Você está na página 1de 15

When to Risk It? Institutions, Ambitions, and the Decision to Run for the U.S.

House
Author(s): Cherie D. Maestas, Sarah Fulton, L. Sandy Maisel and Walter J. Stone
Source: The American Political Science Review, Vol. 100, No. 2 (May, 2006), pp. 195-208
Published by: American Political Science Association
Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/27644344
Accessed: 19-11-2018 12:30 UTC

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

American Political Science Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and
extend access to The American Political Science Review

This content downloaded from 210.212.93.46 on Mon, 19 Nov 2018 12:30:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
American Political Science Review Vol. 100, No. 2 May 2006

When to Risk It? Institutions, Ambitions, and the Decision


to Run for the U.S. House
CHERIE D. MAESTAS Florida State University
SARAH FULTON University of California, Davis
L. SANDY MAISEL Colby College
WALTER J. STONE University of California, Davis
rhe health of any democratic system depends on political ambition to generate a steady supply
of quality candidates for office. Because most models of candidate entry assume ambition rather
than model it, previous research fails to understand its roots in individual and institutional charac
teristics. We develop a two-stage model of progressive behavior that distinguishes between the formation
of ambition for higher office and the decision to enter a particular race. Using data from a survey of state
legislators, we demonstrate that the intrinsic costs and benefits associated with running for and holding
higher office shape ambitions but do not influence the decision to run. For progressively ambitious
legislators, the second-stage decision is a strategic choice about when to run rather than whether to run.
Our research highlights how institutional characteristics that foster progressive ambition also increase
the likelihood that national or local political conditions will be translated into meaningful choices at the
ballot box.

Ambition for office is the raw material of pol Despite the importance of political ambition, there
itics, the grist whereby electoral competition is surprisingly little research that systematically exam
and office holders' accountability is assured. It ines the theoretical and empirical underpinnings of in
lies at the heart of our understanding of democratic dividual ambition, particularly the desire to progress
theory, explaining when, why, and how political elites from one political office to another.2 Seminal stud
respond to citizen interests. Accordingly, studies of ies either equate progressive ambition with the op
a variety of countries and electoral systems link the portunity structure to win higher office or assume it
political career aspirations of office holders to key is an inherent characteristic of political office-holders
political outcomes.1 Ambitions affect office holders' (Rohde 1979; Schlesinger 1966). But does progressive
policy interests, whether and how much they specialize ambition primarily result from the opportunity struc
their activities while in office, and their loyalty to their ture that creates a "career-ladder" for politicians? Or,
party or faction (e.g., Cox, Rosenbluth, and Theis 2000; do personal or institutional characteristics change the
Herrik and Moore 1993). The stability of the legislative incentives for climbing the political career ladder? Is
institutions in which office holders serve, the strength it the case, as Rohde (1979) assumed, that all lower
of committees and parties, and the autonomy of legisla office holders would seek higher office if obtaining
tive institutions relate to the types of career ambition that office were costless and riskless? Or, are some
that dominate (e.g., Epstein et al. 1997; Santos 1999). lower office holders content to stay put regardless of
Even the partisan tides and enduring electoral align their ability and the opportunity to move up? The an
ments that define the contours of history are shaped by swers to these questions are a necessary part of under
the career ambitions of those seeking public office and standing how a political system creates and nurtures a
advancement (e.g., Canon and Sousa 1992; Jacobson pool of skilled candidates for political office. Further,
1989). answers to these questions can help us understand the
factors that influence office-holders' behavior in office,
the institutions in which they serve and, ultimately, the
Ch?rie D. Maestas is Assistant Professor, Department of Political
prospects for representation in the political system as
Science, 531 Bellamy Building, Florida State University, Tallahassee, a whole.
FL 32306 (Cherie.Maestas@fsu.edu).
Sarah Fulton, ABD, Department of Political Science, University We propose a significant revision to the decision
of California, Davis, Davis, CA 95616 (safulton@ucdavis.edu). model commonly used to explain lower office-holders'
L. Sandy Maisel is Professor, Department of Government, Colby choices to seek higher office. We separate the decision
College, Waterville, Maine 04901 (lsmaisel@colby.edu).
into a two-stage process where the formation of ambi
Walter J. Stone is Professor, Department of Political Science, Uni
versity of California, Davis, Davis, CA 95616 (wstone@ucdavis.edu). tion for higher office is a distinct stage that precedes the
We would like to thank Bill Berry, Tom Carsey, Chris Reenock, decision to run. Our interest is in developing and test
Jeff Staton, John Scholz, and Will Moore, as well as the editor and ing a general model that relates progressive ambition
the anonymous reviewers for their insightful feedback and helpful to characteristics of the lower office, to the strategic
suggestions. This research was supported by grants from the Carnegie
Corporation of New York and from the National Science Foundation
(SBR-9515450). 2 There is an extensive literature on candidacies that include some
1 See, for examples of research in various settings, Clarke and Price discussion of ambition (see Fowler 1993 for a review), but very few
1981 (Canada); Cox, Rosenbluth; and Theis 2000; Epstein et al. 1997 studies where progressive ambition serves as a dependent variable.
(Japan); Herrick and Moore 1993 (United States); Jones et al. 2002 An exception to this is the body of research on gender and career
(Argentina); or Santos 1999 (Brazil). ambition. See Fulton et al. 2006 for a review of this literature.

195

This content downloaded from 210.212.93.46 on Mon, 19 Nov 2018 12:30:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
When to Risk It? May 2006

opportunity to win higher


madeoffice, and to
long-term the per
service in
attractive We
characteristics of office-holders. (e.g. Berkman
also explore
lower office conditions same
mediate thescholars
time, translation
offero
ing whether
bition into a decision to enter professionali
a race for higher offic
The immediate locus of
of our research
candidates forishigher
state l
lators' ambition to move to legislatures
sional the U.S. House of
are full
resentatives. We surveyed a national
individuals to sample
focus on ofpos
they
legislators to examine their develop campaign
perceptions of institutiosk
strategic, and personal base
factors that might
of supporters influ
to help
to the next.
their ambition or their candidacy FiorinaWith
decisions. (1994
data, we can directly test1051)
a number
both speculate
of causal that
ass
could increase
tions that have gone untested the researc
in previous pool of
for the U.S.
though we develop the two-stage House,
model in the but
con
of progressive ambitionbiases
in thethat exist
United in state
States, our
level. Moreover,
ment applies to any multilevel this pro
political system w
politicians in one office the
mightintroduction of term
aspire to hold anot
ambitious legislators out o
STATE LEGISLATURES On theANDother
THEhand, prof
PUZZL
the size of the
OF PROGRESSIVE AMBITION U.S. Hou
FOR
professionalized institutio
THE U.S. HOUSE
tive long-term political ca
State legislatures haveThe increasing
provided the array of p
dominant
combined
way to the U.S. House. For with
example, increases
over half of
icymaking resources,
members of the 2002 House held office in a state allo
lature prior to winning of their
their partisan or
congressional perso
seat. A
level. Professional
same time, however, relatively legislat
few state legislator
manyonly
in any given year. In 2002, the destination
45 U.S. Houserather
ra
(Berkman
nationwide attracted a state 1994;as
legislator Squire 19
a candid
from among over 7500 individuals holding that of
The apparent broad pool RUNNING
o? potential FOR HIGH
candidates a
TWO-STAGE
state level does not necessarily translate to DECISI
a large
of actual candidates. Why do so few run?
To identify
An obvious answer is that few raceshow professio
are compet
ambition this
in any given election. However, and the
posesdecision
a "chi
and-egg" problem because ory of progressive
more races might beha
been competitive had pits
an experienced, well-fu
the expected utility of
office?E(Ui)?against
state legislator decided to run. Certainly, we the e
expec
prospects of winning to aweigh
higher office?E(Uh)
heavily (B
on the min
state legislators who are considering a run for highe
fice. But, focusing on prospects alone does not ad
E(Uh) = phBh - Ch (1)
the more fundamental question of whether state E(U,) = p,B! - C, (2)
lators want to move up. If progressive ambition rest
Here, p is the probability
more than just the anticipation of a of competitive
winning the election, B
then year-to-year changesthe value
in of the target office, of
prospects and C winning
is the cost of runni
t
for office. When the
arise from national political or economic tidesexpected utility of winning a highea
or
office fail
ety of local conditions may exceeds the
toexpected utility of winning
stimulate the lower
experien
office,
challengers to run. Thus, we an ambitious
turn politician
to a will attempt to move
broader qu
about the formation oftheprogressive
higher office. ambition and
A key assumption that
distinguish it from the subsequent is commonly to
decision used run
in th
model is that factors,
do personal and institutional politicians place enough value on holdin
independen
and in conjunction with higher office that they would
competition forattempt to move ups
office,
doing so and
state legislators' ambitions were costless
their and riskless (e.g., Rohde 1979
decisions to
for the U.S. House? In other words, scholars assume that politicians are
progressively
We pay particular attention toambitious
how because
lower "higher" office pro
office
vides greater
acteristics influence state status, salary, or
legislators territorial jurisdictio
because pre
than "lower" office
research presents an intriguing (Francis and
puzzle. Kenny 2000).of
Scholars Th
legislatures uniformly assumption
agree isthat problematic, however, because
increases in thele
at
tive professionalism overtributes of higher
the past officefew
that scholars deem attracti
decades h
may not be given the same value by those holding lower
office. For example, some lower office holders may view
3 Data compiled from various policy
issues jurisdictions
of CQ of their own office
Weekly during as more
therewap
of 2001-2002. ing than the jurisdictions associated with the highe

196

This content downloaded from 210.212.93.46 on Mon, 19 Nov 2018 12:30:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
American Political Science Review Vol. 100, No. 2

office. If so, they might not be tempted by the higher their attraction to a House seat with a general view
office, regardless of costs or risks. This is an example of the prestige or effectiveness of the House as an
where we could not assume that the difference between institution, and with a general sense of the competi
Bh and Bi is sufficient to induce progressive ambition. tiveness of their district. These factors, in other words,
Perhaps more important, however, is the implicit as are intrinsic to a congressional candidacy and bear on
sumption that all lower office-holders make this sort of individuals' general attraction to the House rather than
utility comparison each time a race occurs. Theoreti on their decision about whether to enter a particular
cally, this assumption suggests that all state legislators race.
should be responsive to short-term variation in the po Specifically, we argue that the attractiveness of a
litical environment that affect ph, such as incumbent alternative office stems from potential candidates' ge
missteps or shifts in national political tides. However, eral, or long-run, chances of winning that office (pgen),
in-depth interviews with state legislators and other po their marginal expected gain from the target offic
tential candidates suggest that only those with a high (Bmarg), and the marginal costs of running (Cmarg)-
level of ambition are willing to bear the costs associated Long-run prospects reflect a potential candidate's as
with seriously considering a run for higher office, for sessment of the general "winnability" of the seat apar
example, assessing their prospects, ph, for a given race from immediate political conditions or incumbent ch
(Fowler and McClure 1989; Kazee 1994). acteristics. In other words, this term represents the
The two-stage model we propose distinguishes be portunity structure of the target office as well as th
tween ambition formation and the decision to run. In potential candidates' own skills and ability to exploit
our model, only individuals who are sufficiently at that structure. Marginal gains are simply the difference
tracted to the higher office move to the second stage of in the personal valuation of the current position an
the decision process and expend the resources neces the target office. Marginal costs capture the differences
sary to explore whether to run in a particular election in cost associated with seeking and holding the targe
or await a better opportunity. We see the formation of office compared to the current position. Finally, we
progressive ambition as an important step to isolate in note that personal motivations (M) outside of the co
order to understand how institutional and individual benefit analysis might spark ambition as well.
characteristics nurture the ambitions of future lead
ers. Our conception of the process differentiates the Progressive Ambition = /(E(Ua)
general costs, benefits, and prospects associated with ? Pgen-t*marg t-rnarg "i JVIJ.
running for higher office from the specific costs and
prospects of running in a particular race. Progressive ambition, then, is a function of the ex
We define progressive ambition as the general at pected utility of the alternative office, E(Ua). On
traction one holds for a career in a different political those who find that the intrinsic benefits outweigh t
office than the one he or she currently holds, apart intrinsic costs move to the second stage of the decisio
from a specific intent to run in a given year. We treat process?the choice about entering a particular rac
ambition as causally prior to the decision to run in a Those who find that the costs of attaining the high
particular race; we think it unlikely that the decision office outweigh its potential benefits pursue differ
to run precedes the evaluation of the attractiveness ent career avenues. Because they find a House career
of higher office. Of course, this conceptualization does unattractive, national or local circumstances that m
not preclude the possibility that the political oppor create an opportunity in a given race do not encourag
tunity structure or other strategic variables affect the them to run.
attractiveness of office. As Schlesinger (1966) points We depart markedly from Black (1972) and others in
out, political hopefuls direct their ambitions toward of our conceptualization of the second stage of the can
fices that are obtainable. However, opportunity alone didate entry decision in that ours is not an expected
is insufficient to create ambition. Instead, ambition for utility model. We argue that the strategic choice to run
higher office stems from a combination of factors, many is not about whether to run; it is a choice about when
of which are personal assessments about the costs and to run. Those who enter the second stage have already
benefits of moving up. These costs and benefits affect crossed a threshold level of ambition; the general costs
ambition, rather than the immediate decision to enter and benefits of running for higher office are not a signif
a particular race. icant influence on the decision to enter a race. Instead,
Like Black (1972), we see ambition as a function of ambitious potential candidates weigh the conditions
an expected utility calculation, but we suggest that the that tend to shift from race to race:
calculation rests on relatively stable cost-and-benefit
comparisons rather than the attributes of a particular Pr(Run | Progressive Ambition > 0) =/(pt, pgen,Ct,).
race. Many costs of running for the U.S. House and
holding office are known well in advance and vary little
For instance, potential candidates' electoral prospects
from one election to the next. General costs such as for a given race (pt) change dramatically if the incum
bent retires or dies and this affects when it makes sense
time away from family, a move to Washington DC,
and the grueling schedules associated congressional
life are all part and parcel of a congressional career. 4 We make the simplifying assumption that lower-office holders be
Individuals evaluate their attraction to a House career lieve they can win reelection to their own office, thus lower office
with these factors in mind. Similarly, individuals assess chances are not a source of variation in ambition formation.

197

This content downloaded from 210.212.93.46 on Mon, 19 Nov 2018 12:30:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
When to Risk It? May 2006

to run. Those who view their


different prospects
skills and career as high
goals. Squire (1988a, 1988b)
more likely to run than those
links the qualities ofwho view
state legislative institutionstheir
to the ch
as low. Similarly, the immediate
development of static andcost progressive(Q) of
ambition. He givin
one's current position to run for higher
finds that professional institutions withoffice
strong external may l
large for office-holderscareer but decrease
paths promote as they
progressive ambition and have appr
term limits in office. Progressively ambitious
higher turnover. In contrast, legislatures with strong pote
candidates always have the option
internal career pathsof waiting
and fewer for a mo
external opportunities
opportune race; thus there isambition
promote static a temporal
and have lower turnover.dimensi
the choice (see Banks and BerkmanKeiweit 1989).
(1994) finds that states with more profesThose
view their long-term prospects of have
sional legislatures generally securing
a higher proportiona seat
high may require greater odds
of freshmen in the
House members with stateimpending
legislative ex
to enter. perience than states with nonprofessional legislatures,
In contrast, those who did not form ambition for particularly among Democrats. But in a later article,
higher office in the first stage do not respond to vari Berkman and Eisenstein (1999) show that US. House
ations in the prospects or costs associated with the races in states with a professional legislature are more
upcoming race. They simply do not run: likely to have House candidates emerge from outside
the state legislature. This suggests that professionalism
Pr(Run | Progressive Ambition = 0) = 0. may dampen the ambitions of state legislators, their
willingness to run, or both. However, they also find
Separating the decision process into two stages is that when state legislators do run they are more suc
important from both a theoretical and an empirical cessful than their counterparts from less professional
standpoint. Our theory contends that the factors influ legislatures at raising money and gaining votes. Al
encing the formation of ambition are fundamentally though both articles provide evidence that state legisla
different from those driving the decision to run. There tive professionalism shapes House candidacies, neither
fore, we must explicitly identify how and whether rele provides a clear view of the mechanisms through which
vant costs, benefits, and prospects influence each stage this occurs.
in the decision process before we can formulate hy We build on these and other studies and link leg
potheses about the direct and indirect effects of lower islative professionalism to four elements in the model
office professionalism. Empirically, if different ambi outlined previously: the personal motivations of mem
tions lead to different decision processes in the second bers (M), the marginal benefit of moving from the
stage, pooling ambitious and nonambitions potential statehouse to higher office (Bmarg), chances of winning
candidates into a single statistical model of entering a
higher office (pgen), and the marginal costs of running
House race will result in biased and misleading find (Cmarg). In addition, we expect service in a professional
ings for both groups. For example, if we are correct legislature to alter legislators' responsiveness to the
that short-term forces such as partisan political tides or strategic conditions surrounding specific races.
incumbent behavior affect only those with ambition,
the results from pooling both groups would systemati
cally underestimate the effects of short-term forces for Legislative Professionalism and
the ambitious while overestimating the effects for the Progressive Ambition
nonambitious.
We expect legislative professionalism to have offsetting
effects on the ambition stage of the decision process,
THE ROLE OF STATE LEGISLATIVE which makes it impossible to predict a net effect from
PROFESSIONALISM the theoretical model alone. But tracing the expected
paths of influence allows us to set up testable hypothe
Although scholars of congressional elections often dis ses to resolve the question empirically.
tinguish between the qualities and the behavior of of The positive effect of professionalism stems from
fice holders and non-office-holders, they do not typ the ability of professional institutions to attract skilled
ically make distinctions among individuals who hold campaigners and career-oriented politicians. Individu
the same type of elective office (Bianco 1984; Bond, als who are younger and interested in pursuing politics
Covington, and Fleisher 1985, Jacobson and Kernell as a career find the full-time work of a professional
1981). Instead, they assume that legislators who hold a legislature appealing (Francis and Kenny 2000; Squire
seat in New Hampshire's citizen legislature are equally 1988b). Because they come to office with greater am
equipped to mount a House campaign as members bition, they are also more likely to look to higher office
of California's highly professional legislature. More as an avenue to express that ambition.
over, they assume that state legislators in professional Perhaps more importantly, professional legislatures
and nonprofessional institutions respond identically to allow career-oriented politicians to build a portfolio
changes in the competitive environment. of skills and resources that enhance their prospects
In contrast to the assumption that all state legis for winning a US. House seat. Black (1972) argues
lators (and legislatures) are alike, there is reason to that ambition reflects investments in a political career,
believe that the electoral experiences and institutional noting that office-holders are most likely to form ambi
resources associated with serving in professional leg tion for offices that capitalize on their past investments.
islatures result in members developing substantially But the value of the investment for a House candidacy

198

This content downloaded from 210.212.93.46 on Mon, 19 Nov 2018 12:30:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
American Political Science Review Vol. 100, No. 2

depends on the characteristics and resources of the enees between office holders and nonoffice holders, a
state legislature. It is generally more difficult to win of similar logic may apply to state legislators. When the
fice in a professional legislature, which results in greater chances of winning the race are low, legislators who
investment in the development of fund-raising and have the most to lose?those in the most professional
campaign skills. State legislative candidates in profes institutions?should be the most reluctant to jump into
sional institutions typically raise hundreds of thousands the race (Berkman and Eisenstein 1999).
of dollars, hire professional consultants, and campaign If professional legislators are less likely to run when
through both mass and targeted media (Berkman and their prospects are poor, are they also less likely to
Eisenstein 1999; Hogan 2001; Moncrief and Thompson run when their prospects are good? An explanation
1997). In contrast, candidates for seats in nonprofes that centers on opportunity cost alone might suggest
sional institutions raise much less money and often so, but we argue that legislators' prior investments in
rely on friends and family as campaign staff. Once in campaign skills combined with office resources affect
office, the disparity continues as those who serve in the ease with which they can respond to an opportunity.
the most professional institutions have staff and other Thus, it is not simply that professional legislators have
resources at their disposal to help them stay in office, developed skills and resources that increase their
contact constituents, provide constituency services, and chances of winning; they are also more nimble in
build visible records, all of which might help to build deploying those skills and resources when an oppor
a base to run for higher office (Berry, Berkman, and tunity arises. Professional legislators have developed
Schneiderman 2000; Cox and Morgenstern 1993). networks of campaign donors and relationships with
In our model, then, legislative professionalism in professional campaign personnel, they are familiar
fluences ambitions indirectly by encouraging legisla with local media practices, and they have utilized their
tors to invest in the skills that increase their general office staff in building a constituent base for their
prospects of winning a House seat (pgen)- Moreover, it current office. These investments in their political
is likely that members of professional legislatures see careers?particularly in campaign skills?can help
the marginal costs of competing in a House race as less them quickly build the visibility and financial backing
than those in nonprofessional legislatures because the necessary to run a strong race if the opportunity
campaign process to win a professionalized seat more presents itself. As a result, when odds become more
closely resembles running for the US. House (Cmarg). favorable, legislators in professional institutions should
Of course, these positive effects are offset by the op face fewer transaction costs associated with stepping
portunity costs of giving up such a desirable post. from the state legislative ring into a U.S. House
The positive effects of professionalism on ambition campaign. This should produce an interactive effect
may be offset by the opportunity costs of giving up a between the chances of winning (pt) and lower-office
relatively desirable post and by reducing the relative professionalism, where small changes in the strategic
value legislators place on a U.S. House seat. A key context of a race lead to larger changes in chances of
comparison in the formation of ambition is the value running for legislators in professional legislatures.
of the higher office compared to the lower office. It is In a broader sense, evidence of an interaction be
likely that members of professional institutions value tween professionalism and prospects for victory would
their own position quite highly?perhaps even more indicate that professionalism increases the responsive
highly than they value a U.S. House seat. Professional ness of the strongest potential candidates in state
institutions provide a work environment that is more legislatures to the changing political climate. If so,
similar to the US. Congress (Squire 1988b). As a result, professionalism enhances accountability in U.S. House
the marginal benefit of moving from the state legisla campaigns by increasing the odds that a strong chal
ture to the House (Bmarg) even for those who prefer a lenger will emerge from the state legislature when vot
House seat over their state legislative office should be ers become dissatisfied with the status quo.
smaller for members of more professional institutions
and might fail to outweigh the costs associated with EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS
seeking and holding a seat in the House.
We test our hypotheses using data drawn from a sur
Legislative Professionalism and the vey of state legislators whose districts overlap with 200
Decision to Enter a Race randomly selected U.S. House districts in 41 states.5

Apart from influencing ambitions, how might profes 5 During fall 1997 and spring 1998, we mailed a nine-page question
sionalism affect the decision to enter a specific US. naire to 2,714 legislators. A total of 874 responded, for a response
House race? Previous research indicates that experi rate of 32.2%. Logit analysis indicates the following response biases
(p < .05): legislators in professional legislatures, Democrats, upper
enced politicians are more sensitive to the strategic chamber members, and those surveyed during the winter are under
environment than amateur politicians because they are represented; those with longer service, term limits, and in marginal
reluctant to risk their reputation or seat on an un U.S. House districts are overrepresented. We weight all descriptive
certain race (Banks and Kiewiet 1989; Canon 1990; statistics by the inverse of the probability of response. Our multivari
ate models include statistical controls for the factors associated with
Krasno and Green 1988). This is partly a matter of response bias. The data are drawn from the 1998 wave of the Candi
opportunity costs: experienced candidates do not want date Emergence Study, NSF SBR-9515450. Details of the full study
to make the sacrifice unless their chances of winning can be found at http://ces.iga.ucdavis.edu/ or in Stone and Maisel
are strong. Although most studies focus on the differ 2003.

199

This content downloaded from 210.212.93.46 on Mon, 19 Nov 2018 12:30:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
When to Risk It? May 2006

Previous studies of the progressive behavior of state we estimate a separate selection model for each group,
legislators have relied on secondary or aggregate data where the decision to run follows the legislator's self
as evidence of individual-level decision processes (e.g., selection into either the ambitious or nonambitious
Berkman and Eisenstein 1999; Francis and Kenny category.
2000).6 Although these studies advance our under Second, the models correct for biases in the decision
standing, they cannot directly test the relative effects of to-run stage that arise from self-selection into one of
legislative professionalism and personal characteristics the categories of ambition. The empirical model cap
on individual legislators' ambitions and their decisions tures many of the cost-benefit components associated
to run, nor have they resolved the puzzle of how pro with ambitions for a House seat. However, there may
fessionalism affects the pool of potential candidates for be other factors we have failed to include that influ
the U.S. House. ence both stages of the process, some of which may
The survey was administered in the months just prior be psychological components of progressive ambition
to the filing deadline in each state and asked state leg that are unmeasured (and perhaps unmeasurable). If
islators about their general interest in seeking a House so, the errors between the two stages will be correlated
seat, the likelihood they would run in 1998 or at some and coefficients in the second stage may be biased. The
point in the future, and the likelihood that they would selection model corrects these biases and estimates the
win if they were to run. In addition, we sought their correlation of the errors between stages, p.
views on characteristics of their House district, their Legislators are categorized as progressively ambi
evaluations of the incumbent, their perceptions of their tious based on their response to a survey question
own strengths and weaknesses as potential candidates, asking them their level of attraction to a U.S. House
and their motivations for seeking office. We employ career. Those who describe their attraction as "ex
Squire's (2000) index of legislative professionalism to tremely low," "low," or "somewhat low" form the group
identify legislators in the top and bottom quartiles. The of nonambitious legislators. Those who indicated their
index measures the similarity between each state legis attraction was "neutral," "somewhat high," "high," and
lature and the U.S. House on three dimensions?salary, "extremely high," form the group of ambitious legisla
staff, and days in session. Those in the top quartile are tors.9 Nearly 60% of the sample falls in the ambitious
full-time, well-paid legislatures with professional staff; category. State legislators in the ambitious category are
those in the least professional legislatures are part included in a second stage model where we expect the
time, have low pay, and little or no support staff.7 We proximate strategic conditions and costs to influence
use this information to test whether state legislators in their chances of running. We apply an identical second
professional institutions view the benefits and costs of stage model to those classified as lacking ambition, but
running differently than legislators in nonprofessional expect null findings because the costs and prospects
institutions and to study direct and indirect effects of surrounding the race in 1998 should not influence their
professionalism on ambitions and chances of running. chances of running.
The dependent variable for the second stage is legis
lators' reported chances of running for the US. House
Modeling Progressive Ambition in 1998. Because this is a prospective measure based
and the Chances of Running on a survey prior to the filing date in each state, it
We use two ordered probit selection models to capture does not indicate whether the candidate actually ran in
the two-stage process outlined in our theory: the first 1998.10 Instead, it provides a snapshot of the decision
stage models ambition for a House seat; the second process during the period when potential candidates
stage models the decision to run in 1998, given legisla evaluate whether to file a candidacy. The seven-point
tors' ambitions.8 The benefits of using selection models survey scale ranges from extremely unlikely to ex
are twofold. First, they eliminate biases from pooling tremely likely with "toss up" in the middle. Because so
ambitious and nonambitious legislators in the decision few respondents fall in the top three categories (3%),
to-run stage. Because we hypothesize that ambitious we combine these so that the dependent variable has
and nonambitious state legislators use a different de five categories ranging from extremely unlikely to run
cision process in considering a run in 1998 (that is, to at least somewhat likely to run.
nonambitious legislators do not consider a run at all),
EXPLAINING PROGRESSIVE AMBITION
6 The few studies at the individual level have relied heavily on Our model allows us to identify the size and significance
interview data and a small number of cases, making it difficult to of personal, institutional, and electoral influences on
generalize their findings (Kazee 1994; Fowler and McClure 1989). ambition for a House seat. We include measures of the
7 Legislatures in the second and third quartile vary in these attributes
and do not lend themselves to clear classification as "professional" or long-term opportunity to win a House seat, the relative
"nonprofessional." Accordingly, we focus on examining differences
between those at the ends of the scale.
8 An alternative approach is to run a single model for the whole 9 We also experimented with the "neutral" category in the non
sample that interacts ambition with all independent variables in the ambitious group rather than the ambitious category. The substantive
decision to run model. However, if unmeasured factors influence results are nearly identical in both models. In the end, we decided
both ambition and the decision to run, ambition will be correlated that it made more sense to include those who expressed anything
with the error term leading to biases in estimating the coefficients less than low attraction in the unambitious group.
for interaction terms. 10 Only six respondents actually ran in 1998.

200

This content downloaded from 210.212.93.46 on Mon, 19 Nov 2018 12:30:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
American Political Science Review Vol. 100, No. 2

evaluation of the U.S. House to the current seat, and the potential candidates. We asked legislators to indicate
costs associated with running for and serving in the U.S. whether they had been contacted by their local, state, or
House. We also include controls for party, gender, age, national party about running for the U.S. House and use
risk orientation, and personal motivations for entering the sum to capture the degree of party encouragement.
politics.11 How one views the House as an institution is also
The opportunity to win a House seat is central in the essential to the formation of ambition for a House
formation of ambition. Although opportunity structure seat. Yet, it is not simply a question of whether the
is often measured through such objective criteria as the House is valued as an institution, but whether the
number of higher office seats available per member or legislator assigns a greater value to the House than
the competitiveness of district vote, the survey data al to his or her current office. We asked legislators to
low us a unique view of potential candidates' subjective assess the prestige and effectiveness of a career in the
views of the opportunity in their district. Arguably, it U.S. House, as well as the legislature in which they
is those perceptions rather than the objective indica currently serve, using a seven-point scale ranging from
tors that are essential to the formation of progressive extremely low (?3) to extremely high (+3). We com
ambition. bine these two items?prestige and effectiveness?to
To measure the long-term opportunity to win a form an evaluation score for each office, and the dif
House seat, we asked state legislators to estimate their ference between the evaluation scores provides a mea
chances of winning the nomination if they ran in the sure of the personal assessment of the relative value of
foreseeable future and their chances of winning the the House compared to the current office. The overall
general election if they won the nomination. Each of average relative evaluation is slightly negative, with
the two responses is scaled as a "pseudo-probability" 59% of state legislators rating their own office higher
ranging from .01 (extremely unlikely) to .99 (extremely than a U.S. House seat. At first glance, the number
likely), with .5 indicating a toss up. Because winning of state legislators who evaluate their own office as
office requires candidates to win both the nomination higher seems surprising, given that the House offers
and the general election, we multiply the nomination greater salary, resources, and policy jurisdiction than do
chances and the general election chances to capture state legislatures. However, respondents' evaluations
each potential candidate's view of his or her chance are shaped by a number of personal factors apart from
of winning the seat in a future race. These long-term the institutional characteristics of the two offices, such
prospects for winning reflect relatively fixed district as majority status, partisan assessments, and length of
demographics as well as legislators' views of their own service. For our purposes, the most important relation
skills and resources as campaigners.12 On average, po ship is the link between lower office characteristics
tential candidates rate their general prospects as less and evaluations. Sixty-one percent of those in the most
than a toss up (.37), although legislators in the most professional institutions view their institution more fa
professional institutions estimate their future prospects vorably, as compared to only 52% of those in the least
as higher (.42) than do those in nonprofessional legis professional legislatures (p < .05).
latures (.32, p < .01). Even individuals who view the House as a prestigious
We also control for the opportunity structure by in and effective venue for public service may be unwilling
cluding a measure of each potential candidates' per to bear the opportunity costs associated with running
ception of the district partisan balance and a measure for and holding a House seat. Because many members
of party recruitment efforts. We expect potential can serve in institutions where seniority is rewarded, and
didates who view the district structure as favorable to because professional state legislatures offer greater
be more ambitious for a House seat. We also expect perquisites and opportunities to pursue policy goals, we
party recruitment to shape potential candidates' views expect those in more professional institutions and those
of the opportunity structure. Party contact signals a who have served for long periods in office to evaluate
commitment to winning a district and may cue poten those costs more highly. Term-limited legislators, to the
tial candidates that party leaders view them as strong contrary, may view the opportunity costs of losing the
seat as lower because they will be forced out of office
in the near future (Lazarus 2004).13
11 We assessed respondents' risk orientation with a survey question Beyond the opportunity costs of giving up a current
asking about their level of comfort in making risky financial and
career decisions. Those who responded that they were "very com
seat, running for and holding a U.S. House seat re
fortable" or "somewhat comfortable" were coded as risk acceptant. quires a substantial commitment in time, money, and
To measure personal motivation, we asked respondents to assess the personal stress. We constructed a "family cost" index
importance of various reasons for their involvement in politics. We from responses to items assessing how much the "loss
include a "personal motivations" measure that indicates the average of personal and family privacy," "loss of leisure time,"
importance of the importance of "making social contacts," "making
business contacts," and the "excitement of politics" for individuals' and "separation from family and friends" discourage a
involvement in politics.
12 Analysis (not shown) reveals that this measure is related to such
structural factors as the number of state legislators whose districts 13 Previous research on term limits suggests that legislators may exit
overlap with the U.S. House district in their area, perceptions of early to run for higher office as term limits approach (Carey, Neimi,
district party composition, and the professionalism of the state leg and Powell 2000; Lazarus 2004). Our measure reflects this dynamic
islature. It is not related to race-specific factors such as whether the by scoring as term limited those facing limits in 1998 or 2000. Because
seat was open in 1998 or whether the legislator was in the same party so few respondents faced term limits in each year, it is impractical to
of the sitting incumbent. See note 20 for further discussion. separate out the two years.

201

This content downloaded from 210.212.93.46 on Mon, 19 Nov 2018 12:30:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
When to Risk It? May 2006

twenty-fifth percentile value to its seventy-fi


TABLE 1. Selection Model, Attraction to a
centile value while fixing all other variables a
Career in the U.S. House_ sample mean or mode.16
Constant 1.833 *** 0.352
_B_SE_
The largest effect stems from age, as olde
Relative Value of House Seat 0.127 *** 0.042 legislators are much less likely to be ambitiou
Future Chances of Winning 1.048 *** 0.239 U.S. House seat than their younger counterpar
District Partisanship favors 0.059 0.038 predicted probability of being ambitious for t
State Legislator the 60 to 64 age range is .25 less than those in
Democrat 0.051 0.124 range of 40 to 49 age range. This result is con
Terms in Office 0.006 0.041 with the hypothesis that those nearing retirem
Contacted by Party about Running are0.185 ** 0.088in starting a new and chall
less interested
Family Cost Index -0.230 *** 0.084 career in another political office. Legislators wh
Campaign Cost Index -0.196 *** 0.083 to office late in life after private sector career
Serves in Professional Legislature -0.177 0.155 see the state legislature as the pinnacle of their po
Female -0.234 ** 0.142
aspirations.
Term Limited Out by 2000 0.171 0.228
The second largest effect stems from differences in
Personal Motivations 0.121 ** 0.053
how legislators perceive their future chances of winning
Age -0.325 *** 0.059
Risk Acceptant -0.123 0.150 a U.S. House seat. The probability of ambition for those
Total N 597 who view their future chances as quite low is only .46,
Log Likelihood -589.002 whereas the probability of being ambitious for those
Chi Square_3995.306 ***_ who view their chances of winning as relatively high
(just over 50/50) is nearly .65. Schlesinger (1966) argued
* p|z| < .10. ** p|z| < .05. *** p|z| < .01.
a The results for this model are derived from the simultaneous
that opportunity structure is central to the formation
estimation of a selection model where ambition is the selection
of ambition because people are rarely ambitious for
stage and the decision to run is the outcome stage. the unattainable.
Results for Our results are consistent with this
the decision to run portion of the model are presented in Table 3.
expectation. is
The dependent variable for the selection model, ambition, However, optimistic future prospects are
scored 1 if the legislator is attracted to a career neither
in the necessary
U.S. nor sufficient for the formation of
House and 0 if not. Additional controls for mailingprogressive
period and ambition. Setting the prospects variable to
chamber membership were insignificant and are not shown.
zero, its theoretical minimum, does not result in a near
zero predicted probability of being ambitious. Like
wise, setting it to one, its theoretical maximum, does
not yield a predicted
state legislator from running for the U.S. House.14 We probability that approaches one.
Thus, ambitions
also create a campaign-cost index that includes "themay flourish when the prospects of
need to raise large amounts of money" and obtaining
"enduringhigher office appear hopeless, and ambition
is not certain
negative advertising attacks." We expect both to reduce even if the prospects of winning appear
to be guaranteed.
general ambition for a seat in the House. Notably, state
The sizable effects of other variables in the model
legislators in professional institutions view campaign
highlight the importance of looking beyond the oppor
costs as less daunting than those in nonprofessional
legislature (p < .05). tunity structure for explanations of ambition. Evalua
tion
Table 1 presents the results for the selection of thepor
relative effectiveness and prestige of politi
tion of the model. Although we estimate the cal institutions
selectionalters ambitions for higher office. Leg
and outcome models simultaneously, we islatorsdiscuss who the
evaluate their own office more highly than
the
results for each stage separately15 As much as our U.S. House are less likely to harbor attraction to a
findings show that opportunity to win higher careeroffice
in the U.S.
is House.17 At a more personal level,
important to the formation of ambition, the legislators'
opportu expectations about the costs of running
shape theirex
nity structure alone does not provide a complete interest in higher office but play a lesser
planation of progressive ambition. Table 1 role
showsthan age
thatand prospects. Female state legislators
often
the relative evaluation of a House seat, family costsface higher family and personal costs associated
with movingage,
and campaign costs, along with party recruitment, up and are less likely to be ambitious for
personal motivations, and gender, influence a US. House seat. This is reflected in the predicted
ambition
probability
for a U.S. House seat, independent of prospects. To of as
ambition for women, which is .09 lower
than that
sess which factors have the greatest influence, for men.
Table 2a Finally, personal motivations such as
the desire toby
calculates the probability of progressive ambition make social or business contacts modestly
bolster ambitions.
varying each statistically significant variable from its

16 Because 82% of legislators were not contacted by their political


14 Using a 4-point scale ranging from "makes no difference"
party, the 25th andto
75th percentiles are identical. Thus, we vary this
variable
"strongly discourage," we asked respondents to indicate by one category.
whether
each factor discouraged them from running for a U.S. House seat. that those who see their chances of obtaining a House
17 It is possible
seat as small rationalize
15 For the selection model, we present the only the estimates from that their own office is better than a House
the model of those who are ambitious. The selection model contrary
seat. However, for to this hypothesis, the correlation between
ambition = 1 and the selection model for ambitionfuture = 0 chances
are both of winning and relative evaluation of the U.S. House
is small and negative (?.08).
estimated on the full sample and are substantively identical.

202

This content downloaded from 210.212.93.46 on Mon, 19 Nov 2018 12:30:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
American Political Science Review Vol. 100, No. 2

TABLE 2a. Predicted Probabilities of Ambition


Predicted Predicted
Independent Variables (range) 25th Percentile Probability 75th Percentile Probability Difference
Relative Value of House Seat (-3, +3) -1.500 0.534 0.500 0.633 0.099
Future Chances of Winning (.01, .99) 0.111 0.466 0.556 0.649 0.183
Contacted by Party About Running (0,4) 0.000 0.572 1.000 0.643 0.071
Family Cost Index (0,4) 0.667 0.618 1.667 0.528 -0.090
Campaign Cost Index (0,4) 1.000 0.611 2.000 0.534 -0.077
Personal Motivations (-3,+3) -1.330 0.538 0.000 0.602 0.064
Age (0,6) 3.000 0.694 5.000 0.443 -0.251
Female (0, 1)_0.000_0.572_1.000_0.479 -0.093
Note: Predicted probabilities are based on the coefficients from the model in Table
We vary 1.
each statistically significant variable from
the 25th quartile value to the 75th quartile value.

TABLE 2b. The Effect of Serving in a Professional Legislature on the Predicted Probabil
of Ambition
Professional Legislature3 Non-Professional Legislature0
Difference
Predicted Predicted Between
Mean or Mode Probability Mean or Mode Probability Legislatures
Relative Value of House Seat -0.824 0.592 -0.610 0.602 -0.011
Future Chances of Winning 0.415 0.616 0.318 0.576 0.040
Campaign Cost Index 1.463 0.599 1.580 0.590 0.009
Personal Motivations -0.708 0.592 -0.587 0.598 -0.006
Age 3.000 0.715 4.000 0.596 0.119
Cumulative Effects 0.735 0.565 0.170
Note: Probabilities are based on the coefficients in Table 1, varying each variable from the mean or mode in professional legislatures
to the mean or mode in nonprofessional legislatures while holding constant all other variables at the mean or mode for the full sample.
Cumulative probabilities are derived from simultaneously setting the variables at the mean or mode for each type of legislature.
a Legislatures scoring in the top quartile of Squire's index of legislative professionalism.
b Legislatures scoring in the bottom quartile of Squire's index of legislative professionalism.

Legislative Professionalism and Ambitions Lower-office professionalism has both positive and
negative effects on variables that help account for am
A central question is whether state legislative profes bition. Differences in age between members of profes
sionalism enhances the pool of potential candidates bysional and nonprofessional state legislatures generate
increasing legislators' ambitions for a US. House seat.the greatest gap in the predicted probability of being
Table 1 provides no evidence of a direct effect of legisla ambitious. Professional legislatures with full-time pay
tive professionalism on ambition; the coefficient is cortend to attract younger members, and younger mem
rectly signed, but insignificant. However, this is not to bers are more ambitious for the House. In addition
say that state legislative professionalism has no impact. to age, legislators who serve in the most professional
Because professionalism is associated with legislators' institutions view their chances of winning nearly a full
assessments of future chances, relative evaluations of
.10 higher than those in nonprofessional legislatures,
the prestige and effectiveness of the U.S. House, age, leading to a .04 increase in the predicted probability of
and assessments of the costs of campaigning for the being ambitious. Serving in a more professional insti
House, we also consider whether professionalism has tution makes a higher office seem more attainable, and
indirect effects. In other words, if institutional profes the enhanced prospects of securing a seat at some point
sionalism has implications for the characteristics andin the future makes a U.S. House seat a more attractive
perceptions of its members, these differences may in and viable career goal.
directly lead to a gap in House attraction between pro The independent effects of the remaining factors,
fessional and nonprofessional state legislators. Table 2bsuch as costs and personal motivations, are quite small.
evaluates such indirect effects by calculating the preLegislators in professional institutions are, on average,
dicted probability of being ambitious based on mean slightly less discouraged than those in nonprofessional
or mode of each variable for legislators in professional legislatures by the costs associated with campaigning
institution, compared to legislators in nonprofessional for the House, but this difference provides only a .009
institutions, holding all other variables at their sampleboost to the probability of ambition. Legislators in pro
mean or mode.18
fessional institutions are less likely to indicate that they

18 We compare only those variables that were significant in the modelof legislative professionalism in the ambition model is not statistically
and for which a difference of means test between professional andsignificant at conventional levels, and we treat the direct effect as 0
nonprofessional legislatures is significant at p < .10. The direct effectwhen predicting probabilities.

203

This content downloaded from 210.212.93.46 on Mon, 19 Nov 2018 12:30:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
When to Risk It?_May 2006
entered politics for such personal skills and experience. In contrast,
motivations as the long-term chances
excitement of politics, or for business are based moreand on district
social conditions
conand legislators'
nections, but this difference likewise skills andhas
resources
onlyas candidates.20
a slight Candidates who
effect on progressive ambition. believe they have a strong chance of winning the 1998
Because professionalism both stimulates race should be more and likely to run because they have
deters
progressive ambition, the only way greater tolikelihood
assess of the
realizing a return on their ef
cumu
lative effect of lower-office characteristics forts. We expecton ambitions
to see a positive effect of the 1998
is by comparing the overall predicted prospects,probabilities
but a negative effect for forfuture prospects.
members in each type of legislature. Those who see their
The longer term row
bottom chances as high should
of Table 2b shows the cumulative beeffect more likely of to wait
settingthan to run
allin the current
variables in Table 2 at their mean race. or mode for each
type of institution. The predicted probability The other component of being of the entry decision is t
ambitious for members of professional expected institutions
costs of running. isState legislators who h
.735?fully .17 higher than those leadership positions, those who would move from
in nonprofessional
institutions. Although state legislative jority status at the state level to minority status
professionalism
has both positive and negative effects the U.S. on House, and thosethe
ambition, with more seniority in t
benefits that accrue from attracting current positionsmembers
younger are likely to view the immediate
and giving them experience running portunity
tough costs of running as high. Of course, th
campaigns
outweigh the opportunity costs associated facing term limits with leav
face lower opportunity costs of
ing the state institution. As a result, ning since they must give up their seats in short
professionalism
provides a net gain to the poolder. ofWe potential
also include the House "family cost" and "campa
candidates from a state's legislature. cost" measures from the ambition stage, but we
skeptical of their importance in the second stage
EXPLAINING CHANCES OF though RUNNING such measures are typically cited as reaso
IN 1998 for staying out of a race, we argue that this occu
at the level of ambition formation rather than t
Progressively ambitious legislators move to the sec decision to run. Nevertheless, we include these
ond stage of the decision process?the decision about means of testing our expectation that ambitious s
whether to enter the 1998 House race. In this stage, legislators have accepted and discounted these cost
potential candidates weigh their prospects in the cur running.
rent race against their long-term prospects for winning Table 3 supports our view that progressive ambi
a House seat and against the immediate costs of giv tion is a necessary precondition for office holders to
ing up their position. We test whether legislators in assess the strategic conditions surrounding a specific
professional institutions are more responsive to their race. Only legislators with ambitions for a House seat
prospects than those in unprofessional institutions by are influenced by their chances of winning in 1998.
including an interaction between legislative profession Incumbent missteps or unfavorable national political
alism and prospects of winning in the current race. The and economic tides that tend to boost the prospects
model also includes controls for age, gender, risk orien of potential candidates do not lure the unambitious
tation, personal motivations for entering politics, and into the ring. When lower-office conditions and other
legislators' assessments of the quality of the incumbent, factors shape ambitions, then, they also affect the po
all of which may shape the decision to run apart from tential candidate pool that might respond to changes in
strategic considerations. the quality of representation provided by incumbents
We assess the "now versus later" aspect of the deci and their parties.
sion process by including measures that tap how leg The results make clear that the principal decision
islators perceived their chances of winning in 1998 as for ambitious legislators is whether to run in a partic
well as their assessment of their general chances of win ular race or wait. Costs that played a key role in the
formation of ambition have no effect on the decision
ning.19 Interestingly, ambitious legislators' assessments
of future and current chances are correlated at only
.33, indicating that they measure different aspects of
strategic conditions. The 1998 prospects tap the strate 20 Although modeling the 1998 chances of winning and the long
gic conditions surrounding the 1998 race at the time of term chances of winning is beyond the scope of this paper, it is worth
the survey. These estimates are related to the poten noting that factors that stay relatively constant, such as campaign
tial candidates' assessments of the incumbent's skills skills of legislators, the number of legislators per house seat, leg
islative professionalism, and district partisanship significantly affect
and resources, the political climate in the nation and long-term chances of winning, but the presence of an open-seat
the district, as well as the legislator's own campaign race in 1998 and the party of the incumbent do not. In contrast,
incumbency factors dominate chances of winning in 1998. Open seat
and incumbent party are strongly related to prospects in 1998, but
19 Like long-term prospects, we measure chances of winning in 1998 district partisan structure and legislative professionalism have no
with questions asking potential candidates to estimate their chances independent effect. Legislators' evaluations of incumbent prospects
of winning the nomination in 1998 if they were to run and general influence both future and immediate chances of winning, and the
election chances if they were to win the nomination. Prospects for beta coefficient for immediate chances (?.20) is nearly triple the
winning the seat, then, are computed as the nomination prospects X effect on future chances (?.07). Results of this analysis are available
general election prospects. on request.

204

This content downloaded from 210.212.93.46 on Mon, 19 Nov 2018 12:30:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
American Political Science Review Vol. 100, No. 2

TABLE 3. Outcome Stage: Chances of Running for the U.S. House in 1998, Conditioned on
Ambition_
Attraction to U.S. House Career = 1 Attraction to U.S. House Career = 0
SE B B SE
Constant -1.167 0.459 -1.378 2.819
Chances of Winning, 1998 1.330 0.457 0.648 1.286
0.806
Chances of Winning, 1998 X Professional 1.783 0.708 1.428
Legislature
Serves in Professional Legislature -0.442
0.312 -0.066 0.713
Future Chances of Winning -0.660 0.358 -0.890 1.285
Campaign Cost Index -0.049 0.117 -0.063 0.348
Family Cost Index 0.074 0.116 -0.160 0.342
0.244
Democrat State Legislator in Majority Party -0.253 0.521 1.373
Leadership Position in State Legislature 0.090 0.151 -0.349 0.525
Contacted by a Party about Running 0.023 0.106 -0.080 0.664
Term Limited Out by 2000 -0.034 0.311 -0.466 1.452
Terms in Office 0.015 0.053 0.096 0.178
Age 0.250 0.079 0.061 0.338
Quality of Incumbent 0.061 0.085 -0.107 0.245
Female -0.154 0.215 0.092 0.806
Personal Motivations 0.053 0.072 0.094 0.166
Risk Acceptant 0.304 0.181 -0.029 0.523
Mu(1) 0.779 0.141 0.654 ** 0.294
Mu(2) 1.150 0.233 0.803 ** 0.364
Mu(3) 1.220 0.253 0.893 ** 0.377
Selection parameter, 0.205 p 0.393
-0.719 1.528
Total N 597 597
Uncensored 334 263
Log Likelihood -589.002 -407.659
Chi Square_3995.306 p < .001 4861.306 p .001
* p< |z| = .05. ** p|z| < .05. *** p|z| < .01.
aThe results for each model are derived from the simultaneous estimation of a selection model where ambition is the selection stage
and the decision to run is the outcome stage. Results for the ambition model are presented in Table 1. The dependent variable for the
outcome model ranges from 0, extremely unlikely to run, to 4, at least somewhat likely to run. Additional controls for mailing period and
chamber membership, were insignificant and are not shown.

of when to run. Instead, ambitious legislators weigh there is no indirect effect of professionalism on the de
their immediate prospects against their odds in future cision to run through other variables in the model. Leg
campaigns as they consider whether to run. Those who islators who cross the ambition threshold are remark
perceived their chances of winning in 1998 as high were ably similar in their characteristics regardless of the
much more likely to enter the race than those who
type of institution in which they currently serve. Differ
perceived their chances as low. At the same time, those ences that were apparent when pooling all legislators,
who perceived their chances of winning a future race such as age, long-term prospects, and so on, evapo
as high were more likely to wait. Indeed, the higherrate when looking only at the ambitious. Legislators
a legislator perceives the future odds, the greater thein highly professional institutions rate their long-term
current odds must be to compensate and induce a run. chances, on average, at .44, whereas those in nonpro
Finally, we note the significant coefficient for the risk fessional legislatures rate their chances at .41. Chance
orientation variable. Rohde (1979) argued that legislaof winning in 1998 also has only a slight gap; nonpro
tors who are risk acceptant would need a lower probafessional legislators rate their chances at .12, whereas
bility of success to enter a race and our findings provide those in professional institutions rate their chances at
additional support for this. Legislators who feel "very".17, but the difference is not large enough to be statis
or "somewhat comfortable" taking risks in their careers tically significant.
are more likely to run than risk-averse legislators with In contrast to a direct, additive effect of profession
the same probability of victory. alism on the chances of running, the principal effect
Thus far, we have found that professionalism affects of lower office professionalism is interactive. Not only
ambition, and through ambition, who is willing to weighdoes professionalism increase the probability that an
the strategic conditions that surround a specific race.individual state legislator will enter the pool of po
But how does professionalism affect the chances of tential candidates, but also it increases his or her re
running? Lower office professionalism interacts withsponsiveness to the strategic environment surrounding
the strategic environment, but we find no evidenceeach race. Figure 1 graphs the relationship between
that professionalism affects the chances of running,the chances of winning in 1998 and the chances of
independent of the strategic environment. In addition, running. At very low chances of winning, legislators in

205

This content downloaded from 210.212.93.46 on Mon, 19 Nov 2018 12:30:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
When to Risk It? May 2006

FIGURE 1. Effect of Chances of Winning in 1998 on Chances of Running


0.9

0.8

0.7 4

0.6

Member of
I 0.5
o
Professional
>?
Legislature
5(0 0.4
n
o
o.

0.3

0.2
Member of
Non-Professional
0.1
Legislature

0.0
0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 1.0
probability of winning

DISCUSSION
professional institutions are unlikely to run
as their chances improve, the odds of enter
Our analysisto
increase at a faster pace, reexamines
the the sources
point of progressive
thatam the
likely to enter a House race
bition and highlights than
how ambition, are
in conjunction with nonp
state legislators facinglower office
the conditions,
same creates incentives
odds.for respon
As we argued earlier, siveness wein a multilevel electoral system. As
believe Joseph
this effe
Schlesinger (1966) asserted in his
from the fact that legislators in classicthe
study, withmost
out the ambition of
institutions have invested inelites for elective office, citizensresour
political
more easily transferredhave no hold on totheir representatives'
a U.S. behavior.
House Sim cam
islators in professionalilarly, without ambition for office and the risk-taking
institutions have al
oped campaign contacts,behavior required to mount a campaign, there would netw
fund-raising
be no electoral competition,
contacts, and a constituent baseno matter how as muchavot mean
ers might long for
and retaining their office. It a choice,
is and not no matter how much the e
only
of a professional legislator,
political scientists might extol but
competition asalso
essential thei
transfer relevant skills
to democraticand resources that
accountability.
costs of running a House Rohde (1979) assumed
race progressive
less ambitiondauntin
by as
than for legislators serting
inthat all politicians would seek higher office if
nonprofessional set
result, they can more doing so waseasily
without cost or risk. respond
In one sense, our to
model supports
nity than legislators in this assumption. After all, if we set ourinstit
nonprofessional
lack those resources. future prospects variable at 1 and our cost variables
Overall, the findingsat 0, thefrom
model predicts a .92 probability model
this of ambition po
bitious candidates from professional
for a House seat. But the real story is more complex and
sional institutions whobecause lower office characteristics
weigh help shape assess
carefully th
and future chances ments
when of prospects considering
and costs along with the relative whe
benefits of higher office. Moreover,
run for the House. Although we show that op
legislators in
portunity alone
of institutions rate their is insufficient to stimulate
chances ambition
similarly, th
for higher office. State legislators
to their prospects differently. Those who view the
in fixed the m
sional institutions arecosts of running
cautious for and holding a when
U.S. House seat as their
are poor but bold when high and the relative
their benefits aschances
low are unlikely to of v
good. harbor progressive ambition, even if their long-term

206

This content downloaded from 210.212.93.46 on Mon, 19 Nov 2018 12:30:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
American Political Science Review Vol. 100, No. 2

prospects of winning are strong. Indeed, with costs set Congress. Nationally, larger pools of qualified candi
at the maximum value and relative benefits set at the dates increase the odds that in any given race a strong
minimum value, the predicted probability of ambition candidate will emerge when conditions are favorable.
for a House seat never exceeds .4, regardless of future Institutions and conditions that foster progressive am
prospects. bitions increase the likelihood that opportunity will be
Our model further shows that progressive ambition translated into political outcomes.
mediates responsiveness to short-term shifts in the po The presence of strong and ambitious potential
litical environment?responsiveness that is necessary candidates can alter incumbents' assessments of the
to generate a supply of high-quality, experienced can chances a strong challenger will run against them and
didates for U.S. House races. Indeed, it is this point that hasten strategic retirements among incumbents who
perhaps brings to light the greatest problem with the perform poorly. Political systems in which national
classic expected utility formulation of office seeking offices are less attractive venues than local, state, or
behavior: it fails to distinguish between short-term and provincial offices will lack a broad pool of candidates
long-term costs and prospects. As a result, analysis in willing and able to hold national leaders accountable in
this tradition suggests that fluctuations in short-term this way. A system that encourages ambitions by cre
prospects can outweigh the costs of holding higher of ating favorable opportunity structures and favorable
fice or offset low relative benefits. In contrast, our re conditions for serving in higher office also increases the
search demonstrates that short-term prospects do not number of watchful eyes over the activities of higher
encourage a candidacy among those who lack progres office-holders.
sive ambition. Those who see little net gain in moving Our understanding of progressive ambition also
from the state legislature to the US. House, or who see speaks to choices leaders make on a daily basis. Pre
the costs of running for and holding higher office as vious research on legislators in the United States,
prohibitive are uninterested in moving up and are un Canada, Japan, and Brazil shows that progressively
willing to enter a race even if their prospects of winning ambitious office-holders make decisions in office with
the seat in the immediate race are high. Only a fraction an eye toward their future goals and constituents (e.g.,
of state legislators are ambitious for what scholars often Clarke and Price, 1981; Cox, Rosenbluth, and Theis
assume is a more prestigious and influential US. House 2000; Santos 1999). Closer to home, previous research
seat. shows that ambitious state legislators allocate more
Our model has implications for how we view the time and effort to communicate with constituents than
prospects for representation in the political system as do their colleagues who lack progressive ambition, and
a whole. Systemic responsiveness depends in part on that their policy decisions reflect broad rather than nar
how short-term political changes translate into choices row constituencies (Maestas 2000, 2003). As a result,
at the ballot box. Citizens respond primarily to the professional "springboard" legislatures produce policy
quality of candidates rather than to the specific na more consistent with statewide public opinion than
tional conditions; thus it is potential candidates' entry nonprofessional, "dead-end" legislatures (Maestas
decisions that help channel national political condi 2000). Lower-office conditions that foster progressive
tions into competitive local elections (Jacobson 1989; ambition enhance the ties of representatives to the
Jacobson and Kernell 1983). Our research shows that voters and parties that can help them achieve their
long-term costs and benefits associated with various long-term career goals.
offices, along with relatively fixed features of the elec Finally, our research has implications for how we
toral environment, determine the willingness of po think about state legislative professionalism. Legisla
tential candidates to assess and respond to the call tive professionalism encourages and equips younger,
of opportunities created by factors such as short-term career-oriented individuals to seek office, and stimu
national tides. This willingness, in the form of greater lates their sensitivity to factors affecting the opportu
ambition, may in turn affect the size of the potential nity to advance. States that allow legislator salary to
candidate pool in the state legislature, with professional erode, limit legislators' terms in office, or reduce leg
legislatures generating larger numbers of ambitious islative resources may become less attractive to career
potential candidates, taking opportunities offered by oriented, progressively ambitious members (Rosen
national tides, incumbent missteps, or other factors that thai 1998). Reducing the pool of progressively ambi
affect potential candidates' risk. The number of state tious state legislators potentially reduces the prospects
legislators in the candidate pool, moreover, is poten for representation at both the national and the state
tially important to the quality of representation in the level.
system because state legislatures offer invaluable train The founding fathers set up a system of representa
ing grounds for future candidates and policymakers tion that requires and responds to political career ambi
who eventually make the move to Congress. Members tions. Although the concept of the "citizen-legislator"
of Congress with state legislative experience, particu may be popular among voters, it is not clear that their
larly in professional legislatures, exhibit greater policy interests are best served by creating institutions that
mastery in Congress than do amateurs and are more attract politically unambitious members to short-term
likely to be assigned to policy and prestige committees service. They may be better off fostering and chan
(Berkman 1993). Thus, increasing the pool of candi neling the ambitions of their representatives toward
dates in professional institutions enhances the chance higher office. Our results show that the most desir
of well-prepared successors to current members of able offices stimulate ambitions and create potential

207

This content downloaded from 210.212.93.46 on Mon, 19 Nov 2018 12:30:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
When to Risk It? May 2006

candidates better ableFrancis,


to Waynehold
L., and LawrenceU.S.
W. Kenny. 2000.House
Up the Political mem
accountable. Ladder Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage .
Fulton, Sarah, Ch?rie Maestas, L. Sandy Maisel, and Walter J. Stone.
2006. "The Sense of a Woman: Gender and Congressional Ambi
REFERENCES tion." Political Research Quarterly. Forthcoming.
Herrick, Rebekah, and Michael K. Moore. 1993. "Political Ambi
Banks, Jeffrey S., and D. Roderick Kiewiet.
tion's Effect on Legislative 1989.
Behavior: Schlesinger's Typology Re "Expl
Patterns of Candidate Competition in
considered and Revisited." Congressional
Journal of Politics 55 (August): 765-76. Electi
American Journal of Political Science
Hogan, Robert E. 2001. 33 and
"Campaign War Chests (November)
Challenger
1015. Emergence in State Legislative Elections." Political Research
Berkman, Michael B. 1993. "Former State Legislators in the U.S. Quarterly 54 (December): 815-30.
House of Representatives." American Journal of Political Science Jacobson, Gary C. 1989. "Strategic Politicians and the Dynamics
18 (February): 77-104. of U.S. House Elections, 1946-1986." American Political Science
Berkman, Michael B. 1994. "State Legislators in Congress: Strategic Review 83 (September): 773-93.
Politicians, Professional Legislatures and the Party Nexus." Amer Jacobson, Gary, and Samuel Kernell. 1981. (1983). Strategy and
ican Journal of Political Science 38 (November): 1025-55. Choice in Congressional Elections. 2nd ed. New Haven: Yale Uni
Berkman, Michael B., and James Eisenstein. 1999. "State Legisla versity Press.
tors as Congressional Candidates: The Effects of Prior Experience Jones, Mark PI, Sebastian Saiegh, Pable T. Spiller, and Mariano
on Legislative Recruitment and Fundraising." Political Research Tommasi. 2002. "Amateur Legislators?Professional Politicians:
Quarterly 52 (September): 481-98. The Consequences of Party-Centered Electoral Rules in a Federal
Berry, William D., Michael B. Berkman, and Stuart Schneiderman. System." American Journal of Political Science 46 (July): 656-69.
2000. "Legislative Professionalism and Incumbent Reelection: The Kazee, Thomas A. 1994. Who Runs for Congress? Ambition, Context,
Development of Institutional Boundaries." American Political Sci and Candidate Emergence. Washington: CQ Press.
ence Review 94 (December): 859-74. Krasno, Jonathon S., and Donald Philip Green. 1988. "Preempting
Bianco, William T 1984. "Strategic Considerations on Candidacy Quality Challengers in House Elections." Journal of Politics 50
in U.S. Congressional Districts." Legislative Studies Quarterly 2 (November): 920-36.
(May): 351-64. Lazarus, Jeffrey. 2004. Strategic Entry in U.S. House Elections: As
Black, Gordon S. 1972. "A Theory of Political Ambition: Career sessing the Causes and Effects of Interaction Among Incumbents
Choices and the Role of Structural Incentives." American Political and Challengers. Ph.D. Dissertation, University of California, San
Science Review 66 (March): 144-59. Diego.
Bond, Jon R., Gary Covington, and Richard Fleisher. 1985. "Ex Maestas, Ch?rie D. 2000. "Professional Legislatures and Ambitious
plaining Challenger Quality in Congressional Elections." Journal Politicians: Policy Responsiveness of Individuals and Institutions."
of Politics 47 (June): 510-29. Legislative Studies Quarterly 25 (November): 663-90.
Canon, David T 1990. Actors, Athletes, and Astronauts: Political Maestas, Ch?rie D. 2003. "The Incentive to Listen: Progressive Am
Amateurs in the United States Congress. Chicago: University of bition, Resources, and Opinion Monitoring Among State Legisla
Chicago Press. tors." Journal of Politics 65 (May): 439-56.
Canon, David T, and David J. Sousa. 1992. "Party System Change Moncrief, Gary, and Joel Thompson. 1997. Campaign Finance in State
and Political Career Structures in the U.S. Congress." Legislative Legislative Elections. Washington: CQ Press.
Studies Quarterly 17 (August): 347-63. Powell, Richard. 2000. "The Impact of Term Limits on the Candidacy
Carey, John M., Richard Neimi, and Lynda W. Powell. 2000b. Term Decisions of State Legislators in U.S. House Elections." Legislative
Limits in the State Legislatures. Ann Arbor: The University of Studies Quarterly 25 (November): 645-61.
Michigan Press. Rohde, David. 1979. "Risk Bearing and Progressive Ambition: The
Clarke, Harold D., and Richard G. Price. 1981. "Parliamentary Expe Case of Members of the United State House of Representatives."
rience and Representational Role Orientations in Canada." Leg American Journal of Political Science 23 (February): 1-26.
islative Studies Quarterly 6 (August): 373-90. Rosenthal, Alan. 1998. The Decline of Representative Democracy.
Cox, Gary W., and Scott Morgenstern. 1993. "The Increasing Ad Washington DC: CQ Press.
vantage of Incumbency in the U.S. States." Legislative Studies Santos, Fabiano. 1999. "Recruitment and Retention of Legislators in
Quarterly 18 (November): 495-514. Brazil." Legislative Studies Quarterly 24 (May): 209-37.
Cox, Gary W., Frances M. Rosenbluth, and Michael F. Theis. 2000. Schlesinger, Joseph A. 1966. Ambition and Politics: Political Careers
"Electoral Rules, Career Ambitions, and Party Structure: Com in the United States. Rand McNally.
paring Factions in Japan's Upper and Lower Houses." American Squire, Peverill. 1988a. "Member Career Opportunities and the
Journal of Political Science 44 (January): 115-22. Internal Organization of Legislatures." Journal of Politics 50
Epstein, David, David Brady, Sadafumi Kawato, and Sharyn (August): 126-44.
O'Halloran. 1997. "A Comparative Approach to Legislative Or Squire, Peverill. 1988b. "Career Opportunities and Member Stability
ganization: Careerism and Seniority in the United States and in Legislatures." Legislative Studies Quarterly 13 (February): 65
Japan." American Journal of Political Science 41 (July): 965 82.
98. Squire, Peverill. 2000. "Uncontested Seats in State Legislative Elec
Fiorina, Morris P. 1994. "Divided Government in the American tions." Legislative Studies Quarterly 25 (February): 131-46.
States: A Byproduct of Legislative Professionalism?" American Stone, Walter X, and L. Sandy Maisel. 2003. "The Not-So-Simple Cal
Political Science Review 88 (June): 304-16. culus of Winning: Potential US. House Candidates?Nomination
Fowler, Linda L. 1993. Candidates, Congress, and the American and General Election Chances." Journal of Politics (November):
Democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. 951-77.
Fowler, Linda, and Robert McClure. 1989. Political Ambition: Who Thompson, Joel A., and Gary F. Moncrief. 1998. Campaign Finance
Decides to Run for Congress. New Haven: Yale University Press. in State Legislative Elections Washington, DC: CQ Press.

208

This content downloaded from 210.212.93.46 on Mon, 19 Nov 2018 12:30:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

Você também pode gostar