Você está na página 1de 32

13

The laws of international exchange

Anwar Shaikh

Comparative costs other, c~?d lj’ the terms of trade between cloth
and wine were to settle between (p,./puJ1 and
There is no proposition so central to orthodox (p,./~~)~, then each country-as-a-whole would
theories of international trade as the so-called gain from trade. That is, by concentrating its
Law of Comparative Costs. From Ricardo to production towards the relatively cheaper good
Hecksher-Ohlin to Samuelson, in one guise or and exporting part of that good in exchange for
another, the basic principle has remained un- the other good, each country would end up
changed. Even the relentless search of neoclas- better off, in the sense that through trade a given
sical economics for a state of perfect triviality set of inputs could be translated into more out-
has not emptied this particular principle of its puts than before trade.
content; from the time of its derivation by Ri- It is very important for our subsequent discus-
cardo to its current incarceration in an Edge- sion to note that the above proposition in no way
worth-Bowley Box, this law has continued to depends on the absolute costs of wine and cloth
dominate the analysis of international trade. in the two countries. Thus, even if one of the
Even - and this is surely its greatest triumph to two nations were absolutely more efficient in
date - even its public exposure as having been producing both commodities - so that both wine
all along the hidden law behind modern marriage and cloth were absolutely cheaper in one
has not (yet) led to its complete discreditation?, country than in the other3 - “trade can be bene-
It is not surprising that a principle capable of ficial if the country with the all-around inferior
surviving “improvements’ ’ such as the above efficiency specializes in the lines of production
has managed to also withstand repeated attacks. where its inferiority is slightest, and the country
Before we touch upon these attacks, however, it with all-aromd superior efficiency specializes in
will be useful to briefly describe the law itself. the lines of its greatest superiority.” (Yeager,
There are in fact two distinct propositions as- 1966, p. 4) Therefore, this proposition argues
sociated with this law, and the tendency to con- that ij’under the right conditions (differences in
flate the two has been a potent source of confu- pretrade relative prices, the “correct” pattern of
sion in the literature. exports, and an intercountry terms of trade in
Let us begin by considering a country in the “appropriate” range), each country, no
which cloth and wine are produced and sold at mutter how hurckwwd i t s techwlqy, w o u l d
the price ratio (p,/p& in the domestic market. benefit from trade. Absolute costs are of no mo-
Across the channel is another country in which ment; all that matters is relative costs. Hence
cloth and wine are alsn produced and sold lo- the term “the principle of comparative advan-
..
cally, generally at a different price ratio (pJp& tage. ’’
than in the first country. Suppose the price ratios Taken by itself, the first principle says nothing
are different. Then, if the price of cloth relative at all about what actually happens in interna-
to wine is lower in the first country than in the tional trade. In fact, it would appear to be largely
second, the price of wine relative to cloth must
be lower in the second; that is, in each country I wish to express my thanks to Arthur Felberbaum,
one commodity will be relatively cheaper.2 Robert Heilbroner, Edward Nell, Michael Zweig, John
The first proposition is a prescriptive one. It Weeks, and particularly to Adolph Lowe, for their
asserts that if each country were to export its comments, criticisms, and above all their support
relatively cheaper commodity and import the throughout this endeavor.

204
irrelevant to the real process. Exports and im- have been; the real point was that no nation need
ports, after all, are undertaken by capitalists for be afraid of free trade, for it humbles the mighty
the sake of profit, not gains to the “nation.” and raises the weak. Something like God, only
Profits, moreover, depend crucially on absolute quite a bit more reliable.
money costs: the lower-cost producer is always The more recent formulation of the law, the
in a position to beat out its rivals. In trade Hecksher-Ohlin-Samuelson Zuny oJ’ f&or pro-
between two advanced countries, each country pnvtkms, leaves intact the basic principle set out
might be expected to have some absolutely effi- by Ricardo. However, whereas Ricardo identi-
cient producers, so thrtt in this case absolute ad- fied the real social cost of producing a commod-
vantage and comparative advantage coincide: ity as the total labor-time that went directly or
each country will then have one commodity for indirectly into production, the neoclassical for-
which it is the lowest-cost producer and hence mulation insists upon defining the social cost(s)
the exporter. But how could a backward country of a commodity to the nation-as-a-whole as
in competition with an advanced one possibly being the commodities it (the nation) must
hope to enjoy the “gains from trade” when both forego, at the margin, in order to produce an
its producers are the higher-cost producers‘? extra unit of the commodity in question. Since
This is where the second proposition comes this concept of cost as opportunities foregone
in. It is a descriptive proposition, for it asserts cannot be used if there are unemployed
that in free trade the patterns of trade cr~‘N in fact resources - for then any given commodity can
be regulated by the principle of comparative ad- be produced without the national individual
vantage - regardless of any absolute differences (Uncle Sam) having to give up any others, that
in levels of productive efficiency. The crucial is, without any opportunity cost - neoclassical
element in this step, therefore, is the presence of theory finds it necessary also to assume full em-
some crutomutic mechunism that will cause free ployment. The assumption of full employment is
trade undertaken by profit-seeking capitalists to therefore just the,hidden dual of the concept of
converge to this result. opportunity cost.
The sum of the two propositions is what is The second distinguishing characteristic of the
generally called the “law of comparative costs”: neoclassical version is that, whereas Ricardo
if permitted, free trade will end up king rcgu- bases the patterns of internatiorlal sywiali~ation
lated by the principle of comparative (not abso- on international differences in relative costs,
lute) advantage, and the resulting gains from whatever their origin, the Hecksher-Ohlin for-
trade will be shared among the trading partners. mulation attempts to tie the cost differences
In the original form given to it by David Ri- themselves to a single dominant factor: the na-
cardo, the crucial automatic mechanism was the tional endowments of labor and capital. Thus,
relation between the quantity of money and the leaving absolute advantages aside, this approach
level of prices: the so-called chsicul yucrntity would argue that, given any two countries, the
theory n$ money. In Ricardo’s famous example, capital-abundant country (the one having the
for instance, Portugal can produce both wine higher national capital-labor ratio) would tend
and cloth more cheaply than England. Trade to be able to produce capital-intensive goods
between England and Portugal would therefore relutively more cheaply than the labor-abun-
initially be all in one direction, with Portugal ex- dant country. Conversely, the labor abundant
porting both wine and cloth, which England country (the one having the lower national
would have to pay for directly in gold since its capital-labor ratio) would of course have the
products were noncompetitive with Portugal’s. relative advantage in labor-intensive production.
But now the crucial equalizing mechanism It follows therefore that capital-abundant coun-
comes into play: the outflow of gold from Eng- tries (read industrialized capitalist countries)
land is a decrease in its money supply and would will and, for reasons of efficiency and the good
therefore lower all money prices in England; of the world-as-a-whole, should, specialize in
similarly, the inflow of gold into Portugal would capital-intensive (secondary) products, ex-
raise all money prices there. As long as the trade porting them in return for the labor-intensive
imbalance persisted, this mechanism would con- (primary) products of the labor-abundant (un-
tinue to make British wine and cloth progres- derdeveloped capitalist) countries: In other
sively cheaper, and Portuguese wine and cloth words, the existing differences between devel-
progressively more expensive, until at some oped and underdeveloped capitalist countries
point England could undersell Portugal in one of are effic~2nf from the point of view of the
the two commodities, leaving Portugal with the world-as-a-whole. Poor Ricardo dared only to
relative advantage in the other. The exact deter- claim that free trade is better; neoclassical
mination of the terms of trade was understand- theory can boldly claim that international in-
ably not important to Ricardo, nor should it equality is best. No wonder that Gary Becker
206 Anwar Shaikh

found in this analysis so convenient an explana- balances version of the quantity theory, the
tion for institutionalized sexism (Becker, 1973, Keynesian determination of prices through the
1974). level of money wages, and Marx’s theory of
What is perhaps most striking about the neo- money. In order to do this, we need a common
classical approach is that it completely assumes ground of some sort.
away any possibility of absolute advantage on Fortunately for us, most of the history of in-
the part of any one country: wine production in ternational trade, and hence most of its theory,
England and wine production in Portugal are as- has been dominated by precious metals as the
sumed to be characterized by exactly the same standards of both domestic and international
production function; similarly, cloth too has its money.5 Thus, in discussions of the theories of
own universal production function. The central international trade, we always find a common
thrust of Ricardo’s argument was of course that theoretical ground - their operation under the
free trade leads to gains even for countries that so-called gold standard (The discussion of fixed
are absolutely inefficient in comparison to their versus flexible exchange rates and their relation
trading partners; in the Hecksher-Ohlin version to the gold standard is reserved for the second
all this is sacrificed to the need to prove that pat- major section). By contrasting various theories
terns of international specialization are conse- on this basis, differences in the theories them-
quences of the various national “factor endow- selves may be separated from differences in
ments .’ ’ It is interesting to note, however, that institutional arrangements. And because neither
when Leontief’s famous empirical test of the the Ricardian nor the neoclassical versions of
Hecksher-Ohlin model appeared to refute it, the law of comparative costs claim to be depen-
“Leontief rationalized this result by hypothe- dent on any specific monetary institutions, the
sizing that American labor is three times as pro- gold standard is a valid common ground. So
ductive as foreign labor” (Johnson, 1968, p. 89)4 much so, in fact, that the neoclassical treatment
- that is, he resorted to the argument that the of the adjustment mechanism under the gold
U.S. pattern of trade could be explained by its standard is virtually identical to that of Ricardo:
absolute advmtuge over its trading partners! A “The adjustment mechanism under the gold
fuller discussion of Leontief’s study is at the end standard . . . was more or less automatic in
of the next section, “Orthodox critiques.” the sense that central banks were expected to
In general, modern presentations of the law of react to gold outflows and inflows by more
comparative costs make no reference to the restrictive and less restrictive monetary policies,
actual mechanisms by which the law is to be respectively, which would in turn react upon
brought about. The emphasis is almost entirely price and wage levels, lowering them in the defi-
on the gains from trade that would be achieved if cit countries and raising them in the surplus
trade were to be based on comparative costs; countries. These price changes, in turn, were ex-
nonetheless, because these ‘discussions are also pected to shift expenditure from surplus to defi-
intended to be descriptive, “the implicit as- cit countries, thus reducing and eventually elimi-
sumption is [made] that the adjustment of money nating the disequilibrium . . . the theory is
wage and price levels or exchange rates required correct in its broad outline even if its practice has
to preserve international monetary equilibrium been somewhat oversimplified” (Mundell, 1968,
do actually take place . . .” (Johnson, 1968, p. pp. 8-9).
84) As we shall see later, in the second major We find, therefore, that, in spite of their much
section, modern derivations of comparative discussed differences, the fundamental structure
costs rely on what are essentially variants of Ri- of both the Ricardian and neoclassical versions
cardo’s mechanism: in all cases, the very nature of the law of international exchange is the same:
of the desired solution requires monetary vari- in both cases it is relative advantage and not ab-
ables (price levels and/or exchange rates) to ad- solute which determines the pattern of trade: in
just in such a way as to transform absolute ad- both cases trade is mutually beneficial (or, at
vantage into a comparative one. In all versions, worst, not harmful) to each country viewed as a
therefore, given England’s absolutely lower effi- single classless entity; and, above all, in both
ciency and hence initially higher costs of pro- cases the mechanism which brings about the
duction, its ensuing trade deficit must somehow successful operation of the law is essentially the
result in a lowering of English prices while Por- same.
tugal’s trade surplus must lead to a raising of its
prices - until at some point each country has a
cost advantage in only one commodity. Orthodox critiques
The critique of comparative costs conse-
quently requires us to contrast four basic The law of comparative costs, whatever its
theories of money: the Hume specie-flow ver- form, has always been associated with the advo-
sion of the auantitv theorv (Ricardo). the cash cacy of free trade: Ricardo’s own development
The laws of international exchange 207

of this principle was in fact part of his polemic Beginning with the fact that the United States
against the corn laws (laws which prevented the was by all accounts a capital-abundant country,
free import of cheap corn into England), and Leontief reasoned that those goods which
from that time onward free traders of all kinds America exported should be more capital inten-
have based their own arguments on those of Ri- sive than those which it replaced by imports.
cardo. It is not surprising, therefore, to find that What he actually found, however, was just the
the primary thrust of critics has been to attack opposite: “contrary to expectations United
not so much that part of the law which argues States exports are more labor-intensive . . .
that the pattern of trxle will depend nn cnmpra- than TJnited States imports” (Johnson, 1968.
tive costs, as it has been to attack the proposi- p. 88).
tion that free trade is efficient, mutually benefi- Neoclassical theory, it will be recalled, takes
cial, and good for the world-as-a-whole. it for granted that, in accordance with Ricardo’s
Frank Graham, for instance, focuses on the law, each country will export the relatively
assumption of constant cost, which he argues is cheaper commodity. What the Hecksher-Ohlin-
essential to the operation of the law; thus, by Samuelson model seeks to do is to go one step
working with combinations of increasing and de- further and argue that this relatively cheaper
creasing costs, he is able to provide counterex- commodity will in fact be the one which uses
amples in which free trade and specialization are proportionately more of the relatively abundant
harmful to every one of the countries involved factor of production: hence the theoretical ex-
(Emmanuel, 1972, p. XV)? In a similar vein, pectation that the capital-abundant country will
Keynesians often attack the assumption of full export the capital-intensive commodity. In order
employment, which, as we have seen, is a neces- to make the above links, however, it is neces-
sary complement of the nemlussicul versions of sary to assume away the possibility of absolute
the law; here, it is possible to construct coun- advantage. In neoclassical terms, this means
terexamples in which hypothesized combina- that the production function for a given com-
tions of unemployment and inflation may under modity, say wine, is assumed to be the same no
certain circumstances have a feedback effect on matter whether wine is produced in England or
the operation of the law and thus counteract it.7 in Portugal: thus wine could always be produced
Finally, there exists a whole series of modifica- at the same cost everywhere. It is not slqyising,
tions of the law, based on the analysis of interna- therefore, that, when faced with the unexpected
tional differences in taste, on the existence of results of his study, Leontief was led to chal-
tariffs and quotas, transportation costs, customs lenge precisely that assumption.
unions, and so on. Leontief’s challenge did not go unanswered
In spite of their apparent opposition to the for long. In 1961, Arrow, Chenery, Minhas, and
law, all the above criticisms have this in Solow published a study in which they argued
common: implicitly (and often explicitly), they that cross-country comparisons of pruduc;tiun
accept the law us being theoretically vulid on its functions did indeed indicate that American pro-
own grmnds. Instead, they seek to modify one duction was systematically more efficient than
or more of these grounds so as to provide theo- others: in other words, that the United States
retical counterexamples. It is therefore not at all had an absolute advantage (Arrow, et al., 1961;
surprising that these criticisms are usually see note 4 of this chapter). These results
viewed not as refutations of comparative costs, prompted an investigation of the properties of
but rather as its further development; typically, the Hecksher-Ohlin-Samuelson model when
in neoclassical textbooks, the doctrine of com- production functions differ across countries,
parative costs is presented as the fundamental which in turn led to the theoretical possibility
principle underlying international trade, with the that capital-abundant countries might t=xpur-t
foregoing criticisms as extensions and concreti- labor-intensive commodities (Minhas, 1962).
zations of it. Distressing as these results are to the propo-
Orthodox critics, however, have yet another nents of the Hecksher-Ohlin-Samuelson model,
recourse - attack by means of data. Here, the they have little bearing on the principle of com-
two examples most often cited are the results of parative costs, for (as we have already noted)
Leontief s famous study (Leontief, 1953, 1956, the model begins by assuming the Ricardian pat-
1958), now known as the “Leontief paradox,” tern of specialization according to comparative
and those of the Arrow-Chenery-Minhas-Solow costs and then attempts to link this pattern to the
study, which gave rise to the so-called factor re- “factor endowments” of the nations involved.
versal issue (Arrow, et al., 1961). We will exam- At best, therefore, the above empirical and the:o-
ine each in turn. retical paradoxes merely sever the attempted
In the early 195Os, Leontief set out to empiri- link between national factor endowments and
cally test the central proposition of the neoclas- the pattern of trade. They leave the Ricurdian
sical version of the law of comparative costs. lcrw untouched.
208 Anwar Shaikh

Finally, we come to those critics who attack is dominant; Marx’s analysis therefore begins
the law as being yzo Ic)pzgv~ valid, because one or with the latter and only arrives at the former
more of its premises no longer hold in today’s (merchant’s capital) in Volume III of Capital. It
world. Here, we find that the empirical criticism is industrial capital which is involved in the pro-
of the law, and particularly of the efficacy of free duction of commodities, and hence in the eye-
trade, is based on modem developments such as dorz of value and surplus value. Merchant capi-
the loss of wage and price flexibility, the demise tal, on the other hand, is involved in the trading
of the gold standard, the death of competition, of commodities; it therefore accomplishes the
and systematic interference by governments? ttunsfer of value and of surplus value, nationally
For our purposes, it is sufficient to note that this and internationally. It follows from this that in
historical school of orthodox criticism (which, order to understand its role within capitalist
as we shall see shortly, has its Marxist counter- (rather than precapitalist) modes of production,
parts) implicitly accepts the law as valid where merchant capital can be introduced only after
its premises - primarily those involving competi- value and surplus-value have been properly
tive capitalism - can be taken to hold. On its developed. Moreover, because the essential cir-
own grounds (which in this case involve a partic- cuit of rucr&itut capital involves “buying cheap
ular historical epoch), the law is accepted as and selling dear,” the question of the determina-
valid. tion of prices is critical; and this in turn means
*. 4

In sum, we find that so far as orthodox criti- that money - the connection between value and
cism is concerned (whether it be theoretical, price, surplus-value and profit - must be ade-
empirical, or historical), the basic principles of quately developed prior to the analysis of mer-
the doctrine of comparative costs emerge rela- chant capital. This last point bears repetition: a
tively unscathed. correct analysis of the role of money is abso-
lutely crucial to an understanding of the laws of
commodity trade. This applies whether the
Marxist critiques trading is done nationally or internationally.
It was of course Marx’s original intention to
Given Marx’s exhaustive treatment of Ricardo’ s extend the analysis presented in the three vol-
theory of value, it would seem that Marxists umes of Cupid to the treatment of international
long ago have extended his analysis in one way trade and the world market, each to be dealt
or another to deal with the Ricardian law of com- with in separate volumes (Marx, 1973, p. 54).
parative costs. Curiously enough, this is not so: But this never happened; instead, at the time of
instead, the issue is seldom mentioned (Mandel, Marx’s death even Volume III of Capitd existed
1968; Sweezy, 1942). Where it is discussed, Ri- only as a “first extremely incomplete draft”
cardo’s attempt to determine the limits of inter- (Marx, 1967, Vol. III, p. 2). Nonetheless, as I
national exchange is acknowledged only impli- shall attempt to prove in this chapter, the devel-
citly by accepting one of his central conclusions: opment of the law of value in Cupitd contains all
whereas the law of value regulates exchanges the necessary elements for its extension to inter-
within a competitive capitalist economy, it does national exchange. As we shall see, Ricardo’s
not do so between such economies (Sweezy, law af comparative costs follows immediately
1942, p. 289). from his law of value and his theory of money;
Why this striking silence? In part, it arises and Marx has provided us not only with detailed
from the fact that Marx himself never directly criticisms of Kicardo on both value and money,
accepts or rejects Ricardo’s principle of compar- but also with his own formulations of these sub-
ative costs. This appears to be a puzzle until we jects. The principal task of this paper is, there-
realize that, w Marx, RiCab93 r;hapte~- on fore, to attempt an extension of the Marxian law
foreign trade is essentially a special analysis of of value to international exchange.
merchant capital: “The great economists, such The paucity of references in Marx to interna-
as Smith, Ricardo, etc., are perplexed over mer- tional commodity trade is, however. only part of
cantile capital. . . . [Wlhenever they make a the explanation for Marxist ambivalence on the
special analysis of merchant’s capital, as Ri- subject. Another, equally important, part lies in
cardo does in dealing with foreign trade, they the fact that ever since the publication of
seek to demonstrate that it ueutes no value (and Lenin’s Irnperiulism (Lenin, 1939) it has become
consequently no surplus-value). But whatever is a Marxist commonplace to assert that capitalism
true of foreign trade, is also true of home trade” has entered its monopoly stage. Now, in the
(Marx, 1967, Vol. III, p. 324, emphasis added)., case of monopoly, it is widely accepted by
Historically, of course, merchant’s capital Marxists and non-Marxists alike that laws of
precedes industrial capital. But in the capitalist price formation must be abandoned (Sweezy,
mode of production it is industrial capital which 1942, pp. 270-l): “the most serious aspect of
The laws of international exchange 209

monopoly from an analytic point of view, is that he notes he would be “sorry to see weakened”
the discr.epancies between monopoly price and (Ricardo, 1951, p. 136). In Ricardo, therefore,
value are not subject to any general rules the analysis of flows between nations is essen-
(Sweezy, 1942, p. 54). What remain therefore tially confined to commodity flows, and it is his
are the basic social relations of capitalist com- contention that in this case Portugal’s absolute
modity productions, and it is to the various man- advantage is of no lasting consequence; in the
ifestations of these that the theory of monopoly end, only relative advantage matters, so that
capital turns. each nation is assured of having at least one
Of course, Once the Jaws nf price formation in exportable commodity to specialize in.
general are thrown out, the laws of international Emmund ucwpts Ricuudo’s luw OH its OWM
price formation necessarily follow. The focus grclunds (Emmanuel, 1972, pp. xxxii-iii). But,
shifts instead to the domestic and international he argues, its fundamental structure results from
rivalries of giant monopolies, to their political in- the fact that Ricardo restricts his analysis to
teraction with various capitalist states, and to those situations in which only commodities flow
the antagonisms and conflicts between these between countries. The modern world, on the
states themselves - in other words, to imperial- other hand, is characterized by massive interna-
ism as an aspect of mo~~opoly capitalism. The tional movements of capital, in addition to those
law of value, like competitive capitalism itself, of commodities (Emmanuel, 1972, p. xxxiv). To
fades into history. Emmanuel. therefore, the essential question is:
It is beyond the scope of this chapter to at- how do the international movements of capital
tempt a proper construction of a Marxist con- affect the previously valid Ricardian law of in-
cept of monopoly, so as to confront the views ternational exchange ? In other words, what is
mentioned here. It must be noted, however, that the appropriate form of this law in the modern
even an acceptance of the aforementioned views world?] l The emphasis on international capital
in no way puts to rest the ambivalence among movements is of course not unique to Em-
Marxists with regard to Ricardo’s law, any more manuel. In Marxist analysis of imperialism, for
than it resolves the recurring conflicts on the instance, the internationalization of capital plays
transformation problem, the theory of wages, an absolutely central role; even modern day pro-
etc.; instead, it merely sidesteps them? Like ponents of the law of comparative costs often go
their orthodox counterparts, these Marxist criti- on to treat the issue of foreign investment and in-
cisms leave the law of comparative costs still ternational capital mobility. In general, how-
standing - in the case of competitive capitalism, ever, these existing analyses treat capital flows
at least. as a factor strictly separate from the laws of in-
ternational commodity trade (Kenen, 1968);
what Emmanuel proposes to do instead, is to in-
Emmanuel and unequal exchange tqg-ate thib ulvvtxnent into the law itsrslf and, by
so doing, separate the determination of the laws
In recent years, this whole issue has been once of international exchange from any apologetic
again brought sharply into focus by Arghiri for free trade. To Emmanuel, “modern free
Emmanuel’s challenging new work entitled trade” is characterized by both capital tinci com-
Unq44al Exchange: A Study of the Impetkdism modity flows between nations. It is his avowed
uf Trade (Emmanuel, 1972). In this book, Em- intention, moreover, to demonstrate that it is
manuel sets out to overthrow the pernicious precisely the laws of this modern free trade,
doctrine of comparative costs by attacking what which, when applied to the trade between devel-
he argues is its most fundamental assumption - oped capitalist countries and the so-called Third
the immobility of capital between different World, l2 give rise to a variely 0lY phwwi~na
countries. lo In Ricardo’s original derivation of normally associated with the term “imperial-
the law, Emmanuel notes, Portugal is by as- ism” : Imperialism is the highest stage of free
sumption absolutely more efficient than England competition. I3
in both wine and cloth; hence, if Portugal and The first step in understanding Emmanuel’s
England were mere regions of the same nation, analysis is to pose the question: M?!ZJJ does capital
capital invested in Portugal would be consider- flow between countries? And the answer, of
ably more profitable, so that eventually the ab- course, is because there exists a difference in
solute advantage of the Portuguese region would profitability between the countries involved. So
lead to the cessation of both wine and cloth pro- the question becomes, what are the intrinsic de-
duction in the English region. But, says Ricardo, terminants of this difkrence?
Portugal and England are separate nations, and Let us begin with the selling price. In general,
in genera1 this erects significant barriers to the international capital produces for the ~~~rld
mobility of capital between them, barriers which market; if we ignore transportation costs (as
210 Anwar Shaikh

being secondary factors in determining the pat- between rich and poor countries, and wide-
tern of trade), then, no matter where production spread foreign domination of Third World coun-
is located, the selling price for a given type of tries (Emmanuel, 1972, pp. 262-3). The major
product is more or less the same - it is the world cause of all this, he argues, is foreign invest-
market price. Moreover, because commodities ment: the very same low wage/high profitability
do flow between countries, technology is also in- combination which coulc2’ make rapid develop-
ternationally mobile: aside from transportation ment possible in the Third World is exactly the
costs, a given type of plant and equipment can factor that also makes these countries so very
be located for more or less the same cost in any attractive to foreign capital. Because foreign in-
country accessible to international capital. l4 But vestment originates in countries in which the
if the selling price is more or less independent of average rate of profit is much lower than it is in
the international location of production, and the the Third World, foreign capitalists are generally
cost of a given plant and equipment is too, then willing to accept much lower rates of profit than
what gives rise to international differences in local capitalists; they therefore invade local
profitability? The answer, it would seem, could markets, driving out local capitalists, drawing
only be: the abundance of natural ,resources down prices and thus lowering the average rate
and/or the cheapness of wage labor. of profit in the Third World. In this way the
As long as the question is posed in terms of surplus generated in the Third World is siphoned
WZJJ two countries accessible to international off by foreign capital, to the detriment of the
capital, it is not possible to narrow down the list Third World and to the benefit of the developed
of factors any further. What Emmanuel has in capitalist countries. As a consequence, in the
mind, however, is not the relation between just developed capitalist world foreign investment
any two countries but rather the relation leads to higher profit rates, higher prices, and
between developed capitalist countries of the higher growth: hence prosperity and full em-
world and the so-called Third World, that is, the ployment. In the Third World, on the other
underdeveloped, capitalist-dominated countries. hand, the very same movement results in low-
And in terms of this division of the capitalist ered prices, lowered profits, and lowered
world, the overwhelmingly significant difference growth: hence stagnation, unemployment, and
arises from the rclativc chcapncss of wage labor foreign domination (Emmanuel, 1972, p. 265).
in the Third World. The United States is at least It is Emmanuel’s great merit to have revived
as rich in natural resources as India, but it is not the important issue of the laws of price forma-
uncommon to find Indian wages to be one- tion in international exchange, and in particular
twentieth those in the United States. Emmanuel to do so in a way that suggests that it is not nec-
estimates that “the average wage in the devel- essary to abandon the laws of competition in
oped countries is about thirty times the average order to be able to understand the intrinsic de-
in the backward countries” (Emmanuel, 1972, terminants of modem imperialism. But there are
p. 48). According to Emmanuel, therefore, cap- significant weaknesses in the manner in which’
ital flows from the developed to the underdevel- Emmanuel himself deals with this issue. To begin
oped capitalist countries primarily to take ad- with, though he uses Marxist categories such as
vantage of the enormous difference in the cost value and surplus-value, the methodological
of labor-power. basis on which his work rests, and from which
We come now to Emmanuel’s analysis of the he derives his implications, is fundamentally dif-
effects of these international capital movements. ferent from Marx’s; hence his political conclu-
Wages, it will be remembered, are enormously sions, though radical, are as different from
lower in the Third World, so that, other things Marx’s as were, for example, those of a rad-
being equal, profit rates for local capitalists ical contemporary of Marx - Pierre-Joseph
would be very high. If local capitalists tended to Proudhon.16 This, and the fact that his analysis
reinvest heavily, or if through government ac- of imperialism runs counter to that of Lenin, has
tion these profits could be taxed away and rein- led to a largely hostile reaction to his work
vested, high profit rates would imply a high rate among some Marxists (Bettelheim, in Em-
of growth of Third World countries - leading to manuel, 1972; Pilling, 1973).
rapid development, a narrowing gap between Many of the criticisms of Emmanuel are quite
rich and poor countries, and, above all, do- telling. But the challenge implicit in his work re-
mestic control of domestic resources. Whatever mains unanswered by those Marxists who are
else was wrong, there would at least be no content to merely locate the distance between
imperialism. l5 Emmanuel and Lenin. I7 These little exercises,
But the actual pattern appears to be the exact however illuminating, manage to neatly avoid
opposite of the above; what we observe, Em- two central questions. First of all, at the level of
manuel notes, is stagnation, a widening gap abstraction that Marx maintains in his three vol-
The laws of international exchange 211

umes of Capitol, is it really true (as many development. It is precisely because they are
Marxists appear to believe) that Ricardo’s law of unable to refute this law that the above theories
comparative costs is the international form of are forced to put the whole burden of uneven
Marx’s law of value? Second, is it true (as Em- development on capital movements.
manuel argues) that when the export of capital As long as Ricardo’s law is left standing, the
becomes significant the Marxian law of interna- well-known phenomena of uneven development
tional value is transformed into Emmanuel’s law appear inexplicable without some additional
of unequal exchange? factors: monopoly, foreign investment, political
Posed in this way, these questions have ex- power, conspiracy, etc. Now it can hardly be
x~ly tht: bame thrsoretical status as that of any dcnicd that these factors exist and are important
other law developed by Marx in Ccrpital. Marx to any analysis of uneven development on a
lays bare the structure of capitalism on the basis world scale. But the question is: are these
of its “ideal” form, that of free competition, pre- factors in themselves the intrinsic causes, or
cisely because it is this form that gives the freest does the cause lie elsewhere?
expression to the immanent laws of the system. In this chapter it will be argued that the phe-
It is on this basis that Marx derives exploitation, nomena of international uneven development
crises, concentration and centralization, and a arise directly from the so-called free trade of
host of other phenomena characteristic of capi- commodities. That is, just as Marx derives the
talism. Is it not curious, then, that whereas free concentration and centralization of capitals (and
and equal exc;hangt: within a capitalist nation hence their uncvcn development) from free and
gives rise to all of these phenomena, it does not unrestricted commerce within a capitalist na-
appear to do so when it takes place between cap- tion, so too is it possible to derive the phenom-
italist nations ? How is it that whereas Marx ena of imperialism from free and unrestricted
derives the unevenness of development within a commerce between capitalist nations. More-
capitalist nation on the basis of free competition, over, just as Marx’s law of value is the basis for
Marxists generally have to resort to monopoly to his analysis of uneven development within a
explain the unevenness of development het~~~n capitalist nation, so too will the international
capitali st nat ions? These are the questions we form of this law be the basis of the analysis of
turn to next. uneven development among capitalist nations.
What we will see, in cffcct, is that Ricu~~&‘s ILO+
uJ’ compawtive costs is fhlse on its very own
Towards a Marxist law of international grounds.
exchange Once this great stumbling block has been
overcome, the phenomena of imperialism will
Over a period of many years, the phenomena of appear in an entirely new light. Free trade,
international uneven development have come to rather than negating the inequalities between na-
be extensively studied and well documented tions, will be seen to deepen them. The absolute
(Amin, 1974; Nayter, 1972; Jale, 1969; Mag- advantages of the developed capitalist countries
doff, 1969; Payer, 1974). And, as we have seen, (such as Portugal in Ricardo’s famous example)
the existence of these phenomena has generally over the underdeveloped capitalist countries
been attributed to the internationalization of (England) will nut be reduced to a compara-
capital - that is, direct investment by the rich tive-advantage-for-all, as free traders have so
capitalist countries in the Third World. Ac- long asserted. On the contrary, free trade it-
cording to standard Marxist analysis, this inter- self will ensure that the advanced capitalist coun-
nationalization itself arises out of the monopoly tries will dominate international exchange,
stage of capitalism: for Emmanuel, on the other and that the less developed nations will end up
hand, it is merely a fuller development of the chronically in deficit and chronically in debt.
laws of competitive capitalism. In either case, If in fact free trade is uneven development,
the export of capital is the lynchpin of the theory then the question arises: what are we to make of
of imperialism. the export of capital, which plays so prominent a
In addition to their common emphasis on in- part in most other theories of imperialism? Does
ternational capital movements, both of the it offset, or does it enhance, the inequalities
above theories of uneven development accept arising from free trade?
Ricardo’s law of comparative costs as being The answer, it turns out, is that it does both.
valid on its own grounds. In fact, as we shall see, Foreign capital may improve an underdeveloped
this law is in a sense the “hidden secret” of the country’s trading position (and hence offset its
above theories: the law insists that free trade trade deficits) by modernizing and expanding its
between advanced and backward countries will export capabilities; but this will be undertaken
be mutually beneficial and productive of even precisely under the control and domination of
212 Anwar S h a i k h

foreign capital, and only insofar as it is to its own (and so convenient) with orthodox theorists, or
benefit. This, as we shall see, will have impor- at least to contrast his analysis with theirs.
tant implications. Nonetheless, I have tried to avoid doing this: the
primary comparison which can properly be
made here, and that only in a largely expository
A note on the structure of this chapter way, is the one between Ricardo and Marx. The
rest must await another occasion. But let this
In order to undertake the criticism of the law of much be clear: what follows is definitely not in-
comparative costs, we must first see precisely tended as a mere exercise in the history of eco-
how it is derived. The second major section nomic thought. So-called modem economic
therefore contains a brief exposition of Ri- theories of value and money are no more ca-
cardo’s theory of value, his theory of money, pable of withstanding Marx’s criticism than
and then of their interaction in the infamous law. were the classical theories. In a sense, the oppo-
The next step is to set up a similar path in sition between Marx and Ricardo explored in
Marx. In the third major section, first Marx’s this paper is the historical prelude to the more
theory of value (and his criticism of Ricardo’s) is modern confrontation.
outlined, and then his theory of money (with his
criticism of Ricardo’ s).
The first part of the fourth major section Ricardo’s derivation of the law of
unites the two theories in overthrowing the Ri- comparative costs:
cardian law of comparative costs: that is, we see
that when taken together they imply a determi- The Ricardian law of price. Ricardo held that the
nate theory of international exchange which principal problem facing political economy in his
flatly contradicts Ricardo’s law OYI its very owy1 day was the determination of the laws which reg-
grounds. It is in this section that the intrinsic ulate the distribution of the product of (capital-
cause of international uneven development is ist) society among the three great classes: that
seen to be free trade itself, quite independently is, the laws which determine “the natural course
of the traditional villains such as monopoly, of rent, profit, and wages” (Ricardo, 1951, p. 5).
foreign investment, political power, etc. But very soon in the course of his work Ri-
The second half of the fourth major section cardo realized that his analysis could not pro-
takes up the question of the export of capital. teed without a theory of price:
Here, it becomes possible to see how and why it Before my readers can understand the proof I
is the very unevenness of development (as it is IllGall tu uffer ) tht;y must uriclel-3 tancl tht:
reproduced and deepened by commodity trade), theory of currency and of price . . . If I
which in turn posits foreign investment as both could overcome the obstacles in the way of
the salvation n~ci at the same time the damnation giving a clear insight into the origin and law of
of the underdeveloped capitalist countries. It is relative or exchangeable value I should have
also possible at this point to see not only why gained half the battle. (Ricardo, 1951; pp.
Emmanuel’s analysis of imperialism is incorrect, xiv-v)
but also why his proposed solution would be Ricardo’s battle was never completely won;
useless. the question of the law of relative prices was to
At all times it is important to keep in mind that trouble him to the very end. But it is a measure
the very structure of the theory of international of his greatness that the problems he posed have
trade necessitates an introduction to theories of persisted in one form or another down to the
value and theories of money before we can even present.
begin the analysis of trade. Obviously, to do jus- In order to appreciate the gains made by Ri-
tice to Ricardo or Marx on either of these scores cardo we must carefully follow his line of rea-
could easily require volumes. And yet, we must soning. The problem he set himself was the
cover both value and money, in both authors, if determination of the luws which regulate relative
we are to proceed at all! prices. Now of course he was well aware that
Within the confines of a chapter this task can the immediate determinants of market prices
be undertaken only if one sticks to the bare es- were supply and demand; but over the course of
sentials. Consequently, in what follows, brevity time the ceaselessly fluctuating interplay of
has been attempted in the exposition of Ri- supply and demand was itself regulated by a
cardo’s and Marx’s theories. Particularly when more fundamental principle: equal profitability.
dealing with Marx, it is a great temptation to not Thus, if as a result of market conditions a partic-
only present and document the relevant struc- ular sector’s rate of profit rose above the
ture of his analysis but to also defend it against average rate, then the flow of capital would tend
the misrepresentations which are so popular to be biased towards that sector, causing it to
The laws of international exchange 213

grow more rapidly than demand, and driving duction of the inputs required to produce these
down its market price to a level consistent with inputs, and so on, then the total labor time h, re-
average profitability. Conversely, the sectors quired to produce one unit of commodity A is
with low profitability would tend to grow less the sum of its direct labor requirement 1, and its
rapidly than demand, causing their prices and indirect labor requirements la(l), lat2), . . . etc.
profitability to rise. (Sraffa, 1963, pp. 34-5).
The classical economists were thus able to A,, = 1 L( + ( 1 p + 1 p + . .)
l
(13.1)
demonstrate that behind the continuously
varying constellation of market prices there lay On the other hmd, Sraffa points out that if w
another set of more fundamental prices, acting is the uniform wage rate, and r the uniform rate
as centers of gravity for market prices and em- of profit, the price of production of commodity A
bodying more or less equal rates of profit. The is given by (Sraffa, 1960, p. 35)
name given to these regulating prices in classical
Pa = j,$,T( 1, + (1 + 1.)1,(l) + (1 + p1p + *’ .)
political economy was “natural prices,” what
(13.2)
Marx was to later call “prices of production.” l8
Their discovery was the first great law of prices. The preceding equations illustrate the impor-
All this was well known long before Ricardo’s tance of direct and indirect labor requirements:
time. What then was he searching for? Certainly their simple sum is the total labor requirement
not the means by which to calculate the prices of A~, and their weighted sum is the price of pro-
production. Ricardo exhibits many such calcula- duction pa.
tions himself, in the process of investigating his We come now to the critical point in the Ricar-
greater problem; so it is clear that a system of dian argument. In effect, what Ricardo argued
calculation, no matter how elegantly set out in was that even though both the labor require-
terms of matrices and vectors, would differ only ments and their weights (the wage-profit combi-
in form from the arithmetic relations set out by nations WJ) enter into the calculation of prices
Ricardo. What Ricavdo sought to do was some- of production, they are not equally important in
thing considerably more meaningful: to get be- causing changes in these prices.
hind prices of production, to discover their Let us first consider changes in the equilib-
“ r;t;nters of gravity. ’ ’ That is, just as the market rium price weights 1% ’ and r. First, as Sraffa so
price of a commodity was shown to be regulated elegantly demonstrates, a rise in the wage rate w
by its price of production, Ricardo sought to is necessarily accompanied by a fall in the rate of
show that this regulating price was itself subject profit r (Sraffa, 1960, pp. 39-40) so far as rela-
to a hidden governor - the total quantity of labor tive prices are concerned. Therefore, Ricardo
time required to produce the commodity, both in argued that on the average the opposing move-
its direct production process and, indirectly, in ments of these two weights would tend to cancel
the production of its means of production. each other out (Ricardo, 1951, p. 35-6). Fur-
“In speaking . . . of the exchangeable value thermore, it was his belief that in any case the
of commodities, or the power of purchasing pos- wage rate, being such a fundamental social
sessed by any one commodity, I mean always parameter, is only susceptible to relatively small
that power which . . . is natural price” (Ri- variations (Ricardo, 1951, p. 36): it is, as Keynes
cardo, 1951, p. 92). was later to say, “sticky.” Last, Ricardo was
“The great cause of the variation in the rela- careful to point out that the net effect of a rise in
tive value of commodities is the increase or the wage rate and a corresponding fall in the rate
diminution in the quantity of labour required to of profit varied from commodity to commodity:
produce them” (Ricardo, 1951, p. 36). whereas, it might raise some prices of produc-
There we have it: the great cause of the varia- tion, it would lower others, and leave others still
tions in the price of production of a commodity unchanged, so that it would have no determinate
is the variation in the total labor time that goes, effect on the direction of change of any given
directly or indirectly, into its production. The commodity price (Ricardo, 1951, p. 46).
total quantity of labor time was the center of We turn next to the remaining factor -
gravity of the commodity’s price of production, changes in labor requirements. Since any one
just as this price was itself the center of gravity commodity is only one of literally hundreds of
of its market price. This was Ricardo’s attempt thousands, an improvement in its conditions of
to formulate a second great law of prices. production is not likely to have much of an effect
Let me illustrate the logic behind this. Sraffa on the general sot al parameters WJ. Any such
(1960) has shown that if one unit of some com- improvement will, however, in general reduce
modity A requires 1, worker-hours for its direct its price bY lowering it s total labor req uirement
production, 1, (l) for the production of its physical ha: eithe r it will reduce direct labor cost s by low-
inputs (machines, raw materials), 1,(2) for the pro- ering direct labor requirements 1,; or it will re-
2 14 Anwar Shaikh

duce costs of physical inputs used up by saving for instance, roughly a l/4 ounce of gold was
on their use, thus lowering indirect labor re- known as a pound (f). A quantity of steel ex-
quirements la(l), luC2), . . . , etc.; or it will do changing for l/2 of an ounce of gold would
both. therefore be said to have a “price of &2. ”
Of course, a lower price for commodity A By the Ricardian law of prices, all commodi-
might lower costs for other commodities, and ties exchange roughly in proportion to the total
hence their prices too. But it is intuitively plau- labor-times required for their production. It
sible that these feedback effects will not in gen- follows, Ricardo notes, that the money prices of
eral be greater than the original, so that the net commodities are determined by the quantities of
effect 1s a lowering of the commodity’s price rel- the labor-times requiwd for their production rel-
ative to the average: a reduction in the total ative to the quantity of labor-time required for
labor requirement A, of a commodity would be the production of gold. Of course, gold cannot
associated with a reduction in its equilibrium have a money price in this sense, since it is
price pa. money. But to Ricardo, the quantity of steel (or
In estimating, then, the causes of the varia- corn, or cloth, etc.) purchased by &l (l/4 oz) of
tions in the value of commodities, although it gold could be viewed as a “commodity price” of
would be wrong wholly to omit consideration gold. He therefore often refers to the “value” of
of the effect produced by a rise or a fall of real gold.
wages, it would be equally incorrect to attach Suppose it takes 100 worker-hours to produce
much importance to it; and consequently, in a ton of steel, and that in a given year 4,000
the subsequent part of this work, although I tons are produced. The steel will then require
shall occasionally refer to this cause of varia- 400,000 worker-hours. If it takes l/2 worker-
tion, I shall consider all the great variations hours to produce &l (l/4 oz) of gold, then the
which take place in the relative price of com- money price of the year’s steel output will be
modities to be produced by the greater or less f800,000.
quantity of labour which may be required Steel, however, is only one of a whole range
from time to time to produce them. (Ricardo, of commodities produced in a given year. During
1951, p. 36) any one year, therefore, the same gold coin may
Ricardo is true to his word. In the chapters change hands several times, being received by
that follow he ignores the secondary variations one person through the sale of a commodity and
in prices by simply assuming that relative prices then being given over to someone else when it is
are more or less equal to relative labor-times. used to buy another commodity. In this way the
Both the analysis of money and that of foreign same gold coin can function as money more than
trade is conducted on this basis. once, in a given year. Let us say that on the
It should be very clear from the above, inci- average a coin changes hands five times a year;
dentally, that Ricardo’s law of prices in no way its velocity of circulation is then five.
depends on the “assumption of a single factor of Imagine now that the labor-time required for
production” (Johnson, 1968, p. 85), as is so all the commodities produced in a given year is
often asserted. It is hard to believe that anyone 40 million worker-hours. Since we stated pre-
who has ever read Ricardo can make this claim; viously that &l (l/4 oz.> of gold requires l/2
even for a mind steeped in the marginalities of worker-hours, the money price of the society’s
neoclassical thinking it must be difficult to con- yearly output will be &80 million. Moreover, if
front Ricardo and come away with nonsense like the velocity of circulation of f coins is indeed
that. lg five, this means that only 16 million gold coins,
each weighing &l (l/4 oz) will be required as /
The classical quantity theory of money. Having money in that year.
analyzed at great length the causes of the varia- Of course, the laws discussed so far apply
tions in relative prices, Ricardo then proceeds to only to prices of production. We know from the
the causes of variations in the level of (money) laws of market prices, however, that if a com-
prices. For reasons outlined previously, we as- modity’s supply exceeds its demand, then the
sume (as does Ricardo) that gold is the money market price of the commodity will fall, that is, it
commodity. will exchange for less of other commodities. If
The money price of a commodity is of course this law is also applied to money it leads straight-
its relative price expressed in terms of the away to the proposition that when the quantity
money commodity; that is, its rate of exchange of gold coin exceeds the requirements of circula-
with gold. Thus, the price of steel is so many tion (the demand for coin), the “price” of gold
units of gold; normally, when gold is used as will fall. Now, since gold is money, it cannot
money, there arise special names for specific have a money price; however, since it can be
weights of it. In England around Ricardo’s time. used to Purchase anv commoditv on the market.
it can be said to have literally thousands of Table 13.1.
“commodity prices ,’ ’ these being the quantities
of the various commodities one can buy with &I England Portuga2
(l/4 oz) of gold. The quantity theory of money
therefore asserts that when the quantity of gold Cloth: 100 hrs 50 02 g o l d 45 o z gold 90 hrs :Cloth
cuin exceeds the requirt=meriCs of circulalion, afI Wine : 120 hrs 60 oz gold 40 QZ gold 80 h-s :Wine

the commodity prices of gold will fall; since this


means that gold wit1 purchase less of each com-
modity, it is equivalent to asserting that all
money prices will rise. all countries, one escudo Cl/6 oz) of guld would
If we consider England as a closed economy then require l/3 worker-hours to produce. If
with gold produced within its borders, then the then in Portugal cloth took 90 worker-hours, and
reduced price of gold - the higher prices of all wine 80 worker-hours, their domestic prices of
other commodities - would, according to Ri- production would be roughly 270 e. and 240 e.,
cardo’s theory, result in reduced output from the respectively.
goMmines. This reduction in the supply of gold But note that both Z’s and e.‘s are merely dif-
would in turn eventually raise its price, so that ferent national money-names for quantities of
once again gold would exchange against other gold. If England’s payments to foreigners ex-
cnmmcbditie,s i n pmportinn tn th4=%- respxt~ve ceeded its receipts from them, that is, if it Tan St
labor- times. balance of payments deficit, gold bullion would
If instead, gold were produced in a foreign eventually have to be used to make up the dif-
country like South Africa, then to say that the ference.20 Since both currency units are actually
“price” of gold in England has been lowered is to quantities of gold, and the international means of
say that its purchasing power over commodities payment is in fact gold bullion, we can consider-
has been reduced. Gold will therefore have dif- ably simplify the exposition by expressing all
ferent purchasing powers in different countries, prices directly in ounces of gold. Given that an
and will flow out of England into countries ounce of gold requires two hours of labor-time,
where its “price” is higher; once again, the effect we have the following Ricardian tableau for Eng-
will he to lower the quantity of money in Eng- land and Portrrgal (Table 13.1).
land, and hence raise the “price” of gold back Clearly, in this initial situation Portugal’s
towards its natural level. In this way the interna- greater efficiency in production translates
tional Aows of gold would lead to more or less directly in an absvllrte adljantctge in trade. If
the same purchasing power of (gold) money in transportation costs are not prohibitive, Por-
all countries. This conclusion of the classical tuguese capitalists will export both commodi-
quantity theory of money is known as the doc- ties. England will experience a continuing bal-
trine of “purchasing power parity” (Johnson, ance of trade deficit, which will have to be made
1968, pe 92). up by shipping gold to Portugal.
According to Ricardo, it is at this point that
The law of internationa1 exchange. The critical the quantity theory of money becomes crucial.
element in Ricardo’s law of comparative cost is The outflow of gold from England is a decrease
really the quantity theory of money, because it is in its domestic supply of money, so that ac-
through its operation that the law is derived. cording to the quantity theory the goid prices of
However, in order to follow Kicardo’s analysis, lrll English commodities will begin to fall. Con-
we wiU also use his law of prices. versely, the inflow of gold to Portugal will raise
Let us begin by considering two commodities, alI prices there. As this happens, Portugal’s
cloth and wine, produced in England; cloth re- competitive edge in international markets will
quires 100 worker-hours to produce, and wine gradually erode, even though it will of course
120 worker-hours. If, as in our previous ex- have just as great an advantage in terms of effi-
amples, &I (l/4 oz) of goId required 3/2 ciency as it did before. It is just that this greater
worker-hour to produce, then from Ricardo’s efficiency will be increasingly offset by the rise
law of prices the prices of production of cloth in Portuguese prices relative to those in Eng-
and wine would be more or less equaJ to their land.
respective labor-times relative to that of gold. Sooner or later In this process one of the two
Cloth would sell at about ~5200, and wine at English commodities will become just competi-
about X240, domestically. tive with its Portuguese counterpart. But which
Consider now the same two commodities in one? Well, in terms of efficiency, England al-
Portugal. The unit of money in Portugal we take ways has an absolute disadvantage relative to
to be an VSCU&I (e.), roughly 116 of an ounce of Portugal in both commodities. But as all English
gold; assuming the same labor-time for gold in prices fall and all Portuguese prices rise, the
216 Anwar Shaikh

English commodity with the smnllust disadvan- gains from trade. Thus it is said that England can
tage will be the first to overtake its Portuguese get more wine for its cloth through trade than it
rival. If we examine the Ricardian tableau, can get domestically: trade is generally benefi-
(Table 13.1) we fmd that English wine produc- cial. Though Rieardo is careful to derive the
tion is only 66 2/3 percent as efficient as its Por- laws of trade on the basis of its profitability to
tuguese rival (since Portuguese wine takes 80 capitalists, when he turns to the analysis of the
hours and English wine takes 120 hours), effects of trade he abandons the concept of
whereas English cloth production is 90 percent classes and reverts to that of a natiun-as-~-
as ef~cient as Portuguese* England’s smallest whole. Now, it is undeniable that the concept of
disadvantage JI i t s ~~~~~~~~?~ advantages l i e s i n a nation is both valid and necessary at some
cloth, and as English prices drop relative to Por- level of analysis; nations do exist and their in-
tuguese, it is English cloth which first becomes teraction is a real process. But to assert that
competitive. By the same token, it is clear that if trade is beneficial to the nation-as-a-whole is
England has an equal disadvantage in both simply to assert that ‘“what’s good for General
sectors of pr~ductiun then both English eom- Motors is good for the US.” Trade is under-
modities would become e~mpetitiv~ at exactly taken by capitalists because they can make more
the same point. Though trade could still take profits that way; it is they who always gain.
place under these cireumstances~ there would be Even if this gain for the capitalists happens to
no fixed basis fur specialization* Only if England spill over to workers in either country, which is
has different disadvantages in the two eommodi- certainly not necessary from the above analysis,
ties, that is, only if it has a relative advantage in one can only say that in this instance trade also
one, can Ricardian trade take place? benefits a particular set of workers. It is not pos-
Once England can compete in cloth, two-way sible to reduce the fundamentally antagonistic
trade will begin. This will improve England’s relations of classes to the bland homogeneity of
trade picture, but it will probably not eliminate a nation-as-a-wholes Christians are not in a posi-
the deficit; price level movements will therefore tion to cheer for lions as long as they are both
continue to take place, strengthening England’s booked to play in the Coliseum.
international position and weakening Portugal’s
- l~~~t~~ ~~~llzy at SOme poiizt trude ~~~~~ ~~~~~~ 01 Moans ~e~ivat~~~~ of the law, It should be ubvi-
/PSS ~~~~~~~, with each country exporting the ous from the preceding derivation how crucial
one commodity in which it HOW has a relative ad- the “right” sort of monetary theory is to the
vantage. If for some reason the adjustment derivation of the law of comparative costs. Any
process goes too far, to the point where even monetary theory which translates the initial
English wine undersells Portuguese, then the en- trade deficit of the backward country into falling
suing gold flows would reverse the price level price levels (falling relative to the price level in
movements until once again relative advantage the advanced cou~t~~~ will do the trick. We need
reigned. therefore to say a bit about the modem deriva-
An important implication of the process of ad- tions of this law.
justment is that in the end each country’s inter- Let us begin with a modern version of the
national terms of trade (the quantity of imports quantity theory, based on the cash balance ap-
that can be bought with a unit of its exports) will proach. The classical quantity theory argued
necessarily be better than its domestic, In Eng- that an outflow of gold from a country would
land, for example, the cloth on the market will lead to a fall in the money supply and hence in
be English cloth; but the wine available will gen- the price level. Here, it is argued that the de-
erally be imported from Portugal. Those whose crease in the money supply implies a decrease in
unbounded patriotism would require them to in the cash balances of individuals and firms; in
sist on English wine will have to pay a higher order to “not let their cash balances shrink too
price fur it than they would for the imported far,” people in the deficit country curtail their
variety* Therefore, a unit of cloth, England’s ex- consumption and investment spending, and this
port commodity will be worth more units of drop in aggregate demand in turn leads to lower
Po~uguese wine than it will be af domestic wine prices and wages (Yeager, 1966, p, 64). The op-
simply because domestic wine costs more. Simi- posite movement takes place in the surplus
larly, in P~~ugal, its export, wine, is worth more country, and eventually absolute advantage
units of English cloth than it is of Portuguese gives way to comparative.
cloth simply because the English cloth is An alternate path to this same result is made
GhtXpX. possible by tying the price level to the level of
The proposition just forwarded, on the terms money wages. In this version, since the competi-
of trade of each country has often been used as tion of cheap cloth and wine from abroad means
the basis of a proof that each nation-as- ,a-whole a reduction in dumestic wine and cloth produc-
The laws of international exchange 217

tion in the backward country, the resulting trade in this mode, therefore, it operated like a system
deficit will be associated with a rise in un- of fixed exchange rates. The theoretical notion
employment. Money wages in the backward of the two polar extremes of fixed versus flexible
country will consequently fall, and with them exchange rates thus have their origin in one-
money prices; in the advanced country, the sided (and hence false) abstractions of the real
trade surplus is associated with expanded em- process. We will return to this important point
ployment, a rise in money wages, and hence a later on.
rise in money prices. Even if money wages were
relatively sticky downwards, the above result
would hold since all that is required is a move- Marx’s development of the laws of capitalist
ment in one of the two price levels so as to arrive exchange
at the correct relative price levels. Once again,
this leads to the eventual rule of comparative ad- As the preceding discussion of Ricardo should
vantage (Amin, 1974, p. 47). have made clear, it is the interaction of the Ri-
All discussions so far have been predicated in cardian theory of price with his theory of money
terms of the gold standard, in which the “ulti- which results in the law of comparative costs.
mate” basis of international currency is a money Now, as we turn to Marx, we face the task of
commodity (which we call gold for conve- trying to present, in a few short pages, the es-
nience). In most theoretical discussions, the sence of Marx’s theories of price and money so
gold standard is treated as being equivalent to a that we may see what implications they in turn
regime of fixed exchange rates. The preceding have for international exchange. Here, the over-
modern derivations of comparative advantage riding question is whether the international ex-
are therefore also presented as holding true for tension of Marx’s law of value will indeed turn
the case of fixed exchange rates. out to be the law of comparative costs (as has
At the opposite theoretical extreme from fixed been generally assumed), or whether it will in
exchange rates, we are told, lies the notion of fact turn out to be something quite different.
purely flexible exchange rates determined solely Marx’s law of value has, of course, many
by the relative supplies and demands of the na- points of comparison with Ricardo’s analysis;
tional currencies. Here it is possible that each often, through an emphasis on these common
nation will have a fully independent monetary points, the impression is given that Marx was
system (Yeager, 1966, p. 104). In this case, the therefore a (major or minor) post-Ricardian clas-
price levels in each country are “insulated” sical economist. Such an impression is, how-
from external influences, and all adjustments are ever: completely misleading and can arise only
brought about through the exchange rate. In the through the redtiction of Marx’s analysis to only
backward country the trade deficit will imply a those points which overlap with Ricardo’s. As
depreciation of the country’s currency, which long as one begins with Ricardo as the home
would make imports relatively more expensive base, all such comparisons are inevitably posed
to it and its exports relatively cheaper abroad. in Ricardian terms; Marx thus emerges as the
Since this process is assumed to have no limits, cleverest Ricardian of them all.
eventually the flexible exchange rate would Within the context of this brief exposition, it is
settle at the level which made comparative ad- hardly possible to do justice to even the notions
vantage a reality. of value and price in Marx, much less to the
We cannot consider the merits of these methodological break between Marx and the
various derivations until we have examined classical economists. Of necessity, many of the
Marx’s theory of money. But it is useful to note points we seek to cover are precisely points of
even at this point that it is completely false to comparison with Ricardo; nonetheless, the
equate the notion of the gold standard with fixed reader must be forewarned that the differences
exchange rates. As indicated at the end of this which do emerge are not merely variations on a
chapter, note 20, in actual fact the gold standard Ricardian theme. On the contrary, it is exactly
was a system of flexible exchange rates whose because Marx does not operate within a Ricar-
movements were hounded by limits determined dian framework that he is able to go beyond Ri-
by the costs of transporting gold. This meant cardo’s own analysis.22
that insofar as the “normal” variations of trade
were concerned, the gold standard operated as if Commodities. In the discussion of Ricardo’s law
it wcrc a system of purely flcxiblc cxchangc o f prices, the fundamental question seemed
rates. On the other hand, insofar as systematic fairly well defined: what are the laws of the
imbalances were concerned, the exchange rate movements of prices of production?
soon reached one of the two limits and it became What Ricardo perceives is that the “worth,”
cheaper to settle debts by shipping gold directly: the “exchangeable value,” or commodities
218 Anwar Shaikh

bears an intrinsic connection to labor-time gold, for instance, gold must also be worth
(Marx, 1969, pp. 164-7). This, says Marx, is Ri- something itself. Otherwise I cannot say how
cardo’s greatest scientific merit (Marx, 1969, much gold is equivalent to a bushel of corn. It is
p. 166). But at the same time, rather than devel- just like my saying that a stone weighs 10 grams;
oping the various intermediary links between what I mean is that on a scale it takes ten pieces
labor-time and price, Ricardo attempts instead of iron called gram-weights to equal the weight
to fuse the two together in his law of prices. His of the stone. But clearly, in order for me to carry
failure to adequately distinguish between labor- out this operation, both stone and iron must
time and price is, according to Marx. the first already possess the property of being heavy, of
great source of error in his analysis (Marx, 1969, having weight; the gram-weights don’t make
Ch. X; pp. 106, 164, 174-6). stones heavy, they only measure the already ex-
In addition to that, however, there is another isting heaviness of stones.
problem. How can Ricardo attempt to analyze Exactly the same conclusion applies to quanti-
the effects of a uniform rate of profit on prices, tative worth. The factors which cause conlmodi-
asks Marx, when he nowhere discusses what de- ties to have quantitative worth in the first place
termines the level of this rate of profit? And this must be carefully distinguished from the mea-
in turn leads to an even more basic question. A surement of this worth. Measuring the worth of
uniform rate of profit is simply a way of saying corn in iron will give a different result from mea-
that profits on different capitals are proportional suring it in gold; but neither measure causes
to the size of these capitals: that is, each capital corn to possess quantitative worth. Rather, each
gets a share of total profit in proportion to its merely expresses the preexisting worth of corn
own size. But Ricardo nowhere discusses what in terms of some particular commodity.
determines the total profit in the first place. How The question of price is therefore really a
then can he attempt to isolate the factors which two-fold one: first, what is the cause of quantita-
regulate the movements of prices of production tive worth; and second, how is this worth actu-
when he is missing a crucial ingredient - profit? ally expressed, measured, in exchange?
It is apparent to Marx that before one can ar-
rive at the laws which govern price, one must Value. If we look at society as a regularly repro-
first answer two prior questinns: first, what is duced set of social relations, it becomes very
meant by price and how does it arise? And sec- clear that the production and reproduction of the
ond, what is meant by profit, and how does it masses of useful objects which correspond to
arise? various social needs requires a definite, quanti-
Since the concept of price refers to the ex- tative distribution of social labor. Each different
change of commodities, Marx begins by exam- useful product requires a concretely different
ining what a commodity is. In all societies, he type of labor; reproduction of the material basis
notes, human beings produce useful objects. It is or tlit: suc;itAy cvr~sequ~r~lly r-txpirt;s tlit: ksl-
only in a particular type of society, however, ence and reproduction of the appropriate quan-
that the useful products of human labor are in- tities of different concrete labors. That is to say,
tended not for some direct social use but for ex- social labor from the point of view of its capacity
change. And precisely because exchange is a so- to produce different use-values is what Marx
cial process which quantitatively compares and calls social-labor in its role as concrete labor
equates different products, in societies which (Marx, 1967, Vol. I, p. 46).
produce for exchange the products of human We noted earlier, however, that in commod-
labor acquire the property of having quantitative ity-producing societies each product, in addi-
worth. No longer are they merely useful; they tion to being useful, acquires the further prop-
a~ ww also valuable: they are commodities. As erty of being valuable. Hence, labor which
Marx expresses it, a commodity is both a use- produces commodities (i.e., objects intended for
value and an exchange value. exchange) itself acquires a new property:
But when we say that a commodity is worth namely, the capacity to create value or quantita-
something, just what is implied? Suppose I say tive worth. In this role, moreover, all com-
that in barter, a bushel of corn is worth a ton of modity-producing labor is qualitatively alike,
iron, and also a yard of silk, and an ounce of since different types of labor differ only in
gold, and so on. At first glance, what I appear to their resulting amounts of value. The very same
be saying is that there are many different quanti- social conditions which make varied useful ob-
tative expressions for the worth of a bushel of jects quantitatively comparable by reducing
corn, depending on which other commodity them to a common denominator, also make the
(iron, silk, or gold) I choose to meusure it by. corresponding labors quantitatively comparable.
But there is a deeper problem here. In order In the case of the useful objects, their common
for me to measure the worth of corn in terms of denominator is auantitative worth: in the case of
The laws of international exchange 219

the labors, it is the capacity to result in quantita- We turn now to the second aspect of price:
tive worth. From the point of view of this latter how is quantitative worth actually expressed in
property social labor is qualitatively alike and exchange? To this Marx answers: in exchange,
quantitatively comparable: it is what Marx calls the quantitative worth of a commodity must nec-
social labor in its capacity as abstract labor. Ab- essarily take the form of money-price. Since ex-
stract labor, that is, labor which is actually change is the interchange of two commodities, at
engaged in commodity production, is the cause first glance it seems obvious that there are as
of quantitative worth. 23 The total quantity of ab- many measures of a commodity’s worth as there
slracl labor r-cquirt;d dil-ectly or indirectly for the are other commodities to measure it by. And his-
production of a commodity Marx therefore calls torically, where exchange is sporadic or irregu-
the intrinsic measure of its quantitative worth, lar, this is in fact true. But as exchange spreads
or its value. and develops, this variety of different possible
The value of a commodity, the intrinsic mea- measures increasingly becomes a barrier to the
sure of its exchange-value or worth, is the quan- smooth functioning of the process; without a
tity of abstract labor-time necessary for the pro- point of reference, the direct comparison of
duction of the commodity under average condi- every commodity with every other becomes
tions. If looms, for instance, are made in one impossibly complex. Consequently it becomes
year by hand, and in a given year 100 looms are increasingly necessary to settle on a given com-
produced, SO by t;ffic;it;n t p-oducers rr=quiring modity out of all those available as the one com-
900 worker-hours per loom and 50 by inefficient modity in which all other commodities express
producers requiring 1,100 worker-hours per their worth; this special commodity therefore
loom, then the value of a loom in that year is becomes the universal equivalent, the money-
1,000 worker-hours. It is the average quantity of commodity. We will henceforth assume it is
labor-time necessary, not as in Ricardo, the gold.
marginal, which counts here (Marx, 1967, Vol. I, Notice that money does not by itself cause
p. 39). commodities to have worth, any more than
Suppose the production of a bolt of cloth took gram-weights cause stones to have weight. On
10 workers ten hours a day for one week (six the contrary, it is only because both gold and the
days) to gather cotton seed, plant it, harvest tilt: o t h e r commodities have quantitative worth
cotton, and with the aid of a loom, spin the (exchange-value) in the first place that we can
cotton into cloth. Then the value of the cloth has express their worth in terms of gold. The
two components: the living labor of the cloth money-price of a commodity is the “golden” re-
worker, 600 worker-hours, which represents the flection, the external measure, of its exchange-
value added in cloth production during one value. It is what Marx calls the $5~~2 taken by
week; and that part of the value of the loom value during exchange (Marx, 1967, Vol. I, pp.
which is transferred to the cloth. But how is the 47-8).
latter to be determined? Well, if the loom was
used up in one week then it is clear that all the Price. We have already seen that value, the in-
value of the loom would be incorporated into the trinsic measure of exchange-value or quantita-
cloth, since from a social point of view the tive worth, and price, the external measure, are
labor-time required to build the loom is the indi- two very different things. Money-price is the
rect social cost of producing cloth. If the loom manner in which the exchange process reflects
lasted longer, say one year (50 weeks), then over value. This in itself implies that all the relations
one year it will be entirely used up and all of its which intervene between the production of a
value transferred to the 50 bolts of cloth pro- commodity and its actual sale can give rise to
duced in that period of time. On the average, further determinants of the precise form in
therefore, the loom would transfer l/50 of its which this reflection will take place. For in-
value each year to a bolt of cloth. Because the stance, in general the market price of a commod-
second case is basically the same as the first, we ity is an expression not only of the amount of ab-
will simplify the exposition from now on by stract labor-time required for its production (its
assuming a uniform period of turnover of one value) but also of the distribution of social labor
week. Then the value of the cloth is 1,600 - that is, of the correspondence between the
worker-hours: 1,000 of these trawferred by the amount of social labor devoted to the production
loom as it is used up, 600 added by living labor. of a given commodity and the amount necessary
If we designate the total value of any output to supply the social need for this commodity. if
produced in a given week as W, the value trans- at any moment this latter correspondence does
ferred by its means of production as C, and the not hold, it will show up in the process of ex-
value added by living labor as L, then: change as a discrepancy between supply and de-
C+L=W (13.3) mand; t,hen even if on the average exchange is at
220 Anwar Shaikh

value it will not be so in this case. Market price italist’s cost would be equal to his price: there
will deviate from natural price. would be no profit! For capitalist production to
Marx himself points out this and other pos- be profitable, workers must accept as wages the
sible discrepancies between value and price money equivalent of a value less than that
(Marx, 1972, pp. 61-2). But he notes, the only which they themselves add to the product. But
way in which we can proceed to actually deter- then, it would seem, exchange is no longer at
mine any quantitative differences between value values !
and price is to first proceed on the assumption This paradox was in fact a major source of
that price directly reflects value - that is, that problems in classical political economy, and
supply and demand are balanced (so that market Marx considered the solution to it one of his
prices equal regulating prices, or natural prices) great triumphs. 25 The way out, Marx shows,
and that the money-price of a commodity is its lies in the distinction between labor-time and
value relative to the value of gold. In this way labor-power. What workers sell in the market is
we can identify the structural determinants of their capacity-for-labor, not their labor time.
the various steps in the movement from produc- The capitalist pays them a wage in return for the
tion to exchange, and hence of the transition right to set them to work each day; but how long
from value to price. Only then can we show how they work and how hard, how many hours of
these structural determinants can in turn give average labor-time the capitalist actually gets
rise to more complex paths from value to price out of them, will depend on the struggle between
(Marx, 1967, Vol. I, p. 166, footnote 1).24 capital and labor. Quite apart from the wage rate,
the intensity of labor and the length of the work-
Surplus-value and profit. We come now to the ing day have always been important battle
second major criticism that Marx levels against grounds in the class struggle. The capacity-to-
Ricardo: his inadequate treatment of profit. labor, what Marx calls labor-power, is therefore
Let us begin by recalling that it takes 1,000 very different from labor-time: it is the sum of
worker-hours of abstract labor-time to produce a the mental and physical capabilities which a
loom by hand, and 600 additional worker-hours worker can put to use in production, and as
to use this loom in producing cloth: C = 1,000, such, its production and reproduction implies
L = 600, W = 1,600. that workers must receive as wages enough
1000C + 600L = 1600W = value of cloth (13.4) money to buy their means of subsistence: food,
shelter, education, and training - in short, what-
But from the point of view of the capitalist, ever is necessary to reproduce themselves as
the matter looks very different. To him, the workers. The value of labor-power, the social
process starts with an investment of money M labor-time required for the reproduction of
and ends with the sale of the loom for. another workers’ capabilities, is therefore the value of
sum of money M’. The difference between the their means of subsistence.
two, AM = M' - M, is that all important sum, The paradox is now resolved. Workers enter
profit. How does this have anything to do with production as inputs having a specific value;
labor-time, he asks? they leave production having added a quantity of
Well, since exchange is in proportion to val- value to the product through their labor-time.
ues, if the value of an ounce of gold is two From the point of view of capitalist society,
worker-hours, then the money-price of the cloth therefore, profit can only arise if the abstract
must be 800 oz of gold. That gives us the end of labor-time socially necessary to sustain workers
the circuit of capital: M' = 800 oz of gold. (the value of their labor-power) is less than the
What about the beginning? From the point of labor-time that they actually put in (the value
view of the capitalists, the initial investment M they add to production); in other words, if
goes to buy the inputs of the process. One part workers produce surplus-value. Profit is the
of M, which I will call MC, goes therefore to buy money equivalent, the money form of appear-
a loom; since the value of a loom is 1,000 ance of surplus-value. In the case of cloth pro-
worker-hours, its price is 500 oz: MC = 500 oz duction, the value added by 10 workers in a
of gold. week is 600 worker-hours; if the value of their
The other input is, of course, labor. But what labor-power was 400 worker-hours, the sur-
does it cost? Living labor, we have seen, plus-value would be 200 worker-hours. Wages
transfers the value of the loom to the value of the would be 200 oz of gold so that profit AM =
product (cloth), and adds 600 worker-hours of M' - M = 800 - (500 + 200) = 100 oz: profit
value in the process. If exchange is at values, is the money equivalent of surplus-value.
then the value-added by living labor is equiva- We can summarize all this diagramatically.
lent to 300 oz of gold-money. Clearly, if the Let V stand for the value of labor-power, and Mv
labor input cost as much as 300 oz, then the cap- for its money equivalent (the monev-capital ex-
The laws of internationnl exchnnge 221

AM each will vary with the number of workers em-


/ ploy ed.
\
This has two immediate consequences for the
M (CW) . . . . PRODUCTION en.. (Cd) A4
issue of profitability. First of all, the ratio S/V,
\ / the rate oj’ surp/~s-value, will be the same in
S every sector. Second, since the proportion of
L : V is the same in every sector, the ratio C/V,
the organic composition of capital, will in each
sector be proportional to the ratio C/L. So
pended on wages). Since L is the value added by whether or not C/V is, like S/V, the same in
living labor, L - V = S is the surplus-value pro- each sector will depend on whether or not C/L is
duced bv workers. In Figure 13.1, the circuit the same.
begins with a money investment A4 = MC + The ratio CfL however, is in general not likely
Mv, with which the capitalist purchases means to be uniform across sectors. It is the ratio of the
of production (a loom) having value C, and hires labor-time embodied in the means of production
labor-power (10 workers) having value V; what to the living labor-time required to transform
‘emerges from the process of production is a these into the product; as such it reflects the
product having value C + L, which then sells technical conditions of production in each
for its money-equivalent A4’. The surplus-value sector, and unless they are generally similar, it
S is thus reflected in its money-equivalent, the will vary from sector to sector. This in turn
profit AM. means that although the rate of surplus-value,
S/V, is iniform across sectors, in general the
Prices of production. We have up to now as- organic composition, C/17, is not. From the cx-
sumed exchange in proportion to values, so that pression for the rate of profit in equation 13.5
we may isolate the intrinsic determinants of we can see that sectors with a high organic com-
price and profit. This is how Marx begins; but position will have a low rate of profit, and vice
then he immediately goes on to point out that in versa. It is an inescapable implication therefore,
general prices proportional to values would im- that prices which are proportional to values will
ply different rates of profit in different sectors. in general embody unequal rates of profit.
Figure 13.1 illustrates the problem. If all When prices are proportional to values, profit
money prices are proportional to values, then in in any given sector is directly determined by the
every sector the money investment 44 will be surplus-value produced in that sector alone; but
proportional to the value cost C + V, and then, as we have seen, rates of profit will differ
noney profits M will be proportional to from sector to sector. It follows therefore that if
surplus-value S. It follows from this that the rates of profit are to be equalized, if high and low
money rate of profit (AM/M) in each sector will rates of profit are to be made equal to the social
be equal to the corresponding value rate of average, some sectors must get less profit, and
profit: others more, than that indicated by their respec-
tive surplus-values. This can only come about if
(AM/M) = S/(C + V) = & (13.5) prices of production deviate from direct prices in
a systematic way so as to redistribute the total
The expression for the value rate of profit ob- pool of surplus-value: in other words, in order
viously depends on the two ratios S/V and C/V. that the equal rates of surplus-value in various
We therefore need to Jo,ok at these a little more sectors be realized in exchange as equal rates of
closely. money profit, the sale of products must actually
Recall that surplus-value S is the excess of the take place at prices which differ systematically
value added (L) by living labor over the value of from direct prices.
its labor-power. Now, if the wage rate is the Clearly, what is involved here is aschange, a
same for each worker (assuming that all labor is transformation, in the form-ofivalue (money
of the same skill level - the issue of skill dif- price). But such a transformation can in no way
ferences is outside of the scope of this chapter), alter the total sum of values or the total pool of
then the value of labor-power is the same for surplus-value; the same products as before are
each; if in any given period each worker puts in circulated, only now at different prices which
the same amount of labor-time as any other, therefore entail a dBerent sharing out of the
then each adds the same value to the product. pool of surplus value.
Consequently, each worker produces the same Marx deals with the transformation in the
amount of surplus-value. It follows therefore form-of-value in a simple and powerful way. Ba-
that in every sector the proportions of L: S: V sically, he points out that when exchange is
will be the same, though the respective size of ruled by direct prices, sectors with hinher than
222 Anwar Shaikh

average organic compositions C/V will have transformed money rate of profit is directly re-
lower than average rates of profit, and vice versa lated to the value rate of profit, though they
(look at equation 13.5 to see why); from this need not be equal in magnitude.26
Marx concludes that in order for each sector’s For most analyses, knowledge of the above
profit rate to be equal to the social average, connections is generally sufficient. In this chap-
sectors with high organic compositions must ter, therefore, I have used only direct prices
therefore sell their products at prices above their and Marx’s derivation of prices of production,
respective direct prices, while sectors with low on the implicit understanding of the connection
organic compositions must sell at prices below between the latter and their further-developed
thei r-espective direct prices. What takes place form.
in the transformation from direct prices to prices
of production is a kind of rotation of prices, with The theory of money. We began the analysis of
the average price as the (unchanged) center of price by noting that a commodity is a product of
rotation. The total sum of prices is unaltered, as human labor which is not just useful but also
is total profit; they remain directly proportional valuable. This led us to examine the duality
to the total sum of values and the total implicit in the notion of quantitative worth,
surplus-value respectively. Hence the average which in turn led to the sharp distinction
rate is simply equal to the value rate of profit, as between value, the intrinsic cause of quantita-
in equation 13.5. tive worth, and money-price, the measure or ex-
In his exposition, and in several other places, pression of this worth in terms of some universal
Marx notes the existence of what I call a feed- equivalent (gold). In order for commodities to be
back effect of the transformation just men- equal in worth to some quantity of gold, that is,
tioned: since individual prices of production in order for them to have money-prices, they
differ from direct prices, this also means that must already have worth: money does not cause
individual money investments, M, will in general worth, it only measures it.
differ from the corresponding value costs C + V It is a necessary consequence that the factors
(Marx, 1967, Vol. III, pp. 161, 164-5). Such a which determine how valuable a commodity will
feedback effect could make the relation between be in exchange, determine its money-price. And
value magnitudes and their price forms more these factors, as we have seen, are the amount
complex, Marx observes. But then he leaves this and distribution of social labor-time _
issue aside, clearly because he considers it to be If the distribution of social labor is such that
of relatively minor importance in the process of the commodities produced correspond to the
deriving price from value and profit from various social needs, supply will equal demand,
surplus-value. and the money-price of a commodity will equal
Marx’s opponents immediately seized upon its regulating price - direct prices if we assume
the incomplete nature of Marx’s transformation, exchange in proportion to values - prices of pro-
and, ever since then, this issue has been the duction at a higher level of analysis. In either-
focus of a long-running debate. Recently this de- case, it is the amounts of labor-time which deter-
bate has flared up once again, leading to some mine these regulating prices.
important new results which support the essen- If, on the other hand, the distribution of labor
tial nature of Marx’s derivations. It is entirely is not appropriate to various social needs, then
beyond the scope of this chapter to go into this the market price of a commodity will deviate
matter in any depth; however, in a separate from its regulating price, and a change will take
paper (Shaikh, 1977) I do treat this connection in place in the distribution of social labor so as to
detail. For our purposes here, three of its as- reduce the discrepancy between market and
pects are significant. First, that the procedure by regulating prices. For the purposes of this analy-
which Marx transforms direct prices can be also sis, therefore, we may leave out of consider-atiun
viewed as the initial step in an iterative proce- the constantly fluctuating market prices and
dure for ~crlculntin~ the actual prices of produc- focus directly on regulating prices.
tion themselves. This helps establish a fruitful In any given year, the sum of prices of all the
mathematical connection between Marx’s pro- commodities produced must equal the number
cedure and further-developed prices of produc- of coins in circulation times the velocity of circu-
tion. Second, it can be shown (in the case of lation. This, as Marx points out, is simply a tuu-
three departments of production, at least) that tology. In order to make it something more, we
for each sector both the actual and the regulating must embed it in a theoretical structure.
price of production deviate in the same direction Let us begin by assuming that the regulating
from the sector’s direct price, so too will be the prices are direct prices. Then the price of any
actual price of production. (Seton, 1957, pp. commodity is its value relative to that of gold, so
157-60) Last, it has been established that the that the sum of the prices of all the commodities
The laws of international exchange 223

produced in a given year is given by their total quantities, requires that every commodity
value relative to the value of gold. Let TP stand owner have on hand a reserve of money to
for the sum of prices, TW for the sum of values, accommodate day to day variations. Conse-
and U, for the value of a mnit (an ounce) of gold, quently, the first manifestation of a persistent
we can write excess of coin over the needs of circulation will
be the buildup of these reserves above the requi-
TP = (TW/o,) (13.6)
site levels; but then this superfluous gold, being
In this equation, the sum of (regulating) prices necessary neither for immediate circulation nor
is the direct expression of the sum of values of for its anticipated variations, will be withdrawn
commodities. If the velocity of circulation is k, altogether from the vicinity of the sphere of ex-
then the amount of gold, G (in the form of one- change. It will either enter into hoards or it is
ounce coins), which is required as a medium of transformed into articles of luxury:
circulation is We have seen how, along with the continual
fluctuations in the extent and rapidity of the
G = TP/k = [(l/k)(TW/o,)] (13.7)
circulation of commodities and in their prices,
The causation in this is very clear: the sum of the quantity of money current unceasingly
the values of the commodities produced in a ebbs and flows. This mass must, therefore, be
given period determines the sum of their money- capable of expansion and contraction. At one
prices, and this in conjunction with the velocity time money must be attracted in order to act
of circulation ,27 determines the number of (1 oz) as circulatmg coin, at another, circulating coin
gold coins required for the circulation of the must be repelled in order to act again as more
commodities (Marx, 1967, Vol. I, p. 123, et or less stagnant money. In order that the mass
passim). of money, actually current, may constantly
Though the preceding relations were derived saturate the absorbing power of the circula-
on the basis of direct prices, they are not the tion, it is necessary that the quantity of gold
least bit altered when we move on to prices of and silver in a country be greater than the
production, for, as we have seen, the regulating quantity required to function as coin. This
prices of production that Marx derives have the condition is fulfilled by money taking the form
same sum of prices as do direct prices. This of hoards. (Marx, 1967, Vol. I, p. 134)
means that as far as the sum of the prices of all In countries where commodity production is
commodities is concerned, the determination is still primitive, hoards take the form of private
the same whether we assume direct prices or. accumulations of gold scattered throughout the
prices of production: the sum of prices equals country. But as commodity production, and
the sum of values divided by the value of an hence the banking system, develops and ex-
ounce of gold. As a result, the quantity of gold pands, hoards become concentrated in the res-
required is the same in either case. ervoirs of banks (Marx, 1972, pp. 136-7). Under
What happens then if there exist more gold these circumstances, excesses or deficiencies of
coins than the required number? Well, the quan- gold money relative to the needs of circulation
tity G is the number of gold coins which cir- manifest themselves as increases or decreases of
culate because they facilitate the circulation of bank reserves.3o
commodities. Therefore any quantity of coin Hoards in the form of bank reserves, how-
over and above this amount will be redundant in ever, are very different from private hoards: to
circulation: it will at first take the form of idle the bank, an excess of bank reserves over the
coin, excess coin (Marx, 1972, Ch. 2, Sec. 3a).28 legally required minimum is a supply of idle
But an excess supply of gold is a very different bank-capital, money-capital which could be
thing from an excess supply of any other com- earning profit for the bank but is instead lying
modity. All other commodities, in order to fulfill fallow. An increase in bank reserves is therefore
their function, must be sold, turned into gold generally accompanied by a decrease in the rate
through the alchemy of exchange; but gold itself of interest as the banks strive to convert re-
does not have to be, in fact cannot be, sold. It is serves into capital. Conversely, a drop in bank
money, 2g the perfect and durable form of wealth reserves below the legal minimum tends to lead
which all other commodities seek to obtain. to a rise in the rate of interest. Rather than
From the earliest stages of commodity produc- raising the price level, the immediate effect of an
tion, therefore, gold circulating in the form of excess of gold-money is to lower the rate of
coin has existed side by side with noncirculating interest: “If this export [of capital] is made in
gold in the form of reserve coin, in the form of the form of precious metal, it will exert a direct
hoards, and in the form of luxury articles. Influence upon the money-market and with it
The very nature of commodity production, the upon the interest rate . . .” (Marx, 1967, Vol.
unceasing fluctuations of market prices and TIT, p. 577).
224 Anwar Shaikh

But now it might be asked: surely the fact that characteris tic forms of capital generally, since
the bank puts this extra money into circulation a great many phenomena of the bourgeois
via a lowering of the rate of interest also implies economy - the period of the economic
that effective demand is thereby raised? And if cycle, . . . the effect of new demand; even
so, won’t this in turn imply that as a conse- the effect of new gold-and-silver producing
quence of this higher effective demand prices countries on general production - [would
will eventually rise - so that in the end the quan- otherwise] be incomprehensible. It is futile to
tity theory is right after all? Marx’s answer is speak of the stimulus given by Australian gold
unequivocal: no. or a newly discovered market . . . [ifi it
We begin by noting that an increased supply were not in the nature of capital to be never
of gold can indeed lead to an increase in effec- completely occupied . . . At the same time,
tive demand, either insofar as it is spent by its [note] the senseless contradictions into which
original owners, or indirectly because it will ex- the economists stray - even Ricardo - when
pand bank reserves and hence the supply of they presuppose that capital is always fully
loanable money-capital, which will tend to drive occupied . . . (Marx, 1973, p. 623)
down interest rates, which may in turn increase Having located Marx’s criticism of Ricardo’s
capitalist borrowing for investment.31 However, theory of money,32 we can now turn to its impli-
even though this increase in effective demand cations for gold flows generated by changes in
may temporarily increase prices of some com- the balance of international trade. In the case of
modities, and hence raise profits in some a surplus, for instance, there will be a net inflow
sectors, it must eventually lead to an expansion of gold into the country and a consequent in-
of production to meet the new demand. And as crease in the country’s supply of gold. Insofar as
production expands prices will fall until (all this leads to an increase in effective demand,
other things being equal) they regain their origi- production will expand, and with it the needs of
nal levels. In this case the sum of prices of all circulation. Part of the increased gold supply
commodities will have increased, not because will therefore go to meet the expanded require-
the level of prices has increased, but because the ments of circulation, part will pile up in bank re-
mass of commodities thrown into production has serves, and part will be absorbed in the ex-
itself increased. Thus, insofar as a pure increase panded production of luxury articles made of
in the supply of gold does generate an increase in gold. In addition, once we take international
effective demand (i.e., insofar as it does not sim- trade into account, a part of the surplus gold
ply expand bank reserves or go into the produc- may be re-exported in the form of foreign loans
tion of luxury articles) it will also generate an in- in search of interest rates, or as foreign invest-
creased need for circulating gold coin. ment in search of surplus-value. These last two
It is important to note at this point that to possibilities, as we shall see shortly, become im-
Marx, the notion of a capitalism that tends to be portant in a Marxian analysis of international ex-
more or less at full employment is a vulgar fan- hirgt; .
tasy. First of all, Marx notes that it is an inherent In any case, Marx emphatically rejects the no-
tendency of capitalism to create and maintain a tion that a “pure” increase in the supply of gold
relative surplus population of workers - the re- will in general lead to an increase in prices:
serve army of the unemployed (Marx, 1967, Vol. It is indeed an old humbug that changes in the
I, Ch. 25). Second, even with a given pattern of existing quantity of gold in a particular
fixed capital (plant and equipment), expansion of country must raise or lower commodity-prices
production can easily be undertaken by ex- within this country by increasing or de-
tending and/or intensifying the working time in a creasing the quantity of the medium of circula-
given working day (Marx, 1967, Vol. II, p. 258). tion. If gold is exported, then, according to the
Last, it is an intrinsic requirement of capilalisl Currency Theory, commodity-prices must
commodity production, which is regulated only rise in the country importing this gold, and de-
by the constant fluctuations of the circulation crease in the country exporting it . . . But,
process, to maintain stocks of various commodi- in fact, a decrease in the quantity of gold
ties so that the exigencies of circulation may be raises only the interest rate, whereas an in-
met without disrupting the continuity of the pro- crease in the quantity of gold lowers the inter-
duction process. It is precisely because of these est rate; and if not for the fact that the fluctua-
possibilities that the continuity of the production tions in the interest rate enter into the determi-
process is possible alongside constantly varying nation of cost-prices, or in the determination
levels of production and sale. (Marx, 1973, pp. of demand and supply, commodity-prices
X52-6) would be wholly unakctd by t&m (Marx,
It is extremely important to grasp this aspect Capital, 1967, Vol. III, Ch. XXXIV, p. 551)
of circulating and fixated capital as speci$c It should be noted at this point that Marx’s
The laws of international exchange 225

theory of money implies not only a rejection of value of a commodity. The very nature of com-
the Hume specie-flow mechanism on which Ri- modity production requires not only that every
cardo’s results were based, but also rejection of commodity be assessed in terms of some univer-
the various modern versions (discussed in the sal equivalent (hence the necessity of money),
fourth part of the second major section) which but also that this assessment be contingent on a
have replaced it. series of factors, ranging from the vagaries of
The cash balance approach, for instance, re- supply and demand to the social limits imposed
lied on a fall in effective demand in the backward by reproduction (hence the ultimate regulation
country to lead to a fall in money prices. But this of market prices by value).
connection between effective demand and the Marx’s analysis of the exchange of commodi-
permanent level of prices is precisely what Marx ties within a nation is thus characteristically dis-
denies. Similarly, the price level of commodities tinct from Ricardo’s. In what follows we shall
being determined by their value relative to that see that it is these very same differences which
of gold, the money wage cannot permanently necessarily imply an equally distinct Marxian
influence the price level: the Keynesian price analysis of international exchange.
theory therefore will not work either.
That brings us back once again to the possibil- Comparative costs reexamined. We begin once
ity of purely flexible exchange rates. As noted in again with the familiar Ricardian tableau (Table
the fourth part of the second major section, the 13.2). Portugal is absolutely more efficient in
actual gold standard operated with a flexible e7c- both branches of production, and given the
change rate bounded by limits (gold-points) value of gold33 as two worker-hours per ounce,
based on the costs of transporting gold. This this greater efficiency translates directly into an
meant that in its normal variations it was a absolute cost advantage. Portuguese capitalists
system of flexible exchange rates, whereas in its will therefore export both cloth and wine, and
“limited” mode it operated as a fixed exchange England will have to counterbalance its ensuing
rate system. trade deficit by shipping gold to Portugal.
It is out of this long experience that orthodox According to Ricardo, the gold outflow from
theory falsely abstracted fixed and flexible ex- England would lower all prices there, since it
change rates as two separate regimes. In this would lower the domestic supply of money; con-
context purely flexible exchange rates are pre- versely, the gold inflow into Portugal would raise
sented as a mechanism whereby in theory a the prices of all Portuguese commodities. As we
world capitalist system can be made up of fully have seen, this process implies that sooner or
“independent” national currencies (Yeager, later English cloth would undersell its Por-
1966, p. 104). As a theoretical possibility this tuguese counterpart, so that in the end two-way
idea has always had an uneasy existence: the trade would always reign. No nation need fear
history of currency “floats” strongly suggests trade, for it benefits all.
only a limited flexibility (Yeager, 1966, pp. But the mechanism which leads us to this har-
176-80), and the history of the international monious conclusion rests squarely upon the
money system is very much a history of increas- operation of the classical quantity theory of
ing monetary integration, not separation. In a money, And this we know to be false. Let us
sense, the notion of a purely flexible exchange therefore begin again.
rate determined solely by supply and demand Because of their absolute advantage, Por-
considerations is one more manifestation of the tuguese capitalists in both branches are able to
general neoclassical method in which all undersell their English competition. Portuguese
“prices” are determined only by supply and de- cloth and wine invade English markets, and
mand. In opposition to this, Marx’s method very English gold begins to flow back to Portugal. In
rnuc!l ernphasks lhe inlr-irlsic hails l o these England, therefore, the supply of gold de-
apparent variations: in the case of prices, these creases, while in Portugal it increases.
arose from labor-times; in the case of exchange It is at this point that Marx’s theory of money
rates, from the existence of the money commod- becomes critical. In contrast to Ricardo, Marx
ity (as in gold-points).

Table 13.2.
The law of value in international exchange
England Portugal
Perhaps the most fundamental result to emerge
from Marx’s criticism of Ricardo is the crucial Cloth: 100 hrs 50 oz gold 45 oz gold 90 hrs :CIoth
distinction between value and price. Money Wine: 120 hrs 60 oz gold 40 oz gold 80 hrs : Wine
mice. to Marx. is the external measure of the
1 , I
226 Anwar S h a i k h

expressly denies any link between pure changes trade deficit which it covers by means of short-
in the supply of gold and the level or prices. term international borrowing, and Portugal run-
Instead, according to Marx’s analysis, the pri- ning a trade surplus which enables its capitalists
mary effect of an outflow of gold from England to engage in international lending. But of course
will be to diminish the supply of loanable this is not quite correct: capitalist loans are
money-capital. On the other hand, as English made in order to get profit (in the form of inter-
cloth and wine production succumbs to foreign est). Thus England would have to eventually pay
competition, the demand for money-capital will back not only the original loan, but also the
also decrease. Nonetheless, when these sectors interest on it. The net effect must be an outJEow
have reached their minimal size (there will of gold from England, albeit at a later date. All
always be Englishmen who will never buy from other things being equal,36 the piper must be
foreigners), the continuing drain of gold will tend paid: in the end, beset by chronic trade deficits
to raise the rate of interest; insofar as this cur- and mounting debts, England must eventually
tails investment, production of other commodi- succumb.
ties will decline. In England therefore, the drain The foregoing results take on an unpleasantly
of bullion will lead to lower bank reserves, cur- familiar ring when we express them in terms of
tailed production, and a higher rate of interest. developed and underdeveloped capitalist coun-
In Portugal, the effects are just the opposite. tries. Curiously enough, in Ricardo’s example
As gold flows into Portugal, part of it will be ab- England corresponds to the under-developed
sorbed by the expanded circulation require- capitalist country (UCC), its generally lower ef-
ments of cloth and wine production; part will be ficiency being the reflection of its lower level of
absorbed in the form of luxury articles; and the development. Portugal, on the other hand, cor-
rest will be absorbed in the form of expanded responds to the developed capitalist country
bank reserves. This last effect will increase the (DCC).
supply of loanable money-capital, lowering Cast in these terms, we may say: in free trade,
interest rates and tending to expand production t h e a b s o l u t e discndvantage o f t h e undevde-
in geneI-al. Thus, in Pmtugal, the inflow uf gvld veloped ccrpitulist country will r~su11 in chronic
will raise bank reserves, expand production, and trade dejkits und mounting international bor-
lower the rate of interest. rowing. It will be chronically in deficit und chron-
What we find therefore is that according to icully in debt.
Marx’s analysis England’s absolute disadvan- In our analysis so far, we have assumed only
tage will be manifested in a chronic trade deficit, two commodities, so that an absolute advantage
bulanced by a persistent outflow of gold. On the implies greater efficiency in producing both: oth-
other hand, Portugal’s greater efficiency in pro- erwise it would obviously be a relative advan-
duction will manifest itself in a chronic trade tage. But when we consider the whole range of
surplus, balanced by a persistent accumulation products possible in both countries, then it be-
comes evident lhat in spik of a gm~-uZ supcl.iur-
Obviously such a situation cannot continue ity in production, the DCC may nonetheless pro-
indefinitely. 34 If we stick to commodity flows duce certain commodities at a greater cost than
alone, then as English bank reserves decline, so the UCC, and yet others not at all. Since we are
too will the credibility of the English 2; eventu- still considering direct prices, the only possible
ally, the & must collapse, and with it the trade exports of the underdeveloped country will con-
between England and Portugal. form precisely to these types: commodities it
The end need not come in such a straightfor- can produce at a lower value and/or those com-
ward manner, however. We noted earlier that as modities peculiar to it only.37 On the whole,
English reserves shrink, the rate of interest in these types of commodities will reflect some
England will rise; conversely, as money-capital specific local advantages great enough to over-
piles up in Portugal, the rate of interest there will come the UCC’s generally lower level of effi-
fall. At some point, therefore, it will be to the ad- ciency: a good climate, an abundance of particu-
vantage of Portuguese capitalists to lend t h e i r lar natural resources, a propitious location, and
money-capital abroad, in England, rather than at so on; lower wages, however, will not matter
home. When this happens, short-term financial here, since in the case of direct prices the level
capital will flow from Portugal to England;35 of wages affects profits but has no effect on
England’s rate of interest would then reverse it- prices. Under these circumstances, then, the
self and begin to fall, while Portugal’s would underdeveloped country will be able to eke out a
rise, until at some level of short-term capital few exports; although, of course, its overall
flows the two would be equal. trade will still be in deficit, and its position still
It may seem that at this point the s ituation that of a debtor nation. Trade will serve not to
would be balanced: England running a chronic eliminate inequality, but to perpetuate it.
The laws oj’international exchunge 227

This result is’not substantially modified by the vestment). The law of comparative costs is then
consideration of prices of production. Since used to justify the patterns of commodity trade,
within a given country the average price of pro- while direct investment is treated (separately) as
duction is equal to the average direct price, the a transfer of savings from the rich capitalist na-
overall advantage of the DCC remains un- tions to their poor relatives.3s The underde-
changed. What may change, however, are the veloped capitalist nations thus emerge as doubly
trading positions of individual sectors. Within blessed: the overwhelming productive superior-
each country, sectors with high organic compo- ity of the developed nations is manifested only in
sitions will have prices of production above their the cheapness of their exports, while their
direct prices, and sectors with low composi- incumyarably greater wealth manifests itself as a
tions, prices of production below their direct mass of capital eager and willing to go over there
prices; but this dispersion effGct holds true in and help spread freedom, equality, property,
both countries, to differing degrees, so that it is and Coca-Cola.
quite possible that in either country some pre- The preceding section has demonstrated that
viously marginal sectors may enter international the law of comparative costs is invalid even on
competition while others drop out. its owy2 groutids. The concentration and central-
What we are left with, therefore, is that in gen- ization which is inherent in capitalist production
eral the developed capitalist country will domi- is as much a part of world capitalism as it is of
nate trade because its greater efficiency will any single national entity; no form of exchange,
enable it to produce most commodities at abso- be it national or inturliztiunal, can do more than
lutely lower values, and hence, to sell them on to give vent to the fundamental laws of capitalist
the average at absolutely lower prices of produc- production. Rather than negating the inequality
tion. of development, commodity trade affirms and
Above all, it must be kept in mind that these reinforces it.
results represent the automatic tendencies of But then what are we to make of the existing
free and unhumpered trade among capitalist na- analyses of the effects of direct investment?
tions at different levels of development. It is not On one hand, orthodox economic analysis
monopoly or conspiracy upon which uneven argues that direct investment “redistributes
development rests, but free competition itself: world savings’ ‘I(Kenen, 1968, p. 29) from the
free trade is as much a mechanism for the con- rich capitalist nalions tu the yuu~- ones, which
centration and centralization of international tends to eliminate international inequality by
capital as free exchange within a capitalist na- slowing down the growth of the investing coun-
tion is for the concentration and centralization of tries and speeding up the growth of the recipient
domestic capital. We will return to this point countries. As such, might it not offset the
after we consider the effects of direct invest- inequality-widening effects of commodity trade?
ment _ On the other hand, as I outlined earlier, both
Incidentally, it is worth remarking that trade conventional Marxist analysis and that of Em-
between capitalist nations with more or less the manuel rely heavily on the export of capital as
same level of development will have a character- being the critical factor in modern imperialism.
istically different pattern. Suppose we consider But both analyses are based on an explicit
the example lying at the heart of the Hecksher- acceptance of comparative (instead of absolute)
Ohlin-Samuelson model, in which both capitalist advantage, a law which we now know to be
countries possess the same technology and level incorrect. To what extent, therefore, does the
of productivity - so that absolute advantage is overthrow of this law also modify either or both
impossible. In this limiting case, factors such as of the above theories of imperialism?
climate, location, avail;lbility of resources, These issues lead us directly to the central
experience, inventions, and above all the com- question of this section: how does the consider-
petitive struggle among capitalists, become all ation of direct investment modify the previously
important. We would expect a more or less bal- derived law of international exchange? In order
anced pattern of trade in this case, with a large to answer this, we begin by developing the de-
variety of goods being produced in both coun- terminants of foreign investment.
tries, and with the advantage in particular com- Let us recall the results of merchant capital
modities shifting back and forth in the short-run. (i.e., commodity) flows: on the average, the
This is quite different from the structural imbal- absolutely greater productive efficiency of the
ance of DCC-UCC trade. DCC translates into lower international prices
for its products. If we consider products whose
The effects of direct investment. It is traditional in consumption is common to both,3g the DCC will
the analysis of international trade to separate dominate trade, with the UCC managing to eke
commodity flows from flows of capital (direct in- out exports only in those sectors where local
228 Anwar Shaikh

advantages such as climate, availability of the rates of profit. In the case of prices of pro-
resources, etc. are so great as to offset their gen- duction, because the wage rate affects the
erally lower efficiency. average rate of profit, it can affect the extent to
We must keep in mind the elements of this re- which individual prices of production deviate
Iationship. The DCCJ has the advantage precisely from direct prices; but the average price is still
because it has a more developed structure of directly connected to value. Up to this point,
pruduction, two aspects of which are of impor- therefore, it has been necessary to focus on dif-
tance here: first, a superior technology; and sec- ferences in productive efficiency as the most im-
ond, a work-force more conditioned to capitalist portant manifestations of uneven development,
production. The UCC, on the other hand, has an even though differences in wage rates between
inferior technology and a work-force which is DCC and UCC are just as symptumatic of the
still new to wage-labor. The greater efficiency of disparity between their levels of development,
production in the DCC is therefore due partly to Once we admit the possibility of internationai
the superior technology, and partly to the higher movements of industrial capital, however, wage
direct productivity of its work-force. The term, disparities between capitalist nations become an
“direct productivity,” refers to the fact that important factor in their own right.
even when both work-furces use the same tech- Consider the case of an individual capital in
nology, the work-force of the DCC is likely to be the DCC. If we ignore transportation costs, then
able to produce more output, because of its the same price rules everywhere. Thus, it wiII
greater conditioning to capitalist production, its take more Or Iess the same amount of gold to
greater familiarity with machines, etc. build and supply a given type of plant anywhere
On the basis of these differences, then, in the world: the sole difference between coun-
merchant-capital will facilitate trade between tries will therefore arise from the differing costs
the two countries in those commodities which of labor-power; that is? from the combined ef-
are of use Jn either country. 3ut note that so long fects of the differences in direct productivity and
as the differences in development manifest the differences in wage rates.
themselves in the above-stated ways, the means In Uneylrul Exchunge . . . , Arghiri Em-
of production of the two countries will not be manuel points out that though the direct produc-
among the traded commodities: each country’s tivity of labor is generally lower in the UCC, tlze
capitalists will use means of production consist- wage rate is much lower still: whereas the direct
ent with its general level of development. productivity “of the average worker in tlze
Merchant capital necessarily carries with it underdeveloped areas is 50 to 60 percent of that
the possibility o-F modernization, however: the of the average worker in the industrialized
capitalists within the UCC may (and do) switch areas . . . the average wage in the developed
over to the superior technology of the DCC. But countries is about 30 times the average wage in
there are many factors which militate against the backward countries” (Emmanuel, 1972,
this: the vastly greater cost and scale of ad- p. 48). This means that although it takes roughly
vanced techniques, the complex interdepen- twice as many workers in the UCC to produce
dence required among different techniques for the same output from a given plant &U-I it would
any one to be viable, and the greater socializa- at home, each worker costs the developed
tion required of the work-force. For these country’s capitalist only I/30 of what workers
reasons, modernization from the inside as an cost at home; the net effect is that the average
inherent tendency of trade relations is usually wage bill of a plant located in the UCC would be
overwhelmed by another more powerful inher- 1 /I5 of what it would be at home: cheap labor at-
ent tendency: nodenzizaGon from the outside, tracts foreign investment.
or direct investment.40 It must he emphasi7ed at this pint that cheap
Precisely those factors which work against labor is not the only source of attraction for
modernization from the inside tend to work in foreign investment. Other things being equal,
favor of direct investment: capitalists from the cheap raw materials, a good climate, and a good
DCC have much larger capitals available for in- location (if transportation costs are taken into
vestment, are familiar with modern techniques, account) are also important in making individual
have access to all the necessary skilled workers. sectors of production attractive to foreign capi-
But the most important factor which favors tal. But these factors are specific to certain
direct investment, as we shall see, is the low branches only; cheap wage-labor, on the other
level of wages in the UCC. hand, is a general social characteristic of under-
During the analysis of commndity trade, wage develcqwd capitalist crrtlntries, one whnse impli-
differences did not appear to be an important cations extend to all areas of production, even
factor. In the case of direct prices, price is deter- those yet to be created.
mined immediately by value: wages affect only One immediate consequence of considering
The laws of international exchange 229

direct investment is that the export industries of profits will lead to an increase in the supply of
the UCC emerge as the prime targets of foreign the commodities produced, driving down their
capital. As we have already seen, when we treat prices and hence reducing the excess profits
flows of merchant capital, the only sectors of the which attracted them in the first place. No
UCC capable of surviving are those whose prod- matter where this process stops, it is clear that it
ucts have no foreign counterparts, so that they will end up lowering the prices of the chosen in-
face no competition from imports, and those dustries until the foreign capital invested in them
which do face foreign competition but can over- earns the same rate of profit as it would at home.
come it due to local advantages such as plentiful From the point of view of local capital the ef-
raw materials, etc., which enable them to offset fects of foreign investment will generally be
their generally inferior technology and lower disastrous. The prices which existed before the
labor productivity. The latter group of sectors, if modernization from the outside were prices of
they exist at all, become the export sectors of production embodying the average rate of profit
the UCC. And once the possibility of foreign in- in the UCC. When these prices are driven down
vestment is taken into account, these export by the influx of foreign capital, the domestic cap-
sectors become leading candidates for foreign italists will be forced out - out of business, into
takeover: even if foreign capitalists had to ship yet unaffected areas or into new industries
over workers from their own country their supe- created in response to the needs of the foreign
rior technology would still enable them to take dominated sectors.
advantage of the cheap raw materials, etc., to We have up to now confined ourselves to ana-
make exceptional profits; in addition, since labor lyzing the effects of direct investment on indus-
in the UCC is available at a lower net cost,41 the tries already existing in the UCC. Given that
export sectors begin to appear even more attrac- only a few industries would survive the rigors of
tive to foreign investors. commodity trade, the question that arose was:
The sectors confined solely to domestic pro- will direct investment help offset the devastation
duction are not exempt from this process, how- of competition from foreign imports, or will it
ever. Insofar as there exist within this group cer- make matters worse?
tain industries in which the superior technology From the point of view of local capital, the
of foreign capital and the lower net cost of do- answer seems unambiguous: worse! Struggling
mestic labor power enables the capitalists from to exploit their workers in peace, they find them-
the DCC to make higher profits there than they selves beset by foreign devils: first their indus-
would at home, these industries too will be prey tries are ruined by cheap imports, and then those
to the foreign invasion. that survive are taken over by foreign capital! It
In all the sectors subject to this discipline, is no wonder that protectionism becomes their
foreign capital enters because by selling at or religion.
even below the existing prices, it can enjoy a The invasion and takeover of existing indus-
higher rate of profit than the rate which rules at tries in the UCC does not, however, exhaust the
home. The existing prices, however, are the possibilities inherent in direct investment. It
prices of production of these sectors, embodying must be remembered that all capitals compete
the average rate of profit in the UCC. At first against each other. This means that when capital
glance therefore, it would seem that direct in- from the DCC takes the form of foreign invest-
vestment would only flow from the DCC to the ment it competes not only with capital from the
UCC if the former’s average rate of profit was UCC but also with capital still at home. Where it
higher than the latter’s - because of the lower can take advantage of the cheap labor in the
wage, for instance, in the UCC. But this is not UCC, new capital in the DCC can set itself up in
necessnq~ nt n/Z. By modernizing from the out- oppositiorz t o e x i s t i n g hor72~ irduslries, b y
side, foreign capital lowers the cost-price of a opening plants abroad and exporting the
commodity and so raises its profitability. Thus (cheaper) products.
even if the national rate of profit in the UCC We see, therefore, that attraction of cheap
were below that of the DCC, the sectors moder- labor for foreign capital can be detrimental not
nized by foreign capital could still yield for it a only to local capitals in the UCC but also to cer-
higher rate than either national average.42 tain capitals in the DCC. It is for this reason that
Regardless of the actual differences in the the cry for protectionism resounds on both sides
average rates of profit of the two countries, of the development gap. Where merchant capital
therefore, foreign capital will seek to enter those dominates, or where foreign investment is still
particular industries in which it can enjoy a no threat to home capital, then only the plaintive
higher profit (at the going prices) than it would wail of UCC capitalists is heard in favor of pro-
at home. As it does so, however, the competi- tectionism. But when foreign investment
tion among foreign canitals for these excess develops to the point of competing with home
2 3 0 Anwar S h a i k h

production itself, the protection quickly be- capitalist country. If anything, direct investment
comes the reality of the day. Only the free can be an “offset” of a sort, albeit one which
traders remain, tirelessly selling the patent medi- eventually intensifies the unevenness of devel-
cine of comparative costs. opment: inflows of foreign capital, even though
From a nationalist point of view, the effects of they may be eventually repaid many times over
direct investment on the UCC seem mixed. We in outflows of profit, are nonetheless an impor-
have seen that merchant trade will be dominated tant source of long-term borrowing to offset the
by the DCC; the UCC will emerge as perpetually chronic trade deficits, ones which are generally
in debt and perpetually in deficit. preferable to the volatile financial capital flows
Insofar as foreign capital invades the sur- upon which short-term borrowing is based,
viving industries, it adds insult to injury by Moreover, as noted above, direct investment
increasing the dependence of the UCC on the can lead to the creation of new industries in the
developed capitalist world. Direct investment, it UCC, which can help reduce its trade deficit as
is true, does lower prices and modernize in- well as increase employment within the country.
dustry; but, as Emmanuel emphasizes, lowered The basic point, which Emmanuel’s proposed
prices of exports are actually a loss to the solution completely misses, is that you are
nation-as-a-whole, since they constitute a deteri- damned if you do, and damned if you don’t.
oration of the terms of trade and hence a worsen- What Emmanuel sees as an inequality between
ing of the trade balance. Moreover, for Em- nations is in fact the international manifestation
manuel the important point would be that both of the inequality between capitals which is inher-
modernization and the lowered prices are in fact ent in the necesstrvily uneven development of
mechanisms by which the surplus-value pro- capitalist relations of production. Concentration
duced by workers from the UCC is in fact trans- and centralization as inherent tendencies of cap-
ferred to the foreign capitalists. This, he argues, italist development are just as valid internation-
further widens the gap between developed and ally as they are nationally. In either case, the
underdeveloped countries; by strengthening the patterns of exchange are symptoms, not causes,
rich and weakening the poor: “wealth begets of these fundamental laws, The international
wealth . . . Poverty begets poverty” (Em- equalization of wage rates can no more solve the
manuel, 1972, p. 131). problem of uneven development in capitalism
What Emmanuel does not see, however, is than can the suppression of a symptom cure the
that foreign investment may also transplant in- disease. The problem lies with capitalism, not its
dustries from the DCC to the UCC, because of symptoms: to argue for the same wage every-
the advantages of cheap labor. lnsofar as this where is in reality to argue that the exploitation
happens, the export capability of the UCC is of workers should be equal in all countries43 -
strengthened (albeit under the aegis of foreign without reference to race, color, creed, or na-
capital) by the addition of these new sectors. tional origin! Democratic, no doubt, but limited
This side of foreign investment will tend to im- in its implications.
prove the underdeveloped nation’s balance of
trade, and create new avenues of employment
for its labor. Summary and conclusions
The fundamental error in Emmanuel’s analy-
sis, however, is much more basic: because he The purpose of this chapter has been to work
accepts the law of comparative costs as being towards the treatment of the laws of interna-
correct on its own grounds, he is forced to put tional exchange from the Marxist perspective.
the whole blame for international inequality on This is a theoretical task, one which has its roots
the effects of direct investment. Since he iden- in the law of value as it is developed in the SUC-
tifies the lower wages of the UCC as the basic cessive volumes of Capital. As such, this analy-
factor leading to foreign investment, Emmanuel sis is not a substitute for the concrete reality of
must argue that the sollrtion to the problem of international trade or of its historical develop-
uneven development is to eyuulize wuges he- ment. No attempt is made, for instance, to
tween countries. By so doing, the flow of explain the historical roots of uneven devel-
industrial capital from the DCC to the UCC opment ; nor is primitive accumulation ever
would cease, and with it all the deleterious ef- treated. Instead, the point is to uncover the sorts
fects which arise from it. of forces which are inherent in the international
But we know that in fact Ricardo’s law of interactions of capitalist nations precisely so
comparative costs is wrong: quite independently that we may be better- prepared to &A with tlxir
of direct investment, commodity trade by itself concrete existence.
will result in the penury of the underdeveloped Perhaps the most enduring proposition in the
The laws of international exchange 231

analysis of international trade has been the so- ist country in this example, will end up with a
called law of comparative costs, which, as we persistent trade deficit balanced by gold out-
have seen, has generally been accepted by flows and/or short-term borrowing.
orthodox economists and Marxists alike as being When this result is expressed in terms of its
valid on its own grounds. In all of its various real content, we can say: free trade will ensure
disguises, this so-called law has asserted that that the underdeveloped capitalist country will
when it came to international trade between cap- be chronically in deficit and chronically in debt.
italist nations, inherent inequalities will be It is ahsolute advantage, not comparative, which
negated. Thus even if one of two nations cmld rules trade.
only produce all commodities at a higher price This result represents the extension of Marx’s
than the other, it would nonetheless end up ex- law of value (which in Marx subsumes a theory
porting some and importing others. No nation, of money) to the realm of the international ex-
however humble, need ever fear “free trade,” change of commodities. But as Marx points out,
for, like bourgeois justice, it is blind to dif- these commodities are capitalistically produced
ferences in station. Or so the story goes, any- commodities, the commodity-form of various
way, national capitals. As such, the interchange of
But it turns out that aside from the multitude commodity-capitals among nations carries with
of proofs about the “optimality” of specializa- it the seeds of other forms of international capi-
tion according to comparative costs, the real tal, such as financial capital (foreign bor-
heart of the matter lies in the assertion that the rowing/lending), and direct investment.
basic thrust of international trade is to actually The question of direct investment is particu-
bring about such specialization. And the auto- larly important, since its analysis plays so im-
matic mechanism which supposedly accom- portant a role in various theories of trade. Ortho-
plishes this, we found, was the operation of the dox theory, for instance, finds direct investment
various orthodox theories of money. to be a means of closing the gap between rich
The second part of this chapter therefore pre- and poor capitalist countries, on the grounds
sented the development of the principle of com- that it transfers savings from the developed
parative costs in its original (and basically unal- countries to the underdeveloped ones. Marxist
tered) form: that of David Ricardo. Only then theories of imperialism, on the other hand, have
were modern derivations of this law presented. traditionally derived the major phenomena of
It was important in this section to show that the uneven development from direct investment; in
so-called law was a logical outcome of the con- this regard Emmanuel, too, makes the export of
junction of Ricardo’s theory of value with his capital pivotal in his theory of imperialism.
theory of money; this enabled us to establish But all these analyses of direct investment are
that the locus of a critique of the law lay in its based on an acceptance of Ricardo’s law of com-
antecedents - not in the law itself. parative costs. Since the central result of this
In his analysis of Ricardo, Marx provides us paper is the overthrow of this law, and the sub-
precisely with the necessary critiques of Ri- sequent location of many of the phenomena of
cardo’s theories of value and money. Moreover, imperialism - previously attributed to the export
in his own work he treats these subjects under of capital - in the workings of commodity trade
the developments of the law of value. The third alone, it became imperative at that point to ex-
section of this chapter presented Marx’s critique tend the analysis to incorporate the effects of
ofRicardo as well as his own treatment of value, direct investment.44
price and money. This has a double conse- In the second part of this chapter’s final sec-
quence: the critiques of these antecedents of the tion, this question was taken up. There, it was
su-called law of comparative costs provides us found that though foreign capital can provide an
with a basis for a critique of the law itself; and offset to chronic balance of trade deficits, in part
Marx’s own development of the law of value because of the capital inflow and in part through
provides us with the basis for an adequate treat- the modernization and expansion of the export
ment of the laws of international exchange. And sectors, it does so only at the expense of an
when this is done the law of comparative costs is eventual capital outflow (surplus-value trans-
seen to be impossible precisely on its own ferred out in the form of repatriated profits), de-
grounds. Rather than finding, as Ricardo did, clining terms of trade, and increased foreign
that Portugal and England will each end up spe- domination. Instead of negating international
cializing in one commodity - in spite of Por- inequality, therefore, foreign investment tight-
tugal’s absolure superiority in the production of ens the grip of the strong over the weak - not
both - we find that Portugal will necessarily ex- merely through monopoly or state power, but
port both. England. the underdevehed capital- through “free” competition itself.
232 Anwar Shaikh

There are many aspects of this analysis which petition; competitors become monopolists
need to be developed further in order to be theo- . . . the more the mass of the proletariat
retically capable of tackling the concrete history grows as against the monopolists of one na-
of trade among capitalist nations. Let me briefly tion, the more despemte competition becomes
cite two major areas to be investigated. between monopolists ofdifferent nations. The
First, there is the question of a fuller develop- synthesis is of such a character that monopoly
ment of Marx’s theory of money to account for can only maintain itself by continually en-
different forms of money and credit, so that we tering into the struggle of competition. (Marx,
may trace their effects on the previously derived 1971, p. 152, emphasis added)
laws of money. This is a complex and controver- In any case, these are concerns to be followed
sial task, in which not only must the tangled his- up elsewhere. The central focus here has been
tory of monetary phenomena be theoretically the manner in which the inherent tendencies of
absorbed, but also the various modern (Keynes- capitalist development manifest themselves in-
ian, monetarist) theories of money be con- ternationally. The law of uneven development,
fronted. In recent times there has been a rapid of the concentration and polarization of wealth
reawakening of interest in distinguishing a which characterizes capitalism, can be seen to
Marxist theory of money from its various ortho- manifest itself in the form of a widening gap
dox counterparts, and a growing number of peo- between poor and rich capitalist nations - not
ple are now focusing on this task (de Brunhoff, due to some external factor or political conspir-
1967; Foley, 1975). acy, but precisely as the necessary form of devel-
Second, there is the question of distinguishing opment of free trade. This gap and its attendant
monopoly from concentration and centraliza- consequences are symptoms, not causes: the
tion. It was Marx’s concern to show that con- cure must address itself to the disease.
centration and centralization are immanent ten-
dencies of capitalist development, fostered pre-
cisely by what Marx calls the “competition of
capitals;’ ’ it has been the intention here to dem-
Notes
onstrate that precisely the same thing occurs in-
temationally , for precisely the same reasons. To Sexism is proved tu be buth ratiurml arld efXcienl:
some Marxists, however, concentration and men and women enter the marriage market with
centralization imply monopoly; and monopoly various initial endowments consisting of home-
being the opposite of free competition, it signals capital and market-capital: men being in general
the end of the law of value and the beginning of relatively more endowed with market-capital, and
the era of monopoly capital (Sweezy, 1942, p. women with home-capital, they specialize to their
54). I would argue, however, that this notion of mutual advantage in market and home activities
monopoly is inadequate; it stems largely from respectively (Becker, 1973, 1974) _ The potential of
orthodox theory, whose analysis is located in this fantastic analysis is, I feel, not even ap:
proached by Becker’s use of it. What about blacks
the sphere of circulu tion, and refers to the ability and whites ? Nazis and Jews? Surely there is
of individual capitalists to control and influence much more work still to be done.
the conditions of purchase and sale. As I out- (p,/p,) J = relative price of cloth to wine in
lined in the third section of this chapter, Marxian country J. Then if~Pc/Pw)l < ~PclPuA ~Pw/P,hz <
analysis is located primarily in production and (Pw/PJl*
reproduction; as such, it is not a question of the One definition of absolute efficiency would be that
will of individual capitalists, but of the limits im- if both countries had the same currency and the
posed upon them by those sets of relations same level of money wages, the more efficient pro-
which define the capitalist mode of production.4s ducers would have lower costs.
Similarly the scalar differences in production func-
The analysis of the manner in which these limits tions in different countries for the same good can
manifest themselves is what the term law of also be interpreted as indexes of absolute advan-
value means in Marx; in this regard, the compe- tage (Arrow, et al., 1961).
tition of capitals is not to be understood as the This is a period that by most accounts dominates
opposite of monopoly, and the era of monopoly the history of capitalism up to at least 1914, and by
capital need not be severed from the law of some accounts up to the 1960s. In any case, the
value: period under consideration is one in which pre-
In practical life we find not only competition, cious metals function as the ultimate international
money; this by no means excludes the phenomena
monopoly and the antagonism between them, associated with token money and credit money.
but also the synthesis of the two, which is not Though I do not develop the different forms of
a formula but a movement. Monopoly pro- money here, the analysis outlined here can be ex-
duces competition, but competition produces tended to deal with token and credit money based
monopoly. Monopolists are made from com- on a commodity money (gold, silver, etc.).
The laws of international exchange 233

6 Graham’s examples, in a manner similar to Leon- 18 The natural prices of Ricardo and the prices of pro-
tief s anomolous results, have come to be sancti- duction of Marx currently go by a variety of names,
fied under the name of Graham’s paradox. the most common being “long-run equilibrium”
7 Properly speaking, neo-Keynesian analysis seeks prices. We will stick to Marx’s terminology here.
to trace the short-run consequences of changes in 19 Adam Smith of course postulated a precapitalist
patterns of trade, rather than attempting to specify law of prices in which relative prices equalled rela-
the actual determinants of trade. It is therefore tive labor-times. In that sense, one could claim that
often presented as a complemerzt to the law of com- Smith dealt with a case in which there were no cap-
parative costs. italists. But this has nothing to do with ignoring
8 Barrat-Brown surveys various arguments blaming means of production, which is what neoclassical
“seclionalisl rnoriopoly and ubstl ul;tiunist yrinci- asxrtiurls abuut Ricardo and Smith amount to.
pies,” “postcolonial nationalism and self-imposed 20 In fact, the gold standard operated with exchange
autarchy , ’ ’ “trade union action,” and the inequal- rates which could vary within certain limits. These
ity of “bargaining power” between developed and limits, called gold-points, determined whether it
underdeveloped capitalist countries, for the his- was cheaper to change local currency into foreign
torical inapplicability of free trade arguments currency via the exchange-rate, or to buy gold with
(Bar-rat-Brown, 1974, pp. 32, 35, 38, 233). the local currency and spend the gold abroad. The
9 It might be added that a satisfactory resolution of basic determinant of the gold-points was the cost of
the problem of price formation in competitive capi- transporting gold-bullion from one country to an-
talism (the so-called transformation problem) may other.
well point the way to a better treatment of monop- 21 In neoclassical presentations, the comparison is
oly. An inadequate undtxstanding of the former between price ratios of cloth and wine in each
would almost surely hinder the development of a country, rather than efficiency of production. But
satisfactory understanding of the latter. the conclusion is the same.
10 “The behavior of labor remains a matter of indif- 22 Althusser discusses the methodological break
ference for the application of the law of compara- between Marx and the classical economists (Alt-
tive advantage, the sole condition, both necessary husser, 1970).
and sufficient, for this proposition being the mobil- 23 The distinction between concrete labor and ab-
ity of capital” (Emmanuel, 1972, pp. xxxi-ii). stract labor is related to (though different from) the
11 Emmanuel does not abandon the law of compara- distinction between productive and unproductive
tive costs, even for the modern world. Rather, he labor. In both cases the properties of value (and
sees the modern law to be the sum of two pro- surplus value) producing labor are at the heart of
cesses; first, the formation of international prices the distinction.
of production via international equalization of the 24 The case of rent is a good example of this method.
rate of profit; and second, specialization according Land is not a product of human labor and conse-
to comparative costs, where comparative cost quently has no value; yet land has a price. A clear
ratios are determined precisely by the international contradiction in Marx’s theory of value, it would
prices of production. In Chapter 6 of Urmpal Ex- seem. Not at all, Marx replies. One of the neces-
change . . . , he illustrates the effects of unequal sary steps in the theoretical transition from value to
exchange on the pattern of specialization. assum- price is the formulation of the concept of rent.
ing throughout that this pattern is based ultimately Once it is understood how value determines rent,
on comparative costs. and it is seen that the price of land is nothing but
12 The term Third World is used occasionally rent capitalized (percent-discounted) into a sum of
throughout this chapter in deference to its wide- money, then rather than contradicting the law of
spread popularity. It is, however, a very mislead- value the price of land affirms it!
ing term in that it suggests a separation between the 25 Marx mentions his treatment of surplus-value inde-
poor capitalist countries and world capitalism. pendently of its fetishistic forms (interest, rent,
13 Emmanuel particularly emphasizes stagnation, profit) as one of the “ three fundamentally new ele-
poverty, a widening “development gap,” and de- ments of’ Capitcd (Marx to Engels, January 8,
clining terms of trade for Third World countries 1868).
(Emmanuel, 1972). 26 See Morishima, 1973, Chs. 5, 6; and Shaikh, 1973,
14 It is clear from Emmanuel’s analysis that capital- Ch. IV, Sec. 4. In both of these, it is established
ists are free to use the best technique of production that there is a monotonic relationship between the
available. On page 6 1 he refers to the example of money rate of profit Y and the Marxian rate of
page 63, which assume the same technology in both surplus-value s/v, for given conditions of produc-
countries (Emmanuel, 1972). tion. Of course, the Marxian value rate of profit
15 Emmanuel’s analysis tends to be posed in terms of S/(C + V) is also a monotonic function of S/V, for
nations as the primary units, not classes. given production conditions. Thus the money rate
16 It is worth remembering that Proudhon’s philoso- of profit is a monotonic function of the value rate.
phy of poverty also depends on a notion of equal 27 The velocity of circulation of money is actually the
exchange. rate at which commodities enter and drop out of
17 It is interesting to note that Marx’s reaction to Ri- circulation. But because money remains within cir-
cardo, for example, is critical, appreciative, and culation, and commodities enter to be sold and
nonpolemic. This is different from Marxist critics leave when consumed, it is the money which ap-
of Emmanuel (who might rightly be called a neo- pears to cause, rather than measure, the movement
Ricardian). of the commodity.
2 3 4 Anwar S h a i k h

28 Marx distinguishes reserve funds of coins, which 34 We exclude the case where England is also a pro-
are really within the sphere of circulation from ducer of gold (directly or through colonies), since
hoards, in which gold leaves circulation altogether. that is obviously a special circumstance. If we treat
It is the reserve funds of coins which.$Psr manifest gold production as taking place in a third country
an excess of coin (Marx, 1972, p. 137). (South Africa), then the only way for England to
29 Of course, gold bars may appear to be sold for an uc‘quiw gold is through exports to South Africa.
equal weight of gold in the form of coins; but this is But given the conditions of this example, in which
only a change of form from bullion to coin. It is not England is at a disadvantage in both (exportable)
a sale since there is no price involved: an ounce of commodities, it is Portugal which will export to
gold is an ounce of gold regardless of its shape. The South Africa, not England.
same conclusion applies to the sale of gold for 35 Under the gold standard, in the event of a drain of
paper money which is backed by gold. In this case gold, the central bank of a country would fre-
the paper is a token of a quantity of gold equal to quently make money scarce precisely in order to
that which it buys. Marx discusses the illusions to raise the interest rate and attract short-term foreign
which token money gives rise (Marx, 1972). capital (Marx, 1967, Vol. III, Ch. 35, p. 575).
30 It is important to note that in Marx’s analysis, 36 The crucial point of free trade arguments is pre-
hoarding arises out of s t r u c t u r a l reasons specific to cisely that, all other things being equal, trade will
commodity production and/or capitalist commod- benefit all parties concerned.
ity production. In Keynesian analysis, hoarding is 37 Commodities whose production is peculiar to a
ultimately based on psychologicul propensities. single nation are really subsumed under the cate-
31 There is no automatic link in Marx’s analysis gory of commodities which can be produced at a
between a fall in the rate of interest and an expan- lower cost in that nation than elsewhere. There-
sion in the level of investment. Investment depends fore, from now on we will refer only to the latter
ultimately on the possibility of making profits; a more general category.
lower rate of interest raises the net profitability of 38 This is the orthodox analysis of the effects of direct
investments financed out of borrowing. But this investment even though it is generally acknowl-
does not by itself imply an automatic expansion of edged that the factor-price equalization theorem
investment. (derived from the Hecksher-Ohlin-Samuelson
32 Marx also notes that it is the empirical association model of commodity trade) eliminates any reason
of price rises with the discovery of new gold mines for international capital flows. According to this
which leads to the idea that the increased supply of theorem, commodity trade alone will equalize
gold causes the higher prices. Yet, as he points out, wage and profit rates in all countries, so that there
the discovery of a new, more productive gold mine will be no advantage in foreign investment.
lowers the unit value (w,) of an ounce of gold, and 39 In this analysis we ignore the creation of consump-
thus raises the price level. This by itself means that tion patterns, even though they represent an impor-
more gold would be needed for circulating even the tant aspect of the internationalization of capital.
same mass of commodities. This implies a rise in 40 This by no means implies that it is impossible for a
the sum of prices due to a rise in the price level, particular underdeveloped capitalist country to
with a corresponding rise of gold in circulation. A modernize from the inside, any more than it is im-
portion of the new gold is thus absorbed by this in- possible for a particular small capitalist to make the
creased need for circulating gold. leap into the big-time. I am only concerned to ana-
In addition, as outlined in the text, the remaining lyse the overwhelming tendencies of free trade and
new gold will tend to raise effective demand and competition among capitalist nations within this
hence production. In this case the sum of prices chapter’s scope.
rises because output rises, and this in turn requires 41 Net cost here refers to the fact that the lower direct
more gold to be in circulation. productivity of labor-power in the UCC is more
On the surface, therefore, what we will observe than offset by even lower wage rates.
in such circumstances is a rise in price accom- 42 Suppose the average rate of profit in the UCC was
panied by a rise in the supply of precious metals 10 percent. Then if copper had a cost-price A4 =
extant in the world. To the quantity theorists this 100 oz of gold, its price of production (before
correlation becomes causation; the I-ix in pl-ice is direct invcstmcnt) would bc 111’ = 110 oz. Now,
uttributed to the rise in the supply of gold (Marx, even if the average rate of profit in the DCC was 15
1972, 160-65). percent, foreign capital would attempt to enter
33 The value of any commodity is the uveruge amount copper production in the UCC if through modern-
of labor-time required for its production. As such, ization it could lower the cost-price of copper to say
gold produced in various countries will have a 80 oz - because then, at or even under the going
value representing the average of the differing price of copper of 110 oz, this foreign capital could
amounts of labor-time required in the different receive a rate of profit above the 15 percent it
countries (and mines). This distinction between would get at home.
individual labor-time required and the social 43 This, too, is logically impossible. The standard of
average (value) plays an important role in Marx’s living (the real wage) of workers in any country
analysis of rent and surplus profit. Whether the must ultimately be limited by the level of develop-
individual labor-times refer to differing conditions ment of its forces of production. By what magic will
of production of gold (different mines) within one the Indian worker be able to achieve the same
country or between countries, does not matter as standard of living as the U.S. worker? The total so-
far as the value of gold is concerned. cial product per capita in India - by any conceiv-
able index - is lower than the real wage of the U.S. Foreign: the American Capital Position Re-
worker. Even if Indian workers were to consume examined, ’ ’ Proceedings of the Americun Philo-
their whole social product, real wage differences sophicul Society, Vol. 97.
would not be wiped out - but of course Indian capi- 1956. “Factor Proportions and the Structure of
tal would bc. Thus the incentive for foreign invest- American Trader Further Theoretical and Empiri-
ment - wage differences - would remain, while the cal Analysis,” Review of Economics and Sta-
competition - the local capitalists - would be long tistics, Vol. XXXVIII,
gone! 1958. “Reply,” Review of Economics and Statistics
44 As noted earlier, the location of uneven develop- (Supplement) Vol. XL.
ment in free trade itself implies that we must be Magdoff, H. 1969. The Age of lmpevialism. New
more precise in distinguishing imperialism as a York: Monthly Review Press.
stage in capitalist development from uneven devel- Mandel, E. 1968. Marxist Economic Theory. Vols. I,
opment as an immanent process in all stages. This II. Brian Pearce, trans. New York: Monthly Re-
task cannot be attempted here. I thank John view Press.
Weeks for pointing this out to me. Marx, IS. 1967. Capitak Vol. I, II, III. Moscow: Inter-
45 “The will of the capitalist is certainly to take as national Publishers.
much as possible. What we have to do is not to talk 1972. A Contribution to the Critique of Political
about his ~$1, but to enquire into his ponies, the Economy. New York: International Publishers.
limits of that power, and the character of those 1973. Grundrisse. New York: Penguin Books.
limits” (Marx, 1970, p.. 190). 1971. The Poverty qfphilosophy. New York: Inter-
national Publishers.
1969. Theories @’ Surplus Value, Parts I-III.
References Moscow: Progress Publishers.
1970. “Wages, Prices, and Profits,” in Marx-Engels
Althusser, L., and Balibar, E. 1970. Reading Capital. Selected Works in One Volume. New York: Inter-
Ben Brewster, trans. New York: Pantheon national Publishers.
Books. Minhas, B. S. 1962. “The Homophypallagic Produc-
Amin, S. 1974. Accumulation on a World Scale: A tion Function, Factor-Intensity Reversals and the
Critique of the Theory of Underdel,elopment. 2 Hecksher-Ohlin Theorem,” Journal of Political
vol. New York: Monthly Review Press. Economy, Vol. LX,
Arrow, K., Chenery, H. B., Minhas, B., and Solow, Morishima, M. 1973. Marx’s Economics. Cam-
R. W. 1961. “Capital Labor Substitution and Eco- bridge* Cambridge 1 rniversity Press.
nomic Efficiency, ’ ’ Review of Economics and Mundell, R. A. 1968. “Balance of Payments,“ Znter-
Sructisfics, Vol. 43. nutionul E~cyclnpedia of the Social Sciences.
Barrat-Brown, M. 1974. The Economics of Imperial- VoI. 8. David L. Sills, ed. New York: Macmillan.
I’sr?x. New York: Penguin Books. Payer, C. 1974. Tl?c Debt Trup: The 1,M.F. and the
Becker, G. 1973. “A Theory of Marriage: Part I,” T h i r d W o r l d . New York: Monthly Review Press.
Journal of Political Economy Vol. 81, No. 4. Pilling, G. 1973. “Imperialism, Trade, and Unequal
1974. “A Theory of Marriage: Part II,” Journal of Exchange: The Work of Arghiri Emmanuel,”
Politica/ Economy, Vol. 82, No, 2. Economy und Society.
Brunhoff, S. de 1967. La Monnaie chez Marx. Paris: Ricardo, D. 1951. The Principles of Political Economy
Editions Sociale. and Taxation, Vol. I of Collected Works and Cov-
Emmanuel, A. 1972. Unequal Exchange: A Study of respondence of David Ricardo. P. Sraffa, ed.
the Imperialism of Trade. New York: Monthly Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Review Press. Seton, F. 1957. “The ‘Transformation Problem’,” Re-
Foley, D. 1975. “Towards a Marxist Theory of view ofEconomic Studies, Vol. 25. pp. 149-60.
Money ,’ ’ Technical Report No. 181, Economic Shaikh, A. 1973. “Theories of Value and Theories of
Series, Institute of Muthemcrticnl Studies in the Distribution ,’ ’ Columbia University; Ph.D. dis-
Social Sciences. Palo Alto, Calif.: Stanford Uni- sertation.
versity Press. 1977. “Marx’s Theory of Value and the ‘Transfor-
Hayter, T. 1972. Aid as Imperialism. New York: mation Problem’ ,’ ’ in The Subtle Anatomy of
Penguin Books. Cupitulism. Jesse Schwartz, ed. Santa Monica,
Jalee, P. 1969. The Third World in World Economy. Calif.: Goodyear Publishing, pp. 106-39.
New York: Monthly Review Press. Sraffa, P. 1960. Production of Commodities by Means
Johnson, H. 1968. “International Trade: Theory,” In- of Commodities. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer-
ternationai Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, sity Press.
Vol. 8, David L. Sills, ed. New York: Macmillan. Sweezy, P. 1942. The Theory of Cupitalist Develop-
Kenen, P. B. 1968. “International Monetary Econom- me/It. New York: Monthly Review Press.
ics: Private International Capital Movements,” Tooke, T., and Newmarch, W. 1838-57. A History of
International Encyclopedia of the Social Sci- Prices from I792 -1856. Reprinted from the origi-
ences, Vol. 8. David L. Sills, ed. New York: Mac- nal published in six volumes, with an introduction
millan. by T. E. Gregory. New York: Adelphi.
LcIiiIi, V. I. 1939. Imy4riuIi3-m, thtz Higkst Stugc of Yeagel-, L. 13. 1966. Inter~zatiorza/ hdonctavy Rclatic-)ns:
Capitalism. New York: International Publishers. Theory, History and Policy. New York: Harper &
Leontief, W. W. 1953. “Domestic Production and Row.

Você também pode gostar