Você está na página 1de 4

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OCTOBER 2014


OF CHICAGO NUMBER 327

Chicag­o Fed Letter


Understanding the relationship between real wage growth and
labor market conditions
by Daniel Aaronson, vice president and director of microeconomic research, and Andrew Jordan, associate economist

The authors find that the share of the labor force that is medium-term unemployed
(five to 26 weeks unemployed) and the share working part time (less than 35 hours per
week) involuntarily are strongly correlated with real wage growth. Moreover, they estimate
that average real wage growth would have been between one-half of a percentage point
and a full percentage point higher in June 2014 if 2005–07 labor market conditions had
been restored, indicating that the slack in the jobs market still weighs heavily on the
real wage prospects of U.S. workers.

While labor market conditions have percentage point to 1 percentage point


improved markedly over the past few higher. We also find that the impact of
years, real wage slack labor market conditions on real
growth remains dis- wage growth is stronger for those workers
1. Real hourly wage growth, 1979–2014
appointing. In this at the bottom of the wage distribution.
percent Chicago Fed Letter, we
5 discuss the labor Background
market conditions In figure 1, we plot quarterly real wage
that have historically growth from 1979 through 2014, using
been associated with three sources of average hourly wages
real wage growth. We from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics
document a strong (BLS): the Current Employment Survey,
0 correlation between or CES (commonly referred to as the
real wage growth and payroll survey); the Employment Cost
medium-term unem- Index, or ECI; and the Current Population
ployment and find a Survey, or CPS (commonly referred to
link between real wage as the household survey). Real wage
−5
growth and marginally growth was particularly strong during
1979 ’84 ’89 ’94 ’99 2004 ’09 ’14 attached labor force the jobs boom of the late 1990s but has
CES ECI (wages) CPS participants, particu- decelerated since then. During the
larly those working 2008–09 recession, real wage growth
Notes: The CES data are for 1979:Q1–2014:Q2, the ECI data for 1981:Q1–2014:Q2, and
the CPS data for 1980:Q1–2013:Q4. All data are deflated by the Personal Consumption part time involuntarily fell but, perhaps surprisingly, not dramati-
Expenditures Price Index. The shaded bars indicate recessions as defined by the National
Bureau of Economic Research.
for economic reasons.1 cally. Still, it has been slow to return to
Sources: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Employment Survey (CES) and Employment As of June 2014, labor pre-2008 levels.
Cost Index (ECI), from Haver Analytics; authors’ calculations based on data from the U.S.
Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey (CPS). market conditions
Historically, the national unemployment
had yet to revert fully
rate has been a useful predictor of real
to pre-recessionary
wage growth. However, that relation-
levels. If 2005–07 labor market condi-
ship, dubbed the “wage Phillips curve,”
tions had been restored by then, we esti-
broke down over the past five years.
mate that average real wage growth
Given that the unemployment rate fell
would have been roughly one-half of a
(black line in figure 2). exercises (explained in note 5) that in-
2. Labor market conditions, 1979–2014
Combining this with clude different labor market measures or
percent evidence that the long- are estimated on different time periods.
10 term unemployed
The first column of numbers reports the
have difficulty transi-
results of a statistical model that includes
8
tioning to employment
only the STUR and the LTUR as labor
regardless of the state
market variables. In that specification,
of the local labor
6 a 1 percentage point increase in the
market, Krueger,
STUR leads to a change in real wage
Cramer, and Cho ar-
growth of –0.40 percentage points
4 gue that the long-term
(standard error of 0.08 percentage
unemployed are dis-
points)—a statistically and economically
2 connected from the
significant correlation. For context, note
labor market and
that when the STUR rose from 4% in
0 therefore have little
2005–07 to 6.4% in 2009, we would ex-
1979 ’84 ’89 ’94 ’99 2004 ’09 ’14 impact on aggregate
pect real wage growth to decelerate by
Short-term unemployment rate (<27 weeks) real wage growth.
1 percentage point, all else being equal.
Long-term unemployment rate (≥27 weeks)
What is real wage Similarly, a 1 percentage point increase
Share of labor force working part time involuntarily
for economic reasons growth tied to? in the LTUR translates into a change in
National data is prob- real wage growth of –0.38 percentage
Notes: All three data series are from January 1979 through June 2014. For details on
those working part time involuntarily for economic reasons, see the text, particularly
lematic for studying points—which is similar in magnitude
note 1. The shaded bars indicate recessions as defined by the National Bureau of
Economic Research.
the relationship be- to the STUR effect and likewise statisti-
Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey, from Haver Analytics.
tween various labor cally and economically significant. The
market conditions and LTUR rose from 0.9% in 2005–07 to
from a peak of 10% during 2009 to 6.1% wage growth. The national time series 2.9% in 2009—an increase that would
in June 2014, the historical relationship are relatively short, and many labor mar- be associated with a 0.8 percentage
between the unemployment rate and ket measures, such as the LTUR and point deceleration in real wage growth.
real wages would have predicted real STUR, co-move, offering limited ability The second column shows that the re-
wage growth to have been 3.6 percentage to distinguish the effects of particular sults are a little over half the size but
points higher by mid-2014, according to labor market variables or other con- still statistically significant and econom-
our calculations using BLS data. Instead, founding factors. Moreover, wage growth ically meaningful when we use just the
real wage growth has been relatively is plausibly tied more closely to the rela- past 20 years of data. Moreover, the re-
flat over the past few years. tive strength of local or skill-specific labor sults are broadly similar, although some-
markets than to the national market. times less precisely estimated, when we
Many researchers have studied whether include both the contemporaneous
Accordingly, we follow a long tradition
the duration of unemployment—in and lagged unemployment rates in the
of narrowing the definition of a labor
particular, the extent of long spells of analysis, use a sample of large MSAs
market to a geographic area such as a
unemployment—affects aggregate real rather than states, or do not adjust the
state or metropolitan statistical area
wage growth.2 Most of that research has wage data for demographics (not shown
(MSA).4 Using annual data derived from
historically been based on the European in figure 3). Strikingly, the association
the outgoing rotation files of the CPS
experience, but this topic has gained between the LTUR and real wage growth
from 1982 through 2013, we generate
renewed interest in the United States as also shows up strongly in a sample where
estimates that associate demographically
a result of the unprecedented increase we include only the dozen states in each
adjusted real wage growth in a state-year
in long-term unemployment since 2008 year with the highest STUR (12 states ×
(e.g., Illinois in 2007) to a variety of mea-
and the breakdown of the wage Phillips 32 years = 384 observations)—i.e., the
sures of labor market conditions in that
curve. A prominent example is a paper states where firms have access to a large
state-year while holding constant factors
by Krueger, Cramer, and Cho,3 in which pool of the recently unemployed (not
that impact real wage growth and are
the authors use national time-series data shown in figure 3).
invariant to states or particular years.5
to conclude that U.S. real wage growth
is strongly correlated with the short- Figure 3 presents our estimates of the The STUR (and LTUR) data used to get
term unemployment rate (STUR)— impact of a 1 percentage point change the first two columns of results are from
the fraction of the labor force that has in a labor market condition on real a heterogeneous group of job seekers.
been out of work for less than 27 weeks wage growth (along with state cluster- Therefore, we experimented with split-
(gray line in figure 2)—but not with the corrected standard errors in parentheses). ting the STUR into more-detailed group-
long-term unemployment rate (LTUR)— The labor market measures are listed in ings. One such example, reported in
the fraction of the labor force that has the left column. The remaining columns the third column, is made up of the very-
been out of work for at least 27 weeks report the results from the statistical short-term unemployment rate (VSTUR),
the wage distribution (the results for the
3. Impact of 1 percentage point change in labor market conditions on real wage growth
10th percentile wage are even stronger,
1 2 3 4 5 6 though they are not shown); and for the
Short-term –0.40** –0.25* most part, the effects decline mono-
unemployment rate (0.08) (0.11) tonically, but always remain statistically
Very-short-term 0.03 0.12 0.11 0.08 significant, at higher wage levels. That

unemployment rate (0.11) (0.11) (0.11) (0.07) is, the impact of slack labor market
Medium-term –0.71** –0.54** –0.38** –0.19** conditions is strongest for jobs that pay

unemployment rate (0.11) (0.10) (0.10) (0.05) near the bottom of the wage distribu-
Long-term –0.38** –0.21* –0.27** –0.06 0.06 0.01 tion and is weakest, but still present,
unemployment rate (0.09) (0.10) (0.09) (0.10) (0.08) (0.05)
for jobs at the top.
Part time for –0.40** –0.32** –0.20**
economic reasons rate (0.09) (0.08) (0.04) Conclusion
Wage measure Average Average Average Average 25th 75th
Although our estimates are not meant to
wage wage wage wage percentile percentile
wage wage be interpreted as causal, they do suggest
Time period 1982–2013 1994–2013 1982–2013 1982–2013 1982–2013 1982–2013
a strong association between real wage
growth and medium-term unemploy-
Notes: See note 5 for the regression model. See the text for the definitions of the variables. The standard errors reported in
parentheses are clustered at the state level. *Significant at the 5% level. **Significant at the 1% level. ment, as well as a link between real
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey. wage growth and marginally attached
workers, particularly those working part
which we define as the fraction of the employment-to-unemployment, NILF- time involuntarily for economic reasons.
labor force that has been out of work to-unemployment, and unemployment- What do these results imply about real
for less than five weeks, and the medium- to-NILF transitions). wage growth today? We estimate that
term unemployment rate (MTUR), average real wage growth would have
The PTERR stands out. Even after con-
which again is the fraction of the labor been roughly one-half of a percentage
ditioning on the unemployment rates
force out of work for five to 26 weeks. point to 1 percentage point higher in
from the third column, the fourth col-
We find no relationship between the June 2014 if labor market conditions
umn shows that a 1 percentage point
VSTUR and real wage growth. Indeed, had been similar to those of 2005–07.
increase in the PTERR is associated with
the VSTUR has little variation across the Thus, it appears that the slack in the jobs
a change of –0.40 percentage points in
business cycle and has been on a long market still weighs heavily on the real
real wage growth (standard error of
secular decline since the early 1980s. wage prospects of American workers.
0.09 percentage points). Conditioning
However, the MTUR seems to be strongly on PTERR also reduces the impact of
associated with declining real wage growth. LTUR, to the point that this result is Charles L. Evans, President ; Daniel G. Sullivan,
Again, the results are of a similar flavor, economically small and no longer sta- Executive Vice President and Director of Research;
Spencer Krane, Senior Vice President and Economic
although a little weaker, when we restrict tistically significant (see the fourth row, Advisor ; David Marshall, Senior Vice President, financial
the sample to the past 20 years (not fourth column).7 Notably, the share of markets group ; Daniel Aaronson, Vice President,
shown in figure 3). microeconomic policy research; Jonas D. M. Fisher,
the labor force working part time for Vice President, macroeconomic policy research; Richard
Although much of the discussion of the noneconomic reasons (see note 7) has Heckinger,Vice President, markets team; Anna L.
Paulson, Vice President, finance team; William A. Testa,
wage Phillips curve is focused on un- no impact on real wage growth or the Vice President, regional programs, and Economics Editor ;
employment rates, it is reasonable to other coefficients, including PTERR and Helen O’D. Koshy and Han Y. Choi, Editors  ;
STUR, in the statistical model. The Rita Molloy and Julia Baker, Production Editors ;
expect other measures of labor market Sheila A. Mangler, Editorial Assistant.
conditions to matter. We looked at a PTERR results are particularly striking
Chicago Fed Letter is published by the Economic
variety that are calculable in the CPS— given that this rate has been elevated Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank
in particular, the share of the labor force over the past six years (blue line in fig- of Chicago. The views expressed are the authors’
and do not necessarily reflect the views of the
working part time for economic reasons ure 2). The PTERR rose from 2.9% Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
(the part time for economic reasons rate, during 2005–07, peaked at 5.9% in 2009, Reserve System.
or PTERR), the share of the working-age and then fell back to only 4.8% as of © 2014 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
June 2014. Chicago Fed Letter articles may be reproduced in
population that is not in the labor force whole or in part, provided the articles are not
(NILF) but wants a job,6 the white prime- Finally, the results discussed thus far reproduced or distributed for commercial gain
and provided the source is appropriately credited.
age (25–54 years old) male unemploy- relate to the growth of average real wages. Prior written permission must be obtained for
ment rate, the employment-to-population The fifth and sixth columns report re- any other reproduction, distribution, republica-
ratio, the share of the population that tion, or creation of derivative works of Chicago Fed
sults for real wage growth at the 25th Letter articles. To request permission, please contact
switched employers, and the share of and 75th percentiles of a state’s wage Helen Koshy, senior editor, at 312-322-5830 or
the population that switched labor distribution. The impacts of a 1 percent- email Helen.Koshy@chi.frb.org. Chicago Fed
Letter and other Bank publications are available
market status (e.g., those who went age point jump in the MTUR and PTERR at www.chicagofed.org.
through unemployment-to-employment, are particularly strong at the bottom of ISSN 0895-0164
1
Survey respondents reporting this labor Bank of Minneapolis, working paper, estimating this regression, we first scrub Yit
force status to the U.S. Bureau of Labor No. 713, May, and Michael T. Kiley, 2014, free of the influences of changes in the
Statistics (BLS) are currently working less “An evaluation of the inflationary pressure composition of the population—in partic-
than 35 hours per week for economic associated with short- and long-term ular, gender, education, a quartic in age,
reasons such as “slack work or unfavorable unemployment,” Finance and Economics gender × education, gender × quartic in
business conditions, inability to find full- Discussion Series, Board of Governors of age, and marital status.
time work, or seasonal declines in demand.” the Federal Reserve System, working 6
The BLS defines NILF as individuals who
For details on how the BLS categorizes paper, No. 2014-28, March 21. For the
have not actively looked for work in the
part-time workers, see www.bls.gov/news. U.S. Census Bureau’s MSA delineations,
previous four weeks; for more details and
release/empsit.t08.htm. see www.census.gov/population/metro/.
further NILF distinctions, see www.bls.
5
2
See, e.g., Stephen Machin and Alan To derive our estimates, we perform a re- gov/news.release/empsit.t16.htm.
Manning, 1999, “The causes and conse- gression analysis—a statistical process that 7
Part of this finding might be because the
quences of longterm unemployment in measures the degree of correlation between
transition from long-term unemployment
Europe,” in Handbook of Labor Economics, two variables. In particular, the regressions
to part time for economic reasons is com-
Orley C. Ashenfelter and David Card we perform take the following form:
mon. Using matched CPS data over the
(eds.), Vol. 3C, Amsterdam: Elsevier / Yit = α + β Xit + γi + γt + εit , past ten years, we calculate that 26% of
North-Holland, pp. 3085–3139.
where Yit is wage growth in state i at time t, the long-term unemployed who find a job
3
Alan B. Krueger, Judd Cramer, and David Xit is labor market conditions in state i become part time for economic reasons,
Cho, 2014, “Are the long-term unemployed and at time t, the γi and γt are state and compared with 18% of the short-term
on the margins of the labor market?,” year fixed effects, and ɛit is the error term. unemployed who find work. By contrast,
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Note that β measures the relationship be- 32% of the short-term unemployed who
Spring, forthcoming. tween X and Y, conditional on other right- find a job become part time for noneco-
4 hand-side variables, and is what we report nomic reasons (e.g., child-care problems,
Recent examples that use this strategy to
in figure 3. The year fixed effects account family obligations, school, or Social Security
estimate the price Phillips curve are Terry
for, among other factors, trends in U.S. limits on earnings in retirement), com-
J. Fitzgerald and Juan Pablo Nicolini, 2014,
price inflation, making the interpretation pared with 23% of the long-term unemployed
“Is there a stable relationship between
of Yit a real wage growth measure. Prior to who find work.
unemployment and future inflation?
Evidence from U.S. cities,” Federal Reserve

Você também pode gostar