Você está na página 1de 21

World Development, Vol. 23, No. 12, pp.

2079-2099, 1995
Elsevier Science Ltd
Pergamon
Printed in Great Britain
0305-750x/95 $9.50 + 0.00
0305-750x(95)0010%6

Macroeconomic Policy and the Salvadoran Peace


Accords

ELISABETH WOOD*
Harvard University, Cambridge, Massachusetts
and
New York University, U.S.A.
and
ALEXANDER SEGOVIA
University of London, U.K.

Summary. - We analyze the relationship between macroeconomic policies and the implementation of
the peace agreement that ended civil war in El Salvador. We review recent stabilization and adjustment
policies and identify potential impediments to sustained growth. We observe that the agreement man-
dated thorough-going democratization of political institutions, but its socioeconomic reforms promised
little more than excombatants’ reintegration into civilian life; the poverty and inequality impelling the
war were not addressed. We analyze the political bargaining governing the agreement’s uneven imple-
mentation, and conclude that the macroeconomic policy environment of austerity, rather than resource
constraints per se, impeded its timely implementation.

1. INTRODUCTION The separation between economic policy and the


peace process in El Salvador thus results from domes-
In an influential contribution to the debate about tic political dynamics as well as inadequate coordina-
postwar reconstruction and macroeconomic policy in tion among international agencies. From the begin-
El Salvador, de Soto and de1 Castillo decried the lack ning of the peace negotiations, the Salvadoran
of coordination between the United Nations on the government successfully insisted that the macroeco-
one hand, and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) nomic stabilization and adjustment policies begun in
and the World Bank on the other. They likened El 1989 were not on the table for discussion. At the same
Salvador to a patient lying “on the operating table with time, the leadership of the Farabundo MartI National
the left and right sides of his body separated by a cur- Liberation Front (FMLN) emphasized pressing mili-
tain and unrelated surgery being performed on each tary and political rather than socioeconomic issues in
side” (1994a, p. 74). their negotiating agenda. As a result, economic issues
The metaphor is a dramatic depiction of the diff- were not discussed until the 11th hour of the peace
cult challenge of achieving both the consolidation of negotiations, and even then the discussion centered on
peace and economic growth following civil war. If the narrow questions of devising channels for postwar
efforts at policy reform - economic and political reconstruction assistance which would not exclude the
alike - are not coordinated, either “operation” may opposition and of creating conditions which would
undermine the other. Yet the surgical image, with its facilitate the reintegration of excombatants into civil-
sole emphasis on the role of the international agencies, ian life.
does not capture important aspects of the political
dynamic of peace-building in El Salvador. Far from a
*The authors would like to thank James Boyce, Colin
passive individual patient undergoing surgery, El Danby, Richard Fagen, Francesca Jessup, Terry Karl and
Salvador is made up of divergent groups whose evol- Manuel Pastor, Jr. Elisabetb Wood would like to acknowl-
ving interests and shifting alliances not only fueled the edge the support of the Harvard Academy for International
war but continue actively to shape the peace. and Area Stndies.

2079
2080 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Two broader issues were therefore neglected. The the implementation of the peace agreement as they did
first is the short-run question of how to finance the to the implementation of economic reform. In section
implementation of the programs mandated by the 5, we analyze the uneven implementation of the peace
Peace Accords signed in January 1992. The second, agreement to date, and the social costs of deferral of
raised by the apparent tension between macroeco- the peace agenda. Some concluding remarks are
nomic objectives of fiscal austerity and the expendi- offered in section 6.
ture requirements of peace-building, is the longer run
question of how economic policy might be recast to
undergird the consolidation of peace in postwar El 2. MACROECONOMIC POLICY SINCE 1989
Salvador.
This paper focuses primarily on the former ques- In 1989, the newly elected government of Alfred0
tion. The agenda of reforms, which included the Cristiani embarked on a new set of stabilization and
founding of new institutions, the reconstruction of adjustment policies. The government’s program,
war-tom areas, and the development of reintegration which included a major reform in the trade and tax
programs including the transfer of land, required a regimes as well as a general thrust toward privatiza-
substantial commitment of resources. The Salvadoran tion and liberalization, was backed by all the relevant
government called on international donors to finance international institutions. The World Bank played a
the implementation of the peace agreement, arguing particularly key role, substituting for the role USAID
that its commitment to fiscal targets under agreements had previously played in directing and supervising the
with the international financial institutions pre- Salvadoran economy in the 1980s (Rosa, 1993). The
cluded a significant change in the size or orientation program was, moreover, generally supported by the
of the national budget. While international donors private sector, easing the tense business-government
did provide significant funding, programs essential relations that had characterized the previous presi-
to the peace agreement were delayed or scaled dency.
back. During the period of the adjustment program’s
In section 2, we review the macroeconomic poli- implementation, the economy has experienced rela-
cies pursued since 1989 and the bases for the signifi- tively high rates of growth (reaching 5% or more in
cant expansion of the Salvadoran economy after the recent years) and the rate of open unemployment has
beginning of peace negotiations. Given the extraor- diminished, albeit marginally. While poverty indexes
dinary inflow of remittances and the beneficial conse- have remained high, they do not appear to have grown
quences of the resolution of the regional political cri- worse; and inflation has been controlled. International
sis over this period, the causal contribution of the institutions have thus judged the program as both
stabilization and adjustment policies to the resump- highly successful on its own terms, and important as a
tion of economic growth can be easily exaggerated, supportive economic basis for the peace process
and frequently is. We analyze three characteristics of (USAID, 1994b, p. 3).
the economy that may undermine both economic This period of macro-management has, however,
growth and political stability: vulnerability of foreign not been an unqualified success. Stability and growth
exchange earnings to changes in US immigration pol- have depended heavily on a very large and increasing
icy, the weakness of export performance resulting influx of remittances from Salvadorans residing over-
from the overvalued exchange rate, and continuing seas. This influx has financed - and indeed can be
high rates of poverty inadequately addressed by social regarded as the principal cause of - a large and
programs. widening trade deficit. Growth in nontraditional
In section 3, we discuss the key elements of the exports to countries outside the Central American
peace agreements, particularly its core agenda of Common Market (CACM) has been quite sluggish, in
reform of the coercive institutions of the state and its part due to the appreciation of the real exchange rate
meager agenda of socioeconomic reform (including driven by remittances.
some land transfer) limited primarily to facilitating the At the same time, remittances have mitigated tbe
reintegration of excombatants into civilian life. We social costs of adjustment, not only by sustaining
describe the postagreement bargaining that defined growth and checking inflation, but also by directly
reconstruction and reintegration policies, as well as augmenting the incomes of poor and middle-class
their costs. In section 4, we describe how the macro- households. The fact that poverty has remained so
economic policy environment with its emphasis on high despite these inflows is therefore quite troubling.
fiscal austerity resulted in delays in needed public Moreover, the long-term future of the flows is uncer-
investment and legitimated deferral of expenditures tain, particularly given recent changes in US immigra-
essential to the peace agenda. We suggest that the tion policy. The policy “space” provided by the cur-
international financial institutions might have con- rent foreign exchange bonanza could have been used
tributed more to postwar reconstruction had their dis- to develop the infrastructure for competitive exports
cussions of conditionality given as much attention to and to repair the poor distribution of assets and
MACROECONOMIC POLICY AND THE SALVADORAN PEACE ACCORDS 2081

income that was a fundamental factor in causing the impacts. Moreover, the end of the war permitted the
war. Instead, the government chose to push a neo- government, particularly after 1992, to redirect
liberal model of economic adjustment that may even- resources that were dedicated to the war effort toward
tually worsen equity and increase macroeconomic social sectors. Again, more could have been done, but
fragility. this spending shift toward nontradable services also
The new government which took power in June helped domestic employment and income.
1994 has chosen to deepen this neoliberal restructur- The positive economic effects of this domestic peace
ing and has recently announced a new program aimed process were reinforced by successful peace negotia-
at turning El Salvador into a large free-trade zone. The tions in other areas of Central America. In Nicaragua,
program, which has as its central pillar a fixed for example, the electoral defeat of the Sandinistas
exchange rate and convertibility of the col6n (along helped to usher in an era of detente in the region and of
with further market liberalization), has generated slow but sustained recovery of the regional market. El
much debate in El Salvador and in Central America. Salvador has particularly benefited from this and
In contrast to the previous reforms, this new proposal demand from the Central American Common Market
has neither the unconditional backing of the private (CACM) has been one of the principal sources of growth
sector nor the formal approval of the international in recent years. Thus, the resolution of both the domes-
financial institutions. tic and regional crises had positive externalities which
helped the post-1989 Salvadoran reform program to
achieve better economic results.
(a) General context of the reform program

Macroeconomic policies are never implemented in (ii) Reestablishment of the private sector-government
a vacuum. Negative trends and external factors can alliance
often make a coherent adjustment fail while positive The coming to power of the ARENA party in June
trends can give flawed approaches the aura of success. 1989 also brought a warming of business-government
In our view, at least three background factors are key relations, in contrast to the various tensions that had
to evaluating the adjustment program initiated in characterized the decade of the 1980s. In a country in
1989. The first is the reduction in regional and internal which the private sector has the power to make any
political and military tensions, a trend which economic strategy unviable, its almost unconditional
enhanced social stability and raised private invest- support for the government was decisive in imple-
ment because of the attendant reduction in risk. The menting the adjustment program, which by its nature
second factor was the restoration of the alliance involved changing the existing economic rules of the
between the government and the private sector, a phe- game with sometimes negative effects - at least in
nomenon which also aided the process of private cap- the short term - for certain sectors (particularly agri-
ital formation. The final factor was the massive culture and certain manufacturing firms). That busi-
increase in the flow of foreign exchange coming from ness was willing to go along with such short-term sec-
remittances, a trend which produced a more favorable toral pain suggested the depth of the new alliance.
growth-inflation tradeoff. While private sector support for the government
and its program was partly driven by ideological con-
siderations, it also reflected the impact of US efforts to
(i) The amelioration of the politico-military crisis “modernize” the business community. US efforts over
After the guerrilla offensive of November 1989, El the 1980s had created a social base for support of the
Salvador entered a period of relative socio-political export model, much of it centered in the new business
stability. Peace negotiations began in 1990 and culmin- institutions such as the Foundation for Economic and
ated in the signing of the Chapultepec Accords in Social Development (FUSADES). Indeed, FUSADES
January 1992. The signing of the Peace Accords lifted played a leading role in the design and promotion of
a principal obstacle to economic management of the the adjustment program and at least 17 business lead-
country - that is, the war - and the relative (and ers and others linked with that institution became part
growing) tranquility improved the investment climate of the new government. Other factors that contributed
and helped to reactivate some sectors and activities to business modernization and support for the new
that were depressed during the conflict. government were: the crisis of traditional export agri-
The end of the war and the subsequent reconstruc- culture, which forced many business people to explore
tion phase also had a favorable direct impact on the new opportunities in other areas and economic sectors;
economy. The peace effort has some required expan- the internal political crisis which had spurred an emer-
sion in public spending; while we would argue that gent process of internationalization of Salvadoran cap
even more “investment” in consolidating the peace ital; and generational change in some of the most
would have been desirable, large sums have indeed important economic groups in the country (Johnson,
been expended and this has had the usual multiplier 1993; Segovia, 1994a; Wood, 1995).
2082 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

(iii) The massive growth in theflow of remittances The problem, as we will note below, is that the inflow
During most of the 198Os, remittances bypassed of remittances has resulted in an overvaluation of the
official channels. After the post-1989 government Salvadoran currency, which strongly militates against
opened currency exchange shops and established a the success of the government’s export- oriented
single exchange rate, a move intended to eliminate the growth model3
black market, recorded remittances soon took the Remittances also played a fundamental role in
place of official transfers as the largest single source cushioning the social costs of adjustment and stabi-
of foreign exchange, increasing from 3.5% of GDP in lization. As several studies point out (Montes, 1987;
1988-89 to more than 8% in 1992, exceeding for the CEPAL, 1993; USAID, 1993), remittances have had a
first time the total earnings from exports (see Table strong redistributive effect, as they often represent a
l).’ By 1993, remittance inflows were double the vol- direct transfer to the poor sectors of the society.
ume of official external assistance, and in 1995 they Montes (1987) estimated that one-third of Salvadoran
may surpass 10% of GDP. families have at least one relative in the United States,
Perhaps the most important impact of remittances and that the remittances received by each family rep-
was that they allowed the government to focus on resent on average 47% of their income; USAID (1993,
economic restructuring and not simply stabilization.2 p. 31) cites studies showing that remittances increase
Remittances allow the country to live “beyond its the income of poor urban and rural families by one-
means,” importing more than it exports (that is, aside third. Thus for many poor families remittances play a
from labor). The large volume of remittances provide crucial role in subsistence.4 Given the close relation-
sufficient foreign exchange to finance the trade gap ship between worsening income distribution and ris-
and maintain a stable exchange rate, making it easier ing social tensions, remittances have played a crucial,
to maintain growth and control inflation. albeit not consciously orchestrated, role in the
Remittances have been the key factor preventing the Salvadoran peace process, and certainly helped to
adjustment process from producing recession, as reduce political opposition to the post-1989 economic
internal investment as well as domestic consumption restructuring.
have been financed with external savings (ANEP, In addition to direct effects, remittances indirectly
1992, p. 52). affect the income distribution in several ways. Most
With the problem of short-run stabilization more obviously, emigration reduces the supply of labor,
or less solved, the government concentrated its atten- putting some upward pressure on employment and/or
tion on the task of structural adjustment, understood as wage rates within the country. A substantial fraction
a general process of economic liberalization. Indeed, of remittance income undoubtedly translates into
the greatest achievements of the adjustment program demand for food, helping to boost basic grain prices,
from the point of view of its designers and backers, thereby benefiting net sellers of grain, some of whom
were advances in installing in the country an eco- are poor. Some remittance income also provides
nomic system based increasingly on market forces. working capital for small businesses (Lopez and

Table 1. Macroeconomic significance offamily remittances, 1979-94

Remittances Remittances Remittances Remittances


(millions as a % of as a % of as a % of
Year of us $) Exports Net Transfers GDP

1979 49.2 4.4 95.7 1.4


1980 59.6 5.5 86.5 1.7
1981 74.7 9.5 92.4 2.2
1982 87.3 12.5 42.0 2.4
1983 97.0 12.8 35.7 2.4
1984 121.0 16.7 38.4 2.6
1985 101.9 14.7 31.9 1.8
1986 134.5 17.8 35.0 3.4
1987 168.7 28.5 29.4 3.6
1988 194.0 31.9 38.1 3.5
1989 203.7 41.0 39.2 3.5
1990 322.1 55.4 56.6 5.9
1991 518.0 88.1 94.6 6.8
1992 686.0 114.7 91.7 8.1
1993 789.0 107.8 89.4 8.1
1994 870.0 104.7 NA 9.7

Sources: PUSADES; BCR.


MACROECONOMICPOLICYAND THE SALVADORANPEACEACCORDS 2083

Seligson, 1989).5 Despite these ameliorative effects, significant impact on the real level of protection.6
poverty rates in El Salvador remain extremely high, as Interest rate restrictions were relaxed and price con-
we shall see below. trols were eliminated on approximately 200 products.
An accompanying fiscal reform eliminated export
duties, reduced and simplified direct taxes, and intro-
(b) Logic and content of thepost-1989 adjustment duced a value-added tax (VAT). Partly to reduce pres-
program sure on the spending side, steps were taken to restruc-
ture the public sector, particularly the education and
While the adjustment program initiated in 1989 health ministries. In addition, a privatization program
had the usual goals of inflation reduction and macro was designed which included the sale of some state
stability, its more fundamental objective was to install property, the privatization of public services, and the
an economic model based on private enterprise. This privatization of the financial system which had been
implied eliminating all restrictions and controls on nationalized in the 1980s.’
markets (i.e., liberalization) as well as opening the The adjustment program did not undergo substan-
greatest possible space for accumulation of capital by tial changes as a result of the signing of the peace
business sectors, principally through privatization and agreements, as we shall see below, despite the need to
reducing the size of the state. It was assumed that the dramatically increase expenditures to implement the
external sector would be the new axis of accumula- agenda of reform and reconstruction.
tion, with exports providing the foreign exchange nec-
essary to maintain short-run financial and exchange
rate stability. In contrast with the long-standing (c) Progress in stabilization
agroexport model, where the bulk of exports consisted
of a few primary commodities facing unstable prices One of the successes of the program is the progress
on the world market, the new model was to rely on achieved in stabilizing the Salvadoran economy.
nontraditional agricultural and industrial exports to Annual inflation slowed to 15% in 1990-93, versus
markets outside the region. 25% in the preceding five years. In our view, this is
The government moved quickly to implement the due principally to the availability of foreign exchange
program. In mid- 1990 the single rate of exchange was from remittances and international aid.8 Moreover,
established and a “dirty float” system was put in place this inflation success has been “purchased” with an
to promote exports while maintaining a flexible and increasingly overvalued exchange rate, as the Central
realistic exchange rate. profound tariff reductions Bank has sought to essentially fix the nominal
were carried out in little more than two years, with a exchange rate in the face of modest price increases

Table 2. Basic economic indicators, 1990-94

Average Average
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994* 1985-89 1990-94

Real growth of GDP (%) 3.4 3.5 5.3 5.1 5.5 1.6 4.6
Real GDP per capita6 (1962 colones) 635 644 663 672 n.a.t 624 654
Gross Domestic Investment (% of GDP) 11.9 14.0 16.9 17.1 18.5 13.3 15.7
Private investment (% of GDP) 8.9 10.3 11.5 12.4 13.5 9.4 11.3
Public investment (% of GDP) 2.9 3.2 4.6 4.6 4.6 3.8 4.0
Deficit in non-financial public sector
(% of GDP) 2.5 4.5 6.3 4 3.4 3.6 4.1
Deficit of central government (% of GDP) 3.2 4.5 4.8 3 n.a. 3.7 3.9
Public saving of non-financial public
sector (% of GDP) -0.3 -0.1 0.2 0.8 n.a. 0.6 0.0

Exports (millions of US$) 582 588 597 122 797 629 658
Non-traditional Exports 285 316 380 450 540 199 394
Imports (millions of US$) 1262 1406 1900 2067 1012 1667
Trade deficit 680 818 1101 1177 1270 382 1009
Deficit in current account (millions of US$) 330 292 338 266 234 306
Net international reserves (millions of US$) 463 471 587 714 ;;“d 252 605

*Estimates.
tn.a. = not available.
Sources: FUSADES, BCR, IMF, USAID.
2084 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Officials at international financial institutions inter-


viewed in November 1994 tended to discount this
possibility, but later that month the US announced
plans to terminate the Deferred Enforced Departure
program under which some 180,000 Salvadorans
lived in the U.S. without immigrant visas.‘O Although
the affected persons will be able to delay their depar-
tures, the termination of the program could affect
large numbers of Salvadorans in the next few years.
Other anti-immigration measures in the US could also
ao’l”““““““““““’
70 72 74 76 76 90 82 04 96 86 SO 92 lead to repatriation of Salvadorans residing there ille-
gal1y.l’ Repatriation in large numbers could lead to a
Figure 1. Real exchange rate, 1970-93. Index 1980 = 100
sharp contraction in remittances, and thus to shortages
(n’se corresponds to depreciation). Calculated from
of foreign exchange, severe income losses for remit-
Salvadoran consumer prices and U.S. Wholesale prices.
Source: IhfF, International Financial Statistics. tance recipients, and great pressure on labor markets.
In such a case, the stabilization success since 1989
would be exposed as resting on fragile pillars, a result
(see Figure 1). The col6n rose in price by 31% foreshadowed by the recent Mexican collapse.
between the end of 1990 and May 1994. The result has
been a dramatically widening trade deficit, notwith-
standing strong growth in exports to the CACM, rais- (d) Progress in structural adjustment
ing worries for a model supposedly built on export
growth and a “realistic” exchange rate policy (see If structural adjustment is understood simply as the
Table 2). process of installing a neoliberal economic model,
How best to resolve the contradiction between a then El Salvador’s post-1989 experience may be con-
highly valued currency and an export-oriented accu- sidered a great success. ‘* The Salvadoran economy is
mulation model remains a topic of ongoing debate. now less protected externally and more reliant on mar-
Both Harberger (1993) and Hinds (1994) suggest that ket mechanisms and the role of the private sector has
remittances will continue in the long run and that the been expanded through privatization and the reduc-
current real exchange rate is therefore market-appro- tion in the size of the state. In addition to consolidat-
priate; in this view, nominal devaluation would sim- ing the support of international financial institutions,
ply translate quickly into inflation. Other authors, this structural change has generally reinforced the
including Gonzalez Orellana (1994), argue that appre- confidence of the private sector, reflected in the mod-
ciation of the real exchange rate has come at the cost est but sustained recovery of private investment.
of a severe deterioration in export competitiveness, This process of “modernizing” the market econ-
and that a real devaluation is needed to promote com- omy has not, however, been free from difficulties and
petitiveness. Forcing a real devaluation is sensible problems. Some of these clearly contradict the overall
only if remittances are viewed as a short-run phenom- goal of a competitive economy. For example, irregu-
enon, as the devaluation would simply adjust the larities in the privatization of banking have produced
exchange rate to where the market itself will be in few oligopolization in the financial sector, hindering fair
short years, thereby sending the right signal to competition and raising real interest rates (including
investors. commissions) to borrowers. As a result, the banks
Ultimately, what exchange rate policies should be have become the defacto financial arms of major eco-
adopted thus depends on the permanence of the cur- nomic groups, reflecting and reinforcing the concen-
rent remittance flows. An IMF official interviewed for tration of wealth with negative effects on the
this study took an optimistic view, suggesting that in prospects for sustainable economic growth and the
future years remittances are likely to grow at the same strengthening of new economic actors.13
rate as host-country (that is, US) GDP. While this Perhaps the biggest conflict, however, is the afore-
would represent a somewhat lower rate of increase mentioned contradiction between the use of the
than in previous years, it would imply that current lev- exchange rate as an inflation-fighting tool and the
els would be maintained for the foreseeable future.9 In objective of creating a strong and diversified export
a less optimistic scenario, a “soft landing” predicted sector. Despite the export-promoting policies
by some observers, remittance inflows will gradually described above, nontraditional exports outside the
decline in coming years as the ties between emigre region remain weak. The only nontraditional exports
Salvadorans and their homeland grow weaker. that have shown dynamic growth in recent years are
A more alarming possibility, a “hard landing,” those goods directed to the CACM, and assembly ser-
would be a sudden drop in remittances, perhaps pre- vices, a category which generated more than 40,000
cipitated by a change in US immigration policy. jobs in 1985-93 (Paus, 1995). Impressive performance
MACROECONOMIC POLICY AND THE SALVADORAN PEACE ACCORDS 2085

in the assembly industry is not, however, likely to nized as the most serious threat to the consolidation of
make up for generally slack growth: local value-added peace (see, for example, USAID 1994b and World
represents only about 30% of gross value, and the pos- Bank, 1994).
sibilities for future growth have been reduced after the The lack of major progress in the social sector -
US Congress blocked financing for free-trade zones not withstanding the positive impacts of the large
(GAO, 1993). Nor is it likely that the CACM will fuel inflows of remittances - is related to two factors.
ongoing high growth of Salvadoran exports. First, the government placed a much higher priority on
While a key barrier to a new dynamic pattern of structural adjustment than on social policy (Belt and
export growth is the appreciated colbn, Hinds (1994) Lard& 1994). The trickle-down vision underlying the
and the National Association of Private Enterprise program accepted the old premise that growth and dis-
(ANEP, 1993) have also stressed the lack of produc- tribution are incompatible in the short term, and there-
tive investment. Hinds (1994) attributes this to high fore emphasized growth first and redistribution of the
interest rates, high operating costs (due to deficient fruits of growth later. I6 This is hardly an auspicious
infrastructure, taxes on inputs and capital goods, etc.), framework for making significant dents in poverty
the low national savings rate, and the mentality of rates.
many business enterpreneurs, who expect high returns A second reason for slow progress on poverty and
without large risks. I4 ANBP (1992, 1993) has repeat- inequality was the institutional and financial weaken-
edly argued that the weak showing of exports is due ing of the state as a result of the war, economic crisis,
not only to exchange rate overvaluation but also to and fiscal adjustment. On the administrative side,
economic incentives which encourage speculative many social policies were impeded by the lack of
investment and investment in the commercial and ser- qualified personnel and institutional resources; those
vice sectors, rather than in the production of tradable policies that were implemented often lacked adequate
goods. control mechanisms. This institutional weakness has
There indeed has been an increasing orientation of been exacerbated by the emphasis on privatization and
the economy toward the tertiary or service sector: the decentralization, which accorded with the US-sup-
share of agriculture in GDP has declined dramatically ported strategy of building up institutions that were
in recent years, while the share of commerce and ser- parallel to the state. On the fiscal side, revenues have
vices has increased considerably.i5 This shift is not increased only moderately (see section 4). As a result,
surprising, however, given the real exchange rate social programs were heavily reliant on external fund-
appreciation and the direct boost to consumption due ing, suggesting a lack of a deep governmental com-
to remittances. In short, the exchange rate policy and mitment to building appropriate social safety nets.
the lack of productive private investment are closely In sum, the Salvadoran economy has been substan-
linked. A successful macroeconomic alternative tially restructured-the market plays a larger role, the
would have to both depreciate the currency in real state has less power, the private sector has more prop-
terms and increase investment. erty, and agricultural exports play a much smaller
Finally, the adjustment of 1989-94 was not able to role. But progress toward a diversified export strategy
decrease poverty significantly (nor did this goal figure and sustainable growth has been frustrated by an over-
prominently in its intentions). Indeed, urban surveys valued exchange rate and the lack of productive
conducted by the Ministry of Planning indicate that investment. Progress on the social front meanwhile
the number of people living in “extreme poverty” rose has been very slow and largely inadequate to the task
from 23.3% of the urban population in 1988-89 to of meeting the demands of a deeply frustrated society.
29.6% in 1992-93. That the increase was not greater These shortcomings point to the need for a new
was due to governmental compensatory programs - strategy - one which would consciously depreciate
mostly financed with external resources - as well as the real exchange rate to foster a shift to tradables,
economic growth and the redistributive effect of encourage more productive private investment (in part
remittances. The positive impact of remittances, prob- through enhancing public investment), and pay far
ably the main factor in limiting poverty and ameliorat- greater attention to the lot of the poor.
ing distributional inequities, can hardly be viewed as a
deliberate result of government policy, except to the
extent that the government helped to persuade the US (e) The reform program announced by the new
government to allow emigres to stay in that country government
after the negotiated conclusion to the conflict. Both
real wages and basic grain prices have fallen sharply In early 1995, the government which took office in
in recent years, demonstrating that whatever their June 1994 announced its intention to carry out a new
favorable effects, emigration and remittances have economic reform program whose underlying goal
been insufficient to counter unfavorable trends in the appears to be a total dollarization of the economy. The
current macroeconomic environment. The continuing centerpiece of the program is the proposal to fix the
high level of poverty in El Salvador is widely recog- exchange rate at a level of 8.75 colones to one dollar,
2086 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

with total convertibility. This would entail the cre- a domestic business class accustomed to extraordin-
ation of a Currency Board, which would eventually arily high rates of profit by tightening competition and
take the place of the Central Bank, as exchange rate financial oversight. Finally, it recognizes the need to
policy would disappear and credit policy would incorporate the Salvadoran economy into the world
effectively be ceded to Washington. The designers of economy in a different way, recognizing that present
the program anticipate that this policy would have a demand originating in the internal and regional mar-
series of short-term benefits for the country. First, it kets will not sustain high growth rates and reorienting
would increase the confidence of national and foreign the economy toward the world market, particularly the
investors due to the final elimination of the exchange North American market.
rate risks associated with devaluation. Second, fixing But while the new program is a welcome opening
the exchange rate and forcing the dollarization of the for debate, it offers the wrong policies at the wrong
economy would hold inflation to levels prevailing in time. One key premise of the program is that remit-
the United States and reduce the quasi-fiscal deficit tances from Salvadoran labor are akin to having an
which arises due to the exchange rate losses of the assembly zone located in the United States: these
Central Bank. This, it is argued, would increase El earnings will continue in the medium-term and thus
Salvador’s competitiveness, promote saving, and attempts to lower the real exchange rate will only gen-
contribute to raising real wage levels. Third, the new erate exchange losses and reduce the real credit avail-
exchange rate policy would cause interest rates to able to the private sector.
drop substantially, hopefully close to international But declaring defeat in the face of the “Dutch dis-
rates, which would aid in increasing levels of produc- ease” may prove to be a recipe for long-run disaster, if
tive investment. remittances decline, particularly if this were to occur
Accompanying this fixed exchange rate policy quickly as in the “hard-landing” scenario.18 Sooner or
would be a dramatic reduction (over five years) in later, El Salvador will have to fall back on exports -
tariff rates, cutting the current ceiling from 20 to 6% and the export infrastructure will only be there if the
and the new floor from 5 to l%.*’ As fiscal revenues government combines the right policies (i.e., public
would decline, the government proposes to increase investment) with the right prices (i.e., a less highly
the value-added tax, to step up measures to combat tax valued colon). Freezing the exchange rate now against
evasion, to accelerate privatization, reduce public the dollar would instead lay the groundwork for a
employment, and to reform pension schemes. The financial explosion h la Chile in 1982 or Mexico in
immediate impact on income distribution, particularly 1994: bad news or external shocks could then trigger
on the tax side, is likely to be regressive. an economic meltdown.
Announcement of the program set off intense The key shortcoming in this new program is its
debate in El Salvador and in Central America. As of failure to incorporate a serious effort to reduce poverty
this writing, the principal business organizations have directly and to redistribute assets, opportunities, and
given it conditional support (expressing concerns income. Poverty reduction is crucial as an end in
about higher taxes and the fixed exchange-rate), while itself. But the evidence clearly shows also that market
the opposition parties and the trade unions have economies work best when they start from a precondi-
declared their opposition to the proposals. Other tion of relative equality. Among other benefits, greater
Central American countries have reacted cautiously, equality reduces rent-seeking and induces a willing-
partly because the plan would reorient El Salvador ness to share burdens, both of which makes it easier to
away from the Central American market toward the achieve stabilization and adjustment. For El
larger world economy and because the proposed tariff Salvador’s new market-oriented strategy to work, it
changes would violate current subregional agree- must now (and not later) launch a committed redistri-
ments. El Salvador has formal commitments to the butional and anti-poverty program.
CACM which it cannot abandon lightly. Nor should it This is particularly important in a country trying to
do so, for intraregional trade is currently the most fulfill the obligations of a peace accord. The success of
dynamic component of the country’s export sector. In any economic program depends on creating a climate of
light of these reactions, the specifics of the plan stability which gives confidence to national and foreign
remain highly tentative. investors. In El Salvador this presumes the consolida-
Regardless of its final content, the proposal repre- tion of democracy and the full implementation of the
sents a unique opportunity to open a serious debate Peace Accords: the country cannot subordinate peace to
about what kind of economy is most desirable for El economic restructuring. Moving ahead with both
Salvador. This is particularly the case because the pro- processes simultaneously is the only viable option for
gram seeks to respond honestly to three fundamental attaining the goals of development and democracy. The
problems. First, it attempts to respond to the deli- best way to insure such compatibility is to make the
ciency of productive investment, by reducing risk and more general guarantor of social peace-distributional
thereby, it is argued, attracting foreign and increasing improvement and the elimination of poverty -the cen-
domestic investment. Second, it attempts to discipline terpiece of a new economic strategy.
MACROECONOMIC POLICY AND THE SALVADORAN PEACE ACCORDS 2087

3. THE PEACE ACCORDS AND POSTWAR Both exguerrillas and ex-National Policemen would
RECONSTRUCTION participate in the new force (not to exceed 20% of the
new force in either case) after attendance at the
On January 16, 1992, the Salvadoran government Academy.
and the FMLN signed a peace agreement that ended The Peace Accords also reaffirmed earlier agree-
more than a decade of civil war. In essence, the agree- ments on judicial and electoral reform. Most impor-
ment laid out a political compromise in which the left tant of these was the founding of a new investigative
agreed to a democratic political regime and a capital- and prosecutorial body, the National Counsel for the
ist economy with only very limited socioeconomic Defense of Human Rights (Procuradurfa de Derechos
reform, and the right agreed to participation by the left Humanos). Earlier reform of the Constitution had
in a democratic political regime with some degree of changed procedures for the selection of Supreme
socioeconomic reform. The Peace Accords enshrine a Court magistrates, a step toward breaking the tradi-
democratic bargain: the two sides agreed to resolve tional dominance of the judicial system by the ruling
their future differences through a democratic political political party. *OThe Accords also included provi-
process (Karl, 1992; Vickers, 1992; Munck, 1993). If sions to strengthen the independence of the National
fully implemented and consolidated, the Peace Judicial Council and founded a new institution for the
Accords will lay the institutional foundations of polit- training of judges and other judicial personnel. The
ical democracy in the postwar period. Peace Accords also extended earlier reforms to
The principal impediments to full implementation broaden political party representation in the supervi-
of the peace agreement have been domestic political sion of elections. The agreement mandated the legal-
obstacles, not economic constraints. To the extent that ization of the FMLN as a political party, recognizing
a lack of economic resources constrained some its right to meet, to mobilize, to publish and to hold
aspects of the peace process, the shortfall itself licenses for communication (to legalize the FMLN’s
reflected a lack of political commitment. International two clandestine radio stations).
actors, although they contributed significant financial
resources and political pressure at key moments, did
not compensate fully for inadequate political commit- (b) Socioeconomic reforms
ment by Salvadoran actors, particularly the
Salvadoran government. The section of the Peace Accords concerning
socioeconomic reform was in places both vague and
ambiguous - in sharp contrast to the detailed agree-
(a) Political reforms ments on military reform and public security. While
the Accords explicitly declared any consideration of
The core of the peace agreement-the axis around the “philosophy and general orientation” of the gov-
which its democratic promise revolved - was the ernment’s economic policy as beyond the scope of the
agenda of extensive reforms of the coercive apparatus agreement, the government agreed that postwar stabil-
of the state. The agreement reaffirmed previously ity depended on the transfer of some resources to for-
negotiated agreements institutionalized in the April mer guerrillas and their supporters. Principal elements
1991 reforms to the Constitution, particularly the nar- of the agreement’s limited agenda of socioeconomic
rowing of the Armed Forces’ role of defense (not pub- reform were limited land transfer to excombatants and
lic security, except under particular emergency condi- civilian supporters of the FMLN, channels for the
tions). A commission of civilians, the “Ad Hoc flow of external aid to communities in the former con-
Commission,” would review the human rights records flicted zones, the founding of a forum of labor, busi-
of the officers of the Armed Forces and issue recom- ness and government for further negotiations, and a
mendations, and a Truth Commission would investi- National Reconstruction Plan targeted on the excon-
gate a range of human rights violations by both sides. flitted zones with programs to facilitate the reincorpo-
The Accords mandated a set of key institutional ration of excombatants of both sides into civilian
reforms to reduce the military’s historical control over life.2’
rural areas, including the dissolution of the civil The peace agreement thus did not include a redis-
defense patrols, the Treasury Police and the National tributive agenda, a troubling omission in view of the
Guard, the institutional separation of intelligence ser- sustained fall in real wages during the war and the
vices from the Ministry of Defense, and the suspen- contribution of social and economic inequality to the
sion of forced conscription.i9 emergence of civil war. No agreements on wage
The Peace Accords provided for the founding of increases or even the right of unions to organize were
a new National Civilian Police (PNC) under the included. Notably absent was any significant exten-
Ministry of the Interior, separate from the Armed sion of existing agrarian reform legislation; indeed,
Forces chain of command, and a new National the agreement indirectly affirmed the existing consti-
Academy of Public Security (ANSP) for its training. tutional ceiling on landholding (245 hectares). Nor
2088 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

was poverty directly addressed outside the areas tar- struction of damaged infrastructure. Policies facilitat-
geted by the PRN except in the vaguest of terms ing the reincorporation of the Fh4LN were to include
(Vickers, 1992). programs such as scholarships, jobs and pensions,
Redistribution was thus limited to the transfer - housing projects and business promotion. Appealing
more precisely, the purchase - of land to excombat- to the international community for support, the
ants and supporters of the PMLN as part of the rein- Accords assigned to the United Nations Development
corporation measures. There are perhaps two princi- Programme (UNDP) the role of consultant in
pal reasons (Wood, 1995). Fist, as described above, fundraising, project design, and coordination with
the government’s economic policy emphasized diver- nongovernmental organizations.
sification away from a narrow dependence on agricul- While the balance of political forces in the country
tural production and integration into regional and had been sufficient for the reaching of the commit-
international markets - a policy that would be more ments enshrined in the Peace Accords, at the war’s
threatened by wage and labor policies favorable to end it remained an open question whether the evolv-
workers than by the limited transfer of land. That is, ing balance of power in the postwar period would be
for ARENA modernizers, the price to be paid in land sufficient for their realization. The calendar of imple-
for peace did not look steep-if it could be limited to mentation of the socioeconomic agenda was defined
the conflicted zones and did not threaten the political by the political logic of the peace process, not by an
and economic base of the party in the western coffee analysis of its feasibility, an aspect of the agreement
areas. Second, land transfer was critical for the that would complicate its implementation.
FMLN’s internal political cohesion: given the peasant
origins of most of its combatants, to negotiate an end
to the war without some transfer of land would have
led to traumatic internal difficultiesz2
The agreement defined the categories of land to be As the two armies separated to their designated
transferred, including some state properties and pri- “points of concentration” after the signing of the
vate properties in the “conflicted zones” subject to the Peace Accords on January 16, 1992, both domestic
landlord’s agreement, but contained few details and and political actors became increasingly aware of the
many ambiguities. There was no attempt to estimate challenge of peace-building after more than a decade
how much land would fall into any category, and ini- of civil war. Beyond the immediate issue of the effec-
tial estimates varied widely. Nor did the Accords tiveness of the monitoring of the cease-fire by the
define the boundaries of the “conflicted zones,” United Nations Observer Mission (ONUSAL),
despite several references to programs particular to loomed two key issues. First, would the calendar of
those areas. Within 30 days of the signing, the FMLN staggered implementation of the Accords together
was to present an inventory of properties claimed in with the attention of the international community pro-
the conflicted zones; the government was to legalize vide mutual confidence sufficient to engender on-
tenure definitively within six months and extend going compliance? Second, who would pay the costs
credit for land purchase on the terms of the 1980 of peace, given the significant resources required for
agrarian reform. The agreement stated explicitly that the implementation of the peace agreement? These
the current landholders (tenedores) would not be two issues were inextricably related: the political
evicted, but would eventually be resettled if the land- implications of the amount and modalities of funding
lord chose not to sellz3 Landlords were to be paid mar- could either reinforce or undermine the political will
ket prices, but what that would mean in areas where and capacity of one or both parties to carry out the
the civil war had raged was not spelled out. Nor did terms of the peace agreement.
the agreement clearly define a process by which these The fundamental challenge was to translate the
issues would be resolved and the transfer imple- political commitments of the Peace Accords into ade-
mented. quately-funded programs and policies that would
The Accords stated that the government would institutionalize the democratic bargain that resolved
present a draft of the National Reconstruction Plan the war. At the time of the signing of the Accords, no
(PRN) to the FMLN within a month of the signing of overall assessment of the cost of the implementation
the agreement. While the FMLN’s recommendations of the agreement existed; only initial estimates for
and requests would be “taken into account,” its role reconstruction based on a preliminary version of the
was clearly secondary; there was no provision for the PRN existed.24
participation of the beneficiaries in the development Planning for postwar reconstruction began in mid-
of the PRN (except in the case of credit policy). The 1991, half a year before the signing of the Peace
principal goals of the plan were the integrated devel- Accords, with an initial Consultative Group (CG)
opment of “areas affected by the war,” attention to meeting of donors and government representatives
basic needs of the population most affected by the war (MIPLAN, 1991d).= Between that meeting and the
and the excombatants of both sides, and the recon- second CG meeting in March 1992, the Ministry of
MACROECONOMIC POLICY AND THE SALVADORAN PEACE ACCORDS 2089

Planning and Coordination of Economic and Social FMLN and the government began negotiations over
Development (MIPLAN) issued a series of increas- other reinsertion programs for excombatants by mid-
ingly detailed documents describing what was to 1992, with the UNDP acting as an observer.26 After a
become the National Reconstruction Plan (PRN) series of discussions, facilitated and coordinated by
(MIPLAN, 1991a, 1991b, 1991~). Asaresultofcrit- the UNDP, three tracks for reinsertion were defined
icism and debate, some changes were made but the (in addition to the PNC track for those excombatants
broad outlines of the plan remained essentially the who joined the new police force). For those pursuing
same. At the March 1992 CG meeting, the govem- agriculture, training programs by nongovernmental
ment presented three documents outlining programs organizations were to begin immediately; once in pos-
and budgets for the PRN, the strengthening of demo- session of land through the land transfer program,
cratic institutions, and technical assistance agricultural credit, including a five-year loan to capi-
(MIPLAN 1992c, 1992b, and 1992a, respectively). talize the farms, was to follow (UNDP, 1993).
The PRN was to cover approximately 40% of the Excombatants who preferred a nonagricultural future
country, including the 20% of the population most would have access to credit for the founding of
affected by the war. Investments and current expen- “microenterprises” after technical-vocational train-
ditures within the scope of the plan was to vary ing; university scholarships were also available if
between $1,200 and $1,600 million over a five-year appropriate. The approximately 600 mandos medios y
period. The average expenditure in each of these Zideres (mid-level commanders and leaders) of the
years was equivalent to between 4 and 5% of GDP FMLN would participate in a program of business
(IDB, 1993, pp. 3-4). training and credit to start their own enterprises or to
The government appealed for international assis- join existing ones with adequate technical and admin-
tance, arguing that it faced very serious fiscal con- istrative skills. Under UNDP coordination, three sub-
straints as a result of its commitments under the sta- tracks of this last track were developed: technical-
bilization and adjustment programs and the absence vocational training (33% of the participants), business
of a peace dividend given the degree of external administration (58%), and executive training (9%)
financing of the war (MIPLAN, 1992a). The intema- (UNDP, 1994).
tional community pledged some $600 million in Throughout the negotiations, the government
response ($800 million if previous commitments are maintained that the programs should be equally avail-
included). able to excombatants of both sides. Parallel programs
In the months after the CG meeting, two issues for excombatants of the Armed Forces were devel-
dominated debate on reconstruction: the reintegration oped for the agricultural and technical-vocational
of excombatants in general, and the transfer of land in tracks (but not for the mandos medios program, for
particular. Negotiations between the government and which there was no parallel group). In both their
the FMLN collapsed in mid- 1992 over the amount of design process and implementation the programs were
land to be transferred, the number of beneficiaries, and quite separate although the opportunities were
the application of “market prices.” Nor were the roughly similar.
promised training and credit programs - the neces- In April 1993, a third Consultative Group meeting
sary complements to land transfer - in place. of international donors was convened by the World
The impasse threatened the peace process itself as Bank. The government presented a revised proposal
the FMLN suspended its demobilization process and that emphasized the reinsertion programs and poverty
political tensions increased. In an extraordinary alleviation, with updated figures of estimated needs,
instance of its “good offices” mandate, the UN sent a existing government and donor commitments, and a
team of agrarian specialists to evaluate the situation substantial “funding gap” of still unfinanced programs
and then offered the two parties a take-it-or-leave-it (summarized in Table 3).
settlement. The proposal, subsequently considered by Troubling to many observers was the continuing
the UN as an addendum to the Peace Accords, defined inadequate funding of many programs judged essen-
the scope of the transfer in terms of both the number of tial to the consolidation of the peace process - partic-
beneficiaries - 7,500 excombatants of the FMLN, ularly the new public security institutions and the rein-
15,000 excombatants of the Armed Forces, and tegration programs. The discrepancy intensified the
25,000 tenedores - and the amount of land per bene- debate about the relationship between economic and
ficiary. If the agreement had been fully funded and political reform (de Soto and de1 Castillo, 1994a;
fully implemented, the transfer of land would have Segovia, 1994b). Moreover, progressive lack of con-
amounted to 12% of Salvadoran farmland (a bit over fidence by donors in the National Reconstruction
half of the amount distributed under the 1980 agrarian Secretariat resulted in its programs being almost
reform). Subsequent agreements, however, pared exclusively funded by USAID, with other donors opt-
down the amount to be transferred. ing to channel bilateral assistance through other min-
Development of other reinsertion programs trailed istries and through the UNDP (Boyce, 1995; Murray
the negotiations over land. Representatives of the Coletti and Spence, 1994).
2090 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 3. Fundingpriorities and shorrfalls, 1993-96: 1993 Consultative Group budget (millions of US dollars)*

GOES Expected international Shortfall, Shortfall


commitment contribution, (April 1993 (January 1994
PrOgKilllS Requirements (April 1993) (April 1993) est.) est.)

Priority Programs
National Civilian Police 173.0 35.4 6.0 131.6
Public Security Academy 104.7 28.0 9.9 66.8 182.0
Judicial Reform 219.8 162.3 15.0 42.5
Human Rights Ombudsman 16.8 6.4 1.1 9.3 66.6
Elections Tribunal 20.0 0.6 4.0 15.4
Reintegration (PRN) 316.8 26.6 80.0 210.2 177.8
Pensions for disabled 8.2 0.7 0.0 7.5
Land transfer 142.5 23.3 47.5 71.7 62.7
Housing 77.1 2.6 12.5 62.0
Agricultural credit 62.0 0.0 10.0 52.0
Microenterprise credit 27.0 0.0 10.0 17.0
Poverty alleviation (PRN) 310.2 57.2 147.7 105.3 93.7
Subtotal Ll61.3 316.5 263.7 581.1 520.1

Other Programs (PRN)


Social and productive sector 120.0 10.9 55.6 53.5 -14.6
Infrastructure 530.1 78.3 281.3 170.5 161.0
Environmental sector 17.5 1.9 0.0 15.6 15.4
Total 1,828.9 407.6 600.6 820.7 681.9

Sources: MIPLAN 1993a. GAO 1994.


*For further details, see Boyce (1995), Table 2. A negative shortfall indicates a surplus. The report to the 1993 CG meeting
also included a priority request for poverty alleviation funds for non-PRN areas ($372.32 million). As these figures are not
included in other documents, they are here ignored as well. In addition, a separate document requesting $20.4 million for tech-
nical assistance (MIPLAN, 1993b) accompanied the principal document; this request is treated in the text but is not included
in the table.

4. DOMESTIC RESOURCE MOBILIZATION achieve economic growth with social justice. The
government’s tax reform initiative (Gallagher, 1993)
With the signing of the peace agreement, the need has produced some favorable results in terms of
to mobilize domestic resources has grown. While simplification and improved efficiency of the tax
international agencies and foreign governments wel- system, but has not fully yielded the expected increase
comed the end of the war, external aid has, nonethe- in fiscal receipts.
less, fallen. Domestic savings remain low, as does
government revenue. Given the rigidity of public
spending, there has been a constant potential conflict (a) The principal features and results of the tax
between the need to fulfill the commitments contained reform
in the peace agreements and the need to maintain and
strengthen macroeconomic stability. The threat that Recognizing the need to both enhance and stabilize
the “adjusting variable” would be peace expenditures tax revenue, the adjustment program implemented in
has been raised in requests for external assistance. 1989 attempted to establish a more modem tax system
Indeed, key programs were delayed or scaled down as and to reduce the state’s reliance on volatile export
a result of funding constraints, as we shall see. below. income.27 Among the most important measures imple-
Yet it is by no means clear that the scope for the mobi- mented were: (i) a total overhaul of the tax system,
lization of domestic resources for peace through including the elimination of all taxes on exports, of the
expenditure shifting and increased tax revenues has tax on net worth, and of the majority of tax exemp-
been exhausted. tions; simplification of personal and corporate income
While the foreign exchange gap has been filled by taxes; reduction of the top income tax rate from 60%
remittances from Salvadoran emigrants as noted to 25%; and replacement of revenue stamps by a
above, it cannot be assumed that this windfall will be value-added tax (VAT); (ii) a variety of policies to end
permanent. In this context, a crucial task for widespread tax evasion28; and (iii) the simplification
Salvadoran policy makers is to devise mechanisms and reduction of taxes on imports.
that will allow the economy increasingly to use This reform in the structure and composition of tax
domestic resources to finance the costs of peace and to revenues has had a profound impact. First, the elimi-
MACROECONOMIC POLICY AND THE SALVADORAN PEACE ACCORDS 2091

g ;r;;;ltandpropertvtrenefers
sive, worsening the already severe inequality of
incomes. Second, the reform has not had the expected
R Domestic transactions results in terms of increasing revenues, partly because
of an extraordinarily high degree of tax evasion.30
While the tax ratio (ratio of tax revenues to GDP) did
increase by two percentage points during 1989-93,
rising from 7.6% of GDP in 1989 to 9.7% in 1994, it
continues to be very low in comparison to that of other
underdeveloped countries,31 and low even in compari-
son to prewar levels (see Figure 3).
The low level of tax revenues has been largely
0 responsible for the government’s failure to achieve its
1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 prel
1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 est original goal of eliminating the fiscal deficit by 1994
(BCR, 1989,p.20).Infact,thedeficitduring 1989-94
Figure 2. Composition of tax revenue, 1985-94. Source:
USAID,from BCR. was higher on average than during the preceding five
years. Partly as a result, the state has become increas-
ingly reliant on external resources to finance social
nation of export taxes - which had traditionally spending, especially for programs related to poverty
been the most significant source of government rev- alleviation and investment in human resources. This is
enues - and the introduction of the VAT has indeed particularly worrisome as external assistance is
made the tax system more stable (see Figure 2). expected to decline in coming years.
Second, the bulk of state revenues now come from Rivera Campos (1994, p. 11) suggests that
three taxes: the VAT, the income tax, and the tax on “official transfers [of foreign savings] are allowing a
imports. The tax system is now much easier to lower tax burden.” In other words, while the formal
administer and control, particularly because of the conditionalities and less formal policy dialogue of the
tremendous enhancement in computer, auditing, and international donors have sought to encourage an
control systems.29 increased tax effort, the financial resources they pro-
Despite the merits and achievements of the reform vide may, in and of themselves, have had the opposite
there are problems. First, the new system, by reducing effect. In such a context, the strength with which con-
direct taxes and increasing reliance on indirect taxes, ditionality is exercised becomes critical (see Boyce,
has made the overall taxation structure more regres- 1995).

7970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1960 1982 1984 1986 1968 1990 1992
1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1969 1991 1993

Figure3 Tax coeficient 197693. Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics and Government Finance Statistics; 1993
tax revenue drawnfrom USAID.
2092 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

(b) Fiscal targets and the Peace Accords further delay” (World Bank, 1992, pp. i, 1.) The IMF,
however, continued to insist that tight fiscal and mon-
Public finances were in a precarious state in 1992, etary targets were still achievable. A July 1992 mis-
when the peace agreements were finalized and sion held to the original objectives for the overall pub-
sigmd3* The fiscal deficit of the nonfinancial public lic sector and central government deficits, even
sector (NFPS) had climbed to 4.4% of GDP in 199 l- though the mission foresaw a significant increase in
much higher than the figure for 1990 (2.5%) and the peace-related expenditures during the second half of
1991 target of 2.6%. The central government’s fiscal the year, 45% of which could not be covered by for-
deficit had risen from 3.2% in 1990 to 5.1% in 1991, eign resources. The mission suggested that the gov-
again above the targeted goal of 2.5%.33 Alarmed by ernment adopt a series of fiscal measures aimed at
the fiscal imbalances, the IMF insisted on greater fis- raising an additional 1% of the GDP.37 Many of the
cal stringency, including a reduction in the general Fund’s suggested revenue enhancements were never,
NFPS deficit by over 2% of GDP.34 The central gov- however, implemented and others were not put into
ernment itself was to adjust revenue and expenditure effect until September 1992 (introduction of the VAT
by close to 1% of the GDP, with expenditure reduc- and increase in electricity rates). As a result, the fiscal
tions leading the way.35 goals for the year were not attained.
The spending projections were discussed by the Thus the Salvadoran government and the intema-
IMF’s Executive Board on January 6.1992 - a week tional financial institutions did not really “plan for
after the initial signing of the peace agreement and two peace.” Even as rising peace-related expenditures
weeks before the signing of the formal agreement. derailed fiscal targets, the &IF’s macroeconomic pri-
Although the Fund recognized that expenditures on orities remained firm. While economic stability and
demobilization, reintegration and reconstruction would inflation reduction were worthy and shared goals,
far exceed the amounts that could be reassigned from unrealistic assessments which failed to incorporate the
the existing 1992 budget (IMF, 1991b, pp. l&19), the costs of peace threatened to make peace the adjusting
projections made no allowance for the financial impli- variable. The international financial institutions did
cations of peace. Additional outlays beyond the redi- not themselves fund high-priority programs mandated
recting of existing expenditures would have to be by the peace accords, nor did they condition agree-
financed entirely by foreign resources “in order to pre- ments and loans to encourage the government to
serve the price and balance of payments objectives of increase further its domestic resource mobilization for
the program for 1992” (IMF, 199 1a, Attachment III, pp. peace-related needs. The peace process thus remained
59-60). Evidently the assumption was that the expenses largely tangential to fiscal policy, rather than becom-
associated with the peace agreements and national ing integral to it.
reconstruction would be financed entirely through for- The failure to make fulfillment of the accords a pri-
eign resources, in addition to some transitory financing mary economic as well as social objective was com-
from the Central Bank (see also USAID, 1993, p. 25).36 pounded by a tendency to achieve fiscal balance
When peace did come, the failure to account fully through short-sighted reductions in public investment.
for its financial implications produced a worsening of While the 1993 tax-to-GDP ratio rose to 9.3%, and the
the country’s fiscal situation. The NFPS fiscal deficit NFPS and central government deficits were reduced,
rose from 4.4% of GDP in 1991 to 5.9% in 1992 (as these levels were largely achieved because capital
contrasted with the target of 2.3%). The central gov- spending - particularly that associated with the
ernment also failed to meet its targets for current sav- National Reconstruction Program - was lower than
ings and expenditures. planned.38 As can be seen from Table 4, public sector
In mid-1992, the World Bank recommended that investment was substantially below projected levels in
“the authorities should formally incorporate the 1993, a trend which continued in 1994. The principal
‘peace’ impact into [the] monetary program without mechanisms for public investment cutbacks were:

Table 4. Planned and actual capital expenditure by the nonfinancialpublic sector, 1992-94

Planned expenditure Actual expenditure


Percent of planned
Millions of Percentage of Millions of Percentage of expenditure
colons GDP colones GDP realized

1992 2,214 4.1 2,856 5.7 129


1993 4,145 6.2 2,767 4.6 67
1994 4,013 5.3 2,844 4.0 71

Source: BCR.
MACROECONOMIC POLICY AND THE SALVADORAN PEACE ACCORDS 2093

execution of programs on a smaller scale than Stanley (1995) suggests two reasons to account for the
planned, and deferral of program execution until suf- reluctance to fund an institution so obviously key to
ficient funds from the international community were the peace process: the lack of international interest in
available. Among the programs affected were some funding police in general, and the reluctance in partic-
central to the peace process. ular to fund an institution to which the government
International financing agencies accepted the con- seemed inadequately committed.
ditioning of capital spending on the availability of for- One reason for donor skepticism about the govem-
eign funds in the interest of maintaining macroeco- ment’s commitment to the new force was its reluc-
nomic stability. Yet even the IMF’s Executive Board tance or inability to end ongoing efforts by the former
has recognized that cutbacks in public investment may security forces to undermine the PNC’s autonomy,
have jeopardized the achievement of long-term devel- efforts that outlasted frequent ONUSAL attempts to
opment objectives at a time when the country is in the enforce the letter and spirit of the Accords.41 For
midst of rebuilding (IMF, 1994a, 1994b). As with the example, two units of the National Police were trans-
failure to take account of peace-related current expen- ferred in their entirety into the PNC in 1993 with
ditures, this acceptance of delays in public investment neither the evaluation nor the retraining specified in a
may ultimately harm macroeconomic stability itself, previous agreement. Nor were they integrated into the
by undermining growth, improved income distribu- new civilian line of command (Washington Office on
tion, and the consolidation of peace.39 Latin America, 1994). Moreover, the training center
for the National Police continued to produce new
recruits well after the opening of the ANSP, a clear
5. THE UNEVEN IMPLEMENTATION OF THE violation of the spirit if not the letter of the Accords. In
PEACE ACCORDS late 1994, the newly elected President Calderon Sol
decided to dissolve the PN by the end of the year, a
In the three years since the signing in Mexico City, move that some observers attributed to involvement of
remarkable progress has been made in some aspects of high-level PN officers in organized crime, and
the Peace Accords. The FMLN participated in the announced increase funding for the PNC.42
general elections of March 1994, making a To date the investigative capacity of the National
respectable showing at the presidential and legislative Civilian Police remains inadequate, contributing to
levels. The military has been restructured, purged and the general insecurity and rising crime. The judicial
reduced in size; the new civilian police force has been system, including the new National Counsel for
deployed throughout the country. Various reconstmc- Human Rights, remains extremely weak, although
tion programs have been designed and implemented. reform programs are now in place (Popkin, 1994). As
Implementation of the peace agreement, however, has a result, the authorities have been unable to curb the
been incomplete and uneven in several areas, a num- activities of organized crime with increasing insecu-
ber of which remain essential to the consolidation of rity the result (Spence, Vickers and Dye, 1995).
peace in El Salvador. Ongoing and to date unresolvable delays in the
The founding of the new civilian police force transfer of land - an essential aspect of reintegration
(PNC) has been one of the most problematic aspects of excombatants into civilian life - continue to pre-
of the peace process. The decision to start a new force sent serious threats to the consolidation of the peace
made a new “organizational culture and adequate process. The key problem has not been lack of funding
guarantees for civilian rights” more likely, yet posed for the implementing agency, the Land Bank, but
significant obstacles as well (Stanley, 1995, p. 8). rather lack of political will. The Land Bank has had
Among those obstacles were the financial challenge of adequate interim funding from USAID; the bottle-
building a new institution from scratch, the reluctance neck from month to month in the transfer of land has
of the National Police (PN) to cooperate with the PNC not been a shortage of cash (interview with senior
in the transition period, and the crime wave fueled in USAID official).
part by delays in the reinsertion programs (Stanley, Rather, the recurrent delays are due principally to
1993, 1995; UN Security Council, 1994a, 1994~). two factors (Wood, 1995). First, the titling process
As a result of these difficulties, the training and remains remarkably cumbersome, despite repeated
deployment of the PNC were subject to very serious agreements to streamline it (which could have been
delays and problems. One factor was the lack of ade- readily accomplished by Presidential decree). The
quate initial funding.@ Facilities and equipment government has taken a bureaucratic approach to the
belonging to the former security forces were retained process, originally insisting that only those on initial
by the Armed Forces and the PN, forcing costly delays lists would receive land and refusing to extend credit
as the PNC was built from scratch. While the UNDP, until legal title was transferred. Second, the FMLN
Spain and the United States participated in the and its allied peasant organizations have found it
development of curriculum and organizational plans, extremely difficult to construct a stable list of benefi-
adequate international funding was not forthcoming. ciaries for each property to be transferred. In part this
2094 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

reflects the substantial mobility in the countryside in remittances. These advantageous conditions may not
the aftermath of the war and in part the FMLN’s inad- endure: the domestic costs of implementing the peace
equate organizational resources. The instability in the are growing, business may be less enthusiastic as the
lists of beneficiaries was reinforced by the delays in government attempts more direct measures to
titling, leading to a vicious circle fueled by insecurity improve the private sector’s tepid response to market
as some beneficiaries decided the delays and terms of incentives for productive investment, and, most
transfer were too hard a bargain. importantly, the flow of remittances may taper off. In
As a result of the ongoing delays and problems, this sense, the adjustment process is entering a new
representatives of the government and the FMLN and more difficult stage.
agreed in mid- 1994 to scale back the number of bene- So too is the peace process, following the depar-
ficiaries of the land transfer from 47,500 to just over ture of the UN Observer Mission in April 1995. While
40,000. In May 1994, the government introduced a significant reform of key institutions has been
number of measures intended to streamline the achieved, the implementation of some aspects of the
process and announced that adequate funding for the peace agreement remains incomplete and in some
scaled-down program had been secured (UN Security cases precarious. We have argued that the fundamen-
Council, 1994b). But as yet little acceleration of titling tal problem has not been funding constraints but rather
has resulted; as of March 16, 1995, less than 50% of a lack of commitment on the part of the government at
the reduced number of beneficiaries have received crucial stages of the peace process. Thus, as we have
land. seen, a lack of political commitment, not financial
Reinsertion benefits remain a hotly contested issue shortfalls, resulted in ongoing delays in the transfer of
as excombatants and demobilized members of the land to excombatants and consequently in other rein-
National Police, security forces, civil defense patrols tegration programs as well. Further, the government’s
have paralyzed government on a number of occasions, apparent tolerance of repeated efforts by the super-
most recently in January and February 1995 when seded security forces to undermine the new public
thousands of protestors occupied governments build- security institutions signalled a lack of commitment to
ings demanding land and indemnity payments. Many key aspects of the peace agreement. The govem-
of the demands clearly exceed the provisions of the ment’s at-best lukewarm support-both political and
Peace Accords (in particular, civil defense patrol financial - also discouraged international financial
members were never considered eligible for reinser- support. The delays affecting the new police force and
tion benefits). Under the mediation of ONUSAL, the the land transfer program appear particularly threaten-
government agreed to a compromise set of programs ing to the peace-building: according to de Soto and de1
to be implemented in early 1995.43 The specter of Castillo (1994b), “on their success rests the entire
ongoing unrest caused by excombatants of both sides peace process” - and its sustainability in the long
in neighboring Nicaragua offers a cautionary lesson to run.
Salvadoran observers, many of whom associate the The rhetoric of austerity stemming from the
increasing crime rate with the inadequacy of the rein- macroeconomic policy environment, not domestic
sertion programs.” resource mobilization constraints per se, apparently
While the completion of these programs is neces- legitimated delays and the scaling down of these and
sary, it will not be sufficient for successful reintegra- other programs. A greater interest on the part of the
tion, as the sustainability of the excombatants reinser- international financial institutions in the implementa-
tion into civilian life remains precarious (see for tion of the Peace Accords rather than a dominant
example, UNGA, 1994, p. 6). As international donors emphasis on economic reform might have contributed
turn their attention increasingly to other postconflict- to the reconciliation of the apparently conflicting pri-
ual situations, the funding for reintegration and recon- orities of macroeconomic stabilization and peace-
struction in El Salvador will have to come increas- building.
ingly from domestic resource mobilization. While With the declining presence of the international
there is significant scope for such mobilization, as we institutions, the implementation of the remaining
saw above, present policies are undermining the con- agenda of the Peace Accords depends primarily on the
ditions for stable and equitable economic growth. willingness of the government to shoulder the costs of
peace. Scope for significant increase in the mobiliza-
tion of such resources exists.45 Tax reform has pro-
6. CONCLUSION duced rising and more stable revenues and advances
have been made in improving the auditing capability
El Salvador’s stabilization and adjustment pro- of the relevant ministries. Nonetheless, the tax-to-
gram begun in 1989 was undertaken in a highly favor- GDP ratio remains very low by both historical and
able context - its implementation coincided with the comparative standards, the tax structure is quite
beginnings of peace, the growing closeness of busi- regressive, and the government faces a significant
ness and government, and the increasing flow of problem of tax evasion. Most domestic actors recog-
MACROECONOMIC POLICY AND THE SALVADORAN PEACE ACCORDS 2095

nize the latter problem, and there is a broad consensus the country’s peace and its economic future.
in the country on the need to raise revenue.46 Hence the Peace accords should no longer be
Macroeconomic stability and growth will prove treated as an afterthought or a “remainder”; instead,
short-lived in the presence of political turmoil. Given macroeconomic strategy must be designed to support
the potential for further unrest on the part of excombat- the goal of consolidating the peace. Moreover, the
ants and others and the continuing high rates of poverty, importance of the political reforms mandated by the
political stability considerations strongly support a Accords goes well beyond the desirability of democ-
transfer of fiscal resources from military spending (as ratic objectives and ending the civil warper se. While
yet well above prewar levels) to re- integration and the peace agreement did not directly address the pro-
poverty alleviation programs. This implies the need to found economic and social inequalities that fueled the
continue to reduce military expenditures and a need for civil war, the consolidation of the political reforms is
active “peace conditionality” on the part of intema- both necessary and urgent if a future process of politi-
tional lenders. Further substantial reductions would cal bargaining is to define a more equitable model of
allow both social spending and public investment to economic development and a durable peace in El
rise, even if tax revenues lag, thus contributing to both Salvador.

NOTES

1. Orellana Merlos (1992, pp. 5-7) reviews official esti- shock from their sudden contraction, a topic to which we
mates for 1979-91 and their problems. He estimates the return below.
remittance inflow in 1987 at $504 million, compared to the
official estimate of $169 million and Montes’s (1987) esti-
6. The reforms reduced tariffs from a range of O-290% to
mate of $1.3 billion. Table 4.3 reports the official estimates
a range of 5-20%. There was much “water” in the earlier tar-
which seem to be relatively accurate in the most recent years.
iffs, thanks in part to competition within the CACM; hence
the lowering of tariffs did not result in a wave of bankrupt-
2. Moreover, the government’s latitude for defining poli-
cies.
cies was augmented considerably once it had access to these
remittances precisely because they were autonomous - and
as such not subject to the usual conditionalities attached to 7. For a detailed analysis of the process of privatization in
foreign aid and international assistance. For example, the El Salvador, see Segovia (1994~).
government did not have to rely on funds from the IMF,
despite having signed four Stand-By Agreements (these 8. In fact, the only times when the government had prob-
Agreements were considered precautionary). lems in controlling inflation were precisely those in which the
exchange rate underwent strong fluctuations (as happened at
_3 While appreciation of the real exchange rate does not the end of 1989 and beginning of 1990 due to the November
have strong adverse impacts on traditional exports or on guerrilla offensive) or when measures were applied that
exports to the CACM, it is of major importance for the com- impacted directly on costs and inflationary expectations, as
petitiveness of nontraditional exports outside the region. was the case in 1992, when the introduction of VAT and other
fiscal measures led to significant price increases. The infla-
4. A national household survey, conducted by the tionary spiral of 1992 was particularly serious because the
Ministry of Planning in 1991-92, found that 7.1% of introduction of the VAT coincided with a serious shortage of
“extremely poor” and 12.4% of poor households received basic grains (beans) due to the drought that afflicted the coun-
remittances, on average $36 per month and $61 per month, try that year.
respectively. Remittance income is greatly understated in the
survey, however: total remittances extrapolated from the sur-
9. Similarly, Harberger (1993, p. 17) predicts that the
vey were only $149 million/year, compared to the officially
influx of remittances will continue “as long as more than a
registered inflow of $690 million for 1992. Siri and Abelardo
million Salvadorans live abroad,” and that they will probably
Delgado (1995, p. 6) note that understatement is likely to be
grow over time, “particularly if those Salvadorans share in
especially significant for poor households.
the economic growth which is occurring in the United
States.”
5. On the other hand, emigration that has produced remit-
tances has also had some negative distributional conse-
quences. Survey data indicate that emigrants tend to have 10. The DED program was established to provide tempo-
“above-average labor force characteristics” (Funkhouser, rary protected status in 1990, and was extended on three
1990, p. 23) and the country is now deprived of their human occasions “based largely on Salvadoran government con-
capital. The positive income effects of emigration must also tentions that the country was not able to assimilate large num-
be weighed against the social costs of the disruption of fami- bers of its citizens now living in the United States.” In decid-
lies and communities. Perhaps most troubling, El Salvador’s ing to terminate the program, the Clinton administration
heavy dependence on remittances renders the economy in ignored “strenuous appeals by Salvadoran authorities”
general, and the poor in particular, vulnerable to an adverse (Associated Press, 1994).
2096 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

11. For example, California’s Proposition 187, passed by 24. During the negotiation of the Accords, no attempt was
voters in November 1994, seeks to deny public education and made to estimate its financial implications, a process which
health care to illegal immigrants, and requires teachers and would probably have impeded reaching an agreement by the
health-care providers to report illegal immigrants to immi- endof 1991.
gration authorities.
25. USAID contributed importantly to initial aspects of the
12. These advances have been highlighted by international government’s reconstruction planning. Two teams of consul-
institutions as one of the most important achievements of the tants to USAID carried out assessments of two aspects of the
adjustment program. See USAID (1994b, p. 3) and World reconstruction, defining possible priorities and estimated
Bank (1993, p. 2). costs for programs of physical infrastructure (Jones and
Taylor, 1991a, 199lb) and reintegration of excombatants
14. For a critical analysis of the process of privatization in (Creative Associates, 1991).
banking, see Sort0 and Segovia (1992) and Sort0 (1995).
26. In order to address the immediate needs of the FMLN
14. Harberger (1993, p. 16) reports that, with the important combatants confined to certain areas during the cease-fire,
exception of agriculture, real profit rates in El Salvador are the UNDP coordinated an emergency appeal to international
very high, in the neighborhood of 2630% per annum. donors for resources (Weiss Fagen, 1995).

27. The most important measures included under this


15. Changes in relative prices have played the major role in
reform were instituted over a period of slightly more than
this shift (Acevedo, Barry, and Rosa, 1995).
two years, making El Salvador one of few countries in the
world to have executed such extensive tax reform so quickly
16. For example, FUSADES (1993) suggests that:
(Gallagher, 1993).
“Experience shows that the sequence which eventually
makes it possible for a country to eliminate extreme poverty,
while at the same time attaining a condition of solvency (i.e., 28. Policies to rein in tax fraud included the enactment of a
without significant macroeconomic disequilibrium), consists new law on tax fraud, creation of a new unit to focus on col-
of sustained growth first in order to distribute the fruits of lection of taxes from large taxpayers, improvement of the
growth later” [emphasis in the original]. computer, auditing, and control systems.

17. With the goal of giving businesses time to adjust, the 29. Under the joint sponsorship of USAID, the IMF, and
government is considering reducing tariffs by stages (rather the IDB, a tax system modernization project, known as
than a full and immediate cut) and allowing the pace of tariff MOST, was implemented in 1991. According to USAID
reduction to differ by sector; agricultural and animal hus- (1994b), the Ministry of the Treasury now has “a state-of-
bandry sectors, for example, would receive special treat- the-art tax information system and enhanced administrative
ment. capabilities.”

18. The “Dutch disease” refers to the adverse impact of a 30. CENITEC (1993) and Mtndez and Abrego (1994)
foreign exchange bonanza on the competitiveness of other report that tax evasion may be as high as 50%, with evasion
industries in the tradable goods sector (Corden, 1984). of the VAT running near 57%.

19. Irregular Batallions were to be reabsorbed into the 31. The World Bank (1994, p. 39) observes that El
army and civilians would participate in curriculum develop- Salvador’s tax-to-GDP ratio “remains one of the lowest in
ment in the military academy. the world.”

20. Magistrates are now selected by a two-thirds majority 32. In part this reflects increased costs to the hydroelectric
of the National Assembly and serve staggered nine year authority during the 1991 drought. In addition, consolidation
terms (Popkin, 1994). of the internal public debt in 1989 and 1990 provoked a sub-
stantial increase in interest payments in 1991. The situation
21. Other elements included but never adequately imple- was further aggravated by the increase in interest payments
mented were the extension of credit for agriculture and for on the external debt that resulted from the finalization of the
small business and measures to alleviate the costs of struc- debt restructuring period provided for under the Paris agree-
tural adjustment. ment of 1990.

22. One indication of the depth of conviction on this issue 33. In September the government, in conjunction with the
is that FMLN field commanders in Usuluti - many of IMF, revised the original goals, raising the target fiscal
them of peasant origins - repeatedly conditioned the con- deficit for the nonfinancial public sector from 2.6% to 3.4%
centration and demobilization of their forces on progress in and that of the central government from 2.5% to 3.8%. The
the transfer of land, at times without authorization from their final results proved that these targets were too ambitious.
central command (Wood, 1995).
34. The government was also supposed to reduce the total
23. Because tenedores thus did not necessarily public sector deficit (including BCR losses) from 4.3% of
occupy property, we use the Spanish term rather than the lit- GDP in 1991 to 3.0% in 1992, and generate positive savings
eral translation “holders.” of 1.5% of GDP in the current account of the NFPS. For
MACROECONOMIC POLICY AND THE SALVADORAN PEACE ACCORDS 2097

details see “Memorandum on the economic policies of El the number of PN agents admitted to the PNC provided they
Salvador” (IMF, 199lb. Attachment III). were evaluated and attended the Academy (UN Security
Council, 1994b; Spence, Vickers and Dye, 1995, p. 7). The
35. The program also envisioned a shift in the composition number of former National Policemen to have joined the
of spending, with military spending declining and spending new force may well have exceeded those agreed levels; the
on education and health rising. government’s long-standing refusal to supply ONUSAL
with lists of former combatants has made enforcement of
36. The economic program of 1992 assumed that the coun- the agreements extremely difficult. An attempt to imple-
try would receive US$ 160 million in gross loan disburse- ment ONUSAL’s recommendation that all those trans-
ments from multilateral institutions and US$ 320 million in ferred in excess of the December 1992 agreement be dis-
loans and grants from bilateral sources (IMF, 199lb, p. 42, missed led to a month-long strike by one of the units in
Appendix VI). early 1995. The situation was eventually resolved: over 150
members of the unit will retire with a year’s severance pay
37. The mission offered a positive assessment of the (Spence, Vickers and Dye, 1995, p. 7; El Salvador
macroeconomy and attributing fiscal shortfalls to the gov- Information Project, 1995).
ernment’s delay in implementing planned measures (the
VAT, an increase in electricity rates, and the establishment 42. In June 1994, the lieutenant in charge of the criminal
of the large taxpayers unit), as well as to the effect of the investigations division of the PN was identified on a video-
drought on the electric company’s deficit and the impact of tape of a bank robbery in San Salvador (Popkin, 1994). The
the drop in coffee prices on fiscal revenues. PN was disbanded on December 31, 1994 and its facilities
turned over to the PNC in mid-January 1995.
38. In 1993. the Salvadoran government achieved the
majority of fiscal targets specified in yet another stand-by 43. Proceso (El Salvador), February 1, 1995.
arrangement with the IMF, this one also supported by the
World Bank and USAID. The tax-to-GDP ratio, for example, 44. See Collier (1994) for evidence linking rising crime
rose to 9.3%. the highest achieved during the government’s rates in some districts of post-civil war Uganda with land-
term in office. The NFPS and central government deficits lessness of excombatants.
were reduced to 3.9% and 1.4%of GDP, respectively, and
NFPS current savings improved compared to 1992. 45. Various studies have concluded that given the
prospects for economic growth over the next few years and
39. Although the “peace dividend” has yet to materialize the changes in the tax system, it is feasible to raise tax rev-
fully, there has been a notable shift in the composition of enues as a fraction of GDP by between 0.5% and 1% each
government expenditures. Since 1991 the defense budget has year for the remainder of the century, resulting in a tax ratio
declined in real terms and as a proportion of GDP; since 1993 of 14% by the year 1999. Yet the government and FUSADES
the defense budget has been frozen in nominal terms at 866.5 have projected a tax ratio of only 10 to 11%. In addition to
million colones (roughly $100 million). This has been vigorous implementation of existing tax reforms, the tax
accompanied by an increase in allocations for the social sec- ratio could be raised by further taxes on the nonproductive
tors and for activities related to the strengthening of democ- transactions of high-income individuals, such as purchases
ratic institutions. Further progress in these directions is criti- of luxury goods and high-value property transfers, which
cal for the consolidation of the peace. would also improve the distributional incidence of the tax
system.
40. A US State Department official argues that the early
deployment of the PNC, despite inadequate training and 46. Indeed during the 1994 electoral campaign all the pres-
equipment, was important to capitalize on the euphoria of the idential candidates - including Dr Armando Calder6n Sol,
signing of the Accords (interview, December 1994). who won the election - signed a document drawn up by
UNICEF in which they agreed to raise the tax ratio to around
41. The issue was complicated by high and rising levels of 15% during 1994-99 in order to be able to increase social
crime, attributed by many to excombatants of both sides, spending.
which led to an agreement in December 1992 to increase

REFERENCES

Acevedo, C., D. Barry and H. Rosa, “El Salvador’s agricul- Associated Press, “U.S. to ax Salvadoran program,” wire
tural sector: Macroeconomic policy, agrarian change, story, (November 28, 1994).
and the environment,” World Development, Vol. 23, BancoCentral de Reserva (BCR), Memoria annual de
(1995), pp. 2153-2172. labores (San Salvador: BCR, 1989).
Asociacion National de Empresa Privada (ANEP), Belt, J. and A. Lard6 de Palomo, “El Salvador: Transition
“Reflexiones sobre la intermediaci6n y politica towards peace and participatory deveIopment,” Mimeo
financiera,” Chidad Empresarial, (July-August, 1993). (San Salvador: USAID/El Salvador, October 25.1994).
Asociacion National de Empresa Privada (ANEP), “Tres Boyce, J., ‘External assistance and the peace process in El
aiios de gesti6n macroecomjmica: logros y dificultades” Salvador,” World Development, Vol. 23 (1995), pp.
Rev&a Unidad Empresarial (May-June 1992). 2101-2116.
2098 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

CENITEC, “Propuesta de un programa econ&ico-social de International Monetary Fund (IMF), “El Salvador - Recent
consenso para El Salvador,” PoUtica Econdmica, No. 17 economic developments,” IMF Staff Country Report No.
(1993). 9400 (Washington, DC: IMF, November 1994b).
Collier, P., “Demobilization and insecurity: A study in the International Monetary Fund (IMF), “El Salvador - Staff
economics of the transition from war to peace,” Journal report for the 1991 Article IV Consultation and Request
of International Development, Vol. 6, No. 3 (1994), pp. for Stand-By Arrangement,” Mimeo, limited distribution
343-351. document (Washington, DC: IMF, November, 1991a).
Comision Economica para America Latina (CEPAL), “El International Monetary Fund (IMF),‘The Fund and poverty
impact0 econ6mico y social de las migraciones en issues: A progress report,” Development Issues,
Centroamkica,” Estudios e Infonnes de la CEPAl Presentations to the 39th Meeting of the Development
(Santiago, Chile: CEPAL, 1993). Committee, Development Committee Pamphlet No. 26
Corden, M., “Booming sector and Dutch disease economics: (Washington, DC: IMF, 1991b). pp. 29-34.
Survey and consolidation,” Oxford Economic Papers Johnson, K., “Between revolution and democracy: Business
(1984). elites and the state in El Salvador during the 1980s” Ph.D.
Creative Associates International, Inc., “Program options for dissertation (New Orleans: Tulane University, 1993).
reintegrating ex-combatants into civilian life,” Jones, E. and L. Taylor, “Evaluaci6n de la
Consultant’s report submitted to USAID/El Salvador, restauraci6nkconstrucci6n de la infraestructura para el
Contract No. 519-02810-C-00-1014-00 (San Salvador: Plan de Recuperacidn National de1 Gobiemo de El
USAID/EI Salvador, April 26,199l). Salvador. volumen I., informe narrative,” Consultants’
de Soto, A. and G. de1 Castillo, “Obstacles to peacebuild- report to USAID (Washington, DC: Development
ing,” Foreign Policy, Vol. 94 (Spring, 1994ai pp. 69-83. Associates, Inc., September, 1991a).
de Soto, A. and G. de1 Castillo. “El Salvador: Still not a suc- Jones, E. and L. Taylor, “Infrastructure Restoration/
cess story,” Mimeo (June 1994b). Reconstruction Assessment for the Government of El
El Salvador Information Project, “Summary of concerns,” Salvador National Recovery Plan, 1991. Volume II,
Electronic publication (February 25, 1995). Appendices,” Consultants’ report to USAID
Funkhouser, E., “Mass emigration, remittances, and eco- (Washington, DC: Development Associates, Inc.,
nomic adjustment: The case of El Salvador in the 1980s” September, 1991b).
Paper presented at the National Bureau of Economic Karl, T. L., “El Salvador’s negotiated revolution,” Foreign
Research Conference on Immigration (Cat&n, Mexico: Affairs, Vol. 71, No. 2 (1992). pp. 147-164.
January 16, 1990). Mpez, J. R. and M. A. Seligson, “Remittances and small
Fundacion Salvadorena para el Desarrollo Economico y business development in El Salvador,” Report prepared
Social (FUSADES), “Mattes econ6mico.” La Prensa for the Commission for the Study of International
Grdfica (February 9,1993). Migration and Cooperative Economic Development (San
Gallagher, M., “Reforma tributaria amplia en El Salvador,” Salvador: October, 1989).
Revista Econbmica y Social (San Salvador: UCA, MCndez G., J. C. Abrego and L. Abrego, “Estudio de1
1993). Sistema tributario y arancelario de El Salvador,” Mimeo
General Accounting Office (GAO), El Salvador: (San Salvador: April, 1994).
Implementation of Post-War Programs Slower than Ministerio de Planificacion y Coordination del Desarrollo
Expected, Report to the Chairman, Subcommittee on Economico y Social, nd. (date inferred: 1992d),
Western Hemispheric Affairs, Committee on Foreign “Programa de Asistencia Tecnica, Plan de
Affairs, House of Representatives, GAO/NSIAD-94-10 Reconstruction National” (San Salvador: MIPLAN,
(Washington, DC: GAO, January, 1994). March 1992).
General Accounting Office (GAO), Foreign Assistance U.S. Ministerio de Planiticacion y Coordination de Desarrollo
Support for Caribbean Basin Assembly Industries Economico y Social (MIPLAN), “Plan de recuperaci6n
(Washington, DC: GAO, 1993). econ6mica y social national, volumen 1” (San Salvador,
Gonzalez Orellana, M. “Tipo de cambio y desarrollo September, 1991a).
econ6mico en El Salvador,” Mimeo (San Salvador: Ministerio de Planificacion y Coordination de Desarrollo
FUSADES, 1994). Economico y Social (MIPLAN), “Marco global de1 plan
Harberger, A. C., “Las exportaciones y el tipo de cambio real de recuperation econ6mica y social national (San
en El Salvador,” Mimeo (San Salvador: FUSADES, Salvador, August 7, 1991b).
October, 1993). Ministerio de Planitication y Coordinaction de Desarrollo
Hinds, M., “El Regimen de Cambio. Memorandum para Economico y Social (MIPLAN), “Plan de reconstrucci6n
Roberto Orella&, Presidente, BCR,” Mimeo (San national, versidn preliminar revisada, volumen 1” (San
Salvador; FUSADES. 5 de Enero. 1994). Salvador, November, 1991~).
Inter-American Development Bank ‘(IDB), “El Salvador: Ministerio de Planiticacion y Coordination de Desarrollo
Informe socioeconbmic,” Informe No. DES-13 Economico y Social (MIPLAN), “The Government’s
(Washington, DC: IDB, June 1993). Economic and Social Program, 1989-1994,” Report to
International Monetary Fund, International Financial the First Consultative Group Meeting (Paris: May 15-16,
Statistics (Washington, DC: IMF, various years). 1991d).
International Monetarv Fund (IMF). “El Salvador - Staff Ministry of Planning and Coordination of Economic and
report for the 1994Article IV Consultation and Midterm Social Development (MIPLAN), “Consolidating the
Review Under the Stand-By Arrangement,” Limited dis- peace through national reconstruction and poverty allevi-
tribution document (Washington, DC: IMF, September, ation: Report to the Consultative Group meeting” (San
1994a). Salvador: MIPLAN, April 1,1993a).
MACROECONOMIC POLICY AND THE SALVADORAN PEACE ACCORDS 2099

Ministry of Planing and Coordination of Economic and Studies in Comparative International Development, Vol.
Social Development (MIPLAN), “Priority technical 30, No. 1(May 1995).
assistance requirements” (San Salvador: MIPLAN, April Stanley, W., Risking Failure: The Problems and Promise of
1,1993b). the New Civilian Police Force in El Salvador
Ministry of Planning and Coordination of Economic and (Cambridge and Washington, DC: Hemisphere
Social Development (MIPLAN), “National reconstruc- Initiatives and Washington Office on Latin America,
tion plan: Report to the Consultative Group meeting” 1993).
(San Salvador: MIPLAN, March 1992~). United Nations Development Programme (UNDP),
Ministry of Planning and Coordination of Economic and “Illustrated annual report, 1993” (San Salvador: UNDP
Social Development (MIPLAN), “Democratic strength- El Salvador Field Office, January 1994).
ening program” (San Salvador: MIPLAN, March United Nations Development Programme (UNDP).
1992b). Launching New Protagonists in Salvadoran Agriculture:
Montes, S., El Salvador: 1987: Salvadorerios refugiados The Agricultural Training Programmefor Ex-Combatants
en Estados Unidos (San Salvador: Insituto de of the FMLN (San Salvador: UNDP, December, 1993).
Investigaciones, Universidad Centroamericana, United Nations General Assembly (UNGA), “Report of the
1987). Secretary General to the General Assembly” (New York:
Munck, G., “Beyond electoralism in El Salvador: Conflict UNGA, October 2 1, 1994).
resolution through negotiated compromise,” Third United Nations Security Council (UNSC), “Letter dated 20
World Quarterly, Vol. 14, No. 1 (1993), pp. 75-93. March 1994 from the Secretary General Addressed to the
Murray, K., E. Coletti and J. Spence, Rescuing President of the Security Council.” S/1994/361 (New
Reconsfrucfion (Boston; Hemisphere Initiatives, York: UNSC, March 30 1994a).
1994). United Nations Security Council (UNSC), “Report of the
Orellana Merlos, C., “Migracibn y remesas: una evaluation Secretary-General on the United Nations Observer
de su impact0 en la economia salvadorena,” Politica Mission in El Salvador,” S/1994/1000 (New York:
Econdmica, Vol. 1, No. 11 (1992), pp. 2-23. UNSC, August 26, 1994b).
Paus, E., “Exports and the consolidation of peace in El United Nations Security Council (UNSC), “Report of the
Salvador,” World Development, Vol. 23, No. 12 (1995), Secretary-General on the United Nations Observer
this issue. Mission in El Salvador,” S/1994/1212 (New York:
Popkin, M., Justice Delayed: The Slow Pace of Judicial UNSC, October 3 1, 1994~).
Reform in El Salvador (Washington, DC and Boston: United States Agency for International Development
Washington Office on Latin America and Hemisphere (USAID), “El Salvador Action Plan FY-199596” (San
Initiatives, 1994). Salvador: USAID/El Salvador, 1994a).
Rivera Campos, R., “Los Determinantes Financieros y No United States Agency for International Development
Financieros de la Inversibn,” Mimeo (San Salvador: (USAID), “FY 1994 ESF Modernization of the State
January, 1994). Program Assistance Approval Document” (San
Rosa, H., “El Banco Mundial y el future de1 ajuste estruc- Salvador: USAID/EI Salvador, 1994b).
tural en El Salvador,” Prisma Boletin (San Salvador: United States Agency for International Development
PRISMA, December 3-4,1993). (USAID), “FY 1993 ESF Economic and Democratic
Secretaria de Reconstruction National (SRN), “Plan de Reform Program. Program Assistance Approval
Reconstrucci6n National (Fase de Contingencia)” (San Document” (San Salvador: USAID/EI Salvador, 1993).
Salvador: February, 1992). Vickers, G., “El Salvador: A Negotiated Revolution,” Report
Segovia, A., “La economia polftica de1 ajuste en una on the Americas (North American Congress on Latin
economia pequeiia: la experiencia de El Salvador,” America) Vol. 25, No. 5 (1992).
Mimeo (1994a). Washington, Office on Latin America (WOLA), “Recent
Segovia, A., “La implementacidn de 10s acuerdoes de paz y setbacks in the police transition,” El Salvador Peace
las reformas econ6micas en El Salvador,” Mimeo (San Plan Update, No. 3 (1994).
Salvador, June 1994b). Weiss Fagen, P., “El Salvador: Lessons in peace consolida-
Segovia, A., “La privatizaci6n en El Salvador: avarices y tion,” in T. Farer (Ed.), Beyond Sovereignty: Collectively
estado actual de la discusibn,” Mimeo (San Salvador: Defending Democracy in the Americas (Baltimore, MD:
Fundaci6n Ebert, 1994~). Johns Hopkins Press, 1995).
Siri, G. and P. Abelardo Delgado, “Us0 productive de las Wood, E., “Agrarian social relations and democratization:
remesas familiares en El Salvador,” Mimeo (San The negotiated resolution of the Civil War in El
Salvador: FUSADES, January, 1995). Salvador,” PhD Dissertation (Stanford, CA: Stanford
Spence, J., G. Vickers and D. Dye, The Salvadoran Peace University, 1995).
Accords and Democratization: A Three Year Progress World Bank, “El Salvador: The challenge of poverty allevia-
Report and Recommendations (Cambridge: Hemisphere tion,” Report No. 12315-ES (Washington, DC: World
Initiatives, 1995). Bank, June 9,1994).
Sorto, F., “El estado actual de la reforma fmanciera en El World Bank, The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and
Salvador y sus perspectivas,” Mimeo (San Salvador: 1995). Public Policy (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1993).
Sorto, F. and A. Segovia, “La reforma tinanciera de ARENA: World Bank, “El Salvador: SAL II Identification Mission
LHacia d&de se dirige la privatizaci6n de la Banca?,” Aide-M&moire,” Mimeo (Washington, DC: World Bank,
Politica Econdmica (CENJTEC) No. 12 (1992). June 11, 1992).
Stanley, W., “International tutelage and domestic political World Bank, Adjustment Lending: An Evaluation of Ten
will: Lessons from El Salvador’s civilian police project,” Years (Washington, DC: World Bank, 1988).

Você também pode gostar