Você está na página 1de 24

J. Eng. Technol. Manage.

21 (2004) 191–214

Equity alliances, stages of product development,


and alliance instability
Paul E. Bierly III a,∗ , Joseph E. Coombs b,1
a College of Business, James Madison University, MSC 0205, Harrisonburg, VA 22807, USA
b Robins School of Business, University of Richmond, Richmond, VA 23173, USA

Abstract
The purpose of this research is to analyze the stability of strategic alliances initiated at different
stages of the new product development process and to determine the appropriateness of different
governance structures (e.g., joint ventures, minority equity alliances, non-equity alliances). Specif-
ically, we argue that the minority equity form of alliance is an inherently unstable structure for
product development partnerships. Key findings of this study are: (a) minority equity alliances are
more likely to be terminated within 5 years than joint ventures and non-equity alliances, (b) alliances
are more likely to be terminated if they are initiated in the early and late stages of product develop-
ment and less likely to be terminated if they are initiated in the mid-stages of product development,
and (c) alliances are more likely to become acquisitions if they are initiated in the mid-stages of
product development and less likely to become acquisitions if they are initiated in the early and late
stages of product development.
© 2004 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Keywords: Alliance instability; Minority equity alliances; New product development

1. Introduction

Partnerships and a network type of structure can help a firm maintain a superior compet-
itive position in dynamic environments (Hagedoorn, 1993; Powell et al., 1996). Firms can
focus on those tasks that they do well (i.e., core competencies) and rely on partners in other
areas (Hamel and Prahalad, 1994). Partners can be valuable in helping to understand the
changing rules of the game. They also can improve a firm’s strategic flexibility since the
firm commits fewer resources to each of the different technologies and activities. Moreover,
∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 540 568 3236; fax: +1 540 568 2754.

E-mail addresses: bierlype@jmu.edu (P.E. Bierly III), jcoombs@richmond.edu (J.E. Coombs).


1 Tel.: +1 804 287 6631; fax: +1 804 289 8878.

0923-4748/$ – see front matter © 2004 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jengtecman.2004.05.001
192 P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214

strategic alliances provide firms with new sources of competitive advantage, such as access
to complementary technologies, access to new markets, and risk reduction (Hagedoorn,
1993). Interfirm cooperation may also allow industry incumbents to adapt to radical tech-
nological change (Rothaermel, 2001). Koza and Lewin (1998) describe alliances as having
either exploitation or exploration objectives.
Alliances with exploration objectives aim to reduce information asymmetries and facil-
itate the investigation of new opportunities. They are pursued to provide a framework for
learning, for engaging in innovation and basic research, and for building new capabilities.
Alliances formed to establish a market position have exploitation objectives, which involve
the motive to exploit an existing capability. They are pursued to increase the productivity of
capital and assets, engage in cost-reduction, refine existing capabilities and technologies,
and to gain access to resources to compete in a particular market, such as local market
knowledge, distribution systems, and regulatory policies.
As expected, the increased importance and use of strategic alliances over the last two
decades has prompted a large amount of research in this area. However, most of this re-
search has focused on issues associated with the alliance’s initial formation and only a few
researchers have studied alliance evolution over time (Doz, 1996; Hagedoorn and Sadowski,
1999; Park and Russo, 1996). This stream of research is important because alliance gover-
nance can change dramatically for several reasons. First, partners’ strengths and bargaining
power may change over time, changing the alliance’s dynamics. Second, one partner may
learn from the other at a faster rate thereby devaluing the other partner’s future contribution
(Hamel, 1991; Doz, 1996). Third, the competitive environment can change, requiring a shift
in alliance focus. For example, the development of a new technology, inside or outside the
partner organizations, can force the alliance partners to redirect their future research efforts.
Finally, the alliance’s past performance may cause governance instability, whether the al-
liance was exceptionally successful or unsuccessful. When alliance performance is better
than expected, one partner may try to increase its stake, possibly to the extent of acquiring
its partner (Bleeke and Ernst, 1995). When performance is worse than expected, a partner
may reduce its commitment to limit future risk, or it may increase its control in an attempt
to remedy past problems.
In this paper, we intend to determine what circumstances cause strategic alliance gov-
ernance to be less stable. Alliance governance refers to the mode of control the partners
establish through either some form of ownership or formal contract. Specifically, we analyze
the likelihood of the following governance changes throughout the new product develop-
ment process: (1) the alliance turning into an acquisition, (2) the alliance being terminated,
or (3) a major change to the alliance’s governance structure. While alliance instability has
been the subject of research as a determinant of alliance outcomes (Blodgett, 1992; Oxley,
1997; Park and Russo, 1996; Park and Ungson, 1997; Yan and Zeng, 1999), little is known
about factors that promote or limit instability.
This article aims to reduce this literature gap by analyzing the stability of strategic al-
liances initiated at different stages of the new product development process and deter-
mining the appropriateness of different governance structures. We argue that the minority
equity form of alliance is an inherently unstable structure for product development partner-
ships. Further, by focusing on instability, rather than only alliance failure (Hagedoorn and
Sadowski, 1999; Park and Russo, 1996; Park and Ungson, 1997), this research builds upon
P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214 193

recent work in the field (Blodgett, 1992; Dussauge et al., 2000; Kogut, 1989) that takes a
broader view of alliance outcomes while fully realizing that a governance change does not
necessarily imply failure of an alliance. Several factors increasing or decreasing alliance
uncertainty that other researchers have investigated are included in our study as control
variables: partner size, scope of alliance, nationality of partners, financial flexibility, and
previous alliance experience.
We test our research questions by examining a large number of alliances in the pharma-
ceutical industry, where partnerships have become increasingly important in the successful
integration of knowledge and the development of new products (Barley et al., 1992; Bierly
and Chakrabarti, 1996a; Henderson and Cockburn, 1994; Powell, 1998; Rothaermel, 2001).
Each alliance in this study involves a large pharmaceutical firm, which we designate the
study’s focal firm. The focal firms’ partners range dramatically in size from very small
biotechnology firms to large pharmaceutical or chemical firms.

2. The pharmaceutical industry

The pharmaceutical industry has three separate segments: ethical (prescription) drugs,
over-the-counter (OTC) drugs, and generic drugs. All of the focal firms in this study focus
primarily on ethical drugs. The pharmaceutical industry is characterized by extraordinarily
high R&D expenditures, extremely long new product development times, high marketing
costs and very high profits. R&D intensity is higher in the pharmaceutical industry than
any other industry and has consistently risen over the last two decades, resulting in the
industry now spending more than US$ 40 billion a year on R&D. A recent study by DiMasi
(2001) determined that the average cost to develop a new prescription drug is US$ 802
million (2000 dollars). A similar study by the same research group in 1991 determined
the average cost was US$ 318 million (2000 dollars). Part of the reason for this increased
development cost is that pharmaceutical firms have shifted their strategy to focus more on
radically new drugs with large potential payoffs, rather than developing “me-too” drugs
that imitate competitors’ successful products. Cost containment efforts and pressure from
health maintenance organizations (HMOs) and pharmacy benefit managers (PBMs) have
made imitation drugs less attractive.
The lengthy development and approval process also contributes to the higher cost. It
usually takes 10–15 years to develop a new drug and get approval by the FDA in the US
(DiMasi, 2001). The initial discovery stage may take up to 5 years, and only 1 out of 5000
compounds initially screened end up being commercialized. The testing stage includes four
distinct phases. First, preclinical testing, which lasts 3–4 years, is conducted on animals
to determine the existence of any major toxic effects. Second, Phase I clinical testing,
which lasts about 1–2 years, is conducted on 20–80 healthy human volunteers to determine
safety and dosage. Third, Phase II clinical testing, which lasts 2–3 years, is conducted on
100–300 patient volunteers to determine the safety and efficacy of the drug. Fourth, Phase
III clinical testing, which lasts 3–4 years, is conducted on 1000–5000 patients to monitor
the long-term effects of the drug. The cost of clinical testing has increased substantially
because of the difficulty in recruiting patients and the increased focus on developing drugs
to treat chronic and degenerative diseases (DiMasi, 2001). After all of the clinical tests are
194 P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214

complete, the FDA reviews the new drug application for approval, which can take over a
year.
Recently, a dramatic change occurred in the approach used by organizations to discover
new drugs. No longer do pharmaceutical companies, relying on their expertise in chemistry
and pharmacology, use random screening to discover an effective new drug. Almost all
drugs today are discovered by following a rational drug design, an approach that relies on
the structural analysis of target molecules and the deliberate design of agents that affect their
function. However, rational drug design requires the integration of knowledge from many
different disciplines, including molecular biologists, biochemists, physiologists, chemists,
pharmacologists and experts in very specialized fields related to the specific drug. In other
words, successful drug design requires the combination of the traditional knowledge base
of pharmaceutical companies with the knowledge base of biotechnology companies, where
biotechnology companies either provide intermediary products to facilitate the process or
assist in the development of the end product.
From the perspective of the established pharmaceutical companies, biotechnology can
be characterized as a competence-destroying innovation, since the more abstract and tacit
knowledge base associated with biotechnology is markedly different than the knowledge
base of most traditional pharmaceutical companies (Powell et al., 1996; Zucker and Darby,
1997). Since no one company can excel at all of these different knowledge areas, phar-
maceutical firms must rely more on strategic alliances to gain access to and integrate the
knowledge from these different fields (Henderson and Cockburn, 1994; Powell et al., 1996;
Barley et al., 1992). Additionally, pharmaceutical companies use a large number of market-
ing alliances to assist in the fast and comprehensive distribution of their drugs worldwide.
Speed to market is critical because patent protection, and hence large profit margins, is only
guaranteed for a limited period.
However, the pharmaceutical industry is also a very profitable industry because of its
high entry barriers, effectiveness of patents, and strong bargaining power. According to
2002 Fortune 500 magazine, the pharmaceutical industry was the most profitable industry
in the US, as measured by return on sales (18.5%), return on assets (16.3%), and return
on shareholders’ equity (33.2%). The key to success in this industry is successful product
development, especially the creation of new “blockbuster” drugs, which have revenues of
more than US$ 1 billion a year. Almost all pharmaceutical companies rely on a large network
of partnerships to facilitate the product development process.

3. Theoretical framework and relevant literature

3.1. Alliance governance structure

Strategic alliances can be defined as all “partnerships between firms whereby their re-
sources, capabilities, and core competencies are combined to pursue mutual interests in
developing, manufacturing, or distributing goods or services” (Hitt et al., 1997, p. 314).
Almost all past research on the governance structures of strategic alliances has classified
alliances into two categories in some manner: equity and non-equity alliances (Gulati, 1995;
Hagedoorn, 1993; Hagedoorn and Narula, 1996; Kale et al., 2000; Mowery et al., 1996;
P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214 195

Pisano, 1989; Rothaermel, 2001) or joint venture and non-joint venture (Kent, 1991; Kogut,
1988). Using simplified dichotomous measures such as these is a major weakness in the
literature because firms use three distinct forms of governance structure: joint ventures,
equity, and non-equity (contractual) alliances (Barney, 2002; Das and Teng, 1998). Each of
these three forms is significantly different from the others concerning control, commitment,
flexibility, knowledge transfer and transaction costs.

3.1.1. Non-equity alliances


Non-equity alliances are contractual alliances that do not include an equity position.
This governance mode provides greater partner flexibility, less commitment, and is usu-
ally shorter-term (Hagedoorn, 1993; Hagedoorn and Narula, 1996). Non-equity alliances
are very efficient for explicit, simple arrangements and can usually be negotiated rapidly
(Gulati, 1995). However, when the alliance involves uncertainty associated with the transfer
and integration of intangible and tacit knowledge, non-equity alliances often fail because
contracts cannot be written that provide for adequate control within the partnership (Kogut,
1988; Hennart, 1988). Additionally, non-equity alliances may provide little disincentive for
partners to cheat since firms usually do not make large alliance-specific investments and it
is difficult to align the interests of the two partners (Williamson, 1975). Since hierarchical
and ownership control are not feasible, rigid contractual control is the only way firms can
manage for contingencies and deter opportunism, which usually coincides with lower levels
of trust (Das and Teng, 1998). However, if firms have worked together in prior alliances,
trust may already be established and may also act as a form of control (Gulati, 1995; Kogut,
1989).

3.1.2. Joint ventures


Joint ventures are arrangements where a new, separate entity is created by the combination
of the resources of the two or more parent companies (Inkpen and Beamish, 1997). Thus,
a major difference between joint ventures and the other two forms of strategic alliances is
that the object of control is not only the partner but also the new joint venture company
(Das and Teng, 1998). Usually, the joint venture has its own board of directors, with repre-
sentatives from both partners, and most top managers were previously employed by one of
the parent firms. Joint ventures are the most effective mode of governance for transferring
and integrating tacit knowledge since many employees from both of the companies are now
working together (Hennart, 1988; Inkpen, 1996; Kogut, 1988; Mowery et al., 1996). They
are communicating frequently and directly and are able to share experiences. Joint ven-
tures are also effective at aligning the strategic goals of partners to minimize opportunism
(Kogut, 1988; Pisano, 1989). A “mutual hostage” situation is created since both partners
have made substantial alliance-specific investments and are dependent on the performance
of the other (Kogut, 1988; Williamson, 1975, 1991). This commitment by both firms to the
joint venture causes them to view joint ventures as a long-term relationship (Kogut, 1988;
Hennart, 1988).
However, joint ventures, which involve a high degree of commitment, limit firms’ strate-
gic flexibility (Hagedoorn, 1993). To dissolve a joint venture can be a complex and lengthy
process, resulting in high exit costs. The large alliance-specific investments often cannot
be recovered for use elsewhere. There also is the threat that the partners will have different
196 P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214

learning rates such that one firm’s competitive advantage may erode as critical tacit knowl-
edge is leaked (Hamel, 1991; Beamish and Banks, 1987; Kogut, 1988). Of all the forms of
strategic alliances, joint ventures are the most likely to have unintended knowledge trans-
fer since employees from both firms are working so close together. Additionally, many of
these arrangements fail because of management problems, such as conflicting cultures and
different control systems (Ohmae, 1989). Finally, joint ventures may be “trojan horse” in-
vestments by one of the firms that have the hidden intention of acquiring its partner (Bleeke
and Ernst, 1995). However, empirical research by Hagedoorn and Sadowski (1999) has
determined that this actually occurs infrequently.

3.1.3. Minority equity alliances


Equity alliances are arrangements where contractual agreements are supplemented with
an equity purchase by one or both partners in the other partner. Typically, a larger firm, such
as a pharmaceutical firm, takes an equity position in the smaller firm, such as a biotechnology
firm. With this type of direct equity position, no new separate entity is formed. The equity
position usually includes a position or two on the other firm’s board of directors. This type
of governance structure has been described as a favorable form that has the advantages of
both of the other two forms (Pisano, 1989). As compared to non-equity alliances, the firm
taking the equity position has better access to information, can better monitor performance,
and has more control. Equity alliances are structured for a longer time period and require
more commitment, which is reassuring to the smaller firm. As compared to joint ventures,
equity alliances involve more flexibility, and they do not involve the management challenges
associated with forming a third separate entity, such as integrating organizational cultures
and systems.
However, this positive bias toward equity alliances can be misleading. Equity alliances
may be unstable alliance structures that have significant disadvantages in addition to their
frequently stated advantages. In practice, equity alliances are not used at all in most indus-
tries and are used frequently in very few industries, most notably the pharmaceutical and
biotechnology industries. Institutional forces may have legitimated these types of alliances
in certain industries, but little research has been conducted to determine whether this gov-
ernance structure is effective. The positive bias toward equity alliances focuses on their
advantages relative to non-equity alliances and joint ventures, but each advantage is also
associated with a disadvantage.
The advantages, relative to joint ventures, come at the cost of more difficulty in trans-
ferring and integrating knowledge, less commitment, and lower levels of trust (Das and
Teng, 1998). Even though individuals from equity alliance partners may interact on a fre-
quently regular basis, this communication is not as rich as employees working together in
a joint venture; also, these interactions are usually at a higher, strategic level in the orga-
nization, not at the lower, operational levels that are critical to the success of transferring
more tacit knowledge. Partner commitment is usually higher for joint ventures than equity
alliances because joint ventures involve more alliance-specific investments and higher inter-
firm embeddedness (Das and Teng, 1998), creating more of an environment for a long-term
relationship. The advantages of equity alliances, relative to non-equity alliances, come
at the cost of less flexibility and increased possibilities for opportunism (Das and Teng,
1998).
P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214 197

In addition, an equity alliance creates a “single hostage” position, which is not stable and
makes trust among partners difficult. Joint ventures are effective at aligning the strategic
goals of partners to minimize opportunism by creating a “mutual hostage” situation, where
both partners have made substantial alliance-specific investments and are dependent on the
performance of the other (Williamson, 1975, 1991; Kogut, 1988). This commitment by both
firms to the joint venture causes them to view joint ventures as a long-term relationship
(Kogut, 1988; Hennart, 1988) and is associated with more trust and confidence in the
relationship (Das and Teng, 1998). However, in an equity alliance, only one firm has made
a substantial alliance-specific investment, and that firm is held in a “single hostage” position
relative to the other, usually smaller firm.2 This will help align the incentives of the larger,
investing firm with the smaller firm and reduce opportunism by the larger firm, but it is not
necessarily reducing opportunism by the smaller firm.
This can be illustrated with the example of a pharmaceutical company taking an equity
position in a biotechnology firm. The financial support the biotechnology firm receives may
be what it needs to remain viable for an extended period of time, but the tacit knowledge
associated with its research may be difficult to transfer back to the large pharmaceutical
company. After the biotechnology firm has used the investment from the pharmaceutical
company, the smaller firm may hold the larger firm hostage. It no longer has incentive to
act in the best interest of the pharmaceutical firm and the monitoring ability of a member
of the board of directors may not be as effective as expected. Often the opportunism by the
small firm is not a deliberate malicious act in the form of direct cheating the larger firm, but
in a more indirect manner.
For example, a small biotechnology firm in such a situation may shift the focus of its
R&D to areas more promising to itself and less promising to the larger pharmaceutical
company, or it may not fully assist in the knowledge transfer process concerning tacit,
complex knowledge that would require extensive resources. Actually, the link with the
pharmaceutical firm may hinder the biotechnology firm’s performance in that it may limit
its ability to further develop partnerships with other firms, who may be competitors, or
partners of competitors, of the investing pharmaceutical firm. If the alliance is terminated,
the individuals working at the biotechnology firm maintain control of the newly developed
tacit knowledge, which may have substantial value elsewhere.
Equity alliances are also less stable than the other governance forms because each
partner’s roles and expected contributions are less defined. An equity alliance is often
used precisely because there is too much ambiguity associated with a partnership such that
a contractual alliance could not provide adequate control. However, we argue that using an
equity alliance does not necessarily provide the additional control needed. The increased
control is primarily based on the investing firm being granted a position on the board of
directors, which should provide a greater understanding of the partner’s inner workings.
However, this representative may be allowed to observe the partner’s top management
team’s decision-making process, but their influence in decision-making is usually limited.

2 This argument of a “single hostage” position assumes that the equity alliance only involves one firm taking an

equity position in the other. If the equity alliance includes both partners taking an equity position in each other,
then a more stable “mutual hostage” position is created. However, these types of situations are rare, especially in
the pharmaceutical industry.
198 P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214

If, over time, the equity alliance is not producing the desired results, the company will feel a
strong responsibility to change the governance structure. Part of this feeling of responsibility
may be a justification for past investments. Due to higher levels of commitment and famil-
iarity, equity alliances are more likely to be adjusted over time or become an acquisition
than other forms of alliances. Occasionally, firms enter into equity alliances with ulterior
motives, such as the long-term goal of acquiring the partner. They follow this sequential
path to acquisition to minimize their initial investment costs and to provide a trial period to
see how the culture, systems, and structures will be able to be integrated (Bleeke and Ernst,
1995).
Equity alliances tend to be less stable, when compared specifically to joint ventures,
for an additional reason. Equity alliances are a more flexible mode of governance than
joint ventures and can be rather easily adjusted. Joint ventures are usually established for
the long run and an attempt to change the governance arrangement may signal reduced
trust in a partner; thus, parent companies often use a “hands off” management style. In
summary, we argue that equity alliances are more unstable than other forms of alliance
governance structures, and the changes to the alliance structure may be in the form of
alliance termination, alliance amendment, or acquisition.

Hypothesis 1. Equity alliances are more likely than non-equity alliances and joint ventures
to experience governance changes after their initial formation.

Hypothesis 1a. Equity alliances are more likely to be amended than non-equity or joint
ventures.

Hypothesis 1b. Equity alliances are more likely to be terminated than non-equity or joint
ventures.

Hypothesis 1c. Equity alliances are more likely to become an acquisition than non-equity
or joint ventures.

3.2. Product development stage

Recent work on alliance instability has focused on the pattern of interdependence between
partners (Dussauge et al., 2000; Park and Russo, 1996), including the development stage of
the alliance’s main product. The stage at which a strategic alliance is initiated will affect the
likelihood that the alliance will become unstable such that alliances formed during the early
stages of a product’s development are less stable. During earlier stages of development,
the technology associated with the product is usually based more on basic than applied
science, the knowledge is usually more tacit and less detailed, there is more uncertainty
associated with development, and the knowledge is less dispersed throughout the scientific
community (Almeida and Kogut, 1997). Alliances formed in the earlier development stages
involve higher risk.
However, forming alliances in the earlier development stages also enables a better flow of
knowledge and a better opportunity for learning. A firm involved in the development of new
technologies from the beginning will understand the technology better in the long run, and
P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214 199

will be better able to integrate the new knowledge with its existing knowledge base. Forming
alliances in earlier product development stages shows commitment to the development of
certain capabilities and such strategic actions may have importance by either blocking direct
competitors or countering their previous moves. Thus, alliances that are formed earlier in the
product development process are more likely to experience governance changes, particularly
in the form of major amendments, because the large pharmaceutical firms know the partners
better and have already demonstrated a large degree of commitment.
Conversely, alliances formed later in the product development process are more likely to
focus on manufacturing and marketing, and less on R&D. These types of alliances usually
involve more explicit and unambiguous knowledge resulting in more stable alliances.

Hypothesis 2. A higher proportion of alliances initiated earlier in the product develop-


ment process will experience governance changes after formation, as compared to alliances
initiated later in the product development process.

Hypothesis 2a. A higher proportion of alliances initiated earlier in the product develop-
ment process will experience a major amendment after formation, as compared to alliances
initiated later in the product development process.

While we argue that in general strategic alliances are less stable early in the product
development process and more stable later, the timing of acquisitions and terminations
does not necessarily follow that general trend. Terminations are most likely to occur after
development projects reach stages where there is a major test of the project and there is
failure. For example, in the pharmaceutical industry this would be during the preclinical
trials (tests on animals), clinical trials, and Phases I, II and III tests on human volunteers.
Alliances formed after the drug discovery period, but before these tests are complete involve
gambles by the pharmaceutical company. Their intent is not to combine complementary
technologies, since the drug is already discovered. Essentially, they are betting that the drug
will be approved. They may be assisting with the approval process, or they may be acquiring
an option to manufacture and distribute the drug, if it is approved. If the drug fails any of
the tests, then it is likely the alliance will be terminated.
Terminations are less likely to occur when alliances are formed in the early stages of
the development of basic research and the initial design of a product. When alliances are
formed at these early stages, both partners know the alliance involves risk and uncertainty
and they are usually both getting involved in an alliance at this stage for long-term benefits.
Forming an alliance in the later stages of development are less likely to end in a termination
because there is less uncertainty since the product has completed the testing stages and now
more focus is on preparations for manufacturing and marketing.

Hypothesis 2b. Terminations occur less frequently when alliances are initiated in the early
and later stages of new product development, than the mid-stages (inverted U-shape rela-
tionship).

On the other hand, we propose that acquisitions are more likely to occur when alliances
are formed in the early and later stages of product development, but are less likely to occur
200 P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214

when alliances are formed during the mid-stages of product development. Alliances formed
early in the product development process, before a specific product is ready to be tested, are
often formed to either integrate two complementary technologies or combine resources in
a common technological area. While working together in these types of alliances, the two
partners can ascertain how well their cultures, structures and systems “fit” and whether an
alliance would work. Alliances formed later in the product development process involve less
uncertainty and typically focus on manufacturing and marketing the product. This type of
alliance may also lead to an acquisition as the acquiring firm looks to expand its product line;
the alliance in this situation was formed prior to the acquisition to obtain more information
about the firm being acquired so that it is properly valued and that there is a proper “fit”
between the two companies.
Alliances formed during the mid-stages of product development are less likely to lead
to acquisitions because the acquiring firm has less incentive to own the target firm in this
situation. The alliance is formed after the design is already established, so there is no need to
integrate different technologies. The alliance is formed before a final product is established
(and approved by the FDA in the case of pharmaceutical companies), so the alliance is
not used as a precursor to an acquisition because there is still a large degree of uncertainty
associated with the viability of a product. If the larger firm intends to acquire the smaller firm
in this situation, it would make sense to wait until the mid-stages of the product development
process are completed. Acquiring the partner before the drug is approved could be a major
mistake if the drug fails one of the tests. Without being able to market the new drug, the
benefits of the alliance probably would not exceed the substantial integration costs. It would
be better to maintain the flexibility of the alliance until after the drug approval.

Hypothesis 2c. Acquisitions occur more frequently when alliances are initiated in the early
and later stages of new product development, than the mid-stages (U-shape relationship).

4. Research design and measures

4.1. Sample and data

The study focuses on strategic alliances in the pharmaceutical industry from 1988 to 1994.
Our specific focus is on the behavior of 27 large pharmaceutical companies (e.g., Merck,
Eli Lilly, Ciba-Geigy) based in the US (70% of the sample), Japan (14% of the sample) and
Europe (16% of the sample). Firms that were involved in a major merger either during the
period of our study or within 5 years after the alliance, such as SmithKline Beckman and
Beecham forming SmithKline Beecham, were not included in the study. Alliances involving
these companies were not included because the merger may have influenced the decision
to either terminate or change the governance structure of previous alliances. We focus only
on large companies to control for differences due to size.
Many issues for small companies entering strategic alliances are quite different than
the issues for large companies. We designate these firms as the “focal firm” and the other
members of the alliance as the “partner firm.” The sample includes alliances with a wide
variety of partners including other pharmaceutical companies of various size and location,
P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214 201

biotechnology companies, and companies from related industries. In total, 249 alliances are
included in the sample, with the focal firm of each being one of our 27 large pharmaceutical
companies. Thus, there is some lack of independence of observations since many of the
firms have multiple alliances. The Windhover Information Inc. Pharmaceutical Strategic
Alliances database was used as the primary data source for information concerning the
alliances. Windhover is internationally respected as a leading provider of reliable databases
for the health care industry. They compile their databases from SEC documents, company
reports and extensive industry contacts. Firm-specific financial information was obtained
from COMPUSTAT.

4.2. Dependent variable

The primary dependent variable, change, builds upon previous research that has oper-
ationalized change as a major governance structure change (termination, acquisition, or
major reorganization) within the alliance (Blodgett, 1992; Dussauge et al., 2000; Killing,
1983; Lee and Beamish, 1995). This differs from research that focused solely on alliance
termination (Harrigan, 1988; Kogut, 1989, 1991; Park and Russo, 1996; Park and Ungson,
1997). This dichotomous variable is 1 when there is a major change and 0 when there is not
within a 5-year period after alliance initiation. Change is also disaggregated into its three
main components—termination, acquisition, and amendment. Dichotomous variables are
used for each of these components indicating whether or not they occur in the 5-year period
after the alliance initiation.

4.3. Independent variables

We classify strategic alliance governance structures into the three categories of joint ven-
tures, equity alliances, and non-equity alliances by using two dichotomous variables labeled
equity and joint venture. These variables are given a value of one when the alliances are
equity or joint ventures, respectively, and zero when they are not. Non-equity alliances are
those that are neither equity alliances nor joint ventures. Equity alliances include alliances
where either one or both companies have an equity stake in the other, but do not include
situations where a third separate entity is formed, which we label a joint venture. Non-equity
alliances are purely contractual alliances that do not include an equity position.
The variable representing alliance product development stage is an ordinal variable rang-
ing from 1 to 4, and is used to differentiate alliances depending on the development stage of
the primary drug involved in the alliance. The four stages we use in this study are aligned
to development stages frequently used in the industry in the following manner. The first
stage involves R&D, where a specific drug is not yet identified. The second stage, which we
broadly define as the early testing stage, includes: (a) preclinical trials, where the product is
tested in animals or in vitro trials to determine toxicity, (b) investigational new drug appli-
cation (IND) filed, (c) clinical trials, and (d) Phase I testing, where drug safety is analyzed
in human volunteers.
The third stage, which we define as the late testing stage, includes: (a) Phase II testing,
where drug efficacy is analyzed in a sample of patients, (b) Phase III testing, which includes
advanced trials to accumulate drug efficacy data, and (c) new drug application (NDA) filed.
202 P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214

The fourth stage includes: (a) the drug being registered, where the product has received FDA
approval but marketing has not yet begun, and (b) after marketing of the drug has begun.
In most cases, there is more uncertainty during the earlier R&D stages and less uncertainty
in the final stages. This is a more exacting approach than the common view of alliances
as either marketing-related or R&D-related (Dussauge et al., 2000; Kogut, 1991; Park and
Russo, 1996).

4.4. Control variables

Variables were included to control for possible confounding effects in the analyses.
A dichotomous variable separates alliances involving the development, manufacturing or
distribution of a biotechnology product from those that do not. Biotechnology products
are differentiated from other drug categories because knowledge in biotechnology tends
to be more abstract and tacit. Powell et al. (1996) claim that biotechnology represents
competence-destroying innovation because it is based on knowledge that differs signifi-
cantly from the established pharmaceutical industry’s knowledge base. Alliances involving
biotechnology products are coded as 1 while all other alliances are coded as 0.
Alliances formed between partners in the same domestic market can be expected to
experience less difficulty than alliances formed across national borders because of cultural
similarity (Lane and Beamish, 1990; Mowery et al., 1996; Yan and Zeng, 1999). Thus,
the variable domestic identifies whether or not the company and partner are from the same
country (coded as 1) or not (coded as 0). Alliances with partners from two different European
countries are classified as international, even though they are both within the same region.
Firms from societies that value long-term relationships and encourage collective respon-
sibility, such as Japan, are more likely to trust each other and have more stable relation-
ships (Park and Ungson, 1997). Considering these results and the increasing importance of
Japanese firms, especially in terms of their partnerships with US firms (Osborn and Baughn,
1990; Park and Ungson, 1997), this study follows Park and Ungson’s (1997) example and
identifies whether or not the partner firm is from Japan (coded 1) or from another coun-
try (coded 0). Park and Ungson (1997) also differentiated alliances involving a European
partner. Thus, we also control for alliances with a European partner using a dichotomous
variable that is coded 1 if the alliance involves a European company and 0 if it does not.
Previous alliance experience between partners is expected to increase the stability of al-
liances because previous relations promote reciprocity, increase trust (Gulati, 1995; Kogut,
1989) and increase social capital (Tsai and Ghoshal, 1998), thus acting as a deterrent to
opportunistic behavior. Results presented by Park and Ungson (1997) support these argu-
ments. Prior alliance experience between partners may also promote cooperation with the
expectation that future alliances may be better coordinated while bureaucratic complexity
is minimized (Park and Ungson, 1997). Previous alliance was coded as 1 if the firms had a
previous alliance and 0 if they did not during the 5 years prior to the current alliance.
The scope of an alliance has been found to be associated with both equity (as opposed to
non-equity) alliances (Pisano, 1989) and hierarchical modes of alliance governance (Oxley,
1997). Alliances of broader scope may also be expected to be more complex, have higher
levels of uncertainty, and require more coordination by the partners (Boris and Jemison,
1989). Alliance scope is measured as the number of products involved in the alliance.
P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214 203

The control variable size is a measure that represents whether the alliance partners are of
equal or different sizes (Hagedoorn and Sadowski, 1999). Size may be a critical factor in
the stability of alliances as small firms are more likely to cooperate with larger firms (Shan
and Hamilton, 1991) and smaller firms may be more vulnerable to exploitation by larger
partners (Osborn and Baughn, 1990). Further, the greater the difference in size between the
two firms, the more likely they will have different organizational structures, cultures, and
processes (Scott, 1992).
Lane and Lubatkin (1998) provided evidence that firms of different size should have other
organizational similarities to support the transfer of tacit knowledge. Size is coded as 1 if
the partner is of relatively equal size (has over US$ 1 billion of sales) and is coded as 0 if the
partner firm has less than US$ 1 billion of sales. Although it would be preferable to use a
ratio to capture size difference between alliance members, two problems inhibit this option.
First, both foreign and domestic firms are included. Financial size measures then would not
be consistent as there are differences in accounting standards in many countries. Second, a
number of alliance partners in the sample are private firms and little specific information,
such as number of employees, is available.
A control variable, financial flexibility, was used to account for the focal firm’s financial
capabilities to make a major change to the alliance. According to Bourgeois (1981), financial
flexibility, or organizational slack, allows a firm to adapt to changes in both internal strategy
and external pressures. Specifically, the focal firm would require a high level of financial
flexibility to either acquire its partner or restructure the alliance. Firms with more financial
flexibility may be more likely to simply terminate a low-performing alliance and focus
their resources on other projects. Lacking financial flexibility, firms may become locked
into alliances with little ability to change the alliance as internal and/or external conditions
change. The focal firm’s financial flexibility is measured by the ratio of total debt and
shareholder equity. This variable is also a measure of a firm’s leverage and its ability to
invest in large, long-term research projects (Aaker and Mascarenhas, 1984; Bierly and
Chakrabarti, 1996b; Cheng and Kesner, 1997). Low levels of financial flexibility have also
been shown to adversely impact R&D intensity and innovation in large multiproduct firms
(Baysinger and Hoskisson, 1989).

5. Results

Some general information describing our sample is provided in Tables 1 and 2. Table 1
provides a summary of alliances terminated, acquired, and amended when initiated at dif-
Table 1
Percentage of alliances terminated, acquired and amended when initiated at different new product development
stages
NPD stage Terminated Acquired Amended No change

(1) R&D 0.19 0.05 0.33 0.43


(2) Early trials 0.30 0.02 0.17 0.51
(3) Later trials 0.29 0.00 0.17 0.54
(4) FDA approved 0.05 0.10 0.08 0.77
204 P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214

Table 2
Percentage of alliances using an equity, non-equity and joint venture structure when initiated at different new
product development stages
NPD stage Equity Joint venture Non-equity
(1) R&D 0.28 0.01 0.71
(2) Early trials 0.21 0.08 0.72
(3) Later trials 0.24 0.02 0.73
(4) FDA approved 0.05 0.08 0.88

ferent new product development stages. Terminations and major amendments tend to occur
more often during R&D, early trials, and late trials. Acquisitions occur more often following
FDA approval. Table 2 shows the percentages of alliances using equity, non-equity, and joint
venture structures when initiated at different new product development stages. Non-equity
alliances are clearly the preferred structure accounting for 71 (R&D) to 88 (FDA approved)
percent of total alliances. Equity alliances are used primarily during R&D (28%), early tri-
als (21%), and later trials (24%) while being initiated infrequently following FDA approval
(5%). Joint ventures are the least frequently used alliances structures accounting for only
one percent of R&D alliances, eight percent of alliances during early trials, two percent of
alliances during later trials, and eight percent of alliances following FDA approval.
Descriptive statistics are presented in Table 3 and correlations are presented in Table 4. Lo-
gistic regression models are used to test hypotheses associated with dichotomous dependent
variables. The chi-square statistic is used to test the significance of each logistic regression
model. Independent variable logistic coefficient significance is used to test our hypotheses.

Table 3
Descriptive statisticsa
Mean Standard deviation

(1) Change 0.46 N/A


(2) Terminate 0.21 N/A
(3) Acquisition 0.04 N/A
(4) Amend 0.22 N/A
(5) Equity 0.22 N/A
(6) Joint venture 0.04 N/A
(7) Biotechnology 0.47 N/A
(8) Domestic 0.56 N/A
(9) Japan partner 0.02 N/A
(10) European partner 0.08 N/A
(11) NPD stage 2.06 1.13
(12) Financial flexibility 50.63 43.93
(13) Partner size 0.10 N/A
(14) Previous alliance 0.16 N/A
(15) Scope 1.40 0.55
Standard deviations for dichotomous variables are meaningless and not displayed.
a Means for dichotomous variables, with values of 0 and 1, indicate the proportion of cases with a value of 1

(Pampel, 2000).
Table 4
Correlation matrixa

P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214
Variables

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14

(1) Change 1.00


(2) Terminate 0.55∗∗∗ 1.00
(3) Acquisition 0.22∗∗∗ −0.05 1.00
(4) Amend 0.57∗∗∗ −0.27∗∗∗ −0.11 1.00
(5) Equity 0.27∗∗∗ 0.14∗ −0.01 0.22∗∗∗ 1.00
(6) Joint venture −0.04 −0.06 0.06 −0.02 −0.11 1.00
(7) Biotechnology 0.19∗∗ 0.05 0.01 0.17∗∗ 0.28∗∗∗ −0.09 1.00
(8) Domestic 0.09 0.09 −0.03 0.04 0.13∗ −0.09 0.03 1.00
(9) Japan partner −0.15∗ −0.08 −0.03 −0.08 −0.08 −0.03 −0.10 −0.18∗∗ 1.00
(10) Europe partner −0.11 −0.01 −0.06 −0.09 −0.12∗ 0.01 −0.09 −0.34∗∗∗ −0.05 1.00
(11) NPD stage −0.20∗∗ −0.04 0.03 −0.23∗∗∗ −0.17∗ 0.12 −0.39∗∗∗ −0.04 0.07 0.01 1.00
(12) Financial flexibility −0.23∗∗∗ −0.21∗∗∗ −0.00 −0.08 −0.04 0.07 0.00 0.01 0.11 −0.05 0.01 1.00
(13) Partner size −0.13∗ −0.11 0.13∗ −0.12 −0.15∗ 0.12 −0.22∗∗∗ −0.26∗∗∗ 0.38∗∗∗ 0.13∗ 0.26∗∗∗ 0.08 1.00
(14) Previous alliance −0.02 −0.07 0.24∗∗∗ −0.08 −0.10 0.08 −0.08 −0.14∗ −0.07 0.03 0.12 −0.07 0.03 1.00
(15) Scope 0.17∗∗ 0.04 0.11 0.12 0.63∗∗∗ −0.02 0.16∗∗ 0.10 −0.02 −0.09 0.06 −0.07 0.04 −0.01
a Correlations between an ordinal variable and either a dichotomous or interval variable are Spearman correlations; correlations between two dichotomous variables are

phi correlations; correlations between a dichotomous and interval variable are point-biserial correlations; correlations with two interval variables are Pearson correlations
(Nunnally and Bernstein, 1994).
∗ P < 0.05.
∗∗ P < 0.01.
∗∗∗ P < 0.001.

205
206 P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214

Table 5
Logistic regression results for change in alliance governance
Variables Change Amend Terminate Acquisition

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3a Model 3b Model 4a Model 4b

Partner size 0.196 −0.377 −0.045 −0.14 2.343† 2.488†


Previous alliance 0.304 −0.419 −0.364 −0.385 2.814∗∗∗ 3.496∗∗∗
Scope 0.102 0.378 −0.658 −0.891† 0.829 1.209
Biotechnology 0.366 0.161 0.113 0.042 0.790 0.388
Domestic 0.008 −0.391 0.327 0.364 0.179 0.227
Japan partner −6.742 −5.632 −5.202 −5.590 −7.585 −7.534
Europe partner −0.972 −1.198 −0.047 −0.075 −7.110 −8.722
Equity 0.933† 0.211 1.212† 1.363∗ −0.495 −1.205
Joint venture 0.795 0.515 −0.033 0.180 0.807 2.026
Financial flexibility −0.015∗∗∗ −0.005 −0.025∗∗ −0.024∗∗ 0.000 0.004
NPD stage −0.404∗∗ −0.548∗∗ 0.011 3.117∗∗ −0.273 −8.813∗
NPD stage squared −0.679∗∗ 1.703∗
Model chi-square 49.891∗∗∗ 25.431∗∗ 25.396∗∗ 36.510∗∗∗ 20.911∗ 29.199∗∗
Cox and Snell R2 0.205 0.110 0.110 0.154 0.091 0.125
Nagelkerke R2 0.273 0.165 0.170 0.238 0.314 0.431
Change chi-square 11.114∗∗∗ 8.288∗∗
∗ P < 0.05.
∗∗ P < 0.01.
∗∗∗ P < 0.001.
† P < 0.10.

Additionally, block chi-squares, which represent the change in model chi-squares when a
new variable is added, are used to test our hypotheses that propose a nonlinear relationship
and include the squared term of product development stage. We also display Cox and Snell’s
R2 and Nagelkerke’s R2 for each model (Cox and Snell, 1989; Nagelkerke, 1991). These
pseudo R2 measures should not be compared directly to OLS regression’s R2 ; they are
usually lower in value, especially Cox and Snell’s R2 , which has a maximum less than 1.0.
Table 5 presents the logistic regression analysis results with change in alliance governance
and each of the three components of change—amendment, acquisition and termination—as
the dependent variables. All of the models are significant based on the model chi-squares
and pseudo R2 s that range from 0.17 (Model 2) to 0.43 (Model 3b) using Nagelkerke’s R2 .
Hypotheses 1 and 2 proposed that alliances are less stable if they are minority equity
alliances and if they are formed early in the product development process, respectively.
Model 1 of Table 5 is used to test these hypotheses. The logistic coefficient for minority
equity alliances is marginally significant (P < 0.10) and in the proposed direction, par-
tially supporting Hypothesis 1. The logistic coefficient for product development stage is
significant and in the proposed direction, supporting Hypothesis 2.
Hypotheses 1a and 2a proposed that alliances are more likely to be amended if they are
minority equity alliances and if they are formed early in the product development process,
respectively. Model 2 of Table 5 is used to test these hypotheses. The logistic coefficient
for minority equity alliances is not significant; thus Hypothesis 1a is not supported. The
logistic coefficient for product development stage is significant and in the proposed direction,
supporting Hypothesis 2a.
P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214 207

Hypotheses 1b proposed that alliances are more likely to be terminated if they are minority
equity alliances. Model 3b of Table 5 is used to test this hypothesis. The logistic coefficient
for minority equity alliances is significant (P < 0.05) and in the proposed direction; thus
Hypothesis 1b is supported. Hypothesis 2b proposed that alliances are less likely to be
terminated if they are initiated in the early and later stages of product development, and more
likely to be terminated if they are initiated in the mid-stages (inverted U-shape relationship).
This hypothesis is supported if there is a significant change in model chi-square after adding
the squared term of product development stage. The change of model chi-square in Model 3b
is significant as compared to Model 3a, supporting Hypothesis 2b. The logistic coefficient for
the square of product development stage in Model 3b is negative and significant, as expected.
Hypotheses 1c proposed that alliances are more likely to become acquisitions if they
are minority equity alliances. Model 4b of Table 5 is used to test this hypothesis. The
logistic coefficient for minority equity alliances is not significant; thus Hypothesis 1c is not
supported. Hypothesis 2c proposed that alliances are more likely to become acquisitions
if they are initiated in the early and later stages of product development, and less likely
to become acquisitions if they are initiated in the mid-stages (U-shape relationship). This
hypothesis is supported if there is a significant change in model chi-square after adding the
squared term of product development stage. The change of model chi-square in Model 4b is
significant as compared to Model 4a, supporting Hypothesis 2c. The logistic coefficient for
the square of product development stage in Model 4b is positive and significant, as expected.
Most of the control variables are not significant in any of the logistic regression models.
The only two control variables significant in a model are previous alliance and financial
flexibility. Previous alliance is a significant predictor of an alliance becoming an acquisition.
Financial flexibility is a significant negative predictor of both termination and change. In
other words, firms with high debt (low financial flexibility) are more likely to terminate
alliances.

6. Discussion

The purpose of this study was to determine what circumstances cause strategic alliance
governance to be less stable. This study has illustrated that the instability of strategic al-
liances in the pharmaceutical/biotechnology industry is influenced by both alliance and
alliance partner characteristics. More specifically, we found support for increased instabil-
ity in strategic alliances that have an equity governance structure, are formed in the early
stage of product development, and where the focal firms have a greater level of financial
flexibility. These effects are more robust than the effects of other variables that have been
generally thought to influence alliance stability, including the partner’s size, the partner’s
previous alliance experience (except as a predictor of an acquisition), the alliance’s scope,
the type of technology involved in the alliance, and the partner’s nationality.

6.1. Governance structures

A major contribution of this paper is the disaggregation of equity alliances into joint
ventures and other equity based alliances. Previous alliance literature has equated equity
208 P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214

alliances with joint ventures (Hagedoorn and Sadowski, 1999). Our results provide evidence
that equity based alliances are a source of instability in alliances, as measured by termination
of the alliance, while a joint venture structure does not impact alliance instability. The
rationale is that, even though joint ventures also require a high degree of commitment, they
are generally not flexible governance structures. They are also better than equity alliances at
transferring and integrating knowledge, and usually foster more trust among partners (Das
and Teng, 1998).
This is interesting given the growing literature concerned with joint venture instability
(Blodgett, 1992; Gomes-Casseres, 1987; Harrigan and Newman, 1990; Inkpen and Beamish,
1997; Kogut, 1991; Park and Russo, 1996; Park and Ungson, 1997). This literature docu-
ments a high rate of instability in joint ventures and especially international joint ventures
(Inkpen and Beamish, 1997). Our results conflict with these findings in that we found no evi-
dence that an alliance organized as a joint venture in and of itself causes instability. Research
into the discrepancy between our findings and the literature on joint venture instability is
clearly needed.
While our results provide strong support for equity alliances being more likely to be
terminated (Hypothesis 1b), we did not find significant support for our arguments that
equity alliances are more likely to be amended (Hypothesis 1a) or end in an acquisition
(Hypothesis 1c). One reason why equity alliances are not amended significantly more than
joint ventures and non-equity alliances may be that when equity alliances are not progressing
as expected, firms usually terminate the alliances instead of trying to change them. Equity
alliances are formed more frequently in the early stages of product development. When
it becomes apparent that the development of the drug is not going to be successful the
pharmaceutical company chooses to end the relationship instead of starting over with a
different project.
An alternative reason why equity alliances are not amended significantly more than
other types of alliances may be that non-equity alliances, which account for over seventy
percent of the alliances in our sample, are amended more than we hypothesized. This
would be consistent with the practice of developing fewer, more in-depth and long lasting
relational partnerships with suppliers and other alliance partners (Dyer, 1996, 1997). This
practice builds more trust among partners, allows flexibility, and helps communication and
knowledge transfer across firms (Dyer, 1996, 1997). Thus, partners may frequently expand
their working relationship, extending non-equity alliances to cover new research and new
projects.
There are two probable reasons why equity alliances are not more likely than other types
of alliances to become acquisitions. First, our data indicate that a very small percentage
of alliances (4%) become alliances, making it difficult to identify patterns with certainty.
This finding is consistent with Hagedoorn and Sadowski’s (1999) finding using a very large
sample across numerous industries, and contradicts Bleeke and Ernst’s (1995) warning
that alliances, especially equity alliances, can be precursors to an acquisition. Our results
indicate that the only significant predictors of an acquisition are the existence of a previous
alliance and stage of development, not the type of governance structure.
Second, our rationale for equity alliances being unstable may not apply as directly to
acquisitions as terminations or amendments. Acquisitions, unlike terminations and amend-
ments, are only the consequence of a successful alliance, not a result of a failed alliance.
P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214 209

Alliances that are successful are less likely to be changed than alliances that are not suc-
cessful. Our argument that equity alliances are inferior governance structures may still be
true, and hence a lower proportion of them are successful, creating fewer opportunities for
an acquisition.

6.2. Product development stage

With respect to product development stage, firms in alliances formed in the early stages
of product development are more likely to change the alliance’s governance structure,
especially through major restructuring. Early stages of product development are inherently
risky and involve more tacit knowledge and uncertainty (Almeida and Kogut, 1997). When
product development advances, firms may choose to change governance structures to either
increase or decrease commitment to the project or to change their level and form of control
over the developing technology. Activities in the later stage of product development usually
involve more explicit knowledge and more specific and formalized control systems can be
used. The likelihood of major amendments to alliances decreases as alliances are formed
later in the product development stage since the control systems of these alliances are
initially more formalized and require less change.
These results are interesting in light of earlier findings. Dussauge et al. (2000), using a
variable that differentiated between marketing and technical alliances found no significant
relationship with alliance outcomes. They did determine that link alliances, where partners
contribute different capabilities, are more likely to be reorganized; and scale alliances, where
partners contribute similar capabilities, are more likely to continue without material change.
They claim that the reorganization of an alliance is an indicator of firms learning within the
alliance, with the results indicating that link alliances lead to greater levels of learning, as
compared to scale alliances. Extending this logic to our study, reorganizations occur more
frequently in the early stages of product development, indicating that more learning among
partners occurs in the early stages of product development than the later stages.
However, the likelihood of alliances being terminated or acquired follows different pat-
terns. Alliances formed during the R&D stage, along with alliances formed after the prod-
ucts are approved, are more likely to result in an acquisition than alliances formed in the
mid-stages of product development. Alliances formed during the mid stages of product
development are more likely to be terminated than alliances formed in the early or late
stages. Our results expand on the findings of Park and Russo (1996), who found somewhat
ambiguous results when examining whether or not R&D activities were included in joint
ventures. They determined R&D activities were not significantly related to failure but were
significantly associated with acquisitions.
Our study’s findings add value to this area of research by using a product development
stage variable that is better delineated than a simple R&D/marketing variable. Certainly,
governance issues concerning alliances focusing on basic R&D are very different than
those for alliances focusing on R&D activities associated with the later stages of product
development. Our results are consistent with Park and Russo’s (1996) in that alliances
focused on basic R&D activities are more likely to lead to acquisitions, but we also find
that alliances formed after the primary product of the alliance is developed and approved
are more likely to become acquisitions. Acquisitions are less likely during mid-stages of
210 P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214

product development. This implies that firms either acquire to internalize a new technology
that has not been fully developed or acquire to get a finished product. They do not acquire
as frequently to obtain products in development.
This study also adds to our understanding of the actions taken by incumbent firms facing
radical technological change (Christensen and Bower, 1996; Rothaermel, 2001). Table 2
provides evidence that incumbent firms initiate non-equity alliances with their alliances
partners far more than either joint ventures or equity alliances. Table 2 also shows that
non-equity alliance use increases as a percentage of all alliances used as product develop-
ment advances from R&D to FDA approval. Further, the use of equity alliances remains
fairly consistent throughout product development but decreases dramatically after a drug
is approved for sale. Joint ventures, as a percentage of all alliances, are used fairly consis-
tently in earlier and later product development stages. Our results also provide evidence
regarding the use of different alliance structures for the exploration and exploitation of
new technologies by incumbents (March, 1991; Rothaermel, 2001). Table 2 shows that
incumbent firms clearly prefer equity and non-equity alliances when exploring new tech-
nologies (R&D stage). When exploiting technological certainties (drugs approved for sale
by the FDA), incumbents clearly favor non-equity alliances over either joint ventures or
non-equity alliances.

6.3. Financial flexibility

Additionally, our findings concerning financial flexibility yielded interesting results, even
though they were not the primary focus of the study. The results support the view that firms
with greater financial flexibility, which is a key element of strategic flexibility, are bet-
ter able to redirect resources quickly when either internal or external conditions warrant
(Aaker and Mascarenhas, 1984; Bierly and Chakrabarti, 1996b; Bourgeois, 1981; Cheng
and Kesner, 1997). Increased strategic flexibility allows an alliance partner the option of
changing alliance governance structure to take advantage of shifting inequalities between
alliance partners (Doz, 1996; Hagedoorn and Sadowski, 1999; Hamel, 1991) or to read-
just the alliance after a period of learning and reevaluation (Doz, 1996). We specifically
found that firms with higher financial flexibility are more likely to terminate alliances.
Previous research has implicitly assumed that firms make changes to alliances when cir-
cumstances are appropriate. This result provides evidence that firms are better able to make
changes to alliances when they have the financial flexibility to do so, possibly because
they have a buffer against any downside risk associated with alliance changes (Singh,
1986).

7. Study limitations, implications, and directions for future research

While our research provides strong support for most of our hypotheses, we acknowledge
that these results may be questioned on the basis of generalizability and the hypotheses
should be tested in other industries. The pharmaceutical industry is unique in that large
amounts of resources are spent on R&D and marketing, patent protection is very robust, and
the drug approval process is formal and lengthy. Additionally, the new product development
P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214 211

process in the pharmaceutical industry is probably more of a linear process, an assumption


in our study, than in other industries where product development follows more of an iterative
pattern (Wheelwright and Clark, 1992). Furthermore, Cheng et al. (1996) provided empirical
support that the beginning stage of the product development process (Stage 1 in our study)
tends to be chaotic, while later development periods (Stages 2–4 in our study) tend to
be more orderly. Each of the specific characteristics of the pharmaceutical industry could
provide a rationale for using different types of governance structures.
However, ours is a study of how firm and alliance characteristics affect alliance instability.
We believe that the organizational and alliance processes underlying alliance instability
operate widely. Consistent with this belief, other researchers have found evidence that
firm (Blodgett, 1992; Doz, 1996; Hagedoorn and Sadowski, 1999; Park and Russo, 1996;
Park and Ungson, 1997; Saxton, 1997) and alliance characteristics (Dussauge et al., 2000;
Park and Russo, 1996; Saxton, 1997) affect alliance instability. Nevertheless, while our
paper provides several initial insights into alliance governance and instability throughout
the new product development process, further research is needed in other industries to test
our findings in other settings and to test for more complex relationships, particularly in
industries with less formal product development.
The lack of consistently significant results among the control variables suggests that
there are other variables not included in this study that may have a bearing on alliance
instability. Factors such as the technical background of top managers within each firm,
previous experience with alliances in general (not only with a specific partner), and the
compatibility of firm cultures need to be examined. Additionally, multi-industry studies
could test environmental effects, such as competitive intensity, technological dynamism,
and demographic dynamism, on the stability of alliances.

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank David Deeds, Scott Gallagher, Brian Miller, and Dean
Shepherd for their helpful comments. This work was supported, in part, by a Grant-in-Aid-
of-Creativity Award from Monmouth University and a Research Grant from the College of
Business, James Madison University.

References

Aaker, D.A., Mascarenhas, B., 1984. The need for strategic flexibility. The Journal of Business Strategy 5 (2),
74–82.
Almeida, P., Kogut, B., 1997. The exploration of technological diversity and the geographic localization of
innovation. Small Business Economics 9, 21–31.
Barley, S.R., Freeman, J., Hybels, R.C., 1992. Strategic alliances in commercial biotechnology. In: Nohria, N.,
Eccles, R.G. (Eds.), Networks and Organizations. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, pp. 311–347.
Barney, J.B., 2002. Gaining and Sustaining Competitive Advantage. Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ.
Baysinger, B., Hoskisson, R.E., 1989. Diversification strategy and R&D intensity in multiproduct firms. Academy
of Management Journal 32, 310–332.
Beamish, P.W., Banks, J.C., 1987. Equity joint ventures and the theory of the multinational enterprise. Journal of
International Business Studies 18, 1–15.
212 P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214

Bierly, P., Chakrabarti, A., 1996a. Generic knowledge strategies in the US pharmaceutical industry. Strategic
Management Journal 17 (Winter Special Issue), 123–135.
Bierly, P., Chakrabarti, A., 1996b. Technological learning, strategic flexibility, and new product development in
the pharmaceutical industry. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management 43, 368–380.
Bleeke, J., Ernst, D., 1995. Is your strategic alliance really a sale? Harvard Business Review January–February,
97–105.
Blodgett, L.L., 1992. Factors in the instability of international joint ventures. Strategic Management Journal 13,
475–481.
Boris, B., Jemison, D.B., 1989. Hybrid arrangements as strategic alliances: theoretical issues in organizational
combinations. Academy of Management Review 14, 475–481.
Bourgeois, L.J., 1981. On the measurement of organizational slack. Academy of Management Review 6, 29–39.
Cheng, J.L.C., Kesner, I.F., 1997. Organizational slack and response to environmental shift: the impact of resource
allocation patterns. Journal of Management 23, 1–18.
Cheng, Y.-T., Van de Ven, A.H., 1996. Learning the innovation journey: order out of chaos? Organization Science
7 (6), 593–614.
Christensen, C.M., Bower, J.L., 1996. Customer power, strategic investment and failure of leading firms. Strategic
Management Journal 17 (3), 197–218.
Cox, D.R., Snell, E.J., 1989. The Analysis of Binary Data, second ed. Chapman and Hall, London.
Das, T.K., Teng, B.S., 1998. Between trust and control: developing confidence in partner cooperation in alliances.
Academy of Management Review 23, 491–512.
DiMasi, J.A., 2001. Tufts Center for the study of drug development pegs cost of a new prescription medicine at $
802 million. Tufts University Press Release 30 November.
Doz, Y.L., 1996. The evolution of cooperation in strategic alliances: initial conditions or learning processes?
Strategic Management Journal 17 (Summer Special Issue), 55–83.
Dussauge, P., Garrette, B., Mitchell, W., 2000. Learning from competing partners: outcomes and durations of scale
and link alliances in Europe, North America and Asia. Strategic Management Journal 21, 99–126.
Dyer, J.H., 1997. Effective interfirm collaboration: how firms maximize transaction costs and maximize transaction
value. Strategic Management Journal 18, 535–556.
Dyer, J.H., 1996. Specialized supplier networks as a source of competitive advantage: evidence from the auto
industry. Strategic Management Journal 17, 271–292.
Gomes-Casseres, B., 1987. Joint venture instability: is it a problem? Columbia Journal of World Business Summer
97–102.
Gulati, R., 1995. Does familiarity breed trust? The implications of repeated ties for contractual choice in alliances.
Academy of Management Journal 38, 85–112.
Hagedoorn, J., 1993. Understanding the rationale of strategic technology partnering: interorganizational modes of
cooperation and sectoral differences. Strategic Management Journal 14, 371–385.
Hagedoorn, J., Narula, R., 1996. Choosing organizational modes of strategic technology partnering: international
and sectoral differences. Journal of International Business Studies 27, 265–284.
Hagedoorn, J., Sadowski, B., 1999. The transition from strategic technology alliances to mergers and acquisitions:
an exploratory study. Journal of Management Studies 36, 87–107.
Hamel, G., 1991. Competition for competence and interpartner learning within international strategic alliances.
Strategic Management Journal 12, 83–103.
Hamel, G., Prahalad, C.K., 1994. Competing For the Future. Harvard Business School Press, Boston.
Harrigan, K.R., 1988. Strategic alliances and partner asymmetries. In: Contractor, F., Lorange, P. (Eds.),
Cooperative Strategies in International Business. Lexington Books, Lexington, MA, pp. 205–226.
Harrigan, K.R., Newman, W.H., 1990. Bases of interorganizational cooperation: propensity, power, and persistence.
Journal of Management Studies 27, 417–434.
Henderson, R., Cockburn, I., 1994. Measuring competence? Exploring firm effects in pharmaceutical research.
Strategic Management Journal 15 (Winter Special Issue), 63–84.
Hennart, J.F., 1988. A transaction costs theory of equity joint ventures. Strategic Management Journal 9, 361–374.
Hitt, M.A., Ireland, R.D., Hoskisson, R.E., 1997. Strategic Management: Competitiveness and Globalization,
second ed. West Publishing Company, St. Paul, MN.
Inkpen, A.C., 1996. Creating knowledge through collaboration. California Management Review 39 (1), 123–140.
P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214 213

Inkpen, A.C., Beamish, P.W., 1997. Knowledge, bargaining power, and the instability of international joint ventures.
Academy of Management Review 22, 177–202.
Kale, P., Singh, H., Perlmutter, H., 2000. Learning and protection of proprietary assets in strategic alliances:
building relational capital. Strategic Management Journal 21, 217–237.
Kent, D.H., 1991. Joint ventures vs. non-joint ventures: an empirical investigation. Strategic Management Journal
12, 387–393.
Killing, J.P., 1983. Strategies for Joint Venture Success. Praeger, New York.
Kogut, B., 1991. Joint ventures and the option to expand or acquire. Management Science 37, 19–32.
Kogut, B., 1989. The stability of joint ventures: reciprocity and competitive rivalry. Journal of Industrial Economics
38, 183–198.
Kogut, B., 1988. Joint ventures: theoretical and empirical perspectives. Strategic Management Journal 9, 319–332.
Koza, M.P., Lewin, A.Y., 1998. The co-evolution of strategic alliances. Organization Science 9 (3), 255–264.
Lane, H.W., Beamish, P.W., 1990. Cross-cultural cooperative behavior in joint ventures in LDCs. Management
International Review 30 (Special issue), 87–102.
Lane, P.J., Lubatkin, M., 1998. Relative absorptive capacity and interorganizational learning. Strategic
Management Journal 19, 461–477.
Lee, C., Beamish, P.W., 1995. The characteristics and performance of Korean joint ventures in LDCs. Journal of
International Business Studies 26, 637–654.
March, J.G., 1991. Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organization Science 2, 71–87.
Mowery, D.C., Oxley, J.E., Silverman, B.S., 1996. Strategic alliances and interfirm knowledge transfer. Strategic
Management Journal 17 (Winter Special Issue), 77–91.
Nagelkerke, N.J.D., 1991. A note on a general definition of the coefficient of determination. Biometrika 78,
691–692.
Nunnally, J.C., Bernstein, I.H., 1994. Psychometric Theory, third ed. McGraw-Hill, New York.
Ohmae, K., 1989. The global logic of strategic alliances. Harvard Business Review March–April, 143–154.
Osborn, R.N., Baughn, C.C., 1990. Forms of interorganizational governance for multinational alliances. Academy
of Management Journal 33, 503–519.
Oxley, J.E., 1997. Appropriability hazards and governance in strategic alliances: a transaction cost approach.
Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 13, 387–409.
Pampel, F.C., 2000. Logistic Regression: A Primer. Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks, CA.
Park, S.H., Russo, M.V., 1996. When competition eclipses cooperation: an event history analysis of joint venture
failure. Management Science 42, 875–890.
Park, S.H., Ungson, G.R., 1997. The effect of national culture, organizational complementarity, and economic
motivation on joint venture dissolution. Academy of Management Journal 40, 279–307.
Pisano, G.P., 1989. Using equity participation to support exchange: evidence from the biotechnology industry.
Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 5, 109–125.
Powell, W.W., 1998. Learning from collaboration: knowledge and networks in the biotechnology and
pharmaceutical industries. California Management Review 40 (3), 228–240.
Powell, W.W., Koput, K.W., Smith-Doerr, L., 1996. Interorganizational collaboration and the locus of innovation:
networks of learning in biotechnology. Administrative Science Quarterly 41, 116–145.
Rothaermel, F.T., 2001. Incumbent’s advantage through exploiting complementary assets via interfirm cooperation.
Strategic Management Journal 22, 687–699.
Saxton, T., 1997. The effects of partner and relationship characteristics on alliance outcomes. Academy of
Management Journal 40, 443–461.
Scott, W.R., 1992. Organizations: Rational, Natural, and Open Systems. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
Shan, W., Hamilton, W., 1991. Country-specific advantage and international cooperation. Strategic Management
Journal 12, 419–432.
Singh, J.V., 1986. Performance, slack, and risk taking in organizational decision making. Academy of Management
Journal 29, 562–585.
Tsai, W., Ghoshal, S., 1998. Social capital and value creation: the role of intrafirm networks. Academy of
Management Journal 41, 464–476.
Wheelwright, S.C., Clark, K.B., 1992. Revolutionizing Product Development. Free Press, New York.
Williamson, O.E., 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. Free Press, New York.
214 P.E. Bierly III, J.E. Coombs / J. Eng. Technol. Manage. 21 (2004) 191–214

Williamson, O.E., 1991. Comparative economic organization: the analysis of discrete structural alternatives.
Administrative Science Quarterly 36, 269–296.
Yan, A., Zeng, M., 1999. International joint venture instability: a critique of previous research, a
reconceptualization, and directions for future research. Journal of International Business Studies 30, 397–414.
Zucker, L.G., Darby, M.R., 1997. Present at the biotechnological revolution: transformation of technological
identity for a large incumbent pharmaceutical firm. Research Policy 26, 429–446.

Você também pode gostar