected network investments in Great Brit-
without a significant network cost increase. ain to accommodate low-carbon technologies connected
to the distribution network under different planning
scenarios (2012-50)

Figure 3.1 Effect of energy storage to mitigate


Billions
the impact of PV penetration on distribution costs £30
NPV of distribution network cost (2012-2050)

£25
2.0
Relative Change in Total Yearly
Network and Losses Cost

1.8 £20

1.6
£15
1.4

1.2 £10

1.0
£5
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40
PV Energy Share (%) £0
Scenario 0 - Scenario 1- Scenario 2 - Scenario 3 -
Hight Medium Medium Low
SF=0.0 SF=0.2 SF=1.0 (Low DSR)
BAU Incremental Top-Down
Source: MIT, 2015
SF stands for storage factor Source: EA Technology, 2012

(a) Scenario 0 - high domestic decarbonisation; Scenario 1 - domestic decarbonisation to meet carbon targets;
scenario 2 - domestic decarbonisation to meet carbon targets with low DSR; and scenario 3 - low domestic decarbonisation.
(b) T op down approach - A strategy where an upfront investment of enabler technologies is deployed in advance of need,
followed by investment as and when networks reach their headroom limits.
(c) Incremental approach - A strategy where investment only occurs as and when networks reach their headroom limits.
Enabling technologies are deployed alongside the solution variants on an incremental basis.

94
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

3.2.1 P
 roactive grid connection quent requests would trigger reinforcements. In
approach and long-term case generators are obliged to bear these costs,
network planning this could make later projects unviable. Moreover,
an incremental reinforcement strategy can lead
to inefficient network development due to the
The management of grid connection
existence of economies of scale in network com-
applications should be reviewed to speed-up
ponents.
DG connections and allocate grid capacity
more efficiently. Therefore, to the extent possible, a co-ordinated
Information disclosure about grid hosting aggregate management of connection requests
capacity and connection process should should replace the first-come, first-served ap-
be promoted. proach conventionally applied. Thus, the alloca-
tion of existing network capacity and cost alloca-
tion would be carried out in a much more efficient
Mitigating the effect that high levels of DG can and transparent way. See, for instance, the case
have on costs of traditional distribution networks, of Ireland, which introduced a so-called “group
and making the most of the benefits provided by processing”, described in Box 3.2, which has al-
DER, require new approaches to grid connection lowed the handling of a large number of wind
and network planning. Additionally, as discussed power connection requests. 3
in Section 3.2.2 more flexible grid connection
and planning methodologies require distribution Facing a similar problem related to the large
companies to adopt a more active grid operation. number of network connection applications from
promoters of generation projects, the Italian reg-
DG units have conventionally been connected to ulator implemented a specific regulatory mecha-
distribution networks using a fit-and-forget ap- nism to tackle the so-called virtual grid conges-
proach. This means that, due to distribution com- tions, also described in Box 3.2. This approach is
panies’ lack of control over DG units and DER in based on setting additional economic or admin-
general, any potential operational problem, even istrative requirements before granting a certain
exceptional events, had to be prevented through amount of grid capacity to applicants. The main
network reinforcements at the time of connec- goals of the regulator were to prevent opportu-
tion. This conservative strategy aims to ensure nistic behaviour from promoters and handle the
that no operational problem will arise. While this very large volumes of grid connection requests.
goal is a worthy one with low levels of DG, it may
generate an excessive cost burden in the long run New generators wishing to connect to the distri-
when high shares of DG are installed. This ap- bution grid typically have to submit an applica-
proach ought to be progressively abandoned as tion to the distribution company specifying one
DG penetration levels grow to prevent undue in- or more potential points of connection. The gen-
creases in distribution costs and long lead times erator, meanwhile, normally does not possess any
in DG connections. prior knowledge of network conditions. As a re-
sult, applicants may find their connection being
First, grid connection processes should be re- delayed or subject to high connection fees due to
visited. Network connection requests have con- insufficient network hosting capacity.
ventionally been managed through a first-come,
first-served approach, on a case-by-case basis.
As a result, the first applicants would make use
of the existing connection capacity, while subse-

3. This approach successfully addresses the problem of handling a large number of connection requests arriving at different times. As
is often the case with regulations, no solution is perfect. The drawback of this approach is that it may impede the chances of better
performing generators to compete with the existing ones, when their application is made later. It may also encourage the hoarding
of connection permits, unless strict measures are taken to prevent this behavior.

95
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
Box 3.2 Regulatory mechanisms to handle a large number of DG connection applications

Group processing of grid connection applications projects amounting to 128 gigawatts (GW) and 22 GW
in Ireland had applied for connection to the transmission and dis-
tribution grid, respectively, whereas the total installed
At the end of 2003, Ireland’s energy regulator instruct-
capacity and peak demand were roughly 111 GW and 57
ed network operators, both transmission and distribution
GW, respectivelya. Furthermore, generation projects were
companies, not to accept any new grid connections due
concentrated in areas where the grid presented less host-
to concerns about the secure operation of the system.
ing capacity. Hence, important virtual grid congestions
Nonetheless, the number of connection requests from
were identified, i.e., potential grid constraints that would
wind power plants kept increasing during this moratori-
occur in case the existing DG connection requests would
um. Thus, the regulator decided to implement a “group
materialise. Two main mechanisms were devised to ad-
processing” with the following goals:
dress this challenge for non-residential consumers/pro-
sumers in critical network areas, i.e., those facing prob-
“Securing early system access has become
lems of virtual congestion:
particularly valuable and important to applicants.
This also mean that putting in place an orderly regime −− Provide the right for network connection and access
for the resumption of connection offers is essential after additional economic guarantees had been given
to realizing Ireland’s renewable energy obligations.” to the corresponding grid operator. The amount of such
(CER, 2005) guarantees would be proportional to the network capac-
ity requested. The guarantees would only be returned
This method consists of jointly processing connection if the projects were realised and connected within two
applications from renewable generators larger than 500 years from the time of application.
kilowatts (kW) in subsequent batches or “gates”. In each
gate, existing applications are sorted into groups. Gen- −− Provide the right for network connection and access
only to those projects that had already obtained con-
erators in the same group are those sharing the use of
struction and operation permits. Under this alternative,
a portion of the grid. Then each group is evaluated by
promoters have specific deadlines to begin the construc-
its corresponding network operator, both technically and
tion work of the plant before losing the right to connect,
economically. In case this results in a positive evaluation,
which depends on the voltage level.
applicants receive a connection offer, including their cor-
responding share of grid reinforcement costs, which are The application of the first solution, initially preferred,
allocated in proportion to the capacity of each plant. was hampered by a litigation process. Hence, the second
alternative was finally adopted. The implementation pro-
Mitigating virtual congestion in Italy cess is described in AEEGSI (2011; 2012a; 2012b). Residen-
The Italian regulator published a consultation document tial consumers/prosumers were exempt from both these
concerning new technical and economic grid connection requirements.
requirements for generators in response to the large
amount of new generation capacity that had requested
a grid connection (AEEGSI, 2010). By the end of 2010, a. http://www.autorita.energia.it/it/docs/11/073-11arg.htm

In order to achieve faster and more transparent tion charges. This would, in turn, encourage gen-
grid connections, distribution companies should erators to request their connection at the point
be obligated to disclose information on avail- where network conditions are most favourable.
able. On the publication of available generation Box 3.3 provides several examples of distribu-
hosting capacity at potential points of connec- tion utilities that publish this type of information
tion would allow DG promoters to estimate in ad- in different forms, sometimes subject to registra-
vance whether their application will be successful tion. The formats range from simple online calcu-
or what location would result in lower connec- lators to interactive maps using geographic infor-
mation system (GIS) technology.

96
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

Box 3.3 Network information disclosure for new DG connections

In 2012, The United Kingdom’s energy regulator, the Of- Likewise, distribution utilities in California were mandated
fice of Gas and Electricity Markets (OFGEM) decided to to elaborate a so-called “distribution resources plan”. This
host several discussion forums where distribution com- sought to identify optimal locations for the deployment of
panies and generators could discuss the increasing num- distributed energy resources (DER). The three main dis-
ber of generators seeking to connect to the distribution tribution utilities in the state have published the detailed
grid, the difficulties they faced when going through the information used for such analysis.a Figure 3.4 shows an
connection process and the possible solutions. Today, interactive map where users may check the available ca-
distribution companies in the United Kingdom provide pacity for generation connection in different network ele-
extensive and easy-to-interpret information about the ments. As in the previous case, colour-coding and pop-up
connection process, as well as detailed information about menus are used to display the relevant information.
the conditions of the grid. Available tools include distrib-
uted generation (DG) heat maps (SP Energy Networks),
Figure 3.4 DER integration map in California
generation availability maps (Northern Power Grid) and a
(Southern California Edison)
DG mapping tool (UK Power Networks) (see Figure 3.3).

These are interactive web-based tools that allow poten-


tial applicants to perform a preliminary assessment of
grid-hosting capacity in different locations throughout
the distribution grid. Figures below show two examples
of map-based information provided by two distribution
companies in the United Kingdom. A colour code is used
to indicate the loading level of different network ele-
ments, i.e., feeder circuits or substations. More detailed
information (voltage level, rated capacity, existing DG
capacity connected, remaining hosting capacity, etc.) is
displayed by means of pop-up menus. Source: Southern California Edison, 2017
a. See http://www.cpuc.ca.gov/PUC/energy/drp/index.htm.

Figure 3.3 Examples of map-based information for potential DG connections in the United Kingdom
This map shows 33/11KV Primary · Transmission Constraint
Substations and a geographical · General Capacity Connected
footprint of the areas they feed. · Reverse Power Flow
they are coloured red, amber or · 33kV Fault Level
green depending on whether any of · Percentage of 11kV Circuits
the following have been identified Saturated
as affecting further generation
connections.

SUBSTATION  INFORMATION  
 
Name:  Fourstones    
Primary  Classification:  AMBER    
Nominal  Voltage  (KV):  20  
(Latitude,  Longitude):  (55.0119.0-­‐2.165)    
 
Fault  Level  (%):  52.69%  
Voltage  constraint  issue:  5  
Reverse  Power  Flow  Capability:  100|40  (MVA)  
     Upstream:  AMBER  LIMITED  SOURCE  SUBSTAION  CAPACITY  
Physical  Constraints:  GREEN  
 
VIEW    DETAILS          
 
 

DG heat map Generation availability map


Source: Adapted from SP Energy Networks, 2017 Source: Northern Power Grid, 2017

97
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
Over the long term, a more comprehensive, 3.2.2 F
 rom reinforcement-based
co-ordinated and forward-looking network plan solutions to an active network
ought to be undertaken (Jamasb and Marantes, operation
2011; Jendernalik, 2015). Conventionally, this ex-
ercise broadly consists of forecasting peak de-
Integrating DG efficiently requires the
mand over the planning horizon to determine
adoption of active network management as
the necessary grid reinforcements. However, the
an alternative to simple conventional grid
times required to install a DG plant are usually
reinforcements.
shorter than those required to reinforce the grid.
Distribution companies will increasingly need to
foresee the connection of DG well in advance in Capturing the potential benefits of demand re-
order to prevent potential bottlenecks (Jamasb sponse and DG in distribution network planning
and Marantes, 2011). necessarily involves implementing a more active
network management. Thus, instead of prevent-
The main added difficulty is that planning net-
ing grid constraints by simply reinforcing the net-
works with large shares of DG, typically variable,
work or delaying the connection of DG, distribu-
requires knowing not only how much capacity will
tion companies may solve congestion or voltage
be connected, but also when and where DG will
problems during day-to-day operations.
be using this capacity. To do this, utilities will have
to move towards a probabilistic scenario-based On the one hand, distribution companies will
grid planning process. More detailed geographi- need to adopt an enhanced use of information
cal information, such as renewable resource avail- and communication technologies (ICT) and in-
ability or land-use mapping, should be employed novative systems to solve network constraints.
to quantify existing DG potential. Lastly, both These solutions comprise, among other systems,
network reinforcements or expansions and ad- automated voltage control to mitigate the volt-
vanced grid technologies should be considered age rise effect caused by DG (see Box 3.4) or au-
by the distribution companies in order to deter- tomatic grid reconfiguration to reduce the load-
mine efficient and robust investment strategies. ing of a distribution feeder by transferring part of
the DG feed-in to a neighbouring one.
Regulation can promote this change in planning
practices by mandating that distribution compa- In addition to deploying innovative technolo-
nies submit justified investment plans following gies, utilities should interact more often with DER
common criteria. An example of such practices to efficiently manage network constraints. The
is that of the United Kingdom, where distribu- most straightforward approach is mandating DG
tion companies have to apply a common meth- units to comply with certain communications re-
odology to justify their business plans based on quirements and dispatch signals sent by the dis-
a benefit-cost analysis, including innovative grid tribution system operator (DSO), as in the exist-
solutions. In this regard, the regulator states ing PV curtailment system in Germany. A similar
that distribution companies shall use a techno-­ approach may be found in the United Kingdom,
economic model called the Transform Model4 where distribution companies may temporarily
(or other modelling tools with comparable capa- curtail those consumers connected at the high
bilities) and follow the long-term scenarios de- voltage level who have agreed to be curtailed
fined by the Department of Energy and Climate when needed in exchange for lower network
Change (OFGEM, 2013a). charges (Box 3.5).

4. T
 he Transform Model is a spreadsheet model which has been developed and is property of the consultancy firm EA Technologies.
Further information can be found at http://www.eatechnology.com/products-and-services/create-smarter-grids/transform-­
model%C2%AE.

98
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

Box 3.4 The need for more active network management: voltage control with DG

In the absence of distributed generation (DG), bus volt- The conventional solution to this kind of problem con-
ages drop along the distribution feeders. Provided that sists of permanently lowering the voltage at the substa-
the network is adequately designed, no voltage problems tion and modifying the transformer tap position until the
should occur. Nonetheless, the increasing connection of voltage is kept within margins. By doing this, as shown
DG to this network could raise bus voltages up to the in the right-hand side of the figure, all bus voltages are
point where the allowable upper bound is violated. For shifted downwards. However, because voltages are not
instance, the left side of Figure 3.5 shows the voltage pro- normally monitored in real-time, and tap positions cannot
file throughout a distribution feeder under different load- be adjusted accordingly, this could lead to an excessive
ing scenarios with and without DG. It can be seen that the voltage drop in a scenario with high load and very low DG
presence of DG, particularly under low-load conditions, feed-in (right part of figure). Hence, as DG penetration
can cause an increase in voltages that at times may ex- grows, the distribution company would increasingly need
ceed allowable voltage limits, represented by a dashed to monitor local voltage levels and dynamically adjust
red line, in some buses (usually those closer to the loca- the substation voltage depending on actual, rather than
tion of DG units). expected, network conditions. Therefore, voltage control
approaches should evolve from static passive solutions to
location and time-dependent control strategies based on
local measurements and grid monitoring.

Figure 3.5 Impact of DG on distribution voltage control strategies

Voltage Voltage
Upper Low load Upper
Voltage Violation High DG feed-in Low load
Permitted Permitted
voltage voltage High DG feed-in
High load High load
Low DG feed-in Low DG feed-in
Set value
Busbar voltage Set value
primary Busbar voltage
substation primary
substation
Low load
No DG Low load
Lower Lower No DG
permitted High load permitted
No DG High load
voltage voltage Voltage Violation No DG

Network length Network length

Source: Adapted from Jendernalik, 2015

Mechanisms that allow the distributor to tempo- Existing connection requirements and planning
rarily curtail the power injection or withdrawal of criteria may not be flexible enough. Thus, rules
an end user for security reasons are referred to obliging distribution companies to size their grids
as variable or non-firm network access (Eurelec- according to a worst-case scenario should be
tric, 2013) or smart contracts (EDSO, 2015). There modified to allow distribution companies free-
is a trade-off between: 1) reducing the value of dom to decide whether to reinforce the grid or
the RES due to curtailment and 2) the benefits offer non-firm access contracts to their users.
reaped in terms of swifter DG integration. Thus,
A limitation of these connection agreements is
solutions should be promoted, with the aim of
that the compensation for the provision of flex-
keeping the amount of curtailed DG production
ibility is related to the level of network charges,
low, preventing costly grid reinforcements, in-
which does not necessarily reflect the actual value
creasing network hosting capacity, and allowing
that the service has for the distribution company.
for a faster DG connection and access.
Moreover, they do not generally allow different
DER to compete for the provision of the service.

99
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
Box 3.5 Non-firm distribution network access as a means to prevent network constraints

PV curtailment by distribution system problems and reducing lead connection times, the mech-
operators in Germany anism does not allow distribution system operators to en-
tirely rely on distributed generation (DG) management as
According to the German Renewable Energy Sources Act,
an alternative to network reinforcements.
or EEG, since January 2012, German distributors are en-
titled to limit remotely the injection of photovoltaic (PV) Demand-side management agreements
installations above 30 kilowatts (kW), subject to compen- in the United Kingdom
sation. Plants below 30 kW may choose to permanently
Distribution companies in the United Kingdom may of-
limit their power injection to 70% of the nameplate ca-
fer non-firm network access to their network users. For
pacity (leaving the remainder to be curtailed or locally
instance, Scottish Power offers their extra-high-voltage
stored/consumed) or to install the same communication
consumers a demand-side-management agreement. This
system installed on larger plants.
contract offers eligible consumers reduced charges in
This mechanism should be applied only on a temporary exchange for their agreement to reduce their maximum
basis in case of an emergency (congestion or overvolt- consumption in those periods, determined by the distri-
age). The distribution company is still expected to eventu- bution company. Moreover, the demand charge will be
ally reinforce the grid so that no curtailment is necessary. reduced in proportion to the amount of capacity that is
Thus, while helpful in addressing short-term operational subject to such a reduction (SP Energy Networks, 2014).

Thus, more flexible and ad hoc approaches to en- gration is not the only factor driving smart grid
able the interaction of DSOs with DER have been adoption. Additional motives include improved
proposed (see, for example, CEER, 2015a; CEER, market functioning, the development of electric
2015b; and Eurelectric, 2013). These mechanisms, mobility, a reduction in energy losses and en-
as discussed in Section 3.5, may take the form hanced network resiliency and reliability.
of “bilateral flexibility contracts” (CEER, 2015b)
Without specific measures in place, distribution
or that of local markets operated by the distri-
companies have little or no incentive to innovate
bution utility and participated by local DER (Tre-
since innovation involves increasing their risk ex-
bolle et al., 2010; Eurelectric, 2013; Poudineh and
posure. Regulations may not allow them to use
Jamasb, 2014). In both cases, the service provider
tariffs to recover the costs of innovative technol-
may be the network user or an intermediary, such
ogies; and the solutions adopted may not yield
as a supplier or an aggregator.
the expected results, leading to stranded costs.
3.2.3 P
 aving the way through Thus, it is up to policy makers and regulators to
demonstration and pilot projects kick-start the transformation.

Pilot projects should be promoted by means of


Policy and regulation should promote ad hoc policy and regulation so that distribution
the implementation of pilot projects and the companies are able to test innovative solutions
exchange of lessons-learnt and best practices. while mitigating their risks in case of failure. Rele-
vant regulatory instruments offer a higher rate of
New technology deployment should be
return on innovative investments or accelerated
supported through the creation of
depreciation methods, or allow the pass-through
public-private collaborative networks.
of demonstration costs or foster direct project
funding through competitive schemes (CEER,
More active distribution grids, largely reliant on 2015b). In recent years, numerous demonstration
ICTs, are necessary to ensure an efficient integra- and pilot projects have been launched to pro-
tion of DG. The term “smart grid” is widely used mote smart distribution grids worldwide.
to refer to this new paradigm. Renewable inte-

100
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

Joint public-private partnerships and fora pro- projects (both research and development, and
mote the exchange of lessons learnt and identi- demonstration projects), amounting to Euro 3.15
fy common priorities. Examples of such collabo- billion in investments within the period 2002-14
ration networks at the regional level include the (JRC, 2014). The distribution of the budget devot-
European Union (EU) Smart Grid Task Force,5 the ed to demonstration projects shown in Figure 3.6
US GridWise Alliance6 and the Indian Smart Grid clearly illustrates the priorities of enhancing net-
Forum.7 Through these networks, the European work management, empowering consumers and
Union, the United States, and India illustrate dif- integrating DER.
ferent approaches and priorities in the transition
Furthermore, a shift in the allocation of resources
towards smarter distribution grids. At the glob-
from research and development to demonstra-
al level, the International Smart Grid Action Net-
tion projects can be observed over the last few
work (ISGAN),8 includes stakeholders from 25
years (Figure 3.7). This denotes the need to im-
countries across five continents.
plement demonstration projects to prove smart
In the European context, smart distribution grids grid technologies with a view to large-scale de-
are considered essential to achieve more-efficient ployment.
grid operation, the integration of large shares of
The American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of
renewable generation and a fully functional retail
2009 (US Congress, 2009), in short the Recov-
electricity market. The European Commission,
ery Act or ARRA, represented a strong stimulus
through its Joint Research Centre, has built up a
for the development of smart grids in the United
database comprising more than 450 smart grid
States. This law allocated USD 4.5 billion to the

Figure 3.6 Distribution of budget per country and smart grid application in Europe, considering only
demonstration and deployment projects

500
Smart Metering
450
Integration of large scale RES

400 Other
Aggregation (Demand Response, VPP)
350 Integration of DER
Budget [million Euro]

Electric Vehicles and Vehicle2Grid applications


300 Smart Customer and Smart Home
Smart Network Management
250

200

150

100

50

0
UK FR DE ES IT NL DK BE SE AT PT GR CZ SI IE FI NO CH HU LT PL HR SK RO BG LV CY LU EE MT

Source: Adapted from JRC, 2014

5. http://ec.europa.eu/energy/en/topics/markets-and-consumers/smart-grids-and-meters/smart-grids-task-force.
6. http://www.gridwise.org/index.asp.
7. http://indiasmartgrid.org/.
8. http://iea-isgan.org/.

101
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
Figure 3.7 Cumulative annual budget of smart grid projects in Europe, 2002-14

3,000

2,500
Budget [million Euro]

2,000

1,500

1,000

500

0
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
Total budget R&D budget Demonstration & Deployment budget

Source: Adapted from JRC, 2017

United States Department of Energy (US DOE) to In several Indian states, smart distribution grids
promote the modernisation of the US electricity offer a way to tackle pre-existing challenges,
system. Two major programs to foster demon- particularly high losses and poor reliability, and
stration activities in the smart grid area were cre- to facilitate distributed generation, especially the
ated: the Smart Grid Investment Grant and the rooftop solar generation, by allowing movement
Smart Grid Demonstration Programs. These two and measurement of energy in both directions,
programmes accounted for more than 93% of the using control systems and net metering that will
ARRA funds for electric grid modernisation; over help “prosumers” (NSGM, 2017). In recognition of
USD 3.4 billion and USD 0.68 billion, respectively. this, the Indian Ministry of Power has selected 14
They partially funded more than 130 demonstra- pilot projects led by different public distribution
tion projects overall.9 Figure 3.8 shows the num- utilities (see Table 3.1). These demonstration proj-
ber of demonstration projects addressing each ects mainly focus on improvements in metering
type of functionality using data extracted from a systems (essential for any loss-reduction strate-
database of smart grid demonstration projects in gy), peak-load reduction and faster recovery of
the United States. supply after an interruption. In 2015, the govern-
ment also launched the National Smart Grid Mis-
Many of these projects tested more than one
sion (NSGM), under which four additional proj-
functionality. For instance, projects dealing with
ects have been launched in 2016 (NSGM, 2017).
advanced metering infrastructure (AMI) system
Smart grid infrastructure investment is estimated
frequently address pricing and consumer sys-
to be about USD 45 billion over the period 2017-
tems as well. This figure illustrates that the prior-
27 (T&D World, 2017).
ities were mainly placed on improving consumer
information, demand response and network effi- As discussed, in order to integrate large DG levels,
ciency and reliability. As compared to the EU ac- distribution companies will need to implement
tivities, the US projects focus less on retail mar- more advanced grid technologies and operation-
kets than on grid resiliency and security. al solutions. This entails a deep transformation in
current practices, which should be accompanied
by suitable regulations encouraging the change.

9. Full information on the projects can be found at: https://www.smartgrid.gov/ and


http://energy.gov/oe/information-center/recovery-act.

102
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

Figure 3.8 Categorisation of US smart grid demonstration projects per type

Customer Systems 79

Advanced Metering Infrastructure 77

Pricing 76

Distribution Systems 69

DER 43

Transmission System 22

Energy Storage 16

Phasor Measurement Unit 14

Consumer Behaviour 9

Equipment 2
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80
Number of projects

Source: Based on Smartgrid, 2017

Table 3.1 Overview of smart grid pilots in India

Functionalities
Consumers
Jurisdiction
involved AMI AMI
PLM OMS PQM DG
Industrial Residential

Telangana 11,904 X X X X X

Assam 15,000 X X X X X X

Karnataka 24,532 X X X X X X

Chhattisgarh 1,900 X X

Puducherry 87,031 X X

Himachal
650 X X X X
Pradesh

Jaipur 34,752 X X X

Kerala 25,078 X

Maharashtra 29,997 X X X

Punjab 9,818 X X

Tripura 46,071 X X X

Gujarat 39,422 X X X

Haryana 11,000 X X X

West Bengal 4,404 X X X

Notes: AMI – advanced metering infrastructure, PLM – peak load management, OMS – outage management system, PQM – power
quality management, DG – distributed generation.
Source: Based on NSGM, 2017 103
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
3.2.4 Conclusions as some broad conditions to prevent discrimina-
and recommendations tory behaviour from the utilities.

Management of grid connection applications Despite the need for smarter distribution grids,
should be reviewed to enable a timely and at present, distribution companies have scarce
cost-effective DG connection. First, connection incentives to change, due to the inherent tech-
requests should not be processed as they arrive, nology risks and the absence of suitable regula-
but in a more co-ordinated way, e.g., in batches tory mechanisms. In the early stages, policy and
per network area. This would result in a less dis- regulation should promote the implementation
criminatory network capacity allocation and less of demonstration projects and the exchange of
costly network reinforcements. Second, the pub- lessons learnt and best practices among the rel-
lication of detailed information on the capability evant stakeholders. Thus, both the introduction
of the existing network to host additional gener- of explicit economic incentives for pilot projects
ation capacity enhances transparency and allows and the creation of public-private collaborative
promoters to make better informed connection networks are recommended.
applications. Overall, this should result in less
need for reinforcements and swifter connection
3.3 ADVANCED REGULATION
processes.
TO ENCOURAGE INNOVATION
Planning the distribution grid under high DG AND EFFICIENT DISTRIBUTED
penetration levels becomes a more complex GENERATION INTEGRATION
exercise. Greater uncertainty exists about DG
location and future feed-in. Moreover, distribution
companies will need to consider how advanced Conventional remuneration formulas and cost
grid technologies contribute to the reduction assessment methodologies are ill adapted
of conventional investments on the basis of to the high presence of DER. Efficiently
cost-benefit analyses. Regulation can push this integrating high shares of DER requires
transformation by mandating that utilities submit a major regulatory overhaul.
detailed business plans compliant with some
common format or methodology as part of the Distribution regulation has traditionally focused
revenue regulation process. on ensuring adequate investment levels and pro-
Integrating DG efficiently requires relying on a moting short-term efficiency gains whilst pre-
more active network operation to solve network venting a deterioration in service quality. These
constraints close to real-time, instead of exclu- priorities, when supported appropriately, proved
sively preventing them through network rein- successful in a context of stable technologies and
forcements. This involves the deployment of ad- predictable demand.
vanced grid technologies and ICTs as well as a Under this regulatory paradigm, distribution
closer interaction between the distribution com- companies require significant investments to ac-
pany and the existing DER. Nowadays, only a few commodate large levels of DG under safe condi-
countries allow this, mainly by means of flexible tions. Moreover, since distribution remuneration
connection contracts which enable distribution is often linked to the amount of energy distribut-
companies to temporarily curtail the power of ed, high levels of local self-consumption may re-
a network user in case of an emergency. None- sult in a decrease in distribution companies’ rev-
theless, as the presence of DER grows, more ad- enues. Consequently, utilities may see DG as a
vanced forms of contracting, such as bilateral threat to their activities, and this could hamper its
agreements or market-based approaches, should timely connection. Therefore, in the absence of an
be adopted. This should be regulated by means of in-depth regulatory reform, regulatory measures
newly developed distribution network codes de- should aim to at least neutralise the negative ef-
fining the service to be provided by DER as well fects of DG on distribution revenues.

104
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

In addition, as discussed in the previous section, framework should encourage distribution com-
a business-as-usual approach to distribution grid panies to carry out the most cost-efficient invest-
planning and operation is not suitable to accom- ments, including smart grids. In the process, it
modate large levels of renewable and distributed would ensure that remuneration is aligned with
generation in a cost-efficient and timely manner. the companies’ financing needs and reward them
Therefore, distribution companies should be en- partly on the basis of their performance, rather
couraged to deploy innovative grid technologies than only on their efficiently incurred costs.
and benefit from the flexibility offered by DER
Another fundamental aspect that regulators need
when this results in lower costs than conventional
to take into consideration is that the changes that
copper and iron reinforcements. In the early stag-
advanced power systems are experiencing, from
es, pilot demonstration projects are necessary to
the increasing VRE penetration to a more active
test innovative solutions and identify the most
participation of consumers, are strictly interlinked
promising ones on the basis of benefit-cost as-
with power system digitalization. The evolving role
sessments.
of information and communication technologies
The long-term transformation of the distribu- for the efficient management of the power system
tion network will be achieved only with a major calls therefore for a close cooperation between
regulatory overhaul. An appropriate regulatory energy and telecom regulators (see Box 3.6).

Box 3.6 Digitilisation and cooperation between energy and telecom regulators

Digitalisation can be defined as the transformation of launched a survey on “machine-to-machine” (M2M) tele-
power system onto a two-layer system that combines the communication services. The energy regulator (AEEGSI)
traditional electrotechnical technology with a new lay- contributed to the survey by collecting the experiences
er of information and communication technology (ICT), and lessons learnt in the energy sector for the deploy-
which provides functionality for remote monitoring, con- ment of smart grids and smart meters, both in the elec-
trol and protection. Of course, this kind of schematisation tricity and gas sectors. The following aspects were high-
does not mean that power system has not yet been dig- lighted in that context (AEEGSI, 2014).
italized at all. System defense tools, like automatic load
1) 
Ensuring the necessary level of interoperability (be-
shedding in case of severe frequency perturbations, were
tween devices built by different companies, between
introduced decades ago; and in the first years of the sec-
systems based on different technologies, between data
ond millennium, digitalisation made a further step ahead
collection and management platforms, etc.) and easy
in several systems, introducing, for instance, the remote
switchability among different providers (for instance
control of distribution networks. Nowadays, digitaliza-
through e-SIM, which can be provisioned “over-the-air”);
tion of power systems has much to do with deployment
of smart grids and intelligent metering systems and with 2) Orienting regulation to encourage a level of develop-
automation of final usages of electricity (including “do- ment of “smart” applications that can minimise the
motics” in the widest context of the “Internet of Things”). cost borne by the regulated systems and, ultimately,
end users, particularly the cost of communication ser-
The blurring edge between the electrotechnical layer and
vices that sometimes account for the lion’s share;
the ICT layer in digitalised power systems implies a key
regulatory challenge. So far, regulation has been tradi- 3) Ensuring that the widespread adoption of M2M appli-
tionally thought to be based on a vertical (single-sector) cations (encouraged in part by the regulator) in the
jurisdiction and, in most countries, organised with secto- energy and water networks does not pose an obstacle
rial bodies. Only in few countries (such as Germany) the to the development of multisector solutions, (for ex-
regulatory authority is a cross-sector body. In such an ample, smart cities based on shared communications
institutional context, cooperation between energy regu- infrastructure).
lators and telecom regulators is a natural byproduct of Moreover, particular attention has been drawn on the
digitilisation (BEREC, 2017). latency parameter of M2M telecommunication services, in
An example of cooperation between sectorial regula- terms of monitoring, control and protection.
tors is ongoing in Italy. In 2013, the telecom regulators

105
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
3.3.1 S
 hort-term measures to mitigate of network companies. Without knowing how to
the impact of high levels of estimate this impact, revenues could be insuffi-
distributed generation on cient to cover distribution costs – and distribu-
distribution revenues tion companies may incur financial losses. Or the
opposite could happen, and network users could
end up paying too much. Whilst these deviations
Distribution revenues should be independent
can be corrected ex post, retroactive actions
of the volume of energy distributed.
should be avoided because they tend to create
regulatory uncertainty and jeopardise the regu-
The combination of conventional regulation and lator’s credibility. Moreover, corrections are often
the high penetration of DG may result in rising hard to apply in practice given existing informa-
distribution costs and decreasing revenues for tion asymmetries, e.g., regulators would need to
distribution companies. This impact can be coun- determine ex post whether avoided investments
teracted in the short term through relatively sim- in distribution are due to decreased demand or
ple regulatory modifications. due to efficiency gains. Various ways to address
these issues are discussed in Section 3.3.2.
One of the most immediate consequences of DG,
when connected behind the customer’s meter, is Unfortunately, the conventional tools used by reg-
that the amount of energy that is metered de- ulators to assess distribution costs are ill-adapted
creases. Additionally, as discussed above, net- to the above-mentioned task. In a review of in-
work investments may even need to increase ternational practices, Jamasb and Pollitt (2001)
due to the impact of DG. This is because network find that the most common benchmarking meth-
costs typically do not directly depend on the vol- ods rely on past information and still consider the
ume of energy distributed. Moreover, network amount of energy distributed as one of the main
operators have little control over this factor, thus cost drivers. It is urgent that, as discussed in Sec-
being largely exposed to volume risks. Therefore, tion 3.3.2, these limitations are overcome through
in case of high level of DG, remuneration should the adoption of new regulatory tools able to cap-
be independent of the amount of energy distrib- ture the effect of DG and advanced grid technol-
uted in order to prevent hurting the distribution ogies so that regulators may compensate distri-
utilities financially.10 This separation is usually re- bution companies for the incremental DG-driven
ferred to as revenue decoupling. costs and that these companies do not oppose
the connection of DG:
The key element of a revenue-decoupled remu-
neration, as compared to a conventional volu- “We recognise that there is significant uncer-
metric remuneration, is that electricity rates are tainty around the volume of DG that will con-
adjusted to ensure that the utility recovers the nect in DPCR5, its generation type, location
amount of revenues initially determined by the and voltage, all of which make it very difficult
regulator. A study of the implementation of reve- to anticipate the cost of connecting the DG to
nue-decoupling mechanisms in US utilities shows the networks. We want the DPCR5 DG incentive
that, by the end of 2012, 15 states had implement- to ensure that there is still a strong incentive on
ed some form of revenue decoupling for at least DNOs to connect DG, and protect them from
one of their electric utilities, comprising up to 24 the risk of increased connection costs DG”.
electric utilities (Morgan, 2013). (OFGEM, 2009a: 22)
Revenue decoupling effectively addresses the is- Acknowledging this problem, and as a transito-
sue of revenues being depressed by DG. Never- ry measure, the United Kingdom’s energy regu-
theless, regulators will still need to pass the im- lator implemented a specific DG incentive for this
pact of DG growth on to the allowed revenues purpose. This incentive was in place for two con-

10. Similar problems may arise in the short term as a consequence of energy-efficiency measures or any other cause of falling
demand. If any of these measures reduce also reduces peak load, distribution costs may indeed decrease over the long term.

106
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

secutive regulatory periods, between 2000 and be adapted to encourage distribution utilities to
2010, before the implementation of the RIIO re- adopt innovative approaches towards grid plan-
form (see Box 3.7). This incentive comprised two ning and operation (CEER, 2014).
mechanisms which provided distribution network
In fact, several regulatory commissions have car-
operators with an additional remuneration de-
ried out (or are carrying out) various forms of
pending on the amount of DG connected.
public consultation and review processes to eval-
The estimated costs incurred by distribution uate how future regulatory frameworks should
companies to connect DG were partially passed look and the main reforms needed to achieve key
through to tariffs and subject to an accelerated goals. Salient examples include those of the United
depreciation. More specifically, companies could Kingdom (OFGEM, 2010b), Italy (AEEGSI, 2015a)
recoup 80% of the related investments over 15 and the state of New York (New York DPS, 2014).
years (the depreciation period considered for These are described in more detail in Box 3.7.
other assets was 20 years). Companies were also
given an additional amount, between £1 and £2
per every kW of DG capacity connected over an
Box 3.7
3.9 Regulatory reforms to encourage the
additional 15 years.
adoption of innovative grid technolo-
Combined, these two regulatory schemes might gies and solutions
neutralise the negative effects DG could have on
United Kingdom: The pioneering RIIO reform
DSO revenues. However, they may still be not
sufficient to achieve the degree of innovation Starting point: The United Kingdom was a forerun-
and transformation in the distribution networks ner in the application of Retail Price Index (RPI)-X
which, as discussed in Section 3.2, is necessary to regulation to the energy network industries. Over
achieve an efficient integration of high DG. time, distribution regulation evolved towards great-
er separation of revenues from the amount of ener-
3.3.2 Guidelines for smarter gy distributed, a more prominent role of compara-
distribution regulation tive benchmarking across firms, stronger emphasis
on the quality of service provision and equalisation
of incentives to reduce both capital expenditures
Conventional, investment-focused regulation
(CAPEX) and operational expenditures (OPEX) (OF-
should evolve to match the new roles of
GEM, 2009b). In fact, the regulation during the last
distribution companies regarding DER
regulatory period in which the RPI-X approach was
integration.
formally applied (2010–15) already contained many
Remuneration to distribution companies of the elements that characterised the subsequent
should have a long term view. Flexible reform.
remuneration schemes should be adopted. Regulatory reform: In 2009, the energy regulator –
Economic incentives to distribution companies the Office of Gas and Electricity Markets (OFGEM)
should focus on both operational and capital – launched a comprehensive review of network reg-
cost. Forward-looking cost assessments and ulation, which was called RPI-X@20. While acknowl-
long-term detailed utility investment plans edging that RPI-X regulation had worked well, the
should be used. report asked whether new regulatory approaches
were necessary for the challenges ahead (OFGEM,
2009c). This process resulted in a new regulatory
Pilot projects are an essential step to testing model, called RIIO for “setting Revenue using Incen-
technological solutions and disseminating knowl- tives to deliver Innovation and Outputs” (OFGEM,
edge gained and best practices. However, the 2010b).
long-term transformation of the distribution grid
The major features of the RIIO reform were as fol-
cannot rely exclusively on subsidised experimen-
lows. Regulatory periods were increased from five
tation. Over the long term, regulation needs to

1 07
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
to eight years, ex ante total expenditure (TOTEX) revenue to eight years. Input-based innovation incentives will re-
allowances were based on well-justified business plans main for non-tested smart grid solutions, with a particular
and a comprehensive cost assessment toolbox, the num- focus on the modernisation of low-voltage networks and
ber of incentives based on output factors (customer sat- the development of second-generation smart metering.
isfaction, environmental impact or energy not injected by
New York: Proposals for Reforming
renewable energy sources due to network unavailability)
the Energy Vision – REV
was increased, and automatic revenue was adjusted with-
in the regulatory period (menu regulation, profit-sharing Starting point: The traditional utility regulation mod-
and reopeners) (OFGEM, 2010a). The RIIO model is being el in New York was based on the conventional cost of
first applied to power distribution in the period 2015–23. service or rate of return regulation. Nonetheless, rate
cases progressively evolved towards multiyear reviews
Italy: Transitioning from input-based
that implicitly provided utilities with incentives to cut
demonstration to output-based deployment
costs. Therefore, earning-sharing mechanisms and per-
Starting point: The Italian approach to distribution regula- formance-based schemes, mainly related to quality of
tion was based on the combination of an incentive-based service, were also introduced in order to protect both
revenue cap on OPEX and a more conventional rate-of- consumers and utilities from potential deviations with re-
return regulation for CAPEX. In 2010, the Italian regulator spect to the conditions initially considered by the regula-
AEEGSI implemented an incentive scheme to promote tor (New York DPS, 2014).
smart grid projects with a focus on DG integration in the
Regulatory reform: The review acknowledges that con-
medium-voltage network. Under this scheme, smart grid
ventional regulation will not drive the desired evolution
investments approved by the regulator were awarded an
towards a distribution system platform provider mod-
additional 2% in their allowed rate of return for a period of
el. The proposals released so far draw heavily from the
12 years (9% pretax in total) (CEER, 2011).
United Kingdom’s experience: longer regulatory periods,
Regulatory reform: AEEGSI has recently announced its a shift towards an output-based remuneration (both for
willingness to build on the experience collected from revenue adjustment and for monitoring only or score-
the previous demonstration projects and move “from in- cards), use of flexibility mechanisms such as reopeners
put-based demonstration to output-based deployment” and earning sharing schemes and the encouragement of
(Lo Schiavo, 2015). A public consultation process was an efficient allocation of operational and capital expen-
launched in May 2015 (AEEGSI, 2015a). The proposals ditures.
made by the regulator in a resulting report offer two tar-
In this case, a TOTEX-based regulation to mitigate the
gets: equalising incentives to reduce OPEX and CAPEX
CAPEX bias would be hindered by US accounting poli-
(i.e., shifting towards a TOTEX regulation) and promoting
cies.a Another factor that sets the REV reform apart from
the deployment of smart grid functionalities presenting
its European counterparts is that, under the distribution
positive benefit-cost ratios through technical perfor-
system platform provider model, utilities are encouraged
mance indicators. This document was followed by a sec-
to seek additional revenue streams beyond existing rate-
ond round of consultations in September 2015 (AEEGSI,
based earnings in the form of value-added services pro-
2015b) and a document that identified two main function-
vided to other stakeholders (New York DPS, 2015). Ob-
alities to be covered by output-based regulation in the
taining these so-called market-based earnings may not
upcoming regulatory period, i.e., medium-voltage (MV)
be possible for European distribution companies due to
grid observability and voltage control in MV networks.
existing rules on the unbundling of activities.
Furthermore, it states that the power of the incentive
mechanisms depends on the degree of their implemen-
a. The US Generally Accepted Accounting Principles and New
tation and the technical capabilities of the solutions im- York regulations state that utilities are entitled to recover
plemented. assets based on original cost less depreciation as opposed to a
regulatory asset base determined by the regulator (and which
The regulator has recently implemented provisions, in- is not necessarily based on original costs). US utilities’ adoption
cluding incentives for the implementation of smart grid of the TOTEX regulation under the aforementioned accounting
rules could force them to write off certain assets since it is not
solutions in areas with high penetration of DG, a bo- straightforward to demonstrate that a specific asset is being
nus-malus scheme related to the modernisation of old recovered through the rates (New York DPS, 2015).
urban grids, and the lengthening of regulatory periods up

108
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

Despite their different scopes and approaches, crease transparency, provide information rele-
several common trends and guidelines can be vant to system planning and prepare future ad-
found among the most advanced proposals for ditional incentives schemes (New York DPS,
regulatory reform. These are discussed below 2014). Among the indicators proposed are asset
and summarised in Table 3.2. utilisation metrics, DG penetration, emissions re-
duction, customer satisfaction and EV adoption
Output orientation: regulation ought to shift the
(New York DPS, 2015).
focus of regulatory scrutiny from investment ad-
equacy (inputs) to how well distribution com- Efficiency incentives neutral to the actual cost
panies are providing the required services to structure (CAPEX versus OPEX): regulation
network users (outputs). Thus, distribution com- should encourage distribution companies to re-
panies should be increasingly assessed on the alise the contribution of DER to distribution net-
basis of a set of output indicators beyond the work planning and the benefits of smarter grids,
common ones related to supply interruptions and which implies exploiting the trade-offs between
energy losses. These indicators can be used for CAPEX and OPEX, e.g., investment deferral. In-
monitoring, for the purposes of comparison alone stead, existing regulatory approaches tend to en-
or even to affect distribution revenues (depend- courage companies to resort to investment-based
ing on performance levels). solutions.

For instance, New York authorities have recent- In order to rectify this, the Office of Gas and Elec-
ly proposed to relate distribution revenues to in- tricity Markets (OFGEM) has implemented two
dicators, such as peak load reduction, customer mechanisms in the latest application of RIIO to
information or time taken to process connection electricity distribution. First, cost assessments are
requests. Additionally, monitoring other types performed following a total expenditure (TOTEX)
of indicators has been proposed as a way to in- approach, i.e., the joint consideration of all com-

Table 3.2 General guidelines for a smarter distribution regulation

Shift towards an output-oriented regulation

Conventional, investment-focused regulation should evolve to match the new roles of distribution firms
regarding DER connection, environmental impact, customer satisfaction and social obligations.
Thus, additional output indicators should be used for performance monitoring or as utility revenue drivers.

Remuneration formulas neutral to the actual cost structure (CAPEX vs OPEX)

Cost reduction efforts tend to focus on OPEX due to an input orientation and short time intervals between price
reviews. However, exploiting smart grid benefits such as investment deferral thanks to a more-active network
management and DER requires equalising the incentives to cut both types of expenditures.

Forward-looking cost assessment

Due to rapid technology change and DER penetration, revenue allowances may no longer be based exclusively
on past expenditures and benchmarking studies relying on historical information. Forward-looking cost
assessments and long-term detailed utility investment plans should be increasingly used by regulators.

Price reviews with a long-term view

Shifting the goal of regulation from investment adequacy to long-term efficiency raises the question
of extending the length of regulatory periods, with intermediate monitoring and review processes
to check for excessive deviations.

More flexible remuneration formulas

Utilities are bound to face higher uncertainties driven by technology change and uncertain DER connection.
This, together with potentially longer regulatory periods, strengthens the need for more flexible remuneration
schemes such as profit- or earning-sharing mechanisms or index-triggered reopeners.

109
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
panies’ expenditures regardless of type (OFGEM, In this context, New York is planning to extend
2014). Second, a fixed percentage of the TOTEX is its multiyear rate plans from three to five years,
included in the regulatory asset base and subject whereas the United Kingdom has already extend-
to a recovery period of 45 years. Thus, the remu- ed the frequency of price controls from five to
neration is independent of the actual cost struc- eight years. The flip side of this measure is that
ture of the companies (OFGEM, 2013b). uncertainties increase. Flexibility mechanisms
and automatic revisions are then usually needed.11
Forward-looking cost assessment: regulators
ought to adapt their cost assessment tools and Flexible remuneration formulas: as the distribu-
their application, as well as request distribution tion networks evolve, technology and demand for
companies to provide them with detailed invest- network services will no longer be easily predict-
ment plans. The goal is to capture the real condi- able. If the time between price reviews is length-
tions that will be faced by the distribution compa- ened, the uncertainties are worsened. Therefore,
nies and avoid long lags between the time costs remuneration formulas should be flexible in order
are incurred and when they are recovered. to react to unforeseen events and deviations. In
practice, the main tools for this are the so-called
The application of the RIIO approach to electric-
profit- or earning-sharing mechanisms that pre-
ity distribution in the United Kingdom provides
vent distribution companies’ excessive loss or
a good example of using a forward-looking ap-
gain due to the incorrect setting of baseline rev-
proach in cost assessments. For instance, despite
enues. When these deviations exceed a certain
applying conventional regression benchmarking
level, the baseline should be revised by means
models, a combination of past information and
of reopeners. This implies that if actual costs de-
forecasted data is used as input for the models
viate more than a certain amount from baseline
(OFGEM, 2013c). Moreover, distribution compa-
revenues, the regulator is entitled to intervene.
nies were mandated to submit detailed business
plans. As part of this process, the companies had The use of earnings-sharing mechanisms is a stan-
to apply an engineering model, called the Trans- dard in New York. The regulator monitors the re-
form model, to justify that their investment plans turn on equity of utilities. When this exceeds a pre-
captured the effects of smart grids and DG (OF- defined threshold, the benefits are shared between
GEM, 2013a). the utility and the ratepayers. The innovation being
proposed is to determine the sharing factor to the
Focus on long-term efficiency: the principle of
performance indicators (outputs) of the utilities.
encouraging long-term efficiency over myopic or
Thus, utilities presenting a better performance or
strategic short-term cost reductions is embedded
scorecard will be allowed to retain much more of
in all the aforementioned guidelines. Regulators
the efficiency gain as compared to poor-perform-
should progressively extend the length of regu-
ing utilities. OFGEM has implemented a series of
latory periods to force distribution companies to
reopeners in case different types of expenses de-
adopt this long-term viewpoint. This would al-
viate significantly from the forecasts, as well as an
low distribution companies to spend their efforts
intermediate review of the outputs delivered by
in improving their performance rather than on
distribution companies (OFGEM, 2013d).
time-consuming rate cases.

11. Jenkins and Pérez-Arriaga (2014) present an advanced implementation proposal of this guideline. The authors build on the menu
regulation with profit-sharing contracts applied in the United Kingdom by introducing an automatic ex post review based on adjust-
ment factors computed in advance. These factors automatically correct revenue allowances for deviations in the load growth and
DG penetration, thus mitigating the risks derived from forecast errors.
Automatic revisions may be hampered by acceptability issues on behalf of consumer advocates (which usually play an active role
in US ratemaking), particularly when they can lead to tariff hikes. A noteworthy case is that of ComEd in Illinois in 2011. A bill was
introduced enabling this utility to invest in grid modernisation and smart metering in exchange for automatic rate increases that
granted the utility a return on equity of 10%. This bill was opposed by consumer advocates and the state attorney general, and it
was even vetoed by the state governor. It was finally passed with a “veto-proof” majority.

110
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

3.3.3 Conclusions •• Distribution companies should not be incenti-


and recommendations vised to invest in conventional network assets
The efficient integration of DG on a large scale when a less-costly alternative involving higher
is not feasible without appropriate adaptation of operation expenditures exists. Therefore, con-
regulatory practices. The focus so far has been trary to widespread practices, incentives for
placed mainly on neutralising the potential nega- cost reductions should be placed on TOTEX.
tive effect that DG may have on the revenues and •• Cost-assessment methodologies should in-
investment needs of distribution companies. creasingly rely on forecasted data and well-jus-
tified investment plans submitted by the regu-
On the one hand, distribution revenues should lated companies.
be made independent of the volume of energy •• Promoting efficient investment in distribution
distributed. Otherwise, self-consumption or ener- networks requires adopting a long-term per-
gy-efficient measures may immediately translate spective, given the long useful life of assets. In
into a reduction in revenues, whilst costs remain practical terms, this has motivated some reg-
constant or even increase. The main component ulators to lengthen the period between price
of revenue decoupling consists of an ex post reviews.
adjustment of network tariffs so that the utili- •• Remuneration formulas should be more flexible
ty exactly recoups the revenues allowed by the to account for this. Deviations between actu-
regulator. al costs and revenues allowed ex ante may be
On the other hand, as long as cost-assessment subject to profit-sharing mechanisms and even
regulatory tools are unable to capture the impact lead to a revision of the allowances in case this
of DG on distribution costs, it is necessary to set deviation exceeds a certain threshold.
economic compensations for distribution compa-
nies due to the cost increase driven by the con-
nection of DG. These compensations should be
added on top of conventional revenue allowances
and be exempt from efficiency requirements.

However, none of the aforementioned regulato-


ry measures by themselves actually encourages
distribution companies to innovate grid planning
and operation, which is a must for efficient DG
integration. Deeper changes to current regulato-
ry approaches are required to achieve this trans-
formation, as has been acknowledged by some
regulatory authorities. Revenue decoupling is
a first step, to be followed by the implementa-
tion of new regulatory frameworks that promote
long-term efficiency in the presence of large vol-
umes of DER. A review of the ongoing regulatory
reforms of this nature reveals several guidelines
for future reforms of regulatory frameworks for
power distribution:

•• The focus of regulation ought to be shifted from


ensuring that companies carry out enough net-
work investments to assessing them on the ba-
sis of their performance, measured by an ex-
tended set of indicators.

111
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
3.4. SELF-CONSUMPTION: od (IEA, 2016), thus leading to inefficient invest-
TARIFFS AND METERING ment decisions and consumption choices.

The challenge for policy makers is twofold: 1)


Self-consumption can yield benefits both eliminate barriers to the adoption of self-con-
for end users and for the power system as sumption, especially for commercial and residen-
a whole. At the same time, it can promote tial customers and 2) revisit tariff designs for net-
demand side flexibility, including the adoption work and other regulated charges adopting more
of distributed storage behind the meter. advanced retail energy pricing mechanisms that
Policy and regulation should actively promote appropriately value both the energy self-con-
self-consumption and remove administrative sumed and the energy exported to the grid.
barriers. Consumer empowerment and the diffusion of DG
In order to attain a sustainable development have paved the way for end-consumers who lo-
of active agents with consumption, production cally generate part of their electricity needs and
and storage, it is important to adopt a cost- who, during some periods, inject the surplus ener-
reflective design of retail tariffs and support gy into the grid (thus becoming a producer/con-
the roll out advanced metering technologies. sumer). Local self-consumption can deliver sav-
ings both to the end-consumer and the system
as a whole (although, as discussed below, these
Self-consumption12 is a RES promotion policy with
two do not necessarily go hand in hand). Box 3.8
a relatively simple design and with high levels of
reports two examples of commercial consumers
consumer acceptance. Despite the benefits to
that have managed to reduce their electricity bills
consumers and overall system efficiency, in case
to a significant extent thanks to self-consumption
of high DG levels, conventional tariff designs and
with solar PV.
net-metering policies13 may jeopardise a system’s
cost-recovery and create cross-­ subsidisation From a system perspective, the benefits of
among those customers who self-consume and self-consumption are realised when local gen-
those who do not. eration coincides in time with the consumption
behind the meter. Under these conditions, self-­
It is important to highlight that end-consumers
consumption reduces the utilisation rate of net-
make their decisions based not on wholesale
work assets, both at the transmission and distri-
electricity prices, but on the retail tariffs they
bution level. This reduces power flows through
pay. In fact, the cost of generating electricity of-
the grid, decreasing energy losses, especially in
ten accounts for less than half of the final electric-
the distribution network whose losses account
ity costs paid by the end-user. Another relevant
for most of total system energy losses, and re-
clarification is related to the concept of grid par-
ducing peak demand, thus potentially postpon-
ity, i.e. the point at which the LCOE of (usually)
ing the need for network reinforcements and up-
PV generation falls below the volumetric charge
grades in areas presenting scarcity of spare grid
(USD/ kWh). The adoption of PV panels on con-
capacity. Note that the benefits of investment de-
sumer premises might be spurred once this break-
ferral may be realised when the distribution com-
even point is reached. But this may not happen
pany has some certainty about the reduction of
when the retail tariffs do not reflect the actual
peak net demand, e.g., by having the possibility
value of electricity at each location and time peri-

12. S
 elf-consumption policies aim to promote the use of on-site generation for local consumption. The part of the bill that can be com-
pensated varies per different approaches. A ‘self-consumption scheme’ usually refers to the mechanism of energy consumption
in real-time (e.g. per 15 minutes). Schemes that allow compensating electricity injection into the grid and electricity consumption
during a larger timeframe are usually called ‘net-metering schemes’. Schemes that allow the calculation of the compensation on
a cash-flow basis, rather than on an energy basis, are usually called ‘net-billing schemes’. Hybrid schemes also exist (IEA-PVPS,
2016). See also Box 3.9.
13. S
 ee also ‘Review and analysis of self-consumption policies’, IEA-PVPS, 2016

112
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

to manage the injection/withdrawal of network


Box 3.8 Examples of self-consumption benefits
users. This topic is discussed in further detail in
for commercial end users
Sections 3.2.2 and 3.5.1.
The European Commission (2015c) reports the case
How to remunerate this local production is a key of a commercial consumer in Germany, further de-
policy decision. Under net-metering schemes, this scribed in Kraftwerk (2015), which is capable of
production is valued equal to the energy generat- self-consuming 87% of the annual production of its
ed for self-consumption, i.e., at the retail price (as 63 kWp photovoltaic (PV) plant.a This is achieved
discussed in Section 3.4.4). Some legislation, like because the manufacturing process runs mainly
that recently passed in Spain (MINETUR, 2015c), throughout the day, as shown in Figure 3.9. On an
eliminates the incentive to the surplus, giving it a annual basis, the company is able to decrease its an-
value of zero. Another option is to link the value nual electricity bill by more than 50 000 kWh, which
of that generation to the wholesale energy price. amounts to over 15% of its annual consumption.

Several good practices have been shown to pro- Another illustrative case is an Australian winery that
mote the adoption of self-consumption by install- installed a 90 kWp solar rooftop.b The solar system
ing DG behind the meter and to incentivise end is estimated to reduce the winery’s carbon emissions
users to not only install DG, but also to align their by 22% and results in annual savings of up to AU$ 26
production with their consumption profile (by in- 000 (approximately USD 18 900).
creasing the amount of self-consumed energy).
Policy recommendations identified by the Euro- Figure 3.9 Sample daily load profile for a plastic
pean Commission (European Commission, 2015c) manufacturing company with self-consumption
include the following: from PV

•• Allow the installation of DG and storage behind


Sample daily profile
the meter, even for small commercial and resi-
dential consumers. Generated
Operational
solar enegy
•• Simplify authorisation procedures for this kind energy consumption

of installation, allowing simple notification to Grid supply


the distribution grid operator.
•• Promote the deployment of smart meters and
KW

allow aggregators that facilitate the participa- Feed-in to grid


tion of end users into wholesale and retail mar- Self-consumed
kets. solar energy

•• By transmitting the right electricity prices to


end users, e.g., dynamic hourly prices, promote 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24

their reaction through demand-side response Hours of the day


actions and installation of distributed storage.
Source: Kraftwerk, 2015
3.4.1 Net-metering policies
Net metering constitutes a step beyond self-con- a. kWp measures the maximum power (in kW)
instantly deliverable from a PV.
sumption, and consists of allowing prosumers to b. Detailed information on this case can be found at https://
use their production surplus in a given period to www.q-cells.com/consumer/commercial-and-industrial/ref-
erences.html#references_1046894.
compensate for their consumption in a different
moment. Because of this, net-metering is some-
times characterised as allowing end users to use
the distribution grid as storage for their energy
surplus. In fact, the implications of net-meter-
ing are much deeper. These are mainly related
to the fact that, under net metering, the energy

113
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
injected into the grid is implicitly valued at the re-
Box 3.9 Key terms related to self-consumption
tail electricity price. Detailed, relevant definitions
and net-metering
and concepts are provided in Box 3.9.

As shown in Figure 3.10, net-metering is a wide-


−− Billing period: corresponds to how often end-con-
sumers receive and pay their electricity bills. This
spread policy in the United States, present as period typically ranges from one to a few months.
a mandatory rule in 41 states and several other
jurisdictions. According to SEPA (2015), 99% of −− Metering interval: interval of time for which the me-
ter records (net) consumption. In the case of mod-
solar installations across the United States were
ern electronic meters, this can be up to 15 minutes,
under a net-metering scheme in the year 2014,
whereas in the case of conventional electro-me-
representing 44% of total solar PV installed ca-
chanical meters, this would correspond to the peri-
pacity in the nation. For the sake of comparison,
od in which the period meter reading is taken and,
it is worth mentioning that, by contrast, feed-in
normally, also the billing period.
tariffs (FiTs) are present in seven states, and the
Renewable Portfolio Standard (RPS) are present −− Netting period: time interval during which prosum-
in 29 states.14 ers are allowed to compensate energy injections
and withdrawals, i.e., once this time expires, the pro-
On the other hand, the deployment of renew- sumer is no longer entitled to compensate net con-
able DG in Europe has been mainly driven by di- sumption with local excess production. This interval
rect support schemes, such as FiTs or tradable depends on the design of the net-metering scheme
green certificates (CEER, 2015c). Notwithstand- implemented by regulators, usually ranging from a
ing, net-metering, net billing, and self-consump- single hour to a whole year.a
tion have been introduced in several Europe- (a) When local production is not controllable, and once the
an countries (see Figure 3.11). Such schemes are DG installed capacity has been fixed, setting different
netting periods does not affect physical power flows
seen by policy makers as a way to keep promot- through the grid. In other words, if the consumption and
ing the adoption of RES, mainly solar PV, whilst generation profiles are set, power flows are independent
progressively phasing out existing support pay- of metering and billing arrangements. Nonetheless, eco-
nomic transactions may differ in significant ways.
ments. Moreover, self-consumption encourages

Figure 3.10 Net-metering policies across the United States in July, 2016

State-developed mandatory
rules for certain utilities
(41 states+DC+3 territories)

No statewide mandatory rules,


but some utilities allow
net metering
(2 states)

Satewide distributed
generation compensation
rules other than net metering
(4 states+1 territory)

41 States + DC,
AS, USVI, & PR
have mandatory
net metering rules
U.S. Territories: AS PR VI GU

Source: DSIRE, 2016

14. D
 ata extracted from the Database of State Incentives for Renewables and Efficiency (DSIRE.®). Accessible at: www.dsireusa.org
114
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

Figure 3.11 PV production in the European Union in 2014

10

% 5
3.5%
4

0
ly

ce

ia

im

ic

ia

ia

ia

us

ce

ria
ga

la m
ar
an

op

ai
bl
ar

an

en

ak
Ita

do

pr
ee

an
iu

st

er o
s
Sp

rtu
nm
pu
rm

nd
lg

ur

th gd
ov
ov
m
lg

Au
Cy
ng
Gr

Fr
Bu

lE

Po
Ro
Re
Be

De
Ge

Sl

n
Sl

Ki

Ne Ki
ta

d
To

of e
ec

ite

Th
Cz

PV penetration Self-consumption Un Net-biling Net-metering

Source: Solar Power Europe, 2015

locating DG close to where electricity is actually this practice can jeopardise a system’s cost-re-
consumed, thus improving network utilisation. covery rates if tariffs are not cost reflective and
if conventional metering technologies with very
In fact, the European Commission’s initiative
limited capabilities are used.
“Clean Energy for All Europeans” is proposing to
mandate that EU Member States enable renew- Under self-consumption, the value of self-con-
able self-consumption, including the right to sell sumed renewable electricity seen by end users is
excess production, and prevent “disproportion- determined by the level of the retail tariff, more
ately burdensome procedures and charges that specifically the energy term (USD/kWh). Howev-
are not cost reflective” (European Commission, er, current retail tariffs do not necessarily reflect
2016b). Self-consumption has been considered the actual cost of electricity at a given moment. It
so relevant that this provision has been included is acknowledged that the value of electrical ener-
in two different directive proposals, i.e., the elec- gy depends on the times when it is produced or
tricity Directive and the RES Directive (European consumed. Electricity markets value the energy in
Commission, 2016b, 2016c). different time frames, ranging from hourly prices
to real-time prices in periods of several minutes.
3.4.2 S
 elf-consumption and the missing Generally, this price volatility is not transmitted
money problem to retail prices. Frequently, retail prices adopt the
form of flat rates or, in some cases, energy time-
Self-consumption mechanisms with hourly or of-use rates.
even shorter netting intervals would contribute What is more, energy-based rates are often in-
to the sustainable development of on-site tended to recoup system costs that do not de-
generation. pend on the amount of energy consumed, such as
network costs, system operation costs, costs of
Self-consumption involves a straightforward im- efficiency programs or support for domestic fu-
plementation process, high levels of customer els or RES. Therefore, the amount of the system’s
acceptance, and low transaction costs. However, fixed costs that end-users with self-­consumption

115
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
installations, especially those under net-meter- Furthermore, regulators may be forced to raise
ing schemes, defray can fall if tariffs do not re- retail tariffs to ensure cost-recovery. Higher rates
flect costs. Consequently, when self-consumption also increase the economic incentive to become
occurs under conventional tariff designs – with a self-producer, creating a vicious circle. Also,
mostly a volumetric, i.e., USD/kWh, component the potential large-scale adoption of distributed
– consumers without DG are de facto subsidising storage can result in prosumers disconnecting
the ones who adopt such practices. Net-meter- from the main grid (see figure 3.12) – a process
ing schemes intensify this effect and reduce the that some have called the utility death spiral (EEI,
sensitivity of end users to variations in electricity 2013; Paulos, 2015).
costs at different times, undermining efforts to
Although grid defection is a real concern of many
promote demand-response and to promote high
utilities, this possibility should not be overstated;
RE feed-in when it is critical to do so from a sys-
not all users have the financial resources, willing-
tem-wide perspective (CEER, 2016).
ness and space to disconnect from the main grid.
It should be noted that DG can bring significant Understanding how many users do would require
benefits to the power system: it decreases pro- specific and comprehensive analysis of each ju-
duction costs and losses and defers investment risdiction (see RMI, 2014, for an example), a pro-
of new capacity. However, net-metering may not cess that goes beyond evaluating the economics
the most suitable way to compensate DER own- of solar-plus-battery systems as compared to re-
ers. Instead, enabling self-consumption with a tail tariffs. EPRI (2016) suggests that the cost and
cost-reflective pricing system, as described in reliability implications of disconnecting from the
Section 3.4.4, would benefit DER users when they main grid are often underestimated. In any case,
have a positive impact on the system. Cost-re- decreasing utility revenues and cross-subsidisa-
flective tariffs would promote efficient DER in- tion are growing concerns for policy makers and
vestments, bringing additional value to the sys- are being tackled through different policy alter-
tem as a whole as a whole. natives.

Figure 3.12 Possible effects of traditional regulatory approach in the presence of high shares of DER

End-user Perspective:
· Technology cost reduction
(PV, storage)
· Increased consumer awareness
and information

· Tariff increases · Increased DER


· Stronger incentives · Reduced revenues
for DER adoption · Grid defection

Utility Perspective:
· Fixed costs not fully recovered
· DER connection costs
· Grid modernisation investments

116
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

3.4.3 S
 hort term solutions to tackle duced. For instance, although The Kingdom of
the missing money problem Netherlands simplemented a yearly net-metering
In the absence of a well-established methodolo- scheme, prosumers only receive compensation
gy to calculate truly cost-reflective tariffs, regula- of up to 5 000 kWh/year. Similarly, Denmark re-
tors may adopt ad hoc rules to limit the amount cently changed the netting period from one year
of missing money created through self-consump- to one hour, making it a purely self-consumption
tion and potentially worsened by net-metering scheme.
policies when a high share of DG is installed.
3.4.4 T owards a new tariff
To prevent prosumers from oversizing their gen- design approach
eration units, some limitations have been set on
the allowed installed capacities per metering
Moving away from purely volumetric
point. Most net-metering policies in the United
charges towards cost-reflective tariff
States also include cumulative aggregate caps.
structures is required.
For example, PV systems in New York state may
not surpass 25 kW for residential consumers, 100 Cost-reflective network charges should
kW for farms and 2 MW for non-residential users, be allocated to end-users taking into
whereas aggregate installed capacity is limited consideration their location, net hourly
to 6% of the utility’s demand for the year 2005 consumption/injection and impact
(including solar, farm-based biogas, fuel cells, on asset utilisation.
micro-hydroelectric and residential micro-com-
bined-heat-and-power). On the other hand, DG The introduction of a rigorous design for network
units in California may go up to 1 MW in capac- and retail tariffs that sends efficient economic
ity. An overall net-metering programme cap at signals to distribution network users is the ap-
the utility level was defined by the Public Utilities propriate long-term solution to enable sustain-
Commission, beyond which the investor-owned able self-consumption and encourage demand
utilities (IOUs) are no longer obliged to offer response and storage. The following are some
net-metering to consumers. As of March 2016, steps taken by regulators in this direction.
approximately 79% of the capacity cap had been
reached (see Table 3.3). Abandon purely volumetric charges
Adopting more cost-reflective tariff struc-
The volume of energy that is self-consumed and
tures requires moving away from purely volu-
paid for can also be limited to mitigate problems
metric charges and introducing some kind of
of cost-recovery. Either the maximum amount of
fixed charge (e.g., USD/meter-month) or de-
energy consumed could be limited or, indirect-
mand charge (USD/kW). As highlighted in NREL
ly, the length of the netting period could be re-
(2015b), introducing these changes in rate struc-
tures involves careful consideration of the im-
Table 3.3 Net-metering cap at the utility level in pacts they will have on consumer bills as well as
California (March 2016) on the volumetric component. In addition to ad-
dressing the missing money problem, capacity
Remaining charges encourage prosumers to reduce stress
5% NEM
Capacity on the distribution grid. In other words, the:
Utility Capacity
March 2016
[MW]
[MW] “rate design for mass-market customers should
begin to place a greater weight on the peak de-
PG&E 2409 435.4
mand of the customer, which is closely related
SCE 2240 643.7
to the cost of the system and which can be man-
SDG&E 607 34.1 aged by the customer” (New York DPS, 2015:11).
Source: CPUC, 2016

117
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
In the same line, the State of California has recently cost-reflective tariffs, whereas a peak demand
launched a proceeding which, among other goals, charge encourages consumers to install storage
aims to “ensure that the successor tariff is based on capacity for peak shaving, thus mitigating the im-
the costs and benefits of the renewable electrical pact of PV penetration on the system.
generation facility”.15 The residential rate structure
Expose prosumers to time-dependent pricing
was revised, after which the state’s Public Utilities
Commission recommended utilities to implement The energy component of the retail tariff deter-
either minimum bills or fixed charges on residen- mines the value of prosumers’ self-consumed
tial consumers (CPUC, 2014). energy. Flat energy rates have been convention-
ally applied, especially to residential consumers,
Box 3.10 shows how different pricing schemes can mostly for reasons of simplicity, limited metering
affect end-users’ investment decisions. Net-me- capabilities and an alleged lack of demand flex-
tering promotes the installation of higher PV ca- ibility. However, these assumptions are being in-
pacities, probably above the optimal size under creasingly challenged by the ongoing changes

Box 3.10 Simulation of investment decisions in PV and storage under different pricing schemes

Figure 3.13 shows the results of an analysis aiming to purely volumetric charges; in the second, half of the net-
estimate the effect of net-metering together with peak work costs are recovered through a peak demand charge.
demand charges on end-users’ investment decisions
It can be observed that net-metering significantly encour-
regarding photovoltaic (PV) and storage systems un-
ages PV investments, even in the presence of a demand
der three different technology costs (Burger, 2015). The
charge. Nonetheless, the break-even point for PV invest-
results correspond to an average New York residential
ments is affected by this demand charge. Investments
house located in a suburb north of New York City with
in storage, which in this case were not profitable with a
a load profile based on information available at the US
purely volumetric tariff, are also encouraged to meet the
Department of Energy and Energy Information Adminis-
evening peak demand. Storage may even be profitable
tration. Two pricing scenarios for a monthly netting peri-
for end-users in the absence of PV, thanks to its potential
od are considered: in the first, consumers are exposed to
for reducing peak demand.

Figure 3.13 Influence of pricing signals on PV and storage investment decisions

6 6
Storage Installed (kWh)

5 5
PV Installed (kW)

4 4
3 3
2 2
1 1
0 0
PV Storage PV Storage PV Storage PV Storage
With net-metering Without net metering With net-metering Without net metering

Without peak demand charge With peak demand charge

PV (1,750 $/kW) / Storage (250 $/kWh) PV (3,000 $/kW) / Storage (425 $/kWh)

PV (2,250 $/kW) / Storage (355 $/kWh)

Source: Based on Burger, 2015

15. http://www.cpuc.ca.gov/PUC/energy/DistGen/NEMWorkShop04232014.htm.

118
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

in the power sector. Truly cost-reflective elec- based rate design is likely to reduce the current
tricity rates should include time differentiation. level of support provided to NEM […]. The goal
The most straightforward form of time-depen- of promoting customer-sited DG is important,
dent pricing would be time-of-use (ToU) tariffs, but […] subsidies should be explicit and trans-
whereas the most advanced approach is based parent” (CPUC, 2014: 24).
on hourly prices enabled by advanced metering
“Best practice include: […] Preference for
infrastructure (AMI) and, in liberalised settings,
self-consumption schemes over net-metering
by liquid and transparent wholesale markets.
schemes […] Phasing in of short-term market
The European Commission (2015c) provides rec- exposure by valuing surplus electricity injected
ommendations on the implementation of new into the grid at the wholesale market price” (Eu-
grid tariff designs to tackle the missing mon- ropean Commission, 2015c: 12).
ey problem and to incentivise system efficiency
In fact, several alternative approaches to net-me-
through self-consumption. These include:
tering, especially relevant in presence of high
•• Future tariff designs should be based on objec- shares of DG, can compensate excess on-site DG
tive and non-discriminatory criteria and reflect production. In Denmark, prosumers are paid a
the impact of the consumer on the electricity FiT (0.08€/kWh) for their net electricity exports,
grid while guaranteeing sufficient recovery of whereas in the United Kingdom, PV systems small-
grid and system costs. er than 30 kilowatt peak (kWp) are given both a
•• If modifications of the current tariff struc- generation tariff for the energy that is self-con-
ture are deemed necessary and appropriate, sumed and a bonus for the excess electricity fed
they should take into account the need to en- into the grid (European Commission, 2015c).
sure stability for previous investments in self­-
As costs go down and technology matures,
consumption installations.
self-produced electricity will increasingly com-
Decouple feed-in compensation from pete against centralised generation rather than
retail tariffs against a retail tariff. In a recent Portuguese reg-
Implicitly compensating the injection of electric- ulation on self-consumption, for example, the en-
ity at the retail tariff level, as net-metering does, ergy injected into the grid is compensated at the
is de facto a support instrument to RE produc- average value of spot market prices (reduced by
tion that has demonstrated to be very effective 10% to account for grid costs).
to promote the deployment of decentralised Figure 3.14 shows that different US states have
RE solutions in several countries. However, this implemented mechanisms that decouple the val-
mechanism may not adequately reflect the real ue of net excess production from retail tariffs.
value of RE feed-ins at different moments. This is
acknowledged by many policy makers: Advanced tariff designs as a driver
for demand response and distributed storage
“The current convention of crediting at the av-
For end-users’ tariffs to reflect costs, tariff design
erage retail rate may be either too little or too
methodologies should acknowledge the different
much […]. Through the calculation of the full
added cost components of retail electricity rates.
value of DER to the system the utility will be
These components are: 1) the electricity price/
able to determine the total economic value of
cost in each time period and location; 2) the cost
the resource […] used as the basis of the credit”
of the transmission and distribution networks and
(New York DPS, 2015: 13).
3) other regulated costs, such as system opera-
“Given the level of cross-subsidy that [net ener- tion or RES support.16
gy metering (NEM)] represents today, any cost-

16. Note that these components strictly correspond to the costs of electricity supply. Nonetheless, taxes and levies may amount
to a significant share of the final retail tariffs, even exceeding 50% of the final price in some European countries, such
as Germany and Denmark (IEA, 2016).

119
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
Figure 3.14 Treatment of prosumers’ excess energy across the United States in July, 2016

NEG credited at retail rate;


credits do not expire

NEG credited at retail rate


at first, then credits expire
or are reduced
(e.g., to the avoided cost
rate at the end of year)

NEG credited at less


than retail rate
(e.g., avoided cost rate)

NEG is not compensated

No statewide mandatory
net metering rules

Source: DSIRE, 2016

Exposing end-users to energy prices that vary coup network costs and send end-users efficient
over time and location within the grid would pro- long-term economic signals affecting location
mote demand flexibility and distributed stor- and investment decisions. Cost-reflective net-
age. Although this is done through ToU energy work charges should be based on the drivers for
prices or hourly dynamic prices, more advanced network expansion (Bharatkumar, 2015), such as
schemes based on distribution locational margin- location, net hourly profile (how much end users
al prices (DLMP) have been proposed (Bohn et may be consuming or producing depending on
al., 1984). DLMPs essentially extend the concept the hour) and users’ contribution to asset utilisa-
of nodal prices applied at the transmission level to tion during the most critical periods of the year.
distribution networks. Thus, DLMPs reflect elec-
This methodological approach yields network
tricity’s different values depending on where it is
charges that are largely independent of the
being consumed or injected in the network. This
volume of energy injected or consumed, but are
pricing methodology would therefore capture the
rather based to a great extent on a fixed per-
effect of energy losses (which mostly take place
user component, which could be differentiated
at the distribution level) and grid congestion. Dy-
by voltage level or type of network user,17 and a
namic energy prices provide end-users with effi-
time-dependent capacity component (USD/kW)
cient short-term economic signals that promote
reflecting the impact of each end-user on the
a rational utilisation of DG, storage and demand
utilisation of network assets. The aforementioned
response, either by themselves or in combination.
capacity term would reflect the incremental
Network costs, both transmission and distribu- network costs driven by the existence of network
tion, are recovered through the so-called network constraints, either current or foreseen, in the
charges. Properly designed network charges re- corresponding period.18 However, in the absence

17. T
 his term could be calculated for each network user or group of consumers according to different criteria at the choice
of the regulator: Ramsey, fairness, burden sharing between small and large consumers, etc.
18. Note that, if DLMPs were in place, which is not the case in any system, part of these congestion-driven costs would be embedded
into these energy prices. However, DLMPs, as it happens with nodal pricing in transmission networks, would not be enough
to recoup the full network costs.

120
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

of constraints, capacity charges may produce 3.4.5 T he importance


inefficient responses from network users to of metering arrangements
reduce the loading of a grid that is not congested, The flexibility of regulators to implement their de-
e.g., peak load reduction or storage installation. sired self-consumption/net-metering scheme can
Thus, the remaining costs (sunk costs), which are be severely limited by insufficient metering capa-
not driven by peak consumption or generation, bilities. Conventional electromechanical meters
should be recovered through the fixed charge allow only simple schemes with no or scarce time
to prevent the distortion of previous economic granularity and without compensation for net ex-
signals. ported energy. Electromechanical bidirectional
It is noteworthy that network tariffs ought to be meters, or a two-meter configuration, overcome
technology neutral. This means that for each time this last barrier. However, the length of netting
period and location the variable network charge periods would be limited by the meter-reading
(USD/kWh) should be the same, but with the op- process. Since meters are read every one or two
posite sign for consumption and injection. How- months, cost-recovery would hardly be mitigated
ever, contrary to what is common today, these by reducing the netting period.
should not depend on the type of user that is be- Therefore, electronic meters capable of recording
hind the meter. Instead, for example, a power in- bidirectional energy flows every few minutes are
jection from a generator should be valued equal a precondition for the most advanced net-meter-
to that of a storage unit or a reduction in demand. ing schemes relying on time-varying tariffs and/
Lastly, retail tariffs include other regulated costs or very frequent netting periods. Should a new
related to renewable energy support policies or meter installation or replacement be needed,
social policies. These costs can be very relevant regulators should assess the suitability of setting
in some countries and their allocation to end-us- the obligation to install modern metering devic-
ers should not distort the short- and long-term es on prosumer premises. The implementation
economic signals provided through energy prices of efficient self-consumption policies is not the
and network charges. In this regard, several solu- only driver for smart metering. Section 3.5.2 will
tions have been proposed. For example, these further discuss other issues related to smart me-
costs could be removed from the electricity rates, tering, such as its role in enhancing consumer
defrayed through the public budget or in the form awareness, retail market functioning and demand
of a tax applied to all forms of energy consump- response. The section will also outline smart me-
tion, not only electricity. Another option could be tering deployment policies as well as metering
to recover these costs through a fixed charge per data management models.
consumer, acknowledging the existence of differ-
ent customer categories (residential, commercial, 3.4.6 Additional policy considerations
industrial) and even subcategories (residential The implementation of the aforementioned pol-
consumers with small, medium and large hous- icy measures may raise some additional consid-
es, for instance), but independent of their energy erations that are not strictly related to self-con-
and capacity injections of withdrawals. sumption and net-metering but are important to
It is through the implementation of efficient short- take into account.
and long-term economic signals (e.g., energy Regulators ought to bear in mind how changes
prices and network charges, respectively) that in retail tariff structure would affect all consum-
distribution network users will be encouraged to ers, not only new prosumers. For instance, intro-
provide the full value of distributed storage and ducing a capacity charge would modify the eco-
demand response. Moreover, when combined nomic signals seen by pre-existing prosumers,
with DG, both resources can maximise self-con- thus modifying the conditions in which they eval-
sumption and benefit the system as a whole. Ag- uated their investment in DG. Moreover, the in-
gregators may act as mediators to exploit the ad- troduction of fixed or capacity charges can have
ditional flexibilities offered by these resources.

121
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
unintended consequences for low-consumption network investment and enhancing consumer
customers, who may see their bills suddenly in- engagement and participation. Self-consumption
crease. Therefore, gradual reforms and the pro- should therefore be supported by regulation.
gressive implementation of tariff changes are
Nonetheless, if not adequately designed, self-con-
advisable (CPUC, 2014; European Commission,
sumption measures may create a missing money
2015c; New York DPS, 2015).
problem in traditional regulatory settings, that
Burdensome administrative procedures and com- may jeopardise the financial viability of utilities.
plex tariff options may pose a significant barrier The reason for this is usually a combination of
to end-users, particularly residential consumers. a not adequate retail tariff design, which main-
Another policy priority should be to reduce trans- ly relies on a volumetric term to recover all sys-
action costs for prosumers through targeted in- tem costs, and old metering technologies, which
formation, simplified administrative procedures are not capable of measuring bidirectional power
or web-based calculators (CPUC, 2014; European flows with a high level of time differentiation. In
Commission, 2015b). some contexts, the challenge may be worsened
by high volumes of net-metering policies, which
Another important issue to bear in mind is the
implicitly value the energy injected into the grid
impact that a potential massive deployment of
at the retail electricity price. In response, regula-
small-scale storage, coupled with DG, can have
tors have tried to limit the allowed installed ca-
on the power system, and distribution networks
pacity or the amount of energy being compen-
in particular. Prosumers, following price signals,
sated, or shorten the period of time over which
could use the storage systems to store electric-
energy injections are reduced from the amount of
ity and inject it back into the grid at different
electricity billed and paid.
moments in time. Potentially, this could make
it even more difficult for system operators to These provisions, however, do not represent a
forecast production from DG. This is yet anoth- sustainable long-term solution to the missing
er argument in favour of implementing a set of money problem. The potential negative effects
cost-reflective tariff structures. Moreover, DER of high level of capacity supported through net
access to the upstream markets should be en- metering depends on the combination of mostly
abled. This would require, among other things, volumetric (USD/kWh) tariffs and standard me-
extending the conventional roles of distribution ters, which are applied and read monthly at the
companies, strengthening co-operation between most. Therefore, it would be advisable to pro-
transmission and distribution grid operators and mote self-consumption schemes with hourly or
promoting the aggregation of DER. Section 3.5.1 even shorter netting intervals. In addition to this,
discusses these issues in further detail. The key end-users, especially those with self-consump-
regulatory challenge in this regard lies in how tion installations, should be exposed to well-de-
to co-ordinate different economic signals when signed retail tariffs that reflect the value of ener-
these enter into conflict, for example, when the gy at each moment as well as its impact on future
provision of balancing services by a DG unit or investments. When additional incentives com-
a prosumer results in congestion at the distribu- pensating surplus electricity that is not instan-
tion level. taneously self-consumed are deemed necessary,
these should be explicit.
3.4.7 Conclusions
and recommendations Some policy makers and regulators have already
started to implement provisions that could be
Self-consumption through the installation of DG
considered aligned with cost-reflectivity crite-
and, in the future, storage behind the meter is a
ria, such as introducing demand or fixed charges,
policy alternative that benefits end-users by de-
ToU tariffs or decoupling the value of electrici-
creasing their electricity bills and benefits the
ty feed-in from the level of retail prices. Truly
system by reducing energy losses, encouraging
cost-reflective tariffs would send efficient short-

122
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

and long-term signals to end users, reflecting costs, at least in part, through alternative rev-
their contribution to system costs and ensuring enue sources such as public budgets or taxes.
the recovery of total system costs. Their calcu-
Well-designed retail rates, including adequate
lation should consider the following components
time granularity, can only be transferred to
of system costs: 1) the price of the energy on the
end-consumers if an advanced metering infra-
market, with temporal and locational differentia-
structure is available. Electronic meters capable
tion; 2) the cost of the grid and 3) other regulat-
of recording bidirectional energy flows every few
ed costs.
minutes are a precondition for the sustainable
•• Cost-reflective prices of electricity acknowl- development of self-consumption and to spur
edge its different value over time, and also by end users’ demand response, including distribut-
location, reflecting network effects (congestion ed storage.
and energy losses). Time-of-use or dynam-
ic energy prices translated to end-consumers
3.5 F
 UTURE ROLE OF DISTRIBUTION
with DG and future storage installations would
COMPANIES
provide efficient economic short-term signals.
These signals would in turn promote the effi-
cient operation of those resources, including Distribution companies have to bridge
demand-response, generation dispatch and the gap between flexibility providers, markets
storage management. and system operators. Moreover, they should
•• Network charges should provide end-users integrate the flexibilities offered by DER into
with economic signals promoting efficient loca- their planning and operational practices.
tion and investment decisions, which should be Thus, distribution companies should
based on the actual contribution of each net- adopt new roles as market facilitators
work user to the network costs. Cost-reflective and distribution system operators.
network charges should be calculated attending
to the various drivers of grid expansion. Thus,
they should be allocated to end-users taking The energy transition is undoubtedly affecting
into consideration their location, their net hour- all segments of the electricity power industry.
ly consumption/injection and their contribution Nonetheless, it is in the lower end of the supply
to asset utilisation. The resulting charges would chain where these impacts are driving a deeper
consist of a time-dependent capacity compo- transformation. The system’s decentralisation,
nent reflecting the individual contribution to the deployment of ICTs and enhanced consum-
network peak utilisation (both injection and er awareness are forcing distribution companies
withdrawal), plus some fixed component relat- to reconsider their conventional roles as network
ed to the grid connection and other costs that owners and operators.
can be somehow shared by all network users. The agents located at the distribution level are
•• The remaining regulated costs related to ener- gaining in importance and their active contri-
gy or social policies, when transferred to elec- bution will become essential to ensure secure
tricity rates, should not distort the previous system operation. In this context, distribution
short- and long-term economic signals. Several companies represent stakeholders essential to
solutions have been proposed for the alloca- connecting end-users with upstream markets
tion of such costs – e.g., through a fixed charge and system operation. Moreover, utilities should
or differentiated by customer size or category. integrate the flexibilities offered by DER into their
Fixed charges can also have undesired effects, planning and operational practices by newly de-
such as jeopardising low-demand consumers, fined mechanisms. Performing these new roles,
debasing demand response and energy-effi- distribution companies will see themselves in-
ciency efforts or encouraging grid defection. teracting more closely with other agents such as
Policy makers may decide to recoup these suppliers, aggregators and TSOs/ISOs.

123
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
Moreover, regulation should define the role to be tems. Distribution-connected resources will have
played by distribution companies in the deploy- a stronger presence in energy markets, and their
ment of advanced metering, as well as data col- active contribution to the secure system operation
lection and management. These questions are will be increasingly necessary through the provi-
essential to unlock the flexibility potential of de- sion of ancillary services and network support.
mand response, ensure a sustainable develop-
In this new environment, distribution companies
ment of self-consumption and facilitate well-func-
can enable the participation of DER in compet-
tioning retail markets.
itive markets in a transparent and non-discrimi-
Lastly, distribution companies may play a role in natory way. Moreover, the companies themselves
the deployment and operation of new grid-edge are bound to become buyers of these flexibility
infrastructures, such as public EV charging sta- services in order to ensure efficient distribution
tions or distributed storage. The major regulato- planning and operation. Hence, it can be said that
ry question is whether to consider this infrastruc- distribution companies will need to shift their role
ture as part of the business model of distribution from that of network manager to market facilita-
companies or, on the contrary, open them for pri- tor and system operator.
vate initiative.
It is noteworthy that, starting with similar goals
The development of EVs and its impact on the (efficient DER integration, enhanced flexibility),
distribution activity is yet one more signal that different regions may follow significantly differ-
the integration of RES should be part of a holis- ent strategies. This is clearly illustrated by the fol-
tic approach to achieving a low-carbon energy lowing two examples.
system. The electricity system is more and more
In the European context, regulators and poli-
related to other sectors, such as transport and
cy makers have placed a strong emphasis on
heating/cooling. This requires policy makers to
full market liberalisation. Therefore, distribution
consider coherent and co-ordinated intersector
companies or DSOs are prevented from per-
planning.
forming any activity potentially subject to com-
3.5.1 Moving from network managers petition. In those areas where this is not clearly
to market facilitators defined – e.g., energy efficiency advice, distribut-
and system operators ed storage ownership or metering data manage-
ment – a strong regulatory supervision is advo-
cated. Moreover, the enforcement of unbundling
Regulation should grant DER access to rules is seen as a key policy measure to ensure a
upstream energy and ancillary services, and transparent and non-discriminatory market func-
facilitate greater coordination with TSOs/ISOs. tioning (CEER, 2015b). Meanwhile, unbundling
Distribution companies should facilitate this rules make managing a significant amount of dis-
participation and carry out activities such as persed resources a complex task, as discussed
an ex-ante technical validation and an ex-post below.
verification of the provision of the service.
In a second example, the ongoing regulato-
ry reform in the state of New York actually en-
The growing presence of more flexible and di- courages utilities to seek what they have called
verse distribution network users forces distribu- market-based earnings. These are new revenue
tion companies to reconsider their convention- streams stemming from new activities, subject
al roles as mere network owners and operators. to competition or not, beyond their conventional
As the decentralisation of the power system ad- network-related duties. Box 3.11 describes a pro-
vances, DER will become increasingly important posal submitted by one of the state’s utilities com-
players in the overall functioning of power sys- prising four programs to yield market-based earn-

1 24
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

The distribution company as a market facilitator


Box 3.11 Market-based earnings and new roles Despite the power sector transformation, distri-
of utilities in New York bution companies will inevitably remain regulat-
As part of the ongoing regulatory reform in the ed networks. Neutrality and transparency should
state of New York, utilities are requested to submit govern any interaction between distribution com-
to the regulator proposals for innovative business panies and network users. The tasks of regulators
models, consistent with the sector transformation, and policy makers is to set the rules that encour-
that can provide utilities with new revenue streams age network companies to act as neutral mar-
– or so-called market-based earnings. For example, ket facilitators (CEER, 2015b). In this context, the
Central Hudson Gas and Electric Corporation has term “market” comprises retail markets, energy
presented a proposal including four of these pro- markets and ancillary services markets (THINK
grams (PSC, 2014). Project, 2013).
1. A community solar program would install and op-
Concerning retail markets, questions on the new
erate a utility-scale solar plant and sell solar ener-
role of distribution companies arise when the lib-
gy, in blocks of 100 kilowatt hours (kWh) and at a
eralisation process has been introduced in this
fixed rate, to end consumers and energy services
segment. On the one hand, distribution compa-
companies willing to buy them.
nies play a key role in managing the connections
2. A demand-response programme would require (in the case of new users) and disconnections (in
end-consumers or aggregators on their behalf to case of contract termination or non-payments
reduce their consumption upon request from the among the suppliers’ customers). This is a core
utility. The goal is to reduce the state-wide peak function of distribution companies, which in a lib-
demand and defer network investments in areas eralised context requires the intermediation of
selected by the utility.
suppliers who are the entities with a commercial
3. 
New micro-grids, targeted at consumers or relationship with end consumers.
groups of consumers above 500 kilowatts (kW),
The most critical role concerning a transparent
would provide end-users with improved reliabili-
and well-functioning retail market is that of man-
ty in exchange for a given fee.
aging metering data and providing data access
4. Voluntary smart meters would provide consum- to different stakeholders, particularly after the
ers with enhanced information on consumption deployment of AMI. In a liberalised retail mar-
patterns and pricing options to manage their en- ket, providing data access to retail companies in
ergy bills. Subscribers would pay for the incre- a transparent and non-discriminatory manner is
mental cost of the smart metering system.
essential to ensure competitive market function-
ing. Moreover, this information must be offered to
end consumers so that they can actively engage
ings. Distribution utilities will also play a key role and make better-informed contracting decisions.
in facilitating the participation of other players in Overseeing the behaviour of distribution compa-
these services. According to this vision, utilities nies on this matter is particularly relevant where
would become distributed system platform pro- these companies belong to a vertically integrated
viders (New York DPS, 2014). It is acknowledged utility undertaking active in the retail market or
that greater regulatory oversight will be neces- when distribution companies act as default sup-
sary to ensure transparency and prevent unfair pliers. Section 3.5.2 discusses this specific topic
practices among utilities (New York DPS, 2015). in more depth.

Concerning energy and ancillary services mar-


kets, questions on the new role of distribution
companies arise because of the participation of
distribution-connected DER in these markets

125
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
that are run by a market or system operator (see
Box 3.12 Balancing generation and demand
Table 3.4). This participation is to be encouraged,
with distributed flexibility
especially as the power system is more and more
decentralised. Therefore, regulation should en- In Belgium, distributed energy resources (DER) are
sure that the role of each stakeholder involved is already offering their flexibility to the transmission
clearly defined, particularly that of the distribu- system operator (TSO) for balancing generation and
tion company. demand. The distribution company performs a pre-
liminary assessment of those users willing to provide
More specifically, distribution companies may the balancing service in a prequalification stage and
act as market facilitators by technically validat- send metering data to the TSO to verify the service
ing the offers submitted by DER to the upstream provisions from DER (ISGAN, 2014).
markets, i.e., by ensuring no distribution network
The country plans on enhancing the transparency of
constraints are violated. This role would be sim-
this mechanism by setting up a real-time balancing
ilar to what TSOs/ISOs do today with wholesale
platform to allow the TSO to contract flexibility, sub-
markets results. Additionally, after the service de-
stituting the current bilateral agreements. Moreover,
livery, distribution companies may be required to
the distribution company is to be given more visibil-
verify the provision of the services using meter- ity over the actions of DER and contracting options.
ing data from DER. Box 3.12. presents the case of Lastly, if the flexibility provision of DER keeps grow-
Belgium, where distribution-connected resourc- ing, its impact on the planned schedules of balanc-
es are already providing flexibility services to the ing responsible parties should be better considered.
TSO. This case study also shows that the conven- Otherwise, the flexibility of DER would cause a de-
tionally limited interaction between distribution viation in their control areas, for which they would
companies and system operators needs to be re- be penalised.
vised.

Interactions between the distribution


company and the TSO/ISO areas of competence. Transmission and distribu-
tion networks interface in specific substations
Under liberalised electricity markets, system op-
that interconnect them. Under the current prac-
erators (TSOs or ISOs) and distribution network
tices, both operators interact periodically when
operators have been unbundled. Both are in
they plan the need for new network assets. With-
charge of ensuring system secure operation and
in the traditional, centralised, unidirectional flow
adequate investment planning in their respective

Table 3.4 Major services that DER may provide to DSOs and TSOs

Type of DER able System operator procuring


Service
to offer the service such services

System balancing services All types of DER TSO


Frequency control All types of DER TSO
Voltage control All types of DER DSO
Blackstart Larger-scale DS and DG TSO and DSO
Short-term security DG, DS, DR, (EV) TSO and DSO
congestion management

Source: THINK Project, 2013


Note: This table classifies DER into general categories, namely, DG, demand response, EVs and distributed storage. However, when
the table states that a certain type of DER can offer a specific service, this does not mean that any member of that category is
necessarily capable of doing so. For instance, the fact that DG, in general, could provide balancing services does not necessarily
mean that any type of DG is technically capable or that it is economically reasonable for it to provide this service.

126
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

model, distribution companies provide TSOs with In this example, it is proposed that the DSO could
forecasts of the load growth at their respective use the flexibility provided by customers with
network interface points. DER (demand-side response, distributed genera-
tion, storage) to reduce the load condition of the
With the change in paradigm driven by more
TFO (Figure 3.15). There are other operating situ-
flexible and decentralised resources connected
ations – such as line congestion, voltage support
directly to distribution networks and the more
or black-start – where this co-ordination would
active role of distribution companies operating
be beneficial.
those resources, there is an increasing need for
co-ordinating actions between TSOs and distri- Those co-ordinated actions require DSOs to im-
bution companies at the operational level. The plement innovative technology solutions that are
flexibility connected at the distribution level may available but not yet deployed, such as grid mon-
be an efficient resource for solving network prob- itoring, two-way communications with flexible
lems, not only at the distribution level but also in customers and with the TSO, and network quasi
the transmission network. real-time simulations.

Several models enabling this co-ordination be- The distribution company as a system operator
tween the distribution and wholesale levels can The previous example of TSO-DSO interactions
be envisioned. All these typically require some represents a case where the distribution compa-
form of aggregation of a large number of DER, ny ought to request flexibility services from its
either by the distribution company itself (which network users. Nonetheless, this would not be
may be hampered by unbundling rules) or by the only case where the distribution company
competitive agents such as retailers and aggre- should interact with DER to optimise the opera-
gators who deliver services at both the distribu- tion of the grid. There are situations in which this
tion and wholesale level (IEA, 2016). In this re- would be desirable. Regulatory mechanisms that
gard, ISGAN (2014) provides country examples of aim to foster this interaction include non-firm
interaction between TSOs and distribution com- connection agreements, bilateral flexibility con-
panies in grid operation are identified. Table 3.5, tracts and local markets (see Section 3.2.2 and
for instance, shows the current practices and the Eurelectric, 2013; CEER, 2015b).
future needs for TSO-DSO co-ordination in case
of congestion in the transformer at the interface A relevant initiative in this regard can be found
between the transmission and distribution net- in the European context. The new proposal for
works when the transformer (TFO) is owned and an Electricity Directive issued by the European
operated by the TSO. Commission on November 2016, if approved as is,
would mandate Member States to ensure that reg-

Table 3.5 Current and future TSO-DSO interactions

Today Future

· Avoided in many countries by considering · More grid monitoring and intensified data
n-1 criteria in the network planning exchange would allow using flexibility
on the distribution grid to reduce
· Cooperation mostly during transformer loading when necessary
TFO congestion the planning phase
· A request sent from the TSO
· Emergency situations: TSO disconnects to the DSO could translate this request to
distribution feeders, possibly through use-of-flexibility requests to flexible
a request to the DSO customers connected to the distribution grid

Source: ISGAN, 2014

127
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
Figure 3.15 Process for avoiding TFO congestion using flexibility In the distribution grid

Party Input Analysis Output

Required
TSO TFO load monitoring TFO loading
decrease

· Grid configuration
Distribution of
· Grid load monitoring Flexibility request
requested flexibility,
DSO · Monitoring of flexible
taking into account
to single flexible
customers: actual customers
network limits
avaible flexibility

Source: Adapted from ISGAN, 2014

ulation enables and promotes distribution compa- treatment, promote competition when there are
nies to procure flexibility services from network us- several potential suppliers for the same service
ers (European Commission, 2016b). Moreover, this and reduce the potential for market power abuse
Directive calls for the use of “transparent, non-dis- when the number of suppliers is low.
criminatory and market based procedures” and
requires distribution companies to define stan- 3.5.2 A
 dvanced metering
dardised and technology-neutral market products. to enable demand response
and competitive retail markets
This constitutes a deep change in the conven-
Traditionally, small residential and commercial
tional role of distribution companies, whose in-
consumers have been offered very limited tariff
teraction with end-users has been conventional-
options with scarce time differentiation. However,
ly limited to grid connection and disconnection,
the integration of large shares of RES, increased
management of supply outages and, where the
interest from consumers in making better-in-
distribution company was part of a vertically in-
formed decisions and the efforts to introduce
tegrated utility, billing. Thus, distribution compa-
competition in the retail electricity sector re-
nies ought to evolve from purely network manag-
quire a shift in paradigm. Advanced metering is
ers to true distribution system operators, actively
a key enabling technology for the active partic-
managing the resources connected to their grids,
ipation of electricity end-users. Thus, smart me-
similar to what TSOs do today. Moreover, new
tering is a prerequisite for demand response and
market players, such as aggregators, may come
well-functioning retail markets, as well as a sus-
on the scene, who combine the responses from
tainable penetration of self-consumption and an
individual customers responding to the needs of
active management of EV charging and distribut-
the distribution company.
ed storage.
In the new context concerning liberalised mar-
There are two main policy and regulatory deci-
kets, regulation should enable the change and
sions in this domain: 1) ownership and manage-
clearly define the roles and responsibilities of dis-
ment model for the deployment of advanced me-
tribution companies and market players. Regula-
ters and 2) management of metering data and
tory oversight will be needed, particularly where
granting access to stakeholders in a transparent
the distribution company belongs to a larger ver-
and non-discriminatory way.
tically integrated company, to avoid preferential

128
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

Advanced metering roll-out tive cost-benefit analysis is obtained or where


The installation and management of metering a large-scale rollout is not planned. This meter
equipment have been conventionally carried out must be provided under fair conditions and com-
by distribution utilities, especially for small and ply with minimum technical standards defined in
medium consumers. Thus, metering assets have the proposal for a new Electricity Directive (Euro-
been traditionally treated as part of the monopo- pean Commission, 2016b). Table 3.6 summarises
listic activities of distribution companies who re- the cost-benefit analysis results obtained for Ger-
cover the corresponding costs through network many and the United Kingdom.
charges or a rental fee. A model where the dis- According to a benchmarking study carried out
tribution company is responsible for the deploy- by the European Commission, as of mid-2014,
ment of advanced metering seems the most im- 16 countries had decided to implement a large-
mediate solution, even in contexts where retail scale deployment, another three had opted for
and distribution have been unbundled. For ex- selective deployment, and just four had rejected
ample, in the European Union, distribution com- advanced metering altogether (European Com-
panies are responsible for meter installation and mission, 2014a). A potential drawback of a large-
ownership in most member states, with just a few scale rollout is that some consumers may op-
exceptions, such as in Germany and the United pose it due to alleged health or privacy concerns.
Kingdom (European Commission, 2014a; 2014b). Therefore, some regulators have decided to in-
In Germany, consumers are entitled to choose troduce an opt-out clause in the advanced meter-
any metering operator, i.e., metering is legally ing programs, as in the case of California (CPUC,
considered a fully competitive activity. Nonethe- 2012a; 2012b) and the The Kingdom of Nether-
less, distribution companies are still the default lands (European Commission, 2014c).
metering operators and deliver metering services Brazil offers a middle path between a mandat-
to those consumers who do not explicitly opt for ed rollout and complete free customer choice.
a third-party metering operator. Meanwhile, elec- In 2012, the regulator passed a norm mandating
tricity metering in the United Kingdom falls under distribution companies to offer their customers
the responsibility of suppliers (European Com- the choice of installing a smart meter. The offer
mission, 2014a). highlighted the potential benefits of access to en-
In order to foster the penetration of advanced hanced information, more tariff options and re-
metering and benefit from economies of scale, mote connection management (ANEEL, 2012).
policy makers may decide to opt for a large- Advanced metering data management
scale rollout. This process usually stems from a and access
policy mandate on metering operators, normal-
The adoption of advanced metering represents a
ly including rules governing this deployment in
revolution in terms of the volume of information it
terms of schedule or technology capabilities. For
makes available on consumer behaviour and net-
instance, EU Directive 2009/72/EC19 mandates
work utilisation. Further, smart meters may re-
European countries to install smart meters in at
cord not only consumption data, but also techni-
least 80% of consumers by 2020, provided a pos-
cal information on power quality levels, outages,
itive benefit-cost analysis is obtained (European
meter tampering, etc. Hence, advanced metering
Commission, 2009). Acknowledging the key role
data have immediate application to distribution
that smart metering plays in terms of consum-
network operations and planning, and distribu-
er awareness and retail market functioning, the
tion companies should be granted access.
European Commission has proposed to provide
consumers with the right to have a smart meter The main policy and regulatory concerns around
installed even in those countries where a nega- advanced metering lie on the commercial value

19. Directive 2009/72/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 July 2009 concerning common rules for the internal
market in electricity and repealing Directive 2003/54/EC (Text with EEA relevance).

129
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
Table 3.6 Smart metering cost-benefit analysis (CBA) in Germany (left) and the United Kingdom (right)

POSITIVE
CBA OUTCOME (for the Roll-out Scenario Plus) CBA OUTCOME POSITIVE
NEGATIVE for the EU scenario
· € mn 6,493 (by 2022)
Total Investment Total Investment € mn 9,295
· € mn 14,466 (by 2032)

· € mn 5,865 (by 2022)


Total Benefit Total Benefit € mn 21,749
· € mn 16,968 (by 2032)

Cost/metering point
(as communicated €546 Cost metering point €161
by the Member State)

Benefit/metering
point Benefit
€493 €377
(as communicated by per metering point
the Member State)

Consumers’ benefit Consumers’ benefit 28% (domestic sector) and 60%


47%
(% of total benefits) (% of total benefits) (non-domestic sector)

Domestic sector (electricity + gas)


· Supplier cost savings (54%)
· Energy savings – 33% · Energy savings (28%)
Main benefits · Load shifting – 15% Main benefits · Carbon savings (7%)
(% of total benefits) (% of total benefits) Non-domestic sector (electricity + gas)
· Avoided investments in the distribu-
tion grid – 13% · Energy savings (60%)
· Carbon savings (19%)
· Supplier cost savings (15%)

Domestic sector (electricity + gas)


· Smart meters CAPEX+OPEX (43%)
· Investments smart metering systems · Communication costs CAPEX+OPEX
(meter, gateway, communication in- (23%)
Main costs frastructure) – 30% Main costs · Installation costs (15%)
(% of total costs) (% of total costs) Non-domestic sector (electricity + gas)
· Communication costs – 20%
· Smart meters CAPEX+OPEX (49%)
· IT-costs – 8% · Communication costs CAPEX+OPEX
(31%)
· Installation costs (16%)

Energy savings Energy savings


(% of total electricity 1.2% (% of total electricity 2.2%; gas 1.8%
consumption) consumption)

· 0.5% - 1% (as a percentage


Peak load shifting · 1.3% in average between 2014 and Peak load shifting of total consumption)
(% of total electricity 2022 (% of total electricity
consumption) consumption) · 1.3% - 2.9% ( as a percentage
· 2.9 in 2032
of peak consumption)

Source: European Commission, 2014c


Note: The “EU Scenario” analysed in Germany corresponds to the requirement set in Directive 2009/72/EC, i.e., to install smart me-
ters for at least 80% of all consumers by 2020. The Roll-out Scenario Plus considers the installation of smart metering systems
in new and existing RES and CHP units with a contracted power above 250 watts (W), whereas it limits the installation of smart
metering by 2022 to large consumers and new or renovated buildings (remaining consumers will be equipped with meters
without external communications).

130
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

of this data, with respect to retail market func- third party driven by the size and structure of the
tioning and the provision of energy services. distribution sector? Regardless of the model cho-
For companies contracting with end-consum- sen, regulators ought to ensure that data access
ers (suppliers, energy services companies, ag- is granted in non-discriminatory conditions, while
gregators), this information has commercial val- the privacy of end-users is ensured.
ue. Consumers, meanwhile, may be able to make
Another issue that has attracted policy attention
better-informed decisions (CEER, 2015a). Princi-
is the format in which these data are stored and
ples guiding the organisation and regulation of
shared. To remove market barriers and reduce
data access seek to ensure consumers’ privacy
administrative costs, Article 24 of the proposal
and data transparency, accuracy, accessibility as
for a new Electricity Directive in Europe (Europe-
well as the avoidance of discrimination (CEER,
an Commission, 2016a) states that Member States
2015a).
have to define a common data format. Moreover,
These topics are relevant in those countries where the European Commission could define a manda-
the retail market has been liberalised, especially if tory Europe-wide data format as well as data ac-
the regulator is concerned about insufficient un- cess procedures replacing national approaches.
bundling or vertical integration. Note that even in
those countries where a distribution company is 3.5.3 D
 istributed storage
responsible for meter deployment and operation, and ownership models
providing access to these data and managing that The reduced cost of energy storage battery sys-
access is not necessarily the task of distribution tems, combined with the need for enhanced flex-
companies (CEER, 2015b). Thus, despite the fact ibility in the distribution network, opens the pos-
that distribution companies have conventionally sibility of deploying small- and medium-sized
been responsible for metering activities, they will distributed storage for grid support. Interest in
not necessarily act as AMI data managers: such applications is reflected in the large num-
ber of demonstration projects being implement-
“CEER remains of the view that there is a need
ed worldwide. 20 Battery systems may be installed
for a neutral data coordinator or data hub to
both on the premises of end-users or directly
manage and provide access to data, and that
connected to the distribution grid.
this role can be provided by a number of dif-
ferent parties as is already the case in some EU The key regulatory questions here include: 1)
countries. […] CEER believes that DSOs should whether to allow the distribution utility to own
remain as neutral market facilitators but that and operate the storage system, given that this
this does not automatically confer the status may collide with existing unbundling rules and 2)
of data management coordinator to a DSO” how to ensure that the storage is located where
(CEER, 2015b: 13). it is most beneficial to the distribution network
when the distribution company cannot own and
The European Smart Grid Task Force identified
operate the storage system.
three main models for the management of smart
metering data: centralised management operat- Energy storage systems can provide grid support
ed by the distribution company, centralised man- services to distribution companies as well as oth-
agement operated by an independent regulated er system services, such as balancing or price ar-
agent and a decentralised model using a data bitrage (Eurelectric, 2012; THINK Project, 2012; US
access-point manager (Smart Grids Task Force, DOE, 2013). Box 3.13 offers a benefit-cost analysis
2013). All of these models have pros and cons. of a grid-connected battery system, illustrating
They also involve many questions. For example, the challenges faced by this type of application.
is the decision on whether to allocate the role of The benefits from distribution grid support alone
data manager to the distribution companies or a may not be enough to result in a positive business

20. A comprehensive database of storage projects can be found at: http://www.energystorageexchange.org/projects/.

131
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
Box 3.13 The benefit-cost analysis of a grid-connected storage system

The Public Service Company of New Mexico (PNM) has technically. However, as shown in Table 3.7, the bene-
carried out a demonstration project with a battery energy fit-cost analysis yielded a negative result, even including
storage system used to smooth the impact on a photovol- benefits that would not normally go to the distribution
taic (PV) power plant through peak shaving and voltage utility, such as deferred generation capacity or emissions
control in a medium-voltage (MV) utility feeder. The sys- reduction. The same report states that the benefits to the
tem schematic is shown in Figure 3.16 distribution operator could have been much higher if the
storage system had been located in a feeder with a higher
An evaluation of system performance in the period Sep-
PV penetration.
tember 2011 until February 2014 is presented in PNM
(2014). The results show that the system performed well

Figure 3.16. One-line diagram of PNM’s battery storage pilot project

PNM Distribution

835 kVA, 750 kW BES System supplied by


BESS Master 500 kW
Grid-Tied Inverter EPM/Ecoult
Central Inverter
Fixed Voltage 800 VDC
(+/- 400 VDC)

500 kW 250 kW
DC Converter with DC Converter with
Power Regulator Power Regulator

500 kWp
Solar PV
Array
Power Smoothing - 500 kW Peak Shifting - 990 kWhr
Containerised VRLA Containerized Advanced
Ultra Batteries (2xCABS) Carbon VRLA Battery (6xCABS)

Source: Adapted from PNM, 2014

Table 3.7 Summarised benefit-cost analysis of PNM’s battery storage pilot project

Costs Benefits

Utility Revenue Requirement (Variable) $51,576.11 -


Utility Revenue Requirement (Fixed) $2,929,123.43 -
Electricity Sales - $114,735.61
Distribution Investment Deferral - $333,987.30
Base Case
Distribution Losses Reduction - $15.80
System Electric Supply Capacity - $177,036.26
Emmission Offset $45,583.56
Total $2,980,699.54 $671,358.53

Source: PNM, 2014

132
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

case, and the benefits to the grid largely depend storage assets beyond the demonstration proj-
on the location of the storage system. ects (AEEGSI, 2015a). As shown in Figure 3.17,
these conditions would be limited to non-com-
Existing applications for grid support, usual-
petitive activities or to small-scale applications,
ly within demonstration projects, mainly follow
and in all cases subject to a benefit-cost evalu-
a structure where the distribution company di-
ation following a methodology approved by the
rectly operates the storage system. However,
regulator.
this may not be a viable model in regions where
regulation mandates the legal unbundling of Meanwhile, the European Commission has stat-
power distribution. Utilising the storage system ed its will to forbid distribution companies from
strictly for grid support would lead to largely owning, developing, operating or managing stor-
underutilised systems, given that network con- age facilities (European Commission, 2016b). Ex-
straints in a specific area may arise only a few emptions to this rule may be implemented if the
hours per year. On the other hand, the provision following three criteria are met: 1) other parties
of system services subject to competition would do not express interest in these activities in an
result in distribution companies acting de facto open tendering procedure, 2) storage facilities
as market agents. enable distribution companies to fulfil their ob-
ligations and 3) the regulator verifies compliance
In order to address this problem, the Italian reg-
with the previous two requirements and pro-
ulator has recently proposed a framework to de-
vides its approval. In order to ensure that regula-
termine the conditions under which distribution
tion keeps up to date with technology and busi-
operators may be allowed to own and operate

Figure 3.17 Framework proposed by the Italian regulator to decide upon the role of distribution
companies in storage ownership

Are the rules enabling DG to take part


to the ancillary service market defined?

no yes

Is the storage application


connected to MV network?
Is the storage application below
no (LV) the minimum power threshold?

A simplified CBA methodology


is envisaged for LV applications yes yes

Is the DSO able to demonstrate, through a CBA


case (ex-ante approved methodology), no
the cost-effectiveness of this storage application?

yes no

ALLOWED NOT ALLOWED

Source: Adapted from Lo Schiavo, 2015

133
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
ness model developments, the Commission has need to justify their contribution to the following
also proposed that regulators who allow distri- goals: grid optimisation, integration of renew-
bution companies to own storage facilities pe- able energy or a reduction of greenhouse-gas
riodically (every five years) re-assess the pre- emissions. The goal of this policy decision is to
vious conditions through a public consultation spur the adoption of energy storage. Therefore,
and modify regulation accordingly if needed. despite the fact that utilities are given a central
Another interesting initiative to encompass var- role in the elaboration or procurement plans, they
ious phases from storage demonstration to de- may retain the ownership of no more than 50% of
ployment is seen in California, where authorities the storage capacity.
have set binding targets on the three largest in-
An auction-based mechanism similar to the one
vestor-owned utilities to deploy 1 325 MW of stor-
being implemented in California could also be ap-
age capacity by 2020 (CPUC, 2013). The target is
plied in countries like Italy, where unbundling is
broken down per utility and type of application,
in place, as a means to ensure storage systems
distinguishing among grid-connected systems,
are located where they are most needed by the
either transmission or distribution, and customer
distribution company. The distribution compa-
storage (see Table 3.8).
ny may determine the location and grid-support
In order to comply with this requirement, utilities service required, and the winning storage oper-
shall carry out competitive solicitations every two ators would engage in long-term contracts with
years. Before these tendering processes, utilities the distribution company that would contribute
are required to submit procurement plans to the to their business cases.
regulatory commission for their evaluation, which

Table 3.8 Proposed storage targets for IOUs in California (MW installed per year)

Storage Grid Domain Point


2014 2016 2018 2020 Total
of Interconnection

Southern California Edison

Transmission 50 65 85 110 310


Distribution 30 40 50 65 185
Customer 10 15 25 35 85

Subtotal SCE 90 120 160 210 580

Pacific Gas and Electric

Transmission 50 65 85 110 310


Distribution 30 40 50 65 185
Customer 10 15 25 35 85

Subtotal PG&E 90 120 160 210 580

San Diego Gas & Electric

Transmission 10 15 22 33 80
Distribution 7 10 15 23 55
Customer 3 5 8 14 30

Subtotal PG&E 20 30 45 70 165

Total – all 3 utilities 200 270 235 490 1,325

Source: CPUC, 2013

134
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

3.5.4 B
 usiness models for the
To conclude, it is useful to recall the two main
deployment of electric vehicle
regulatory questions posed at the beginning of
charging infrastructure
this section: 1) whether to allow distribution com-
panies to own and operate storage assets and 2)
how to ensure an appropriate siting and sizing of As market forces alone may not be enough
storage units from the viewpoint of the distribu- to foster public charging infrastructure at early
tion grid. As discussed throughout this section, stages, policy makers and regulators may have
enabling distribution companies to install and to step in to kick-start the EV sector.
operate storage assets would facilitate the use
of storage for network support since distributors
Electric mobility has been identified as a key fac-
would directly decide its location and operation.
tor in the reduction of carbon emissions and local
Nonetheless, this may lead to under-utilised stor-
pollution. Hybrid vehicles, which utilise the elec-
age assets since network constraints usually oc-
tricity produced on-board, have been in commer-
cur only on occasions. Moreover, grid-support
cial operation for quite some time. Nonetheless,
services are not normally enough to yield a posi-
the full benefits of e-mobility require the devel-
tive business case for storage devices. Therefore,
opment of plug-in EVs, which recharge their bat-
storage operators would probably need to seek
teries by connecting to the power grid.
additional revenue streams, such as price arbi-
trage or balancing services, which are sometimes Charging points may be located in a wide variety
forbidden for distribution utilities due to unbun- of places such as at homes, working places, park-
dling or market access rules. ing lots or shopping centres. The deployment of
a network of public charging points would en-
On the other hand, leaving the decisions on stor-
able the large-scale adoption of EVs. Distribu-
age siting and sizing to market players would not
tion companies do not play any role concerning
ensure that this is located in the place and in the
charging points in private areas besides granting
amount needed from the network perspective.
access to the distribution grid on the same con-
The distribution company would need regulato-
ditions as any other network user. Nevertheless,
ry mechanisms to overcome these barriers. Thus,
they may play a more active role in the deploy-
regulators may implement exemptions on the un-
ment of public charging infrastructure. 22
bundling obligations under specific circumstanc-
es or enable distribution companies to contract Public charging services can be considered a
services with storage operators through tender- competitive activity subject to pricing alterna-
ing schemes. Concerning the operational deci- tives such as prepayment, flat monthly rates, free
sions over storage systems for the provision of charging to promote another product or service,
network support (and preventing storage sys- etc. For example, in the United States, several dif-
tems from causing grid constraints), distribution ferent charging suppliers provide their services
companies may purchase such services through throughout the country. According to the alter-
the mechanisms discussed in Sections 3.2.2 and native fueling station locator23 from the US DOE,
3.5.1, which enable them to become true system there are more than 11 000 EV public charging
operators. 21 stations across the United States, of which less
than 1.5% are directly operated by the utility. The

21. Note that, as discussed in Section 3.3.2, distribution companies should be encouraged by regulation to reduce overall costs, with-
out favouring OPEX over CAPEX reductions. Otherwise, they would see little incentive to rely on storage as an alternative
to network investments or, provided they are allowed to own storage, they may overinvest in storage assets to increase their regu-
latory asset base, benefitting from information asymmetries.
22. T  he deployment of (plug-in) EVs also affects the distribution grids planning and operation likewise DG, as discussed in Section
3.2. Moreover, distribution companies may resort to the flexibility potential offered by EV charging points, either when these are
decentralised (e.g., in-home charging posts) or centralised (charging stations). Thus, a large-scale adoption of electromobility will
stress the need for distribution companies to adopt their new role as SOs (Section 3.5.1).
23. Accessed in October 2015: http://www.afdc.energy.gov/locator/stations/.

135
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
remaining stations are operated by private net- by unbundling rules. For instance, the Europe-
work charging suppliers or public authorities, as an Directive 2014/94/EU24 on Alternative Fuels
described in Box 3.14. Infrastructure states that the operation of pub-
lic charging points is a liberalised activity and
Market forces alone may not succeed in deploy-
distribution operators ought to co-operate on a
ing this infrastructure where market size is lim-
non-discriminatory basis with any charging point
ited (THINK Project, 2013). Policy makers may
operators (See Box 3.15). Moreover, a deployment
need to kick-start the EV sector in its initial stag-
led by the distribution company would imply that
es, for example, by allocating this role to distribu-
rate payers would be subsidising EV users.
tion companies and treating EV charging points
as regulated assets. But this may be hampered

Box 3.14 Business models and drivers for electric vehicle public charging in the United States

Tesla Motors, a leading electric vehicle (EV) manufactur- overcome range anxiety concerns and promote EV sales.
er, has deployed one of the most widespread networks
The remaining major network charging suppliers (Sema-
of public fast charging points based on its so-called su-
Connect, ChargePoint or Blink)a are subscription-based
percharger. Tesla superchargers across North America
companies that purchase electricity from power utilities
are shown in Figure 3.18.
and sell it to their subscribers. These networks also sell
Tesla Motors follows a strategy based on placing their charging points to private customers, having a range of
superchargers along transited highways and in congested different products for domestic users, commercial cus-
city centres, where users may charge their vehicles for free. tomers and others. Thus, their business model is based
The company’s motivation, as a vehicle manufacturer, is to both on the sales of electricity and charging points.

Figure 3.18 Network of Tesla Motor’s superchargers across North America


Seward

Juneau

Prince Edmonton
George

Calgary
Regina Winnipeg
Vancouver
Victoria Thunder Bay
Seattle
Bismarck
Duluth Québec
Helena Fargo Charlottetown
Fredericton
Portland Billings Montréal
Minneapolis
Salem St-Paul Montpelier
Pierre Augusta Halifax
Boise Toronto
Milwaukee Portland
Buffalo Albany
Boston
Detroit
Omaha
Cheyenne Cleveland New York
Des Moines Chicago Providence
Lincoln Pittsburgh
Salt Lake City Denver
Kansas City Indianapolis Philadelphia
Carson City Colombus
Topeka Cincinnati Baltimore
Sacramento Jefferson
Wichita City St-Louis
San Francisco Richmond
Las Vegas Norfolk
Nashville
Oklahoma Memphis Raleigh
Santa Fe Charlotte
City Little Rock
Albuquerque Chattanooga
Los Angeles Columbia
Phoenix Birmingham Atlanta
Fort Worth Dallas
San Diego Jackson Charleston
Mexicali El Paso Montgomery
Ciudad Juárez Baton Rouge
Austin Tallahassee
Houston Mobile
Hermosillo
San Antonio New
Orleans Tampa
Open Now
Monterrey
Opening soon
Miami

Culiacán

Tampico
Mérida Cancún Santiago
Guadalajara
Campeche de Cuba
Morelia
SanJuan
Acapulco

Source: Adapted from Tesla motors, 2017 Cartagena Maracaibo


Barquisimeto

Ciudad

a. http://www.semaconnect.com/; http://www.chargepoint.com/; http://www.blinknetwork.com/. Medellín


Guayana

24. D
 irective 2014/94/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 22 October 2014 on the deployment of alternative fuels
infrastructure Text with EEA relevance.

136
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

Box 3.15 Charging service model according to the European Directive 2014/94/EU
on Alternative Fuels Infrastructurea

The development of electric mobility requires a careful −− The electricity distributor must operate in a nondiscrimi-
regulation of the contractual relationship between the natory way, both in providing the connection service [4] to
various subjects involved: electricity distribution opera- the CPO and the electricity transport service to the elec-
tors, electricity suppliers, charging point operators, mo- tricity supplier chosen by the CPO [3]; in order to ensure
bility service providers, mobility service providers (for the electricity distributor’s impartiality and efficiency, ap-
instance, EV manufacturers or other specialized subjects) propriate unbundling rules should apply where the distrib-
and EV drivers. utor belongs to a vertical integrated group that also pro-
vides (with undertakings separate from the distribution
As shown in Figure 3.19, the European Directive 2014/94/
operator) the electricity supply and/or charging activity.
EU on Alternative Fuels Infrastructure (AFID) sets some
principles that address these contractual relationships −− The CPO shall be free to choose one or more power sup-
with the aim of creating an open competitive market for pliers from any supplier in the Union [2] and must provide
recharging services. The basic assumption is that the a charging service to EV drivers [1], providing that pay-
good supplied is the bundled “recharge” product; the ment of the service can be, as chosen by EV drivers, ei-
EV driver should not, therefore, separately purchase the ther directly [1a], with the same modes of fuel supply, or
charging service and the electricity needed. The final cus- via the intermediation [1b] of mobility service providers,
tomer of the power system is the charging point operator typically EV manufacturers or other specialised entities.
(CPO), who has a supply contract with an electricity sup-
plier, freely chosen in the retail market. The EV driver has
−− Further, the EV driver must be able to recharge even
without having a contractual relationship with the CPO,
no contractual relationship with the electricity supplier.
on ad-hoc basis (single transaction settled with ordinary
Some of the key guidelines provided by AFID are: payment means).

Figure 3.19 Contractual relationship between actors involved in electric mobility

MOBILITY SERVICE
2
ELECTRICITY 1b PROVIDERS (MSP)
SUPPLIER CHARGING POINT
OPERATOR (CPO) 1b
1a
EV DRIVERS
Charging
point
3 4

Charging Electric
point vehicles
(EVs)
ELECTRICITY
DISTRIBUTION Charging
point
COMPANY
Point of Displays
delivery (can be set
Distribution grid Other uses to zero at each
of electricity transaction)

Smart
meter Charging station

Legend: 1a: EV Driver –Charging Point Operator (directly); 1b: EV Driver – Charging Point Operator (intermediated by Mobility Service
Provider); 2: Charging Point Operator – Electricity Supplier; 3: Electricity supplier – Electricity distribution company; 4: Electricity
distribution company – Charging Point Operator (only for connection)
a: D
 irective 2014/94/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 22 October 2014 on the deployment
of alternative fuels infrastructure.
Source: Adapted from Lo Schiavo, 2017

137
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

3
Other ways to provide the policy push could be Distribution companies ought to facilitate the
explored. For instance, local governments or oth- participation of DER in energy and ancillary ser-
er public entities may allocate the deployment vice markets. In this regard, distribution compa-
and operation of charging points through a long- nies may validate the technical feasibility of the
term contract assigned in a tendering process offers submitted by DER to the upstream mar-
(THINK Project, 2013). Thus, the role of the au- kets and verify the provision of the services ex
thorities would consist of setting the conditions post through metering data. In order to carry out
of such a contract (number of charging points, these duties, the conventionally limited interac-
pricing rules, standardisation requirements, etc.) tion between distribution companies and system
and organising the auction. operators needs to be revised. Co-ordinating the
actions of TSOs and distribution companies at the
3.5.5 Conclusions and operational level requires the implementation of
recommendations innovative technology solutions.
As the energy transition evolves, a growing share
In addition to market facilitators, distribution
of the generation capacity and the flexibility re-
companies themselves should make use of DER
sources needed to ensure the secure system op-
flexibilities to ensure efficient distribution plan-
eration will be connected to the distribution net-
ning and operations. Thus, enhanced interaction
works. An increase in demand awareness and the
with end-users is necessary so that distribution
deployment of advanced metering infrastructure
companies become true distribution system oper-
is contributing to the change in the landscape
ators actively managing the resources connected
seen by distribution companies. In response, dis-
to their grids. In this context, regulations should
tribution companies in liberalised markets need
define clearly the responsibilities of distribution
to adapt their role to ensure the efficient integra-
companies and oversee potential anti-competi-
tion of DER.
tive behaviour, especially where the distribution
In countries where policy makers pursue the liber- company belongs to a vertically integrated com-
alisation of the electricity sector, distributioncom- pany in a context of retail competition.
panies help create well-functioning retail mar-
Lastly, regulation ought to clarify the role of dis-
kets. A critical task related to the increase of DER
tribution companies in the deployment and op-
is the need to provide market agents with access
eration of innovative infrastructures such as ad-
to metering data in transparent and non-discrim-
vanced metering, distributed storage or EV public
inatory conditions. This might be seen as a con-
charging infrastructure:
ventional task of distribution companies. Howev-
er, when these companies belong to a vertically •• Advanced metering is a key enabling tech-
integrated undertaking active in the retail market nology for demand response, as well as for a
or act as default suppliers, regulators may wish sustainable penetration of self-consumption
to explore alternative data management models. and an active management of EV charging and
distributed storage. A large-scale roll-out re-
Different models can be found, depending on the
quires a policy mandate setting the technical
degree of the decentralisation of data manage-
and economic conditions. Advanced metering
ment and the involvement of distribution compa-
deployment is normally performed by distribu-
nies. There is no consensus on the most appro-
tion companies, except in cases where compe-
priate model. The final choice is mainly driven by
tition has been introduced in metering services.
the size and structure of the distribution sector
Optionality clauses may be implemented as a
in each country. In any case, regulators must en-
response to opposition from end users due to
sure non-discriminatory data access and protect
privacy or health concerns.
consumers’ privacy, particularly after the deploy-
•• Distributed storage has the potential to supply
ment of advanced metering.
grid-support services. However, this does not
automatically mean that distribution compa-

138
D I S T R I B U T I O N N E T WO R K S A N D D I S T R I B U T E D E N E R G Y R E S O U R C E S

nies should own and operate storage devices. EV market development. Policy makers may
In fact, unbundling provisions could rule this kick-start the EV sector by endowing distribu-
possibility out due to the fact that storage tion companies with responsibility for its de-
operators may need to provide other services ployment. However, in some context this may
under competition in order to obtain a positive not be possible. On the one hand, unbundling
business case. Thus, exemptions on the unbun- rules may prevent distribution companies from
dling obligations may be necessary. Alterna- selling electricity to EV users. On the other
tively, distribution companies may be entitled hand, treating EV charging points as part of the
to contract services with storage operators regulated asset base would imply that rate pay-
through tendering schemes. ers would be subsidising EV users. Thus, other
•• Market forces alone may not foster public policy alternatives could be explored to provide
charging infrastructure due to the low level of the initial policy push.

139
LESSONS LEARNT
AND POLICY
RECOMMENDATIONS
CO N C LU S I O N S A N D R E CO M M E N DAT I O N S

The world is in the midst of an energy transition. 4.1. W


 HOLESALE MARKET DESIGN
Power sectors are experiencing – or will soon ex-
Chapter 2 focused on the upstream segments of
perience – profound changes that include low car-
the power sector, more specifically on generation
bon technologies in the generation mix; the de-
and system operations, and in particular on the
centralisation of generation capacity; an increase
wholesale market design refinements needed to
in regional inter-connection and market integra-
lead the system expansion towards a more effi-
tion; consumer empowerment, thanks to better
cient and sustainable future.
information on pricing alternatives and consump-
tion profiles; and an increase in the availability The discussion is divided into two major sections:
and utilisation of a diversity of distributed energy
The first reviews the many important design ele-
resources (DER).
ments that need to be fine-tuned to improve the
In response to the challenges posed by this trans- performance of short-term market mechanisms,
formation, renewable energy policy and pow- from the day-ahead market to the balancing mar-
er sector regulation must work in co-ordination, ket. The independent system operators of the
and be adapted to the new reality, as discussed United States and the Power Exchanges of the
in Chapters 2 and 3. European Union were used as case studies. The
lessons extracted from these two can be, trans-
To be effective, both regulation and policy must
posed to other liberalised markets.
be designed and implemented whilst taking into
account the specific characteristics of each pow- The second focuses on long-term mechanisms
er sector, such as the degree of its liberalisation designed by electricity regulators to intervene
and its institutional arrangements, market struc- in markets with the objective of enhancing the
ture, grid development, electrification rate and penetration of additional sources of capacity (in-
renewables penetration. cluding RES), i.e., capacity remuneration and RES
support mechanisms. The discussion follows two
This section summarizes the main findings of this
main perspectives. First, capacity remuneration
volume and provides an overview of the major
mechanisms are reviewed from the point of view
policy and regulatory recommendations offered.
of RES. Second, the main design elements of RES
support mechanisms are evaluated, seeking the

1 41
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

4
best regulatory practices that minimise these In the European Union, day-ahead markets run
mechanisms’ interference in the functioning of by power exchanges were originally envisioned
the markets, while at the same time maximise as simple electricity auctions. Using simple bids
their efficiency as a tool to promote the installa- involves the need for market agents to anticipate
tion of low-carbon technologies. the resulting dispatch and internalise, in the bids,
all operational costs and constraints – a task that,
4.1.1. Adapting short-term market design to be properly fulfilled, requires that market con-
Short-term energy market design needs to be en- ditions be predictable.
hanced and refined at all levels, particularly with
The growing penetration of VRE has increased
respect to time frames, bidding formats, clearing
uncertainty and this has called for greater com-
and pricing rules and integration with reserves
plexity in bidding formats. But instead of opting
and regulation markets.
for the multipart formats used in the traditional
The type of refinements needed depends on the pool or in the United States ISOs, in the European
specific market design approach. Differences in Union each power exchange has progressively in-
the functions of the market operator (and within corporated the so-called block orders and semi-­
it, the Power Exchange) and the system operator complex orders.
are key. These differences are what set apart the
Multipart offers, while more complex than blocks
United States and European Union market de-
or semi-complex orders, are a more “natural”
signs: the degree of separation between the roles
way of representing the generation resources,
of market operators and system operators, which
and have advantages if a multi-part bid is able
is not present in the United States, and quite
to replace multiple blocks. However, including
marked in the European Union.
multipart bids in the European Union power ex-

−− Bidding formats changes would require significant changes in the


market design and pricing and clearing rules.
In liberalised power systems in the United States,
independent system operators (ISOs) require Continuous improvements in bidding formats are
generators to submit multipart offers that try to expected in both market models, with the aim of
faithfully represent the detailed operational (and achieving a more efficient integration of intermit-
opportunity) costs as well as the technical con- tent renewables.
straints of their generating units. This bid format
is robust against high penetration levels of re- −− Pricing and market clearing
newables, because it allows generation agents to There are two ideal properties of pay-as-cleared
be efficiently scheduled and dispatched. (uniform) marginal pricing: first, marginal pricing
is consistent with optimal dispatch and, second,
The capability of the ISO model to integrate these
settling the transactions of all agents at the same
new resources, however, could be further im-
price (uniform pricing) sends an efficient signal
proved. Resources with different characteristics
for bidding at true costs and minimising ineffi-
could be better integrated into the market. This
ciencies.
calls for a larger number of bidding formats tai-
lored to specific needs. For example, regarding Perfect marginal pricing can be achieved only un-
the relevant case of demand response, Liu et.al. der ideal conditions – in particular, the absence
(2015) point out that “the bidding system does of non-linearities or “lumpiness” in the produc-
not always provide a mechanism as an alternative tion cost functions, which are common in actual
to the price-quantity bid format for consumers to markets. The presence of VRE generation exac-
express their willingness to adjust consumption, erbates these complex behaviors. This requires
particularly in response to price signals”. choosing between the objectives of achieving an
optimal dispatch or implementing a uniform mar-
ginal pricing scheme in the clearing and pricing

1 42
CO N C LU S I O N S A N D R E CO M M E N DAT I O N S

market rules. The United States has opted for the •• As mentioned in regard to bidding formats,
first objective, while the European Union has cho- market clearing rules in both market models
sen the second. seek to efficiently integrate larger shares of
variable renewables. Their development goes
In the United States, discriminatory side pay-
hand in hand: bidding formats condition mar-
ments, known as uplifts, are unavoidable ele-
ket-clearing and pricing rules, and these rules
ments of a pricing system consistent with a strict-
in turn affect the bid formats.
ly welfare-maximising dispatch. The underlying
problem is that the uplifts are outside the uni-
form marginal price (or an ensemble of locational
−− Locational granularity of prices
and schedules: zonal versus nodal
marginal prices), and this hampers the develop-
The increased deployment of VRE, particular-
ment of a correct market signal that applies to
ly wind, may result in a more constrained trans-
all agents. The approaches to the uplift problem
mission network. Zonal pricing is a simplified ap-
reviewed in this report share something in com-
proach to reflect network constraints, but it may
mon: an attempt (never completely fulfilled) to
come at the expense of market efficiency. In this
internalise, as much as possible, all costs in uni-
context, nodal pricing can often provide better
form prices, i.e., to minimise the uplift to get as
operation and investment signals, but it may be
close as possible to uniform pricing.
more challenging to implement.
In the European Union, giving priority to the sin-
gle-pricing rule leads to a short-term dispatch −− Rethinking reserve requirements
and procurement
that deviates from the cost-minimising one. As
argued before, this is a matter of trade-offs; in System operators need to implement new solu-
the European context, supporting uniform pric- tions to improve the reserves-supply function so
ing is an objective worth the loss in short-term that they are priced according to the value they
cost efficiency. There are three major problems provide to the system. In addition, energy and re-
with the European Union day-ahead pricing and serve markets should be properly connected to
clearing design: 1) relative lack of transparency in allow the former to reflect the actual conditions
the algorithm,2) some units are unable to set the of the latter.
market price and 3) the algorithm’s complexity
In the reserve markets, quantity requirements
limits the number of complex and block orders
are typically procured through market mecha-
that can be handled.
nisms. The willingness to pay for each megawatt
These three problems are all connected to the (MW) of reserve below a minimum contingency
underlying complexity of clearing the market level is set to the value of lost load – although
with uniform prices. Current efforts concentrate sometimes the price is artificially set below this.
on improving the computational performance of Above this minimum contingency level, the mar-
EUPHEMIA (the algorithm used, see Appendix) to ginal value of any additional MW of reserves is
cope with the increasing number and complexity typically set to zero – a practice that should be
of bids. questioned on the basis of rigorous regulatory
principles (Hogan 2014).
•• PCR-ESC (2015) proposes long-term solutions
to solve the complexity issue, such as:
•• Reduce the amount of blocks types and other
−− Time frame of markets, dispatches and prices
As variability increases, the time granulari-
complex products allowed per participant and
ty of market signals needs to increased. Better-­
market (bidding zones).
adapted and more flexible market timelines are
•• Reduce the range of products treated in EU-
needed. In the European Union case, guarantee-
PHEMIA.
ing full liquidity in intraday markets (through dis-
•• Relax the linear pricing rule (i.e., and simply
crete sessions) is the way to go, while in the Unit-
adapt to the fact there will be more than one
ed States context the link between imbalances
price-per-bidding zone and time period).
and pricing (cost allocation) could be improved.

143
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

−− Balancing markets and products


4
term solution is not to change the pricing rules
Properly designing balancing markets is essential but to address the fundamental underlying mar-
to ensure that: 1) the market provides accurate ket structure that creates the market power (or
incentives for flexibility and 2) all resources can to directly implement a regulated provision of
effectively offer their flexibility potential to sys- the service). Marginal prices, of course, provide
tem operators. sharper and more volatile prices, but these are
the signals needed to reflect the real-time value
Imbalance responsibility and imbalance settle- of flexibility and to incentivise resources that are
ment are the two most important – and con- sensitive to these price signals.
troversial – elements of designing a balancing
mechanism: 4.1.2. I mproving long-term signals
without ruining short-term ones
•• The definition of the balancing responsible par-
ties (BRP) is a contentious issue when coupled The key message of this section is rather straight-
with a dual imbalance pricing scheme. While forward: to the extent possible, renewable tech-
dual imbalance pricing is applied, allowing gen- nologies should be exposed to the same market
eration portfolios to BRP gives a competitive signals as conventional technologies. This is im-
advantage to large companies and introduces portant to foster their efficient integration into
entry barriers to small providers. the power system. While doing this, it must be
•• Dual imbalance pricing does not exactly reflect guaranteed that the design of RES support mech-
imbalance costs and therefore distorts the real-­ anisms is consistent with this guideline. Thus, the
time price signal. economic incentives for RES should account for
•• Today there is a growing trend to make RES the costs and the benefits derived from exposing
increasingly responsible for their imbalances. RES generators to market signals.
This is important to efficiently integrating larg- Long-term mechanisms, including convention-
er volumes of RES in markets. al capacity mechanisms and specific renewable
The definition of the balancing product can in- support schemes, are evolving due to the pen-
troduce significant barriers to the participation of etration of renewable resources and distributed
DER and RES. The following guidelines can help: generation. Generation adequacy mechanisms
are at the top of the regulatory agenda in many
•• Define innovative products to unlock the po- countries. It is a fact that conventional generation
tential of new, flexible resources. suffers the increased short term price volatility
•• Give different price signals to resources per- and the low energy prices when renewables such
forming differently. as wind or solar enter the system in a short time,
•• Separate the procurement of balancing energy, without giving time for the incumbent generation
upwards reserves and downwards reserves. to adapt. However, the need for capacity remuner-
•• To the extent possible, avoid limiting participa- ation is a topic mostly related to the presence of
tion based on size or technology. caps on market prices to regulatory uncertainty as
The pricing of balancing products can be based regards to the long term planning. As discussed,
on either pay-as-cleared or pay-as-bid pricing. the deployment of variable generation has differ-
In many cases, the procurement is bilateral and ent impacts in energy- and capacity-­constrained
therefore by definition the products are pay-as- power systems. In the former, RES technologies
bid. In other cases, it has been implemented as do not complicate the operation of the system if
pay-as-bid (and average reserve pricing charges), the transmission capacity does not create bot-
with the objective of mitigating market power tlenecks, and RES can substantially contribute to
and providing less volatile prices. In general, mar- generation adequacy. In capacity-constrained sys-
ginal prices should set the market price. In case tems, non-dispatchable power plants do affect
policy makers or competition authorities believe operations, and the participation of RES technol-
that market power is a major problem, the long- ogies in capacity mechanisms is scarce and more
difficult to quantify.

144
CO N C LU S I O N S A N D R E CO M M E N DAT I O N S

−− Capacity markets design and RES propriate design, making them generally prefer-
able if the goal is market integration.
As far as technically possible, RES technologies
should be allowed and expected to participate in When RES generation is distributed and is an in-
generation adequacy mechanisms to the extent ternal component of some network users, the
RES agents consider feasible and acceptable in same general considerations regarding support
terms of risk (as is the case for any other tech- schemes hold. Specific implications for the de-
nology). Nonetheless, when this participation is sign of support schemes and tariffs at distribu-
accepted, it must be guaranteed that the compe- tion level are discussed in Section 4.2.
tition in the generation-­adequacy market is effi-
ciently designed. In this context, some design el-
ements are pivotal in achieving fair competition, 4.2. DISTRIBUTION NETWORKS AND
namely constraints on tradable quantities and DISTRIBUTED ENERGY RESOURCES
performance incentives (penalties and credits for As discussed in Chapter 3, the energy transition
under- and over- performance). is driving profound changes in the “downstream
Obviously, the participation of RES technologies segments” of the power sector i.e., the distribu-
in capacity mechanisms, as in any other market tion and retail sectors. This is mainly driven by the
segment, should be coherent with the support decentralisation of generation and the empower-
being received by these technologies out of the ment of small- and medium-size consumers en-
market. It may be possible that renewable re- abled by the diffusion of innovative technologies
sources will still need economic incentives. How- and increased availability of information. What
ever, their incentives should progressively be- follows is the summary of the recommendations
come more market compatible in the future. From for promoting the large-scale deployment and ef-
a market design perspective, support to renew- ficient integration of distributed energy resources
able generation should provide optimal invest- whilst ensuring the reliability and economic via-
ment signals while minimising market distortions. bility of the power system as a whole.
Finally, support to prosumers and DER in gener-
4.2.1. A
 dapting regulation under high
al should be harmonised with end-user tariffs to
shares of distributed generation
guarantee cost-recovery, as discussed below.
Distribution networks are witnessing growing lev-
−− Rintegration
ES support and wholesale market els of DG, driven by cost reductions and policies
promoting the installation of low-carbon technol-
There is a growing consensus on the need to in- ogies. Utilities may install DG units to supply en-
tegrate RES in electricity markets. This requires ergy to their customers. Independent promoters
the adoption of more market-compatible support or end consumers may invest in DG installations,
schemes. However, it must be taken into account particularly in those countries where policies to
that there is no perfect support scheme; all come promote RES favour smaller installations (e.g.,
with pros and cons: net metering, self-consumption or feed-in tariff
policies).
•• Production-based mechanisms are good at
stimulating efficient investment decisions but The deployment of DG has positive effects for the
may create short-term market distortions. system, for example in terms of reduction of net
•• Capacity-based mechanisms are in gener- load (e.g., in the case of photovoltaic (PV) sys-
al more market compatible than produc- tems production during peak demand) and trans-
tion-based mechanisms, but they may be less mission losses (being the generation units close
successful in stimulating optimal investment to consumption points). However, in the tradi-
decisions. tional, passive approach to managing networks,
the connection of high levels of DG may cause
The risks inherent in capacity-based schemes an increase in network costs. This is particular-
can be reduced via the implementation of an ap-

145
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

4
ly true when the network operator, either a utili- per investment”, policy makers ought to promote
ty or an unbundled distribution company, has no pilot projects and facilitate the sharing of lessons
direct control over the location and operation of learnt:
the generators, freely decided by DG investors or
•• Useful measures include the creation of and
end-users. With this in mind, regulators should
participation in, national or international
encourage these companies to adopt more active
public-­private collaboration networks for the
strategies by establishing regulatory incentives
promotion of innovative grid projects, the dif-
that are well aligned with the desired transforma-
fusion of best practices and the involvement of
tion. Such regulatory changes become more rel-
relevant stakeholders. The goal of these initia-
evant as the penetration rate of DG grows and
tives is to identify local priorities and promote
should be progressively refined according to the
knowledge­ -sharing to accelerate the process
experience and data gathered by the network
from testing to deployment.
companies managing generation in their grids.
•• Policy makers and regulators should set ad hoc
Experience shows that in countries with low pen- financial incentives for utilities and distribution
etrations of DG, utilities or distribution companies companies to invest in pilot projects in strategic
that have scarce experience dealing with this phe- areas. Best practices include allocating these
nomenon may see generation they do not direct- funds through competitive mechanisms and
ly own as a threat to their activities. On the one introducing information disclosure obligations.
hand, the installation of on-site generation can
Subsequently, network operators should proceed
lead to a decrease in their revenues due to low-
to the deployment of proven solutions, leverag-
er energy distributed. On the other hand, costs
ing the experience gathered through demonstra-
may remain constant or even increase when DG
tion. To fully exploit the techno-economic effi-
increases network capacity requirements. To pre-
ciency potential of advanced grid solutions and
vent network operators from opposing or delay-
decentralised resources providing network ser-
ing the connection of DG, regulators should fo-
vices and flexibility, there should be transforma-
cus on mitigating the negative impact DG may
tion in the way regulators set revenues and incen-
have distributed revenues and on network costs.
tives for utilities and distribution companies.
Where levels of DG penetration are low, it is rec-
ommended that regulators: A comprehensive reform of network regulations
should be undertaken. Some of the recommend-
•• Decouple the remuneration of network activ-
ed regulatory provisions are:
ities from the amount of energy consumed.
Thus, any deviation between ex ante allowed •• Shift the regulatory focus from ensuring that
revenues and the money collected through the distribution companies invest enough to as-
tariffs can be corrected in subsequent periods. sessing their performance through measurable
•• Compensate utilities and distribution compa- indicators (e.g., energy losses, customer satis-
nies for the possible incremental costs driven faction, carbon emissions, peak load reduction,
by DG, which are outside their control. This may etc.) – in other words, move from an input-ori-
be done through revenue drivers or a pass- ented to an output-based regulation.
through of costs. •• Remove biases towards capital expenditures
so that utilities and distribution companies are
The declining costs of RES will lead to a large-
encouraged to solve network problems relying
scale deployment of DG. In order to support and
on the flexibility provided by DER, even if these
integrate high amounts of DG efficiently, network
avoid network reinforcements.
operators should be incentivised to deploy ad-
•• Perform cost assessments to foresee future in-
vanced grid technologies, i.e., transition towards
vestment needs instead of evaluating only past
smarter distribution grids. Since innovative solu-
information. Forecasts and justified business
tions entail a higher risk for utilities and distribu-
plans prepared by companies should become
tion companies than conventional “iron and cop-
key tools for regulators.
•• Lengthen the duration of regulatory periods to

146
CO N C LU S I O N S A N D R E CO M M E N DAT I O N S

allow companies to focus on delivering long- the existing network to host DG capacity and
term efficiency rather than spending resources disclose this information, so that DG promoters
on frequent and burdensome price reviews. may make better-informed applications.
•• Introduce flexible remuneration formulas to ac- •• The previous recommendations can be rele-
knowledge the existence of higher uncertain- vant even under low or moderate levels of DG
ties, including profit-sharing schemes, menu penetration. Even in these initial stages, DG
regulation and reopeners. capacity, albeit small in general terms, may be
concentrated in specific areas, thus triggering
4.2.2. E
 ncouraging distribution the need to adopt some of the previous solu-
companies to act as system tions for managing locally high DG penetration
operators in these areas.
In response to the growing presence of new
As DG levels become significant, network opera-
types of distribution network users, utilities and
tors can no longer follow a fit & forget approach
distribution companies should actively interact
to connect new generators. For more efficient
with DER and make the most of their contribu-
network development, they need to implement
tion during the distribution network operations.
advanced solutions for managing constraints
This could help reduce grid reinforcement needs.
close to real time, instead of relying exclusively
This is relatively straightforward when these re-
on grid reinforcements. In many cases, this will
sources are owned and operated by a vertically
imply resorting to the flexibilities of DER. Also,
integrated utility. However, in the case of unbun-
ad hoc regulatory mechanisms will be required
dled utilities or distribution companies that need
to enable utilities and distribution companies to
to manage investor-owned DG units or resort to
benefit from the potential of third-party flexibil-
demand response resources, the mechanisms to
ities.
interact become more complex.
•• Under moderate penetration levels, a suitable
When this is the case, utilities and distribution
solution would be to allow network operators
companies need to become actual system oper-
to offer DER non-firm connection agreements,
ators, managing both the grid and the resources
through which DG operators who decide to
connected to it similar to the role conventionally
opt in would pay lower network charges in
played by TSOs/ISOs. In the case of integrated
exchange for a possible limited curtailment of
utilities, they would need to manage both their
their production. Regulators should define the
own and external resources, and regulatory mea-
conditions under which distribution companies
sures are required to prevent discriminatory be-
may resort to this measure, the rules on how to
haviour.
set limits to the amount of RES production to
The need for an enhanced co-ordination with ex- be curtailed and compensation mechanisms to
ternal DG promoters starts from the moment that DG operators.
new generators request a connection to the grid. •• With larger DG penetrations and developed de-
In order to achieve a more cost-effective network mand response schemes, regulators should es-
capacity allocation and better-informed connec- tablish more-advanced mechanisms to enable
tion requests from promoters, the following pro- network operators to purchase services from
visions are recommended: DER such as bilateral agreements and local
markets.
•• Network operators should manage grid con-
•• Regulators should develop distribution grid
nection applications for a given area in a more
codes defining the technical and economic
aggregated manner, instead of on a simple
conditions under which these services may be
first-come first-served basis.
provided in a non-discriminatory way.
•• Regulators should mandate utilities and distri-
bution companies to assess the capability of

1 47
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

4
4.2.3. Enabling distribution sector, either directly or through another com-
companies to act as neutral pany within the same group, regulators could be
market facilitators concerned about potential barriers for indepen-
A consequence of the increasing decentralisation dent suppliers.
of power systems is that the flexibility resources Alternative models for data management have
connected to the distribution grid become pro- therefore been adopted in some countries, some-
gressively needed to balance the systems’ gener- times with the creation of a new regulated entity
ation and demand. Therefore, in contexts where responsible for data management. As these mod-
distributed resources are not negligible anymore, els have their advantages and disadvantages, the
regulation and market rules should enable the final choice depends upon the specific country
participation of DER in system services through contexts and regulatory priorities.
aggregation, if necessary.
Regardless of the model chosen:
Because DER are connected to the distribution
grid, utilities and distribution companies have an Regulators should clearly define the roles, rights
important role to play as mediators. This role is and obligations of different stakeholders, and
particularly relevant in systems where a TSO/ISO the conditions under which the metering data
is independent of the power utilities. Moreover, manager should provide access to retail market
the existence of competitive energy and ancillary agents such as suppliers and aggregators:
services markets represents an additional driv- •• Consumers should be the owners of the data
er for the development of such business models. and have access to them to make better-in-
Otherwise, TSOs/ISOs may rely exclusively on formed decisions on consumption and con-
centralised resources. tracting.
To unlock the flexibilities of DER and enable their •• Market agents should have access to meter-
participation in upstream system services: ing data in transparent and non-discriminato-
ry conditions once consumers’ permission has
Regulators should develop new grid codes that been granted.
define the:
Finally, the deployment of innovative grid-edge
•• Responsibility of utilities and distribution com- technologies may be facilitated through the par-
panies as facilitators of DER participation in ticipation of utilities and distribution companies.
upstream services and markets, which could These infrastructures comprises advanced me-
include an ex ante technical validation and an tering technologies, distributed storage and elec-
ex post verification of the provision. tric vehicle public charging facilities. Given that
•• Information exchange required between utili- the ownership and operation of these infrastruc-
ties or distribution companies and system/mar- tures may be subject to competition, key regu-
ket operators. latory concerns arise in the case of unbundled
Another factor that is driving changes in the con- distribution companies. For instance, when en-
ventional role of utilities and distribution com- ergy storage is used both for grid support and
panies is the liberalisation of retail markets. The to perform price arbitrage. Nonetheless, regula-
reforms undertaken by some countries aim to tors may decide to allow these companies to own
promote more-efficient electricity consumption these assets under certain conditions.
by offering a wider choice in terms of suppliers •• Policy makers should promote the deployment
and prices. In competitive retail markets, trans- of advanced metering technologies in those
parent and non-discriminatory access to meter- countries pursuing the sustainable develop-
ing data is essential for a well-functioning market. ment of self-consumption, demand response
Management of metering data is usually a task and distributed storage.
for utilities or distribution companies. However,
when these companies are also active in the retail

148
CO N C LU S I O N S A N D R E CO M M E N DAT I O N S

•• Rollout strategies should be based on 4.2.4. Promoting sustainable


cost-benefit analyses, potentially leading to development of self-consumption
a mandated large-scale rollout that sets re- and demand response
sponsibilities, time frames, technical require- The installation of DG units behind the consum-
ments and economic conditions for cost-re- ers’ meters for self-consumption can facilitate
covery. the growth of RES and yield important benefits
•• Distribution companies have conventionally both for end users and for the power system.
carried out this task and are a suitable can- Therefore:
didate, especially for a large-scale rollout.
Nonetheless, other entities may deploy these •• Policy makers and regulators should enable
technologies; it may be more efficient, but and promote self-consumption, particularly for
other barriers may arise in this case, such as small commercial and residential consumers.
lack of standardisation or barriers to switch- •• Regulators should reduce to the extend possi-
ing suppliers. ble administrative barriers to the installation of
DG units for self-consumption, such as complex
•• Regulators should enable distribution compa- permission procedures, financial guarantees,
nies to influence the location of storage units costly technical connection studies, etc.
within the grid to provide efficient grid support
services. Meanwhile, traditional self-consumption and net
metering practices may lead to a missing mon-
•• This may be done either by introducing ex- ey problem that, if not properly addressed, would
emptions on the unbundling rules, subject to hamper the recovery of the power system and
size limitations or a preapproval by the reg- other energy policy costs when high shares of
ulator or by enabling distribution companies generation are involved.
to carry out competitive tenders to purchase
grid services from independently owned Conventional tariff designs, i.e., those that are
storage units. based mostly or even exclusively on a volumet-
ric charge (e.g., USD/ kilowatt hour), coupled with
•• Policy makers may intervene to kick-start the conventional energy meters, unable to record
deployment of public charging infrastructure to consumption with a high time granularity, are at
promote the use of EVs. Distribution companies the core of this problem. Several short-term reg-
may be given this role, although policy makers ulatory measures have already been implement-
may consider alternative providers in case this ed in different jurisdictions to tackle this problem,
may collide with the unbundling rules. including:

•• Setting limits on the size of DG units used for


self-consumption, implementing an overall cap
on the amount of DG eligible for self-consump-
tion at the national/local level or limiting the
annual volume of energy consumption that can
be compensated with energy surplus from DG
units.
•• Progressively moving away from purely vol-
umetric tariffs and recovering part of the sys-
tem’s fixed costs through a demand or a fixed
charge, and adjusting the volumetric com-
ponent accordingly. When introducing these
changes in the rate structures, the impact on
consumer bills should be carefully analysed.
Fixed charges may jeopardise low-demand

149
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

4
consumers, debase demand response and en- each of these components are provided. Note
ergy-efficiency efforts or encourage grid defec- that the degree of sophistication, i.e., the granu-
tion. This highlights the importance of ensuring larity of time and location dependent signals, can
cost-reflective changes in the rate structure, as be modulated according to the penetration level
advocated for in this report. of DER in a specific jurisdiction and the level of
•• Implementing alternative schemes to compen- stress on the network.
sate for the prosumers’ production surplus. This
•• The value of energy should reflect the varying
requires the progressive phasing out of net-me-
cost of producing electricity over time, as well
tering policies in favour of self-consumption
as the variation in network effects by location.
schemes with shorter netting intervals and a
Time-of-use or dynamic energy prices would
decoupling of the remuneration of electricity
provide short-term economic signals promot-
feed-in from the retail price. This energy sur-
ing the efficient operation of DG units as well as
plus can be valued, for instance, at the nodal
demand-response and storage management.
energy price or the wholesale market price.
•• Network charges should reflect the impact of
Even though the previous regulatory measures the end user on the utilisation of network as-
help mitigate the missing money problem, they sets and grid expansion. Thus, network charges
do not provide a real long-term solution for the should be based on the individual contribution
efficient development of prosumers. This entails of the network user to the transmission and
developing and implementing rigorous method- distribution costs, differentiated by time peri-
ologies for calculating cost-reflective tariffs that od, location and whether power is being inject-
promote efficient energy consumption and grid ed or withdrawn from the grid. Such charges
utilisation whilst ensuring system cost-recovery. would provide end users with long-term eco-
Such a retail tariff design enables the sustain- nomic signals promoting efficient location and
able development of self-consumption and effi- investment decisions. Most important, they re-
cient decisions regarding demand response and flect the actual contribution of network users to
distributed storage. Whenever support measures network stress (peaks of injection or withdraw-
are deemed necessary (e.g., to renewable gen- al), thus signalling the need for new network
erators or certain consumer categories), these reinforcements.
should be explicit and transparent in order to pre- •• The other regulated costs, when recouped
vent undesired effects. through the electricity rates, should be allo-
cated without distorting the economic sig-
Cost-reflective tariffs, enabled by the deploy-
nals sent by energy and network charges,
ment of advanced metering technologies, would
e.g., through a fixed charge per customer. This
send efficient short- and long-term signals to end
provision is particularly relevant in countries
users reflecting their contribution to the system,
where these costs account for a significant
and ensuring the recovery of total system costs.
share of total system costs, for instance, due
Retail tariffs should be additive, i.e., calculated
to support for RES. Nonetheless, should poli-
considering separately the different cost compo-
cy makers wish to avoid the undesired effects
nents: 1) the value of electricity (energy) at each
of fixed charges mentioned above, these costs
time and location; 2) the cost of the transmis-
may be recouped, at least partially, through
sion and distribution grid and 3) other regulat-
alternative revenue sources such as public
ed costs. Hereafter, some guidelines to calculate
budgets or taxes.

150
CO N C LU S I O N S A N D R E CO M M E N DAT I O N S

151
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

GLOSSARY OF TERMS

Adequacy: existence of enough resources, either installed Distribution feeder: each of the medium-voltage (MV) lines
or expected to be installed, to efficiently guarantee the that originate from primary distribution substations and sup-
match of supply and demand in the long term. ply secondary substations or distribution transformers.

Ancillary services: services that are necessary to maintain Firmness: ability of resources already installed in the system
the stability and security of power systems. to respond to actual requirements to meet existing demand
efficiently.
Balancing market: a market that is usually opened at gate
closure, where agents submit upwards and downwards bids Firm energy and firm capacity: Energy and capacity that are
through which the system operator will be able to fix po- expected to be available during some sort of scarcity condi-
tential imbalances through least-cost resources; term used tions; products usually traded in the framework of adequacy
in the European context. mechanisms.

Capacity mechanism: a regulatory instrument that reinforc- Gate closure time: moment at which the scheduled or fore-
es the economic signal provided by other electricity markets casted production of generation units for a given period is
(usually short-term ones) in order to attract enough invest- fixed for the purpose of determining the generation sched-
ment and ensure system adequacy in liberalised power sec- ule.
tors.
Grid code: document that specifies the technical conditions
Commercial losses: energy losses caused by non-technical that must be met by any agent ¬– whether a generator, con-
aspects of the electricity supply, such as metering or billing sumer or grid operator – connected to the power system in
errors, meter tampering, illegal connections, energy theft, order to ensure reliable, secure system operation.
etc.
Infra-marginal generation: all production units whose mar-
Continuity of supply: a component of quality of service, de- ginal costs fall below those of the latest unit to be dispatched
cided by the number and duration of supply interruptions in a certain time period following the cost-based merit order.
experienced by electricity consumers.
Infra-marginal rent: remuneration earned on a marginal
Distributed energy resources (DER): small- to medium- market by infra-marginal generators.
scale resources that are mainly connected to the lower volt-
Variable generation: electricity production units whose out-
age levels (distribution grids) of the system or near the end
put is not controllable or not continuously available, usually
users, and that is comprised of three main elements: distrib-
because of their reliance on a renewable primary energy re-
uted generation, energy storage and demand response.
source like wind or solar irradiation.
Distributed generation (DG): a generating power plant serv-
Levelised cost of electricity: the average cost of electricity
ing customers on-site or providing support to a distribution
per kilowatt hour (kWh) considering all fixed and variable
network and connected to the grid at distribution-level volt-
costs over the lifetime of an installation.
ages. For the purpose of this report, the technologies used
for distributed generation are renewable energy technolo- Merit order effect: the displacement of thermal generation

gies. units from the generation economic dispatch during hours of


high renewable production, driven by the much lower mar-
Demand-side response: also known as demand-side man-
ginal costs of RES technologies.
agement or energy demand management, refers to the pos-
sibility to shift energy loads around in time. The manage- Operating reserves: generation capacity readily available to

ment of small end-users must be automatically achieved at the system operator for solving contingencies.

the user level, which requires online communications. In this Prosumers: electricity consumers that either show some
regard, smart meters represent a key enabling technology of flexibility in their consumption as a response to price or vol-
demand response. ume signals (proactive consumers), or that have generation
connected on their side of the meter (producer-consumers).
G LO S S A R Y O F T E R M S

PICTURE CREDITS

Real-time market: a market similar to the balancing market, Page 10 © Shutterstock


implemented by U.S. system operators to fix imbalances.
Page 17 © Shutterstock
Real-time pricing: retail tariff scheme in which the energy
Page 18 © Shutterstock
charge corresponds to the price of electricity on the whole-
sale market during a specific trading period, usually one Page 29 © Shutterstock
hour. Page 31 © Shutterstock
Re-dispatch: process through which changes are made in the Page 32 © Shutterstock
generation schedule due to changes in the supply or demand
Page 40 © Shutterstock
curves after a previously computed economic dispatch.
Page 67 © Shutterstock
Residual demand: net electricity demand resulting from
subtracting the foreseen production of intermittent RES in a Page 90 © Shutterstock
given period from the total system load in that period.
Page 111 © Shutterstock
Retailing (electricity): final sale of electrical energy to end
Page 139 © Shutterstock
consumers. Retailing constitutes the final segment of the
electricity supply chain after generation, transmission, and Page 140 © Shutterstock
distribution.
Page 149 © Shutterstock
System operator: institution in charge of managing the
Page 151 © Shutterstock
transmission network and, more generally, of guaranteeing
the constant match between demand and supply in liber- Page 163 © Shutterstock
alised power systems. Page 167 © Shutterstock
Technical losses: energy losses caused by physical phenom-
ena and dissipated in the form of noise or heat in the elec-
tricity network.

Time-of-use pricing: a retail tariff scheme in which the ener-


gy charge varies across blocks of hours (e.g., peak and off-
peak hours) where the rate is pre-determined and constant
over a period of, typically, several months.

Transmission system operator: an entity responsible for op-


erating the transmission system in a given area and, where
applicable, its interconnections with other systems, and for
ensuring the long-term ability of the system to meet reason-
able demands for the electricity transmission.
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

REFERENCES

ACER-CEER (2016a), Annual Report on the Results of Moni- AEEGSI (2012a), “Disposizioni Urgenti In Materia Di Preno-
toring the Internal Electricity and Gas Markets in 2015, Agen- tazione Della Capacità Di Rete a Seguito Delle Ordinanze
cy for the Cooperation of Energy Regulators – Council of 16 Maggio 2012, Nn. 1879, 1880, 1881, 1906, 1907, 1909, 1911,
European Energy Regulators, Slovenia and Belgium. 1912, 1913, 1914, 1915, 1916 E 24 Maggio 2012, NN. Da 2004 a
2019, Del Consiglio Di Stato”, Deliberation 226/2012/R/EEL,
ACER-CEER (2016b), Annual Report on the Results of Moni-
Autorità per l’energia elettrica il gas e il sistema idrico, Milan,
toring the Internal Electricity Markets in 2015, Agency for the
28 May 2012.
Cooperation of Energy Regulators – Council of European
Energy Regulators, Slovenia and Belgium. AEEGSI (2012b), “Disposizioni di Attuazione della De-
liberazione dell’Autorità Per l’Energia Elettrica e il Gas
ACER-CEER (2015), “Joint ACER-CEER response to the Eu-
226/2012/R/EEl, Relative alla Saturazione Virtuale delle Reti
ropean Commission’s consultation on a new energy market
Elettriche”, Deliberation 328/2012/R/EEL, Autorità per l’en-
design”, Agency for the Cooperation of Energy Regulators
ergia elettrica il gas e il sistema idrico, Milan, 26 July 2012.
– Council of European Energy Regulators, Slovenia and Bel-
gium. AEEGSI (2011), “Modifiche e integrazioni alla deliberazione
dell’Autorità per l’energia elettrica e il gas ARG/elt 99/08, in
ACER (2013), Capacity Remuneration Mechanisms and the
materia di condizioni tecniche ed economiche per la connes-
Internal Market for Electricity, Agency for the Cooperation of
sione alle reti con obbligo di connessione di terzi degli impi-
Energy Regulators, Slovenia, www.acer.europa.eu.
anti di produzione (TICA), per la revisione degli strumenti al
AEEG (2011), “Criteri e condizioni per la disciplina del siste- fine di superare il problema della saturazione virtuale delle
ma di remunerazione della disponibilità di capacità produt- reti elettriche”, Deliberation ARG/ELT 187/11, Autorità per
tiva di energia elettrica, ai sensi dell’articolo 2 del decreto l’energia elettrica il gas e il sistema idrico, 22 December 2011.
legislativo 19 dicembre 2003, n. 379,”, Deliberazione 21 lu-
AEEGSI (2010), “Modifications to the technical and eco-
glio 2011 – ARG/elt 98/11, Autorità per l’Energia Elettrica e
nomic conditions for the connection to electricity networks
il Gas, Milan.
with third-party access obligations of power generation
AEEGSI (2015a), “Smart distribution system: Selective plants (original in Italian)”, Autorità per l’energia elettrica il
promotion of innovative investments in the electricity dis- gas e il sistema idrico, Consultation Paper No. DCO 15/10, 25
tribution sector: Initial guidelines (original in Italian)”, Con- May 2010.
sultation Paper No. 255/2015/R/EEL, Autorità per l’energia
ANEEL (2012), “Resolução Normativa Nº 502, de 7 de Agos-
elettrica il gas e il sistema idrico, Milan, 29 May 2015.
to de 2012: Regulamenta sistemas de medição de energia
AEEGSI (2015b), “Criteria for the definition of tariffs for elétrica de unidades consumidoras do Grupo B”, Agência
the provision of the transmission and distribution services Nacional de Energia Elétrica, Brazil, 7 August 2012.
and metering of electricity in the 5th regulatory period: Fi-
Southern California Edison (2017), Southern California Edi-
nal guidelines (original in Italian)”, Consultation Paper No.
son’s Distributed Energy Resource Interconnection Map. Arc-
544/2015/R/EEL, Autorità per l’energia elettrica il gas e il
GIS, California, available at: http://www.arcgis.com/home/
sistema idrico, Milan, 17 November 2015.
webmap/viewer.html?webmap=e62dfa24128b4329bfc8b-
AEEGSI (2015c), “Integrated text of the output-based reg- 27c4526f6b7.
ulation of distribution and electricity metering for the reg-
Barquín, J. (2014), “Spanish RES E Support History.” ENER-
ulatory period 2016-2023 (original in Italian)”, Deliberation
DAY 2014 - 9th Conference on Energy Economics and Tech-
646/2015/R/EEL, Autorità per l’energia elettrica il gas e il
nology - A European Energy Market, Germany
sistema idrico, Milan, 22 December 2015.
Barroso, L. A. and C. Batlle (2011), “Review of support
AEEGSI (2014), “A contribution to AGCOM survey M2M com-
schemes for renewable energy sources in South America”,
munication services,,” Memorandum 457/2014/I/com, http://
IAEE Third Quarter 2011, International Association for En-
www.autorita.energia.it/allegati/inglese/457-14eng.pdf,
ergy Economics, pp. 27-31. www.iaee.org/en/publications/
http://www.autorita.energia.it/allegati/inglese/457-14eng.
newsletterdl.aspx?id=141.
pdf.

154
REFERENCES

Batlle,  C. (2013), “Chapter 7: Electricity generation and Burger, B. (2014), “Electricity production from solar and
wholesale markets”, in Regulation of the Power Sector, wind in Germany in 2014”, Fraunhofer Institute for Solar En-
I. J. Pérez -Arriaga (ed.), Springer-Verlag, London, ISBN 978- ergy Systems, ISE, Freiburg, Germany. www.ise.fraunhofer.
1-4471-5033-6. de/content/dam/ise/en/documents/publications/studies/
Electricity_Germany_2014_CW52.pdf.
Batlle, C. and C. Ocaña (2013), “Chapter 3: Electricity regu-
lation: Principles and institutions”, in Regulation of the Pow- Burger, S. (2015), “Utility business model innovation: A
er Sector, I. J. Pérez-Arriaga (ed.), Springer-Verlag, London, techno-economic and strategic analysis of distributed ener-
ISBN 978-1-4471-5033-6. gy systems”, Thesis submitted to the Technology and Policy
Program, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Boston.
Batlle, C. et al. (2015), “The system adequacy problem:
Lessons learned from the American continent”, in Capaci- Butler, L. and K. Neuhoff (2008), “Comparison of feed-in
ty Mechanisms in the EU Energy Market: Law, Policy, and tariff, quota and auction mechanisms to support wind pow-
Economics, L. Leigh Hancher, A. de Hauteclocque and M. er development”, Renewable Energy, Vol. 33/8, Elsevier,
Sadowska (eds.), Oxford University Press, Oxford, United Amsterdam, pp. 1854-1867.
Kingdom.
CAISO (2017), “Using Renewables to Operate Low-Carbon
BEE (German Renewable Energy Federation) (2014), Grid,” CAISO, California, US. http://www.caiso.com/Docu-
“Factsheet: Renewables from Germany”, www.bee-ev.de/ ments/UsingRenewablesToOperateLow-CarbonGrid.pdf.
fileadmin/Publikationen/Sonstiges/BEE_Factsheet_RE-
CAISO, (2015), “Comments of the California Independent
NEWABLES_FROM_GERMANY.pdf
System Operator Corporation on Technical Workshops.”
Benner, S. (2015), “A brief history of regulation signals Docket No. AD14-14-000. March 6, 2015.
at PJM”, 9 June 2015, www.pjm.com/~/media/commit-
California Solar Statistics (2016), California Solar Incen-
tees-groups/committees/oc/20150701-rpi/20150701-item-
tive (CSI) Program, Accessed on 7 March 2016, Available at
02-history-of-regulation-d.ashx.
Source: https://www.californiasolarstatistics.ca.gov/.
BEREC (2017), Expert workshop on Internet of Things, Brus-
CEEPR (2005), Electricity Market Reform in the European
sels 1 February 2017, http://berec.europa.eu/eng/events/
Union: Review of Progress toward Liberalization & Integra-
berec_events_2017/151-berec-workshop-on-enabling-the-
tion, MIT, USA
internet-of-things
CEER (2016), Key Support Elements of RES in Europe: Moving
Bharatkumar, A. (2015), “Distribution network use-of-sys-
towards Market Integration, CEER Report C15-SDE-49-03,
tem charges under high penetration of distributed energy
Council of European Energy Regulators, Brussels, 26 Jan-
resources”, Thesis submitted to the Engineering Systems
uary 2016.
Division and Department of Electrical Engineering and
Computer Science, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, CEER (2015a), “CEER advice on customer data management
Boston. for better retail market functioning: Electricity and gas”, Ref:
C14-RMF-68-03, Council of European Energy Regulators,
Bohn, R., M. Caramanis and F. Swcheppe (1984), “Optimal
Brussels, 19 March 2015.
pricing in electrical networks over space and time”, The
RAND Journal of Economics, Vol. 15/3, Wiley, New Jersey, CEER (2015b), “The future role of DSOs: A CEER conclu-
pp. 360-376. sions paper”, Ref: C15-DSO-16-03, Council of European En-
ergy Regulators, Brussels, 13 July 2015.
Bresler, F. S. (2014), “Energy and ancillary services uplift in
PJM”, FERC Uplift Workshop Docket No. AD14-14, “Price for- CEER (2015c), “Status review of renewable and energy
mation in energy and ancillary service markets operated by efficiency support schemes in Europe in 2012 and 2013”,
regional transmission organisation and independent system Ref: C14-SDE-44-03, Council of European Energy Regula-
operators”, 8 September 2014. tors, Brussels, 15 January 2015.

155
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

CEER (2014), “CEER status review on European regulatory EA Technology (2012), Assessing the Impact of Low Carbon
approaches enabling smart grids solutions (“smart regula- Technologies on Great Britain’s Power Distribution Networks,
tion”)”, Ref: C13-EQS-57-04, Council of European Energy Report No: 82530, Version: 3.1, prepared for Energy Net-
Regulators, Brussels, 18 February 2014. works Association on behalf of Smart Grids Forum – Work
Stream 3, 31 July 2012.
CEER (2011), “CEER status review of regulatory approaches
to smart electricity grids”, Ref: C11-EQS-45-04, Council of EDSO (2015), “Adapting distribution network tariffs to a
European Energy Regulators, Brussels. decentralised energy future”, EDSO press release, European
Distribution System Operators for Smart Grids, Brussels.
CER (2014), “Integrated single electricity market (I-SEM),
high level design for Ireland and Northern Ireland from EEI (2013), “Disruptive challenges: Financial implications
2016”, Draft Decision Paper, Commission for Energy Regu- and strategic responses to a changing retail electric busi-
lation, Dublin, June 2014. ness”, Edison Electric Institute, Washington, DC.

CER (2005), “Group processing approach for renewable Eirgrid, SEMO, APX Power and SONI (2015), I-SEM Trialling
generator connection applications: Connection and pricing of EUPHEMIA: Initial Phase Report, September 2015, www.
rules: Direction to system operators”, CER/05/049, Com- sem-o.com/Publications/General/I-SEM%20Trialling%20
mission for Energy Regulation, Dublin, 6 April 2005. of%20EUPHEMIA%20-%20Initial%20Phase%20Report.pdf.

Cossent, R. et al. (2011), “Distribution network costs under ELIA (2016), Forecast and actual solar-PV power genera-
different penetration levels of distributed generation”, Euro- tion, Solar PV Power Generator Data, ELIA 2016, Beligum,
pean Transactions on Electrical Power, Vol. 21/6, Wiley On- http://www.elia.be/en/grid-data/power-generation/So-
line Library, pp. 1869-1888. lar-power-generation-data/Graph

CPUC (2014), “Energy division staff proposal on residen- ENTSO-E (2014), “Supporting document for the network
tial rate reform. staff proposal for residential rate reform in code on electricity balancing”, European Network of Trans-
compliance with R.12-06-013 and assembly bill 327”, Califor- mission System Operators for Electricity, 6 August 2014,
nia Public Utilities Commission, 3 January 2014. https://www.entsoe.eu.

CPUC (2013), “Decision adopting energy storage procure- EPIA (2014), Global Market Outlook for Photovoltaics 2014-
ment framework and design program”, CPUC Decision 13- 2018, European Photovoltaic Industry Association, Belgium.
10-040, Date of Issuance 21 October 2013, California Public
EPEX SPOT (2014), “Introduction of smart block bids –
Utilities Commission.
linked block orders and exclusive block orders”, Presenta-
CPUC (2012a), “CPUC approves analog meter options for tion, European Power Exchange, January 2014, http://static.
Edison and SDG&E customers who do not wish to have a epexspot.com/document/25495/Smart%20blocks%20
wireless smart meter”, CPUC Press Release, Docket #: A.11- -%20presentation.
07-020, California Public Utilities Commission, 19 April 2012..
EPRI (2016), Residential Off-Grid Solar + Storage Systems:
CPUC (2012b), “CPUC approves analog meters for PG&E A Case Study Comparison of On-Grid and OffGrid Power for
customers electing to opt out of smart meter service”, CPUC Residential Consumers, Report, Electric Power Research In-
Press Release, Docket #: A.11-03-014,, California Public Util- stitute, Palo Alto, CA.
ities Commission, 1 February 2012.
ERCOT (2014), “Operating Reserve Demand Curve eLearn-
DECC (2014), “Implementing electricity market reform ing”, ERCOT Market training, ORDC workshop, http://www.
(EMR) – Finalised policy positions for implementation of ercot.com/services/training/course/107.
EMR”, Policy document, Department of Energy & Climate
Eurelectric (2015), “Prosumers – An integral part of the
Change, London.
power system and the market”, Paper, Eurelectric, Brussels.
DECC (2012), “Feed-in Tariff with Contracts for Difference:
Eurelectric (2013), “Active distribution system manage-
Operational Framework (Annex A)”, Department of Energy
ment: A key tool for the smooth integration of distributed
& Climate Change, London, www.gov.uk
generation”, Full discussion paper, Eurelectric, Brussels.
DSIRE (2016), Find Policies & Incentives by State, Database
Eurelectric (2012), Decentralised Storage: Impact on Future
of State Incentives for Renewables & Efficiency, N.C. Clean
Distribution Grids, Report, Eurelectric, Brussels.
Energy Technology Center, N.C

156
REFERENCES

European Commission (2016a), “Proposal for a regulation FERC (2014a), “Notice of proceeding regarding the price
of the European parliament and of the Council on the in- formation in energy and ancillary services markets operat-
ternal market for electricity (recast)”, COM(2016) 861 final, ed by regional transmission organisations and independent
European Commission, Brussels. system operators”, Docket No. AD14-14-000, 19 June 2014,
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Washington, DC.
European Commission (2016b), “Proposal for a directive
of the European parliament and of the Council on com- FERC (2014b), “Uplift in RTO and ISO markets, staff anal-
mon rules for the internal market in electricity (recast)”, ysis”, Docket No. AD14-14-000, Federal Energy Regulatory
COM(2016) 864 final, European Commission, Brussels. Commission, Washington, DC.

European Commission (2016c), “Proposal for a directive of FERC (2014c), “Coperator-initiated commitments in RTO
the European parliament and of the Council on the promo- and ISO markets, staff analysis”, Docket No. AD14-14-000,
tion of the use of energy from renewable sources (recast)”, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Washington, DC.
COM(2016) 767 final, European Commission, Brussels.
FERC (2014d), “Order on tariff filing and instituting Section
European Commission (2015a), “Investment perspectives 206 proceeding”, Docket No. ER14 1050 000, issued on 30
in electricity markets (July 2015), Staff Working Document May 2014, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Wash-
(2015)142, European Commission, Brussels. ington, DC.

European Commission (2015b), “Communication from the FERC (2011), “Frequency regulation compensation in the
Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the organised wholesale power markets”, Docket Nos. RM11-7-
European Economic and Social Committee and the Com- 000 and AD-11-000, Order No. 755, issued on 20 October
mittee of the Regions: Launching the public consultation 2011, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Washington,
process on a new energy market design”, European Com- DC.
mission, Brussels.
FERC (2007), “Preventing undue discrimination and pref-
European Commission (2015c), “Commission staff work- erence in transmission service”, Docket Nos. RM05-17-000
ing document: Best practices on renewable energy and RM05-25-000, Order No. 890, issued on 16 February
self-consumption”, SWD (2015) 141 final, accompanying the 2007, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Washington,
document COM (2015) 339 final, European Commission, DC.
Brussels.
Fraunhofer ISE (2016), Energy Charts, Fraunhofer ISE, Ger-
European Commission (2014a), “Commission staff working many www.fraunhofer.de
document: Cost-benefit analyses & state of play of smart
Fraunhofer ISI (2015), “Negative Prices on the Electricity
metering deployment in the EU-27”, SWD(2014) 189 final,
Wholesale Market and Impacts of §24 EEG”, Fraunhofer In-
European Commission, Brussels.
stitute for Systems and Innovation Research ISI. 24 Decem-
European Commission (2014b), Report from the Commis- ber 2015.
sion: Benchmarking Smart Metering Deployment in the EU-
Fraunhofer ISI (2014), (2014), Best Practice Design Fea-
27 with a Focus on Electricity, COM(2014) 356 final, Europe-
tures for RES- E Support Schemes and Best Practice Meth-
an Commission, Brussels.
odologies to Determine Remuneration Levels, www.ecofys.
European Commission (2014c), “Commission staff working com/files/files/diacore_best-practice-design-criteria-and-
document: Country fiches for electricity smart metering”, lcoe_2014_final.pdf
SWD(2014) 188 final, European Commission, Brussels.
Galiteva, A. and K. Casey (2015), “Incentivizing flexibility
European Commission (2009), “Directive 2009/72/EC con- – California perspective”, CAISO presentation at Germany
cerning common rules for the internal market in electricity – United States Joint Expert Workshop “The future of elec-
and repealing Directive 2003/54/EC”, European Commis- tricity market design”, Berlin, 18 June 2015.
sion, Brussels
Gestore mercati energetici (2017), Spot Electricity Market
FERC (2016), “Settlement intervals and shortage pricing in (MPE), GME, Italy Available at: http://www.mercatoelettri-
markets operated by regional transmission organisations co.org/en/mercati/mercatoelettrico/mpe.aspx
and independent system operators”, Docket No. RM15-24-
Gouveia, J. P. et al. (2014), “Effects of renewables penetra-
000, Order No. 825, issued on 16 June 2016, Federal Energy
tion on the security of Portuguese electricity supply”, Ap-
Regulatory Commission, Washington, DC.
plied Energy, Vol. 123/15, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 438-447.

157
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

Graichen, P. (2015), “Flexibility in the power system cur- Huntington, S. et al. (2017), “Revisiting support policies for
rent status and future challenges in Germany”, June 2015. RES-E adulthood: Towards market compatible schemes”,
Presented by Dr. Patrick Graichen at “Future of Electricity Energy Policy, Vol. 104, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 474-483.
Market Design”, Germany–United States Joint Expert Work- (article in press at the time of this writing).
shop, Federal Ministry for Economic Affairs and Energy
IEA (2016), Re-powering Markets – Market Design and Reg-
(BMWi), Berlin, Germany June 17-18, 2015.
ulation during the Transition to Low-carbon Power Systems,
Gribik, P. R., W. W. Hogan and S. L. Pope (2007), “Mar- Organisation for Economic Co-operation/International En-
ket-clearing electricity prices and energy uplift”, Paper, Har- ergy Agency, Paris.
vard Kennedy School, Cambridge, MA.
IEA-PVPS (2016), Review and Analysis of PV self-consump-
Herrero, I., P. Rodilla and C. Batlle (2015), “Electricity mar- tion policies, International Energy Agency, Paris.
ket-clearing prices and investment incentives: The role of
IFC (2013), “Russia’s new capacity-based renewable energy
pricing rules”, Energy Economics, Vol. 47, Elsevier, Amster-
support scheme: An analysis of decree No.449”, Internation-
dam, pp. 42–51, doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2014.10.024.
al Finance Corporation, Washington, DC, www.ifc.org.
Hirth, L. and I. Ziegenhagen (2015), “Balancing power and
Inter-American Development Bank (IADB) (2014), “Analy-
variable renewables: Three links”, Renewable and Sustain-
sis of the impact of increased non-conventional renewable
able Energy Reviews, Vol. 50, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 1035-
energy generation on Latin American electric power sys-
1051, doi:10.1016/j.rser.2015.04.180.
tems: Tools and methodologies for assessing future oper-
Hoff, T.E., (2006). Photovoltaic Incentive Design Handbook ation, planning and expansion”, IDB Discussion Paper No.
Photovoltaic Incentive Design Handbook. National Renew- IDB-DP-341, Inter-American Development Bank, Washing-
able Energy Laboratory, Golden, Colorado, USA, (NREL/ ton, DC.
SR-640-40845). December 2006.
IRENA (2017a), Rethinking Energy 2017: Accelerating the
Hogan, W. W. (2014), “Electricity market design and effi- global energy transformation. The International Renewable
cient pricing: Applications for New England and beyond”, Energy Agency, Abu Dhabi. (forthcoming)
Paper, Harvard Kennedy School, Cambridge, MA, 24 June
IRENA (2017)b, Battery electricity storage, costs and mar-
2014, www.hks.harvard.edu/fs/whogan/Hogan_Pric-
kets to 2030. The International Renewable Energy Agency,
ing_062414r.pdf.
Abu Dhabi. (forthcoming)
Hogan, W. W. (2013), “Electricity scarcity pricing through
IRENA (2015), Renewable Energy Auctions: A Guide to De-
operating reserves”, Paper, Harvard Kennedy School,
sign, The International Renewable Energy Agency, Abu Dha-
Cambridge, MA, 25 April 2013, www.hks.harvard.edu/fs/
bi.
whogan/Hogan_ORDC_042513.pdf.
ISGAN (2014), “TSO-DSO interaction: An overview of cur-
Hogan, W. W. (1995), “A wholesale pool spot market must
rent interaction between transmission and distribution sys-
be administered by the independent system operator:
tem operators and an assessment of their cooperation in
Avoiding the separation fallacy”, The Electricity Journal, Vol.
Smart Grids”, ISGAN Discussion Paper, Annex 6, Power T&D
8/10, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 26-37.
Systems, Task 5, International Smart Grids Action Network,
Hogan, W. W. and B. J. Ring (2003), “On minimum-uplift Paris.
pricing for electricity markets”, Paper, Harvard Electricity
Jamasb, T. and C. Marantes (2011), “Electricity distribution
Policy Group, Harvard Kennedy School, Cambridge, MA.
networks: Investment and regulation, and uncertain de-
Hogan W. W. and ERCOT Staff (2013), “Back cast of interim mand”, Cambridge Working Papers in Economics CWPE 1115,
solution b+ to improve real-time scarcity pricing”, white pa- University of Cambridge, UK.
per, ERCOT, 21 March 2013, Harvard University.
Jamasb, T. and M. Pollitt (2001), “Benchmarking and reg-
Holttinen, H. et al. (2013), “The flexibility workout: Man- ulation: International electricity experience”, Utilities Policy,
aging variable resources and assessing the need for pow- Vol. 9/3, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 107-130.
er system modification”, IEEE Power and Energy Magazine,
Jendernalik, L. (2015), “Renewables integration: Challenges
Vol.  11/6, Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers,
and experiences from DSO perspective”, Renewable Energy
New York, pp. 53-62.
Training Week, Abu Dhabi, 28 January 2015.

158
REFERENCES

Jenkins, J. and I. Pérez-Arriaga (2014), “The remuneration MINETUR (2015), “Real Decreto 900/2015, de 9 de octubre,
challenge: New solutions for the regulation of electricity por el que se regulan las condiciones administrativas, técni-
distribution utilities under high penetrations of distributed cas y económicas de las modalidades de suministro de en-
energy resources and smart grid technologies”, CEEPR WP ergía eléctrica con autoconsumo y de producción con auto-
2014-005MIT, MIT Center for Energy and Environmental Pol- consumo”, Ministerio de Industria Energía y Turismo.
icy Research, Cambridge, MA.
MISO (2015), “Comments of the midcontinent independent
JRC (2017), European smart grid projects: number and system operator”, INC. Docket No. AD14-14-000, 6 March
budget evolution, Joint research centre. Available at: http:// 2015.
ses.jrc.ec.europa.eu/european-smart-grid-projects-num-
MIT (2015), “The future of solar energy”, Massachusetts In-
ber-and-budget-evolution
stitute of Technology Energy Initiative, Cambridge, MA.
JRC (2014), Smart Grid Projects Outlook 2014, Joint Re-
Miura,  J.  P. (2014), “Integrated single electricity market
search Centre of the European Commission, Luxembourg.
(I-SEM): Energy trading arrangements proposed decisions”,
Krad, I., E. Ibanez, and E. Ela (2015), “Quantifying the po- Stakeholder Forum on I-SEM Draft Decision, Dundalk, Ire-
tential impacts of flexibility reserve on power system opera- land, 17 June 2014, www.allislandproject.org.
tions..” In Green Technologies Conference (GreenTech), 2015
Moreno, B., A. J. López and M. T. García-Álvarez (2012),
Seventh Annual IEEE (pp. 66-73). IEEE.
“The electricity prices in the European Union: The role of
Kraftwerk (2015), “Case study: Photovoltaic for commercial renewable energies and regulatory electric market reforms”,
self-consumption”, Kraftwerk Renewable Power Solutions, Energy, Vol. 48/1, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 307-313.
http://www.kraftwerk-rps.com.
Morgan, P. (2013), A Decade of Decoupling for US Energy
Liu et al. (2015), “Extending the bidding format to promote Utilities: Rate Impacts, Designs, and Observations, Graceful
demand response”, Energy Policy, Vol. 86, Elsevier, Amster- Systems LLC, Oregon, revised February 2013.
dam, pp. 82-92.
NERC (2015), “Glossary of terms used in NERC reliability
Lo Schiavo, L. (2017)- ), “Competition and regulatory as- standards”, http://www.nerc.com/pa/Stand/Glossary%20
pects of electric vehicles charging: the Italian regulatory ex- of%20Terms/Glossary_of_Terms.pdf (updated 19 May 2015).
perience,,” FSR workshop on “Competition And Regulatory
Neuhoff K., et al. (2016), “Intraday Markets for Power: Dis-
Aspects of Electric Vehicles”,, Florence, 13 January 2017.
cretizing the Continuous Trading”, EPRG Working Paper,
Lo Schiavo, L. (2015), “Regulation of smart distribution Cambridge
systems in Italy: From input-based demonstration to out-
Neuhoff, K. (2015), “Strengthening market price signals to
put-based deployment”, CIRED, Lyon, France, 18 June 2015.
encourage long-term investments in flexible assets”, pre-
Mastropietro, P., P. Rodilla and C. Batlle (2015a), “Perfor- sented at Germany – United States Joint Expert Workshop
mance incentives in capacity mechanisms: Conceptual con- “The future of electricity market design”, Berlin, 18 June
siderations and empirical evidence”, working Economics of 2015.
Energy and Environmental Policy, Vol. 6/1, IAEE, Cleveland,
Neuhoff, K. and R. Boyd (2011), “International experiences
pp. 149-163.
of nodal pricing implementation”, Climate Policy Initiative,
Mastropietro, P., P. Rodilla and C. Batlle (2015b), “National Berlin.
capacity mechanisms in the European internal energy mar-
Neuhoff K., et al. (2015), “Flexible short-term power trading:
ket: Opening the doors to neighbours”, Energy Policy, Vol.
Gathering experience in EU countries”, http://www.diw.de/
82, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 38-47.
discussionpapers.
Maurer, L. and L. Barroso (2011), Electricity Auctions: An
New York DPS (2015), “Staff white paper on ratemaking and
Overview of Efficient Practices,World Bank Publications,
utility business models”, State of New York, Department of
Washington, DC, ISBN 978 0 8213 8822 8.
Public Service, CASE 14-M-0101, proceeding on motion of
Miller, M. (2015), “Flexibility: How much? From where? And the commission in regard to reforming the energy vision, 28
how?” NREL presentation at Germany – United States Joint July 2015.
Expert Workshop “The Future of Electricity Market Design”,
Berlin, 18 June 2015.

1 59
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

New York DPS (2014), “Reforming the energy vision. NYS OFGEM (2013c), “Strategy decisions for the RIIO-ED1 elec-
department of public service staff report and proposal”, tricity distribution price control: Tools for cost assessment:
State of New York, Department of Public Service, CASE 14- Supplementary annex to RIIO-ED1 overview paper”, 26e/13,
M-0101, proceeding on motion of the commission in regard 4 March 2013, Office of Gas and Electricity Markets, London.
to reforming the energy vision, 24 April 2014.
OFGEM (2013d), “Strategy decisions for the RIIO-ED1 elec-
NYISO (2015), Post-Technical Workshop Comments of the tricity distribution price control: Uncertainty mechanisms:
New York Independent System Operator, INC. Docket No. Supplementary annex to RIIO-ED1 overview paper”, 26c/13,
AD14-14-000. March 6, 2015. 4 March 2013, Office of Gas and Electricity Markets, London.

Norther Power Grid (2017), Generation Availability Map, OFGEM (2010a), Handbook for Implementing the RIIO Mod-
Northern Power Grid, UK https://www.northernpowergrid. el, Office of Gas and Electricity Markets, London.
com/generation-availability-map
OFGEM (2010b), “RIIO: A new way to regulate energy net-
NREL (2016), Advanced Grid-Friendly Controls Demonstra- works: Final decision”, Office of Gas and Electricity Markets,
tion Project for Utility-Scale PV Power Plants, Technical Re- London.
port NREL/TP-5D00-65368, National Renewable Energy
OFGEM (2009a), “Electricity distribution price control re-
Laboratory, Colorado.
view 5 final proposals – Incentives and obligations”, Office
NREL (2013a), “The Western Wind and Solar Integration of Gas and Electricity Markets, London.
Study Phase 2”, Technical Report NREL/TP-5500-55588,
OFGEM (2009b), “Regulating energy networks for the fu-
National Renewable Energy Laboratory, Colorado.
ture: RPI-X@20 history of energy network regulation”, Of-
NREL (2013b), “Solar energy and capacity value”, dissem- fice of Gas and Electricity Markets, London.
ination brochure, National Renewable Energy Laboratory,
OFGEM (2009c), “Regulating energy networks for the fu-
Colorado.
ture: RPI-X@20 principles, process and issues”, Office of Gas
NREL (2011), “Solar renewable energy certificate (SREC) and Electricity Markets, London.
markets: Status and trends”, National Renewable Energy
Omel (2001), Electricity market activity rules, available at
Laboratory, Colorado.
http://www.omel.es/files/EMRules_2.pdf
NREL (2008), “Determining the capacity value of wind: An
Olmos L. et al. (2015), “D3.2 developments affecting the
updated survey of methods and implementation”, Confer-
design of short-term markets”, MARKET4RES, September
ence Paper NREL/CP-500-43433, National Renewable En-
2015, market4res.eu/wp-content/uploads/D3.2_20151009_
ergy Laboratory, Colorado.
final.pdf.
NSGM (2017), “National Smart Grid Mission – Background”.
O’Neill, R. P., T. Dautel and E. Krall (2011), “Recent ISO
http://www.nsgm.gov.in/en/nsgm.
software enhancements and future software and modeling
OFGEM (2014), “RIIO-ED1: Final determinations for the plans”, www.ferc.gov/industries/electric/indus-act/rto/rto-
slow-track electricity distribution companies: Business plan iso-soft-2011.pdf.
expenditure assessment: Final decision”, Office of Gas and
Papefthymiou, G., K. Grave and K. Dragoon (2014), Flexi-
Electricity Markets, London.
bility Options in Electricity Systems, Report, Project number
OFGEM (2013a), “Strategy decisions for the RIIO-ED1 elec- POWDE14426, ECOFYS, Brussels.
tricity distribution price control: Business plans and pro-
Paulos, B. (2015), Regulating the Utility of the Future: Im-
portionate treatment: Supplementary annex to RIIO-ED1
plications for the Grid Edge, GTM Research, Green Tech
overview paper”, 26b/13, 4 March 2013, Office of Gas and
Media, www.greentechmedia.com/research/report/regulat-
Electricity Markets, London.
ing-the-utility-of-the-future.
OFGEM (2013b), “Strategy decisions for the RIIO-ED1
PCR-ESC (2015), “Euphemia performance, price coupling of
electricity distribution price control: Financial issues: Sup-
regions”, Presentation, European Stakeholder Committee,
plementary annex to RIIO-ED1 overview paper”, 26d/13, 4
ENTSOE publications.
March 2013, Office of Gas and Electricity Markets, London.
PCR PXs, (2016), “EUPHEMIA Public Description: PCR Mar-
ket Coupling Algorithm..” Version 1.3.

160
REFERENCES

Perez-Arriaga J. I., (2013), “Power system economics”, Reg- Reuter, W. H. et al. (2012), “Renewable energy investment:
ulation of the power sector, Springer-Verlag London, London policy and market impacts”, Applied Energy, Vol. 97, Elsevi-
er, Amsterdam, pp. 249-254.
Perner, J. (2015), “Capacity markets in Europe”, US-Germa-
ny Electricity Market Design Workshop, June 2015. Rivier, M., I. J. Pérez-Arriaga and L. Olmos (2013), “Elec-
tricity transmission”, in Regulation of the Power Sector,
PG&E (n.d.), “PG&E proposes smart energy reform in sup-
Pérez-Arriaga, I. J. (ed.), Springer, London, ISBN 978-1-4471-
port of growth of rooftop solar”, www.pge.com (accessed
5033-6.
on 8 April 2015).
RMI (2014), The Economics of Grid Defection: When and
PJM (2015a), “Regulation Performance Impacts,,” presenta-
Where Distributed Solar Generation Plus Storage Competes
tion by Eric Hsia at PJM Market Implementation Committee,
with Traditional Utility Service, Rocky Mountain Institute,
October 7 2015. http://www.pjm.com/~/media/commit-
CohnReznick Think Energy LLC and HOMER Energy LLC.
tees-groups/committees/mic/20151007/20151007-item-08
a-mic-regulation-performance-impacts.ashx. RTE (2014), French Capacity Market, Report accompanying
the draft rules, Réseau de Transport d’Électricité, Cedex,
PJM (2015b), Comments of PJM Interconnection, L.L.C.
France.
Docket No. AD14-14-000. March 6, 2015.
Scarf, H. E. (1994), “The allocation of resources in the pres-
PJM (2014), “2017/2018 RPM base residual auction results”,
ence of indivisibilities”, The Journal of Economic Perspec-
PJM DOCS No. 794597, Pennsylvania New Jersey Maryland
tives, Vol. 8/4, American Economic Association, Pittsburgh,
Interconnection.
PA, pp. 111-128.
PJM (2013), “PJM Ancillary Services online training course”.
SEPA (2015), “Utility solar market snapshot: Sustained
Pennsylvania New Jersey Maryland Interconnection, www.
growth in 2014”, Solar Electric Power Association, Washing-
pjm.com/training/course-catalog.aspx.
ton, DC, May 2015.
PNM (2014), “Final Technology Performance Report: Smart
Siewierski, T. (2015), Empirics of Intraday and Real-time
Grid Demonstration Project: PV Plus Battery for Simultane-
Markets in Europe: POLAND, Research report, http://hdl.
ous Voltage Smoothing and Peak Shifting”, Public Service
handle.net/10419/112779.
Company of New Mexico.
Smartgrid (2017), Smart Grid Demonstration Program.
Pope, S.L., (2014), “Price formation in ISOs and RTOs, prin-
Smartgrid.gov, USA
ciples and improvements..” October 2014. FTI Consulting.
Available at www.epsa.org. Smart Grids Task Force (2013), EG3 First Year Report: Op-
tions on Handling Smart Grids Data, Smart Grids Task Force,
Poudineh, R. and T. Jamasb (2014), “Distributed genera-
Expert Group 3, European Commission, Brussels.
tion, storage, demand response and energy efficiency as
alternatives to grid capacity enhancement”, Energy Policy, Solar Power Europe (2015), Global Power Outlook for Solar
Vol. 67, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 222-231. Power 2015-2019, Solar Power Europe, Solar Power Europe,
Brussels, Belgium
Purkus, A. et al. (2015), “Market integration of renewable
energies through direct marketing – Lessons learned from SP Energy Networks (2017), “Distributed generation heat
the German market premium scheme”, Energy, Sustainability maps”, Scottish Power Energy Networks, Glasgow. Available
and Society, Vol. 5/1, Springer, Berlin, pp. 1–13. at: https://www.spenergynetworks.co.uk/pages/connec-
tion_opportunities.aspx
Red Electrica de España (REE) (2016), Wind Generation
Forecasting at REE. June 2016, http://www.ieawindfore- SP Energy Networks (2014), “SP distribution PLC: Use of
casting.dk/-/media/Sites/IEA_task_36/BCN-2016/IEAW- system charging statement: Final notice: Effective from 1st
indTask36-ExpGapsForecastingWorkshop_Barcelona_Ro- April 2014”, Scottish Power Energy Networks, Glasgow.
driguez_2016.ashx?la=da
Stoft, S. (2003), “The demand for operating reserves:
RES-LEGAL (2015), “RES-LEGAL: Legal sources on renew- Key to price spikes and investment”, IEEE Transactions on
able energy”, http://www.res-legal.eu (accessed on 1 July Power Systems, Vol. 18/2, pp. 470-477, doi: 10.1109/TP-
2015). WRS.2003.810679.

161
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

SWECO (2015), “Study on the effective integration of Dis- US DOE (2013), Grid Energy Storage, United States Depart-
tributed Energy Resources for providing flexibility to the ment of Energy, Maryland.
electricity system”. Final report to The European Commis-
Vázquez, S., P. Rodilla, and C. Batlle (2014), Residual de-
sion. 20 April 2015
mand models for strategic bidding in European power ex-
TennetT (2017), “Market Review 2016”, Electricity market changes: Revisiting the methodology in the presence of a
insights. TennetT. The Netherlands large penetration of renewables. Electric power systems re-
search, Power Systems Research, Vol. 108, pp. 178-184.
THINK Project (2013), From Distribution Networks to Smart
Distribution Systems: Rethinking the Regulation of European Ventosa, M., P. Linares and I. J. Pérez-Arriaga (2013), “Pow-
Electricity DSOs, European University Institute, Italy. er system economics”, in Regulation of the Power Sector,
Pérez-Arriaga, I. J. (ed.), Springer, London, ISBN 978-1-4471-
THINK Project (2012), Electricity Storage: How to Facilitate
5033-6.
its Deployment and Operation in the EU ’, European Universi-
ty Institute, Italy. Van Vyve, M. (2011), “Linear prices for non-convex electrici-
ty markets: models and algorithms”, CORE Discussion Paper
Trebolle, D. et al. (2010), “Distribution planning with reliabil-
No. 2011050, Université catholique de Louvain, Center for
ity options for distributed generation”, Electric Power Sys-
Operations Research and Econometrics, Belgium.
tems Research, Vol. 80/2, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 222-229.
Weißbach, T., and E. Welfonder (2009), “High frequency
T&D World (2017), “India to Invest $44.9 Billion in Smart
deviations within the European power system: Origins and
Grid Infrastructure”, Smart Utility, T&D World, March 2017,
proposals for improvement..” In Power Systems Conference
Available at http://www.tdworld.com/smart-utility/india-in-
and Exposition, 2009. PSCE’09. IEEE/PES (pp. 1-6). IEEE.
vest-449-billion-smart-grid-infrastructure
Xu, B. et al. (2016), “A comparison of policies on the partic-
US Congress (2009), American Recovery and Reinvestment
ipation of storage in U.S. frequency regulation markets”, in
Act of 2009, Washington, DC, 6 January 2009, signed into
proceedings of 2016 IEEE PES General Meeting. Boston, MA,
Law on 17 February 2009.
doi:10.1109/PESGM.2016.7741531.

162
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

APPENDIX
EUPHEMIA, THE PAN-EUROPEAN
MARKET CLEARING ALGORITHM

The Price Coupling of Regions (PCR) is the ini- Using block orders and complex conditions to
tiative of seven European Power Exchanges1 (at avoid being matched at a loss:
this writing) to develop a single price coupling
The constraints and cost structure of different
solution to be used to calculate electricity prices
resources can be bid in markets by using block
across Europe, and allocate cross border capacity
bids, for example:
on a day-ahead basis.
•• 
A thermal unit can use a combination of
Under the PCR initiative, a common market clear-
linked block orders to make sure it will recov-
ing algorithm has been developed (EUPHEMIA,
er its start-up cost and it will not produce less
acronym of Pan-European Hybrid Electricity Mar-
than its minimum power output.
ket Integration Algorithm). This algorithm allows
each Power Exhange to continue using the bid- •• A thermal plant can use the complex condi-
ding formats previously in place in their respec- tion (where allowed) to ensure the recovery
tive market, and opens the possibility of homog- of the start-up cost.
enizing bidding formats across Europe in the
•• By combining block orders, storage can sell
future.
during peak hours only if its off-peak pur-
The basic bidding format in EUPHEMIA keeps on chase order has been accepted and buy/sell
being the simple bid, though additional bidding combination is in the money (EPEX SPOT,
formats that enable agents to hedge against un- 2014).
certain market clearing outcomes are used, as
•• Demand response may condition a load re-
shown in the table A.1.
duction in some periods, to an increased con-
sumption in some others.

•• Plants can use exclusive orders to bid differ-


ent production profiles in order to cover a
wide range of possible market outcomes.

In Box A.1 it is analyzed how, with the current


bidding formats in Europe, it is quite complex to
properly bid a resource that is called to play a key
role in the future: storage plants.

164 See, for example, www.nordpoolspot.com


APPENDIX

Table A.1 Bidding formats and description

Bid format Description

Simple orders

Buy or sell orders for a given volume and a limit price. It can be partially accepted if the
Hourly step orders
clearing price is equal to the bid price

Hourly linear Buy or sell order for a given volume and a pair of prices: an initial price at which the or-
piecewise order der begins to be accepted and a final price at which the order is totally accepted

Block orders

Buy or sell order for a single price and volume and a period of consecutive hours that
Regular block order
can only be totally accepted

Regular block order that can be partially accepted, it includes a minimum acceptance
Profile block order
ratio condition

An Exclusive group is a set of block orders for which the sum of the accepted ratios
Exclusive block orders cannot exceed 1. In the particular case of blocks that have a minimum acceptance ratio
of 1 it means that at most one of the blocks of the exclusive group can be accepted.

Set of block orders where the acceptance of some blocks (children) is conditioned to
the acceptance of others (parents)

Figure A.1 Linked block orders

MW
Grandchild

Linked block orders


Child

Parent

Trading Period

Source: Miura, 2014

A flexible “hourly” order is a block order with a fixed price limit, a fixed volume, and
Flexible hourly block
minimum acceptance ratio of 1, with duration of 1 hour. The hour is not defined by the
order
participant but will be determined by the algorithm (hence the name “flexible”)

Complex conditions

Series of hourly step orders conditioning to the recovery of a fixed quantity over the
Minimum Income
entire trading day

Limits the variation between the accepted volume at a period and the accepted volume
Ramp limit
at the adjacent periods

165
A DA P T I N G M A R K E T D E S I G N TO H I G H S H A R E S O F VA R I A B L E R E N E WA B L E E N E R G Y

Box A1 The complexity of bidding some resources Currently, the I-SEM (the Integrated Single Electricity
with existing formats: the case of storage Market, the electricity market of Ireland and Northern Ire-
land) is performing a number of test over the EUPHEMIA
None of the previous types of bids fits perfectly the char-
algorithm to assess the ability of the bidding protocols
acteristics and needs of storage, which is reducing the
to perform complex optimal schedules such as those in-
risk of being uneconomically committed throughout the
volved by storage resources. The analysis of the results
day subject to limited energy constraints.
will provide valuable information about the suitability of
Linked block orders seem to be the only alternative to current bidding protocols. At a high level this study con-
partially hedge such risk: by combining (linking) two sists of two main phases: (i) first an initial Phase, involving
block orders (one block for charging and another block trials performed by SEMO, and then (ii) the commercial
for discharging), storage can sell during peak hours only phase, where trials will be performed by SEMO in con-
if (i) its off-peak purchase order has been accepted and junction with industry participants.
(ii) buy/sell combination is in the money (EPEX SPOT,
At the time of this writing, the first phase has been com-
2014). However, this requires storage to anticipate the
pleted and the report is already available (see Eirgrid
hourly periods for consuming and the hourly periods for
et al., 2015). The results show how “the current SEM algo-
producing in advance.
rithm is capable of running storage units with much great-
The combined use of exclusive block orders with linked er flexibility throughout a day than EUPHEMIA due to the
block orders could help mitigating this risk. This approach rigid profile of the linked block orders. The SEM clearing
allows to enter multiple candidate profiles, created in line algorithm, a unit-commitment-like algorithm, has a num-
with the principles outlined previously, each potential ber of features to optimally represent units with specific
profile conforming an exclusive group. For example, the characteristics (e.g., pumped storage) while EUPHEMIA
profile representing the limited running of the unit could has products which must be adapted, for the purpose of
be entered in various different time periods (e.g., one pro- producing commitment starting point for dispatch, for a
file during hours 10 – 13 and another profile during hours range of technologies.”
15 – 18). Nevertheless, the amount of blocks that can be
In the figure A.2 it is schematically represented the pros
used and combined is quite limited.
and cons of the different alternative methods tested so
far to bid storage units in EUPHEMIA.

Figure A.2 Characteristics of pumped hydro methodologies

Method Benefits Disbenefits

Accounts for reservoir levels; Inflexible due to limited hours;


Linked Block (original) simplest linked block representation; does not restore to target level as used;
units are price takers requires prediction of load and price

Accounts for reservoir levels; Inflexible as rejection of one hour causes


Linked Block (extended) allows use in multiple time periods; rejection of all future hours;
units are price takers requires prediction of load and price

Allows full utilisation; Does not account for reservoir level


allows units to be price makers; limitations;
Simple allows greatest flexibility to follow price would requires significant actions post
signals; DAM;
does not require prediction of load requires prediction of price

Source: Eirgrid et al., 2015

166
APPENDIX

167
© IRENA 2017

IRENA HEADQUARTERS
P.O. Box 236, Abu Dhabi
United Arab Emirates

www.irena.org

Você também pode gostar