Você está na página 1de 17

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/258863293

Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation: Framing the Dynamic Cycle of
Control Points

Article  in  MIS Quarterly · October 2013


DOI: 10.25300/MISQ/2013/37.2.13

CITATIONS READS
111 7,076

1 author:

Margherita Pagani
EMLYON Business School
66 PUBLICATIONS   1,324 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

ADDING VOICE TO THE OMNICHANNEL AND HOW THAT AFFECTS BRAND TRUST View project

HELLO, ROBOT! CUSTOMER RESPONSES TO ROBOTIZATION IN CORE SERVICE ENCOUNTERS View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Margherita Pagani on 15 May 2017.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


SPECIAL ISSUE: DIGITAL BUSINESS

DIGITAL BUSINESS STRATEGY AND VALUE CREATION:


FRAMING THE DYNAMIC CYCLE OF CONTROL POINTS1
Margherita Pagani
Marketing Department, Bocconi University, Via Roentgen, 1,
20136 Milan ITALY {margherita.pagani@unibocconi.it}

Within changing value networks, the profits and competitive advantages of participation reside dynamically
at control points that are the positions of greatest value and/or power. The enterprises that hold these positions
have a great deal of control over how the network operates, how the benefits are redistributed, and how this
influences the execution of a digital business strategy. This article is based on a field study that provides
preliminary, yet promising, empirical evidence that sheds light on the dynamic cycle of value creation and
value capture points in digitally enabled networks in response to triggers related to technology and business
strategy. The context used is that of the European and U.S. broadcasting industry. Specifically, the paper
illustrates how incremental innovations may shift value networks from static, vertically integrated networks
to more loosely coupled networks, and how cross-boundary industry disruptions may then, in turn, shift those
to two-sided markets. Based on the analysis, insights and implications for digital business strategy research
and practice are then provided.

Keywords: Control points, incremental innovation, disruptive innovation, digital business strategy, value
network

The Emergence of a Digital The multichannel digital revolution coupled with the develop-
ment of interactive digital technology, virtualization, peer-to-
Ecosystem1
peer networks, cloud computing, Internet of services, and
other IT developments is changing the rules of the game in
In the last few decades, companies have moved away from
many industries through disruptions of business models. The
hierarchical integrated supply chains in favor of fragmented
result is the emergence of a much more complex and dynamic
networks of strategic partnership with external entities (Bitran
ecosystem for growth and innovation (Iansiti and Levien
et al. 2007). This pattern, already visible in many industries
2004). The profits and competitive advantages of participa-
such as automotive, apparel, textiles, electronic manufac-
tion in a given value network reside dynamically within the
turing, and service, is being repeated in digitally enabled net-
chains, accumulating at the positions of greatest value and/or
works where digital technologies are fundamentally reshaping
power (control points). The enterprises that hold these posi-
traditional business processes as modular, distributed, cross-
tions have a great deal of control over how the network oper-
functional, and global processes enable work to be carried out
ates and how the benefits are redistributed (Rülke et al. 2003).
across boundaries of time, distance, and function (Samba-
murthy et al. 2003; Straub and Watson 2001; Wheeler 2002).
Structural contingency theorists (Burns and Stalker 1961;
Lawrence and Lorsch 1967) have long postulated that the
1 environment is an important factor in defining the organiza-
Anandhi Bharadwaj, Omar A. El Sawy, Paul A. Pavlou, and N.
Venkatraman served as the senior editors for this special issue and were tions within it. In particular, they have pointed to rates of
responsible for accepting this paper. change of key environmental factors like technology (Dowling

MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2, pp. 617-632/June 2013 617


Pagani/Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation

and McGee 1994) and marketing choices (Claycomb et al. The plan of this paper is as follows. We begin by sum-
2000) as driving the optimum structure of organizations marizing the results of a literature search for value network
operating within these environments. For them, however, the and value creation articles published in leading IS, strategic
environment is considered as a static exogenous variable management, and operations research journals. Next, we
moderating organizational structure and successful perfor- offer opinions and supportive arguments on how digital eco-
mance. Technology and innovation theorists (Abernathy and systems evolve and what their dynamics are in order to
Utterback 1978) and affiliated organizational theorists provide insights into defining the control points that influence
(Anderson and Tushman 1990; Henderson and Clark 1990) the execution of a digital business strategy within changing
have taken steps to advance structural contingency theory by value networks. We conclude by summarizing findings and
endogenizing technological evolution and its effect on organi- describing the implications of these findings and insights to
zational evolution. Despite the increasing interest in the research and practice.
topic, there does not appear to be a common understanding of
the effect of technological evolution on the structure and
dynamics of control points in a digitally enabled value
network. Reconfiguring for Value Creation
The present paper provides preliminary, yet promising, empi- Within the strategic management literature, several scholars
rical evidence that sheds light on the dynamic cycle of value have studied the concept of value and the sustainable compe-
creation and value capture points in digitally-enabled net- titive advantage (Brandenburger and Stuart 1996; Mol et al.
works as a result of the emergence of incremental innovation 2005; Porter 1985). Bowman and Ambrosini (2000) define
and cross-boundary industry disruptions. We consider in this value creation as the contribution to the utility of the final
paper the shifts within the broadcasting industry as a result of good or service to end users and distinguish it from value
the ICT revolution. It is worthwhile to mention that other capture defined as the difference between revenue and cost
variables such as regulation, bargaining power of stakeholder, retained by the firm. Mol et al. (2005) conceptualize a pas-
or new players from outside the traditional ecosystem may sage through the multiple value-adding stages, which even-
affect the evolution into one of the three types of network
tually accumulates into an overall value proposition. In their
structure.
model, each stage contributes a particular proportion of the
overall value created, but value capture by each contributor
In this paper, we analyze three value networks—a vertically
depends on the participants’ relative bargaining power (Bran-
integrated one, a loosely coupled one, and one based on a
denburger and Nalebuff 1997; Brandenburger and Stuart
multisided platform—and break them down into their func-
1996; Porter 1980; Teece 1986). Of course, this process may
tional components to examine the ownership and organization
not always be as sequential as this description suggests, but
of these components, which are critical in controlling the
no viable product or service will materialize unless a collec-
dynamics of core and edge competencies of players. We then
tion of these value-contributing parties can settle on a division
analyze how components change in response to triggers
related to a digital business strategy. To accomplish this task, of spoils that keeps each party willing to participate.
we construct a view of the value network as a configuration
of control points, which comprises the various service trans- In this paper, we agree with the new logic of value presented
actions involved in implementing the functional components by Normann and Ramirez (1993), which breaks down the
required to deliver a service offering. We call these configu- distinction between products and services and combines them
rations control point constellations (CPCs). Control points into activity-based “offerings” from which customers can
are analyzed in this paper in terms of how, and to what extent, create value for themselves. According to the authors, as
they create and capture value, and in what forms. potential offerings grow more complex, so do the relation-
ships necessary to create them. As a result, a company’s
Below, we focus on how industry, firm, and resource-related strategic task becomes the ongoing reconfiguration and inte-
variables interact and affect firm outcomes in term of value gration of its competencies and customers. This literature
creation and value appropriation. In doing so, the paper starts with value creation by coalitions of different economic
(1) focuses on the properties of real-world networks, (2) takes actors. Subsequent work in this strand has tended to focus on
the view that networks are not static but evolve in time the conditions that govern the ability of different parties to
according to various dynamical rules, and (3) aims to under- capture value (Lippman and Rumelt 2003; MacDonald and
stand networks not just as topological objects, but also as the Ryall 2004) and the drivers of value creation (Adner 2006;
framework upon which distributed dynamic systems are built. Adner and Zemsky 2006).

618 MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2/June 2013


Pagani/Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation

We find it useful to frame the challenge as the need to engi- supply and demand chain are digitized (Peppard and Rylander
neer a value chain simultaneously with the engineering of the 2006).
products/services and processes for providing value. In this
respect, we build on the “three-dimensional concurrent engi- Scholars working in a parallel stream have studied in
neering” framework (Fine 1998), which adds value chain engineering terms the concepts of architectural modularity in
engineering to augment the traditional two-dimensional con- order to define more precisely the conditions under which
current engineering of products and processes (Fleischer and suppliers and customers of products and services might need
Liker 1997; Nevins and Whitney 1989; Ulrich and Eppinger to engage a in structured versus unstructured technological
1994). We define a value network as one in which a cluster dialogue (Baldwin and Clark 2000; Chesbrough and
of economic actors collaborates to deliver value to the end Kusunoki 2001; Christensen 1997; Henderson and Clark
consumer and where each actor takes some responsibility for 1990; Ulrich and Eppinger 1994).
the success or failure of the network (Barnes 2002; Bitran et
al. 2003; Pigneur 2000; Sabat 2002). We distinguish five Despite increasing interest in the topic, there does not appear
types of actors: consumers, service providers, tier 1 and 2 to be a common understanding of the effect of technological
enablers, and auxiliary enablers (Basole and Rouse 2008). evolution on the structure and dynamics of control points in
Their key strategic task is the reconfiguration of roles and a digitally enabled value network. We depart from this litera-
relationships among this constellation (Normann and Ramirez ture by explicitly linking the dynamics of value creation and
1993) of actors in order to mobilize the creation of value in their implications for value capture to the structure of inter-
new forms and by new players. Partnership management dependence in a firm’s ecosystem following the emergence of
capabilities (Dyer and Singh 1998) will have to be a core an incremental and disruptive innovation. We find it useful
competence that new business actors must possess (Pigneur to frame the dynamic cycle of value creation and value
2000). capture points, defined in this manuscript as control point
constellations, with the business double helix model (Fine
When an incremental innovation appears improving upon 1998, 2000). This model asserts that when the industry struc-
something that already exists or reconfiguring an existing ture is vertical and the product architecture is integral, the
form or technology to serve some other purposes (Christensen forces of disintegration push toward a horizontal and modular
1997), significant value can be created assessing the value of configuration. These forces include (1) the relentless entry of
relevant knowledge residing at different points in the network niche competitors, (2) the challenge of keeping ahead of the
and arranging its transfer to other points in the network where competition across the many dimensions of technology and
it is needed (Doz 1996; Gulati 1999). This implies exploiting markets required by an integral system, and (3) the bureau-
resources that are made available through the network rela- cratic and organizational rigidities. These forces typically
tionships (Gulati and Singh 1998; Inkpen and Dinur 1998; weaken the vertical giant and create pressure toward disinte-
Kale et al. 2000; Khanna et al. 1998). gration to a more horizontal, modular structure (Staudenmayer
et al. 2005).
As products and services increasingly have embedded digital
technologies, it is becoming more difficult to disentangle On the other hand, when an industry has a horizontal struc-
business processes from their underlying IT infrastructures ture, another set of forces push toward more vertical inte-
(e.g., El Sawy 2003). Digital platforms are enabling cross- gration and integral product architectures. These forces
boundary industry disruptions (Christensen 1997), thus in- include (1) technical advances in one subsystem that can give
ducing new forms of business strategies (e.g., Burgelman and market power to its owner, (2) market power in one sub-
Grove 2007). Consequently, theoretical structures for stra- system that encourages bundling with other subsystems to
tegy making in nonlinear dynamic environments are also increase control and add more value, and (3) market power in
emerging (Pavlou and El Sawy 2010). Digital business one subsystem that encourages engineering integration with
strategies call for coordination across firms along product, other subsystems to develop proprietary integral solutions.
process, and service domains, thereby creating more complex
and dynamic ecosystems (Adner 2006; Iansiti and Levien
2004; Moore 1996) for growth and innovation. The whole
value network is underpinned by a particular value creating Premise of this Study
logic and its application results in particular strategic pos-
tures. Adopting a network perspective (Burt 2004; Gulati This study seeks to illustrate how incremental innovations
1995; Kogut and Walker 2001; Marsden and Podolny 1990) may shift value networks from static, vertically integrated
provides an alternative perspective that is more suited to “new networks, to more loosely coupled networks, and how “dis-
economy” organizations, particularly those where both the ruptive” innovations may then in turn shift them to two-sided

MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2/June 2013 619


Pagani/Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation

markets. The study intends to provide insights into defining (empirical results emerging from case studies), (2) selection
the control points that influence the execution of a digital of the model structure, and (3) model estimation and valida-
business strategy within changing value networks. tion. We use as an empirical setting the broadcasting industry
in Europe and the United States in the period 2000–2008. We
Our opinion is that, in order to succeed over the long haul, selected this industry as it transitioned through three distinct
firms within value networks have to periodically reorient technology generations (analog TV, digital TV, and multi-
themselves by adopting new strategies and structures that are sided digital platforms) resulting from the emergence of an
necessary to accommodate changing environmental condi- incremental innovation and cross-boundary industry
tions. These shifts, occurring through incremental or discon- disruptions.
tinuous changes, have different impacts on the structure of
control points in the value networks. Our propositions, built We used both primary and secondary data sources for this
inductively from empirical analysis of digitally enabled net- study. We began by developing a detailed historical under-
works, are as follows: standing of the broadcasting industry during a 10-month field
study. We conducted multiple interviews with 45 industry
1. A closed, vertically integrated model of CPC structure experts from 15 leading companies in Europe and the United
emerges in tiers of the market where customers are States. The interviewees came from a variety of positions
underserved by the functionality or performance avail- within the ecosystem: content providers, semiconductor and
able from products in the market. electronic suppliers, broadcasters, software, terminal pro-
viders, platform aggregators, and telecommunications.
2. When the market is less demanding of functionality and
an incremental innovation appears that improves upon The interviews were semi-structured and lasted two hours on
something that already exists or reconfigures an existing average. We used the information from the interviews to
form or technology to serve some other purposes, a develop an understanding of the ecosystem challenges that
horizontally stratified or disintegrated CPC structure is governed the emergence of the different technology genera-
the dominant business model. tions. We consolidated this information in a document and
discussed it during a meeting attended by all the interviewees.
3. When the dominant business model in a tier of the We incorporated all comments emerging from the first
market shifts from vertical integration to horizontal strati- meeting and discussed the final document in a second meeting
fication, the ability to achieve above-average profitability six months later. All of the experts agreed with our final
tends to transfer to companies that build an infrastructure characterization.
(platform) that creates value by reducing distribution,
transaction, and search costs incurred when different We searched every issue of New TV Strategies and Broadcast
subsystems interact with one another. and Production (leading industry journals whose mission is
to cover the key trends and issues that confront the industry)
4. When performance gaps emerge in markets due to cross from 2000 to 2008 for articles relating to broadcasting inno-
boundary industry disruptions, the pendulum of CPC vation challenges. Using this source, we created measures
structure is likely to swing back toward vertically inte- (discussed below) that characterize the extent of challenges in
grated CPCs structures. the core and edge capabilities for each of the technology
generations. Finally, longitudinal data were collected on a
Our primary purpose in offering this paper is to invite other sample of 792 firms across the supply chain of broadcasting
scholars to empirically test these hypotheses and thereby con- industry (15% content providers, 15% semiconductor and
tinue to build deeper understanding of the dynamics of value electronic suppliers, 13% broadcasters, 17% software, 14%
creation and value capture in digital business networks, thus terminal providers, 12% platform aggregators, 14% tele-
providing a better understanding of digital business strategy. communications) in Europe and the United States between
April 2000 and May 2008. We constructed a unique data set
to test our arguments. Using an observational method
(Bernard and Killworth 1979; Bernard et al. 1980, 1982;
Field Study and Context of the Killworth and Bernard 1976), we collected detailed archival
Broadcasting Industry market data from websites, newspapers, and the leading
industry consulting firms. The information recorded for each
The methodology adopted in this study includes a system company (every year) was the specific horizontal functions
identification process called black-box modeling (Norgaard controlled and secondary capabilities acquired in other func-
et al. 2000) and follows a three-phase process: (1) experiment tions along the value chain.

620 MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2/June 2013


Pagani/Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation

The content validity was proven by consulting multiple Media companies in the United States and Europe (1980–
sources (interviews and documents). Internal validity was 1985 phase) adopted strategies aimed at obtaining scale
tested by constructing a detailed research framework ahead of economies within mutual horizontal core businesses (focali-
time. External validity was limited, since it was an explora- zation strategies) and expanded their activities to adjacent
tory study. Reliability was based on a detailed case study markets through cooperation strategies and alliances (vertical
protocol that documented the selection procedures, analysis, and horizontal strategies). Based on the case studies ana-
and summary database. lyzed, the following forces were found to drive vertical and
horizontal alliances:
We controlled for a number of firm- and industry-level
effects. Henderson and Clark (1990) identified important 1. Risks linked to the uncertain demand and the rapid
differences between incumbents and entrants during tech- market change. (For example, the short-lived alliances of
nology transitions in the broadcasting industry. We control TCI with Microsoft or Kirch, Bertelsmann with BSkyB
for this effect using the variable incumbent, which takes a for the creation of a digital satellite platform in
value of one if a firm also was present in an earlier technology Germany.)
generation. We included one industry-level control repre-
sented by the number of firms, which controls for the compe- 2. Market positioning and access to new capabilities (For
titive density in the generation in a given year. example, the alliance of Bertelsmann with America
Online to form AOL Europe enabled the group to
increase network technical capability and supply Internet
services. BBC developed Internet services and online
Three Types of Control information with ICL, which supplies the informatics
Point Constellations capabilities required to run the service. The merger of
Bell Cablemedia, NYNEX CableComms, and Videotron
In this section, we first examine three types of CPCs emerging with Mercury Communications Ltd. originated Cable and
from the case studies analyzed and the longitudinal data Wireless Communications and the expansion of service
(Figure 1): (1) closed vertically integrated model, which providers Internet UUNet through acquisition of Unipalm
defines the short-term static properties of industry structure; PIPEX in the United Kingdom and France.)
(2) loosely coupled coalition model, which implies the
emergence of an incremental innovation; and (3) multisided 3. User control possibilities and the increase in the share of
platforms which define the midterm dynamic—but non- profits deriving from the sale of products and services.
evolutionary—process of competition characterized by the (For example, Disney Corporation obtained access to
emergence of cross-boundary industry disruptions. many distribution channels by taking over ABC and
Capital Cities in 1995, thereby accessing terrestrial and
We then illustrate transition from one CPC type to another by cable TV channels. BSkyB developed new opportunities
examining the changes experienced by control points in of distributing new interactive services with BT,
response to triggers related to technology and business potentially gaining access to the BT installation base.
strategy. We model the mechanisms through which incre- Similar advantages drove Bertelsmann to cooperate with
mental and cross-boundary industry disruptions change the Deutsche Telekom in Germany.)
structure of value networks and provide support for the
double helix model (Fine 1998) while adapting it to a digital 4. Shifting to value chain areas with a higher added value.
business environment. (Mobile service providers such as Cellnet and Orange in
the United Kingdom tended to shift in the supply of
Internet services with UUNET. Microsoft and NBC
Type 1: Closed Vertically Integrated Model created the joint venture MSNBC, which enables NBC to
add value to its basic TV activities through Internet and
Prior to the disintegration and fragmentation of supply chains, Microsoft to become a content supplier.)
media companies were responsible for coordinating their own
value chains, and the control of core activities was strictly 5. Facing the competition of companies in connected mar-
centralized through vertical alliances determined by the need kets. (For example, the investments by U.S. Regional
of the single company to develop along the vertical dimension Bell Operating Companies in cable TV aimed at
of the value chain (Figure 1a). preventing competition in cable companies entering the
telecommunication market.)

MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2/June 2013 621


Pagani/Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation

(a) Closed Vertically Integrated Model

(b) Loosely Coupled Coalitions

(c) Multisided Platform

Figure 1. Three Types of Control Point Constellations

Value creation. For this value system configuration model we Value capture. As the industry structure is vertical and tend
distinguish four main sequential primary activity categories: to integrate the main functions the value capture is controlled
(1) content creation, (2) multimedia packaging and services, by key players (mainly media companies) integrated in all of
(3) network and infrastructure equipment provision, and the four main sequential primary activity categories.
(4) telecommunication service provision (Figure 2). The ten-
dency to integrate these main activities is driven by the need
to achieve independence, control the content access in order Type 2: Loosely Coupled Coalition Model
to guarantee access to the most interesting and innovative
contents (i.e., contractual agreements, primarily between TV We examine next the emergence of digital broadcasting
channels and film production companies), and acquire access systems as an incremental innovation. Digital broadcasting
control on the target user. systems enable the delivery of more TV channels and the high

622 MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2/June 2013


Pagani/Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation

Figure 2. Value Network of the Analog Broadcasting Offering (Closed Vertically Integrated Model)

definition (HDTV) format, as well as interactive services such value network structure, and that use their prominence to
as EPG, VOD, and interactive advertising. Previous studies perform a leadership role in pulling together the dispersed
show that the value network changes as a function of a resources and capabilities of network members (digital TV
technological shock (Knoben et al. 2006). channels, application service providers, network providers).
These firms can be labeled as hub firms (Brass and Burkhardt
In this phase of evolution of the industry, the emerging inter- 1993; Wasserman and Galaskiewicz 1994) and are repre-
active digital television marketplace is more complex, with sented by digital delivery platforms.
competing platforms and technologies (satellite, cable,
terrestrial, IP) providing different capabilities and oppor- We define network orchestration as the set of deliberate, pur-
tunities. The TV value chain is increasingly being decon- poseful actions undertaken by the hub firm (digital delivery
structed, leading to the development of a complex and rapidly platform) as it seeks to create value and capture value from
evolving value network (Pagani 2003). We look in depth at the network. This type of value network may be viewed as
the changes occurring in the TV value chain, that is, the “loosely coupled coalitions” (Provan 1983), where loose
digital terrestrial, cable, and satellite systems in the United coupling is a situation in which elements are responsive, but
States and 10 countries in Europe. For each country, we retain evidence of separateness and identity (Weick 1976).
mapped the main players. Figure 3 uses the example of Italy.
The supply chain now appears more disintegrated and open.
In this changed context, we can distinguish the emergence of Traditional broadcasters, who in the previous stage developed
firms (digital delivery platforms) that possess more promi- primary skills in the phases of packaging and signal transmis-
nence and power gained through a central position in the sion (network provision), now develop contractual links with

MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2/June 2013 623


Pagani/Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation

Figure 3. Digital TV in Italy

other players in the market (application service providers, digital technology, value creation control points tend to
network providers etc.). TV channels and delivery platforms increase. Network providers (i.e., traditional delivery plat-
compete to capture the attention of the viewer and the value forms such as cable, satellite, OTA or newer telco IPTV and
is provided by the most compelling content and useful inter- wireless services) offer a walled garden of content acquired
active service. Figure 4 illustrates the location of the biggest and aggregated into various consumer packages.
players along the value chain and the relations among them.
Value capture. With reference to the flow of revenues among
Digital TV offers attractive opportunities to players who by the different operators we found that network operators have
tradition were foreign to the broadcasting world, particularly an advantage in gaining revenue. Their condition of “bottle-
to companies operating in the field of telecommunications neck,” through which all of the content that appears on tele-
(i.e., France Télécom, Telecom Italia, Telefònica, BT, AT&T) vision must pass, provides a steady revenue stream for pay-
and informatics (i.e., Microsoft). Such companies are TV services while interactive-TV applications are being
interested in exploiting digital TV primarily as it pertains to developed. Service providers collect their revenues directly
interactive services and the interconnection, software, and from final users through their services. Revenues are then
hardware demands arising from them—either alone or in distributed among the other upstream stages of the value
combination with traditional television contents. chain. Broadcasters gather relevant additional revenues from
indirect sources, such as advertising, which represents a
Value creation. Once the digital TV market matures, the fundamental part of the revenue model. Within telecoms, the
retention of viewers will be determined by the quality and percentage of call revenues funded by advertisers (through
range of content and services provided by the operator. free phone, national call rate, and local rate numbers) con-
Service providers that secure attractive content services at an tinues to rise. As advertising is the central revenue stream in
early stage will have an advantage in attracting and retaining the broadcasting and telecom business model, it is extremely
subscribers. As the number of TV channels increase due to important for capturing the value generated in the ecosystem.

624 MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2/June 2013


Pagani/Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation

Figure 4. Value Network of the Digital TV Market (Loosely Coupled Coalitions)

Type 3: Multisided Platforms in some way, and where the company builds an infrastructure
(platform) that creates value by reducing distribution, trans-
Next, we examine the collision of multiple disruptions that action, and search costs incurred when these groups interact
influence computing (as devices are more personal), networks with one another (Eisenmann et al. 2006).
(connectivity is ubiquitous), value chain clockspeed (value
capture is fleeting), content control, regulatory, consumer and Value creation. In this model we distinguish three main
IP protection, consumer experience, software distribution, players: (1) end user peers, (2) transport peers (network), and
social networking, storage and time shifting, and content pro- (3) platforms/aggregators.
duction (webcams). These cross-boundary industry disrup-
tions lead to the emergence of new business models (Google End user peers are able to interact (real-time communication
TV, Brightcove, Hulu, Joost), new interactive services, and or asymmetric), be part of a social network (i.e., Facebook,
radical changes in the traditional viewing habits, meeting new some gaming environments), consume content (push versus
needs. We call this model (depicted in Figure 1c) the multi- pull—i.e., downloads, broadcast, on demand), publish content
sided platform. (as individual end users or for-profit), and advertise. The
transport peers (ISPs, carriers) provide the “pipes” that enable
The emergence of the multisided platform (Eisenmann et al. utility/consumption and are concerned with ROI.
2006; Geoffrey and Van Alstyne 2005; Parker and Van
Alstyne 2005) represents a new form of market structure and These two players are linked by platforms/aggregators, which
can be seen as a consequence of the disruptive innovation provide environments that support end-user utility, usually
related to the emergence of new services and new business using transport networks. Examples analyzed are eBay (or
models. It exists wherever a company brings together two or Yahoo! Auctions, etc.) bringing together buyers and sellers;
more distinct groups of customers (sides) that need each other Google with content providers, consumers, and advertisers;

MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2/June 2013 625


Pagani/Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation

Figure 5. Multisided Platform Model

Visa, American Express, or other payment systems bringing control is necessary for the platform to function and because
together merchants and consumers; Sony PlayStation with they have the market power to do so. Apple, for example, in
users, game developers, and middleware providers; Apple almost all cases mandated a single, across-the-board pricing
iTunes/iPod with music labels (content publishers) and con- structure on the iTunes music store. Other MSP companies
sumers; and DoCoMo i-mode bringing together online content allow participants broad latitude in their platform activity,
providers, application developers, handset makers, and setting minimum rules that will enable and encourage the
consumers. platform to function smoothly and profitably. Thus, eBay lets
sellers decide minimum bid amounts, auction duration, and so
Multisided platforms (MSPs) can vary from having two sides on. Microsoft places no restrictions over who can sell
(eBay, Visa), three sides (Windows, Google), four sides (i- applications for Windows and how.
mode, Brightcove), or potentially even more. However, the
more sides, the higher the degree of complexity and the Value capture. In multisided networks, cost and revenue are
greater the strategic challenge of balancing the interests of all on each side. The platform incurs costs in serving all of the
sides (other things being equal). The choice of which sides to groups and can collect revenue from each, although one side
target can have an immense impact on the structure and the is often subsidized. In cases like eBay or Visa, one side pays
success of an MSP business. to play (sellers, merchants), and the other doesn’t (buyers,
consumers)—although the latter may pay indirectly. Craigs-
MSPs create value by generating indirect network effects list is open on both the sides. With Windows, Microsoft
between the multiple sides they serve. iTunes becomes more derives its revenues from licensing fees charged to users,
valuable to music labels as more and more consumers buy whereas application developers do not pay anything and are
into that platform by purchasing iPods. As more merchants in fact subsidized through various forms of development sup-
opt to take Visa, the Visa card becomes more valuable for port. By contrast, with Xbox, Microsoft derives the bulk of
consumers and vice versa. its revenues from royalties charged to game developers, while
selling the consoles to users at or below cost. Their business
Governance patterns vary from MSP to MSP. Some plat- model can be not-for-profit (i.e., Gnutella, BitTorrent) or for
forms retain a high degree of control over actions by all sides profit (Google, eBay, Facebook, Akamai, Skype, or corpor-
of their platform, because they conclude that centralized ations, universities, etc.).

626 MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2/June 2013


Pagani/Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation

Framing the Dynamic Cycle of CPCs cross-boundary industry “disruptions” may in turn shift them
to multisided markets.
Finally, we analyze the changes experienced by control points
in response to triggers related to technology and business stra- We use the business double helix (Fine 1998) to explain how
tegy and compare the three evolving value network structures digital ecosystems evolve and their dynamics. We identify
in terms of value creation logic, primary activity categories, three main types of network structures. Two of them are
main interactivity relationship logic, primary activity inter- linear systems, while the third is characterized by non-
dependence, and key cost and value drivers. Table 1 sum- linearity.
marizes our analysis and description.
In this evolving pattern, the parts can display complex non-
What we find most critical is the change in the value creation linear dynamics, and their implications can be quite stunning,
and value capture logic. The closed vertically integrated as they often imply an effective disconnection between the
model is characterized by the presence of giant, strongly con- well-defined behavior of the components and the global out-
nected components that create and capture value. The busi- come that one observes. What this means is that the precise
ness value system structure is characterized by interlinked knowledge about the plans and strategies of individuals in the
chains. In the loosely coupled coalitions, resulting from the market would not suffice to understand the behavior of the
emergence of an incremental innovation, different players market.
along the value chain create value through a pooled, sequen-
tial, and reciprocal primary activity interdependence. Value We have drawn a number of insights for the evolution of
is captured by referred hubs and redistributed. In the multi- digital ecosystems and showed how digital business strategy
sided platform type, resulting from cross-boundary industry shifts. These insights also provide two implications for both
research and practice.
disruptions, a main infrastructure brings together two or more
groups and creates value by reducing distribution, transaction,
and search costs.
Transform Organizational Intelligence
Figure 6 frames the dynamic cycle of CPCs and the mech- into a New Relational Intelligence
anisms through which incremental and cross-boundary
This study shows that in order to survive in an increasingly
industry disruptions change the structure of value networks.
uncertain and complex environment, the firm has to transform
Findings support the business double helix model (Fine 1998)
its organizational intelligence into a new relational intelli-
in the digital environment and show that when the industry
gence, enacting an open communication process with its
structure is vertical and the product architecture is integral,
stakeholders.
the forces of disintegration and the emergence of an incre-
mental innovation push toward a horizontal and modular
The closed vertically integrated model (type 1) is no longer
configuration. On the other hand, when an industry has a
the best organizational architecture because it is designed to
horizontal structure, another set of forces, named cross-
centralize the organizational intelligence, not to maximize it.
boundary industry disruptions, push toward more vertical
In the loosely coupled coalition (type 2), it is much more
integration and integral product architectures. valuable to play in an orchestra than to be an outstanding
soloist as part of a value creation ecosystem (Adner 2006;
Adner and Kapoor 2010). Value creation is the output of a
process that encourages creativity and diversity, yet does not
Implications and Insights for Digital allow the players to go out of tune completely. In the third
Business Strategy and Research type of digital networked world, where everyone and every-
thing is connected (multisided platforms), economic value be-
The study analyzes the structure and dynamics of value con- haves very differently than it does in the traditional, bounded
figuration in a technology-enabled industry in order to pro- world. These three types of value networks show different
vide insights into identifying and defining the control points ownership and organization of functional components, which
that influence the execution of a digital business strategy are critical in controlling the dynamics of core and edge
within changing value networks. Our study makes a number competencies of players. Understanding these three types and
of contributions. First, it illustrates how incremental innova- their transition allows companies to better recognize how
tions may shift value networks from static, vertically inte- components change in response to triggers related to a digital
grated networks to more loosely coupled networks, and how business strategy.

MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2/June 2013 627


Pagani/Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation

Table 1. Overview of Alternative Control Point Constellation Models


Closed Vertically Integrated
Model Loosely Coupled Coalitions Multisided Platform
Value creation Presence of giant strongly Focus on a specific phase of Bringing together two or more
logic connected components the value chain managing rela- distinct groups of customers,
tions with partners along the building an infrastructure that
value chain creates value by reducing distri-
bution, transaction, and search
costs.
Value capture Value is captured by the giant • Network operators have an In multisided networks cost and
logic advantage revenue are on each side. The
• Service providers collect platform incurs costs in serving
revenues directly from final all the groups and can collect
users and distribute them revenue from each, although
among the other upstream one side is often subsidized.
stages of the value chain
• Broadcasters gather relevant
additional revenues from
indirect sources
Primary activity • Content provision • Content provision • Network promotion
categories • Packaging • Content and interactive • Service provisioning
• Network provision service packaging • Infrastructure operation
• Conditional access • Network provision
• Managing relationships with
customers and partners
Main interactivity Sequential Symmetric/asymmetric Simultaneous, parallel
relationship logic interactivity
Primary activity • Pooled • Pooled • Pooled
interdependence • Sequential • Sequential • Reciprocal
• Reciprocal
Key cost drivers • Scale • Scale
• Capacity utilization • Capacity utilization
Key value drivers • Market positioning and access • Scale • Capacity utilization
to new capabilities
• Possibility of user channel
control
• Shifting to value chain areas
with higher added value
• Facing competition of com-
panies in connected sectors
• High costs of new digital
technologies
Business value • Interlinked chains • Referred hubs • Layered and interconnected
system structure networks

From Content Gatekeeper to through which value is created and who captures this value.
Customer Gatekeeper We have been able to distinguish five layers of value.

By comparing the three value constellation models, we • Value in Customer Access: This revolves around
observe a gradual shift in the critical role of a firm in a value becoming a customer gatekeeper. Most economic value
network from being a content gatekeeper to becoming a will be created at the periphery/ends of networks. At the
customer gatekeeper. If we want to understand who controls core, the end most distant from users that possesses only
the network, we need to explore in depth this evolving path generic scale-intensive functions will consolidate. At the

628 MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2/June 2013


Pagani/Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation

Figure 6. The Adapted Double Helix Model

end closest to users, highly customized connections that • Value in Orchestration: As modularization takes hold,
generate value with customers will be made. the ability to coordinate among the modules will become
the most valuable business skill.
• Value in Common Infrastructure: Elements of infra-
structure can be brought together and operated as
utilities. Concluding Thoughts
• Value in Modularity: Devices, software, organizational This paper broaches a key, unexplored issue in value network
capabilities, and business processes will increasingly be management, with implications for researchers in network
restructured as well-defined, self contained modules that theory, IS, strategy, knowledge management, alliances, and
can be quickly and seamlessly connected with other international business. Our main contribution is a novel way
modules. Value will lie in creating modules that can be to study the control point constellations (value creation and
plugged into as many different value chains as possible. value capture points) topology and the influence of incre-
Companies and individuals will want to distribute their mental innovations and cross-boundary industry disruptions
capabilities as broadly as possible rather than protect on them. The proposed conceptual framework captures con-
them as proprietary assets. cisely the highly skewed distributions of the value configura-
tion models. We support the double helix model and discover
• Value in Content Access: Findings show that for the three models that characterize the control point constellations
purpose of achieving and holding onto long-lasting com- of the multimedia industry.
petitive positions, a critical success factor is also the
gradual control of content in order to become a content Finally, what distinguishes the research described in this
gatekeeper. article from previous work is that traditional approaches to

MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2/June 2013 629


Pagani/Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation

networks have tended to overlook or oversimplify the rela- Bitran, G., Bassetti, P. F., and Romano, G. M. 2003. “Supply
tionship between the structural properties of a network system Chains and Value Networks: The Factors Driving Changes and
and its behavior. Which outcomes occur, how frequently they Their Implications to Competition in the Industrial Sector,”
occur, and with what consequences, are all questions that can Working Paper, MIT Center for eBusiness Research Brief,
only be resolved by thinking jointly about structure and Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Bitran, G., Gurumurthi, S., and Sam, S. L. 2007. “The Need for
dynamics and the relationship between the two. That is how
Third-Party Coordination in Supply Chain Governance,” Sloan
we can clearly identify and define the control points that
Management Review (48:3), pp. 30-37.
influence the execution of a digital business strategy within Bowman, C., and Ambrosini, V. 2000. “Value Creation Versus
changing value networks. Value Capture: Towards a Coherent Definition of Value in
Strategy,” British Journal of Management (11:1), pp. 1-15.
Brandenburger, A. M., and Nalebuff, B. J. 1997. Co-Opetition: A
Acknowledgments Revolution Mindset that Combines Competition and Coopera-
tion: The Game Theory Strategy that’s Changing the Game of
The author is very grateful to Professor Charles Fine at MIT Sloan Business, New York: Currency.
School of Management for his valuable suggestions and comments Brandenburger, A., and Stuart, H. W. 1996. “Value-Based Busi-
which laid the foundations of this study.
ness Strategy,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy
(5), pp. 5-24.
Brandes, U., Raab, T., and Wagner, D. 2001. “Exploratory Net-
References
work Visualization: Simultaneous Display of Actor Status and
Abernathy, W., and Utterback, J. 1978. “Patterns of Innovation in Connections,” Journal of Social Structure (2:4) (http://www.cmu.
Industry,” Technology Review (80:7), pp. 40-47. edu/joss/content/articles/volume2/BrandesRaabWagner.html).
Adner R. 2006. “Match Your Innovation Strategy to Your Brass, D. J., and Burkhardt, M. E. 1993. “Potential Power and
Innovation Ecosystem,” Harvard Business Review (84:4), pp. Power Use: An Investigation of Structure and Behavior,”
98-107. Academy of Management Journal (36), pp. 441-470.
Adner, R., and Kapoor, R. 2010. “Value Creation in Innovation Burgelman, R. A., and Grove, A. S. 2007. “Let Chaos Reign, Then
Ecosystems: How the Structure of Technological Interdepen- Rein in Chaos—Repeatedly: Managing Strategic Dynamics for
dence Affects Firm Performance in New Technological Gener- Corporate Longevity,” Strategic Management Journal (28), pp.
ations,” Strategic Management Journal (31:3), pp. 306-333. 965-979.
Adner, R., and Zemsky, P. 2006. “A Demand-Based Perspective on Burns, T., and Stalker, G. M. 1961. The Management of Inno-
Sustainable Competitive Advantage.” Strategic Management vation, London, UK: Tavistock.
Journal (27), pp. 215-239. Burt, R. S. 2004. “Structural Holes and Good Ideas,” American
Anderson, P., and Tushman, M. 1990. “Technological Discontin- Journal of Sociology (110:2), pp. 349-399.
uities and Dominant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Techno- Botafogo, R. A., and Schneiderman, B. 1991. “Identifying Aggre-
logical Change,” Administrative Science Quarterly (35:1), pp. gates in Hypertext Structures,” in Proceedings of the 3rd Annual
604-633. ACM Conference on Hypertext, San Antonio, TX, December 15-
Baldwin, C. Y., and Clark K. B. 2000. Design Rules, Volume 1, 18, pp. 63-74.
The Power of Modularity, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Claycomb, C., Germain, R., and Droege, C. 2000. “The Effects of
Baltagi, B. H. 2005. Econometric Analysis of Panel Data (3rd ed.), Formal Strategic Marketing Planning on the Industrial Firm’s
Chichester, UK: John Wiley & Sons. Configuration, Structure, Exchange Patterns, and Performance,”
Barnes, S. J. 2002. “The Mobile Commerce Value Chain: Analysis Industrial Marketing Management (29), pp. 219-234.
and Future Developments,” International Journal of Information Chesbrough, H. W., and Kusunoki, K. 2001. “The Modularity
Management (22), pp. 91-108.
Trap: Innovation, Technology Phase Shifts and the Resulting
Basole, R. C., and Rouse, W. B. 2008. “Complexity of Service
Limits of Virtual Organizations,” in I. Nonaka and D. J. Teece
Value Networks: Conceptualization and Empirical Investi-
(eds.), Managing Industrial Knowledge, London: Sage
gation,” IBM Systems Journal (47:1), pp. 53-70.
Publications, pp. 202-230.
Bernard, H. R., and Killworth, P. D. 1979. “Informant Accuracy in
Social Network Data II,” Human Communication Research (4:3), Christensen, C. M. 1997. Innovator’s Dilemma: When New Tech-
pp. 3-18. nologies Cause Great Firms to Fail, Boston: Harvard Business
Bernard, H. R., Killworth, P. D., and Sailer, L. 1980. “Informant School Press.
Accuracy in Social Network Data IV: A Comparison of Clique- Dowling, M. J., and McGee, J. E. 1994. “Business and Technology
level Structure in Behavioral and Cognitive Network Data,” Strategies and New Venture Performance: A Study of the
Social Networks (2), pp. 191-218. Telecommunications Equipment Industry,” Management Science
Bernard, H. R., Killworth, P. D., and Sailer, L. 1982. “Informant (40), pp. 1663-1677.
Accuracy in Social Network Data V: An Experiment Attempt to Doz, Y. L. 1996. “The Evolution of Cooperation in Strategic
Predict Actual Communication from Recall Data,” Social Science Alliances: Initial Conditions or Learning Processes?,” Strategic
Research (11), pp. 30-66. Management Journal (17), pp. 55-83.

630 MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2/June 2013


Pagani/Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation

Dyer, J. H., and Singh, H. 1998. “The Relational View: Coopera- Lawrence, P., and Lorsch, J. 1967. “Differentiation and Integration
tive Strategy and Sources of Interorganizational Competitive in Complex Organizations,” Administrative Science Quarterly
Advantage,” Academy of Management Review (23:4), pp. (12), pp. 1-30.
660-679. Lippman, S. A., and Rumelt, R. P. 2003. “A Bargaining Perspec-
Eisenmann, T., Parker, G., and Van Alstyne, M. W. 2006. tive on Resource Advantage,” Strategic Management Journal
“Strategies for Two-Sided Markets,” Harvard Business Review (24:11), pp. 1069-1086.
(84:10), pp. 92-101. Mac Donald, G., and Ryall, M. 2004. “How Do Value Creation and
El Sawy, O. A. 2003. “The IS Core IX: The 3 Faces of IS Identity: Competition Determine Whether a Firm Appropriates Value?”
Connection, Immersion, and Infusion,” Communications of the Management Science (50:10), pp. 1319-1333.
AIS (12:39), pp. 588-598. Marsden, P. V., and Podolny, J. 1990. “Dynamic Analysis of
Fine, C. H. 1998. Clockspeed, Cambridge, MA: Perseus Books. Network Diffusion Processes,” in Social Networks through Time,
Fine, C. H. 2000. “Clockspeed-Based Strategies for Supply Chain J. Weeise and H. Flap (eds.), Uthrecht, The Netherlands:
Design,” Production and Operations Management (9:3), pp. ISOR/Rijksuniversiteit Utrecht.
213-221. Mol, J. M., Wijnberg, N. M., and Carroll, C. 2005. “Value Chain
Fleischer, M., and Liker, J. K. 1997. Concurrent Engineering Envy: Explaining New Entry and Vertical Integration in Popular
Effectiveness, Cincinnati, OH: Hanser Gardner Publications. Music,” Journal of Management Studies (42), pp. 251-276.
Geoffrey, G. P., and Van Alstyne, M. W. 2005. “Two-Sided Net- Moody, J., McFarland, D. A., and Bender-deMoll, S. 2005.
work Effects: A Theory of Information Product Design,” “Dynamic Network Visualization,” American Journal of
Management Science (51:10), pp. 1494-1504. Sociology (110:4), pp. 1206–1241.
Gulati, R. 1995. “Does Familiarity Breed Trust? The Implications Moore, J. F. 1996. The Death of Competition: Leadership and
of Repeated Ties for Contractual Choice in Alliances,” Academy Strategy in the Age of Business Ecosystems, New York: Harper
of Management Journal (38:1), pp. 85-112. Business.
Gulati, R. 1999. “Network Location and Learning: The Influence Nevins, J. L., and Whitney, D. E. 1989. Concurrent Design of
of Network Resources and Firm Capabilities on Alliance Products and Processes: A Strategy for the Next Generation in
Formation,” Strategic Management Journal (20), pp. 397-420.
Manufacturing, New York: McGraw-Hill.
Gulati, R., and Singh, H. 1998. “The Architecture of Cooperation:
Newman, M. E. J. 2003. “The Structure and Function of Complex
Managing Coordination Costs and Appropriation Concerns in
Networks,” SIAM Review (45:2), pp. 167-256.
Strategic Alliances,” Administrative Science Quarterly (43:4), pp.
Norgaard, M., Ravn, O., Poulsen, N. K., and Hansen, L. K. 2000.
781-814.
Neural Networks for Modelling and Control of Dynamic Systems,
Henderson, R., and Clark, K. 1990. “Architectural Innovation: The
London: Springer-Verlag.
Reconfiguration of Existing Product Technologies and the
Normann, R., and Ramirez, R. 1993. Designing Interactive
Failure of Established Firms,” Administrative Science Quarterly
Strategy: From Value Chain to Value Constellation, Chichester,
(35:1), pp. 9-30.
UK: John Wiley & Sons.
Iansiti, M., and Levien, R. 2004. The Keystone Advantage: What
Pagani, M. 2003. Multimedia and Interactive Digital TV:
the New Dynamics of Business Ecosystems Mean for Strategy,
Managing the Opportunities Created by Digital Convergence,
Innovation, and Sustainability, Boston: Harvard Business School
Press. Hershey, PA: Idea Publishing Group, Inc.
Inkpen, A. C., and Dinur, A. 1998. “Knowledge Management Pro- Parker, G., and Van Alstyne M. 2005. “Two-Sided Network
cesses and International Joint Ventures,” Journal of Organization Effects: A Theory of Information Product Design,” Management
Science (9:4), pp. 454-468. Science (51: 10), pp. 1494-1504.
Kale, P., Singh, H., and Perlmutter, H. 2000. “Learning and Pavlou, P. A., and El Sawy, O. A. 2010. “The ‘Third Hand’: IT-
Protection of Proprietary Assets in Strategic Alliances: Building Enabled Competitive Advantage in Turbulence through Impro-
Relational Capital,” Strategic Management Journal (21:3), pp. visational Capabilities,” Information Systems Research (21:3),
217-237. pp. 443-471.
Khanna, T., Gulati, R., and Nohria, N. 1998. “The Dynamics of Peppard, J., and Rylander, A. 2006. “From Value Chain to Value
Learning Alliances: Competition, Cooperation, and Relative Network: Insights for Mobile Operators,” European Manage-
Scope,” Strategic Management Journal (19:3), pp. 193-210. ment Journal (24:2), pp. 128-141.
Killworth, P. D., and Bernard, H. R. 1979. “Informant Accuracy in Pigneur, Y. 2000. “An Ontology for m-Business Models,”
Social Network Data III: A Comparaison of Triadic Structures Working Paper, Ecolé des HEC, University of Lausanne,
in Behavioral and Cognitive Data,” Social Networks (2), pp. Lausanne, Switzerland.
19-46. Pirolli, P., Pitkow, J., and Rao, R. 1996. “Silk from a Sow’s Ear:
Kogut, B., and Walker, G. 2001. “The Small World of Germany Extracting Usable Structure from the Web,” in CHI ’96:
and the Durability of National Networks,” American Sociological Proceedings of the SIGCHI Conference on Human Factors in
Review (66), pp. 317-335. Computing Systems, New York: ACM Press, pp. 118-125.
Knoben, J., Oerlemans, L. A. G., and Rutten, R. P. J. H. 2006. Porter, M. E. 1980. Competitive Strategy: Techniques for Ana-
“Radical Changes in Inter-Organizational Network Structures: lyzing Industries and Competition, New York: Free Press.
The Longitudinal Gap,” Technological forecasting and Social Porter, M. E. 1985. Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sus-
Change (73:4), pp. 390-404. taining Superior Performance, New York: Free Press.

MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2/June 2013 631


Pagani/Digital Business Strategy and Value Creation

Provan, K. G. 1983. “The Federation as an Interorganizational Weick, K. E. 1976. “Educational Organizations as Loosely Coup-
Linkage Network,” Academy of Management Review (8), pp. led Systems,” Administrative Science Quarterly (21), pp. 1-19.
79-89. Wheeler, B. C. 2002. “NEBIC: A Dynamic Capabilities Theory
Rülke, A. Chiasson, G., and Iyer, A. 2003. “The Ecology of for Assessing Net-Enablement,” Information Systems Research
Mobile Commerce: Charting a Course for Success Using Value (13:2), pp. 125-146.
Chain Analysis,” in Mobile Commerce: Technology, Theory and Wooldridge, J. 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and
Applications, B. E. Mennecke and T. J. Strader (eds.), Hershey,
Panel Data, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
PA: Idea Publishing Group, Inc., pp. 122-144.
Sabat, H. K. 2002. “The Evolving Mobile Wireless Value Chain
and Market Structure,” Telecommunications Policy (26), pp.
505-535. About the Author
Sambamurthy, V., Bharadwaj, A., and Grover, V. 2003. “Shaping
Agility through Digital Options: Reconceptualizing the Role of Margherita Pagani is an assistant professor of Marketing at
Information Technology in Contemporary Firms,” MIS Quarterly Bocconi University (Milan), and a senior faculty member at Lorange
(27:2), pp. 237-263.
Institute of Business (Zurich). She was visiting scientist at MIT’s
Staudenmayer, N., Tripsas, M., and Tucci, C. L. 2005. “Interfirm
Sloan School of Management (2008 and 2003). She has published
Modularity and its Implications for Product Development,” The
Journal of Product Innovation Management (22), pp. 303-321. several books (in the United States, Korea, and Italy), two
Straub, D., and Watson, R. 2001. “Transformational Issues in encyclopedias, and articles in leading international journals such as
Researching IS and Net-Enabled Organizations,” Information International Journal of Electronic Commerce, Information &
Systems Research (12:4), pp. 337-345. Management, Journal of Interactive Marketing, Journal of Business
Teece, D. J. 1986. “Profiting from Technological Innovation: Research, Psychology & Marketing, Technology Analysis and
Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing and Public Strategic Management, Technological Forecasting and Social
Policy,” Research Policy (15:6), pp. 285-305 Change, and a variety of other publications. For her research
Ulrich, K. T., and Eppinger, S. D. 1994. Product Design and activity and publications in the mobile marketing field, she won the
Development, New York: McGraw-Hill. 2009 Mobile Marketing Association Global Award “Academic of
Wasserman, S., and Galaskiewicz, J. 1994. Advances in Social
the Year.”
Network Analysis, Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.

Appendix
Data Analysis
We used panel data for our empirical analysis. Each panel corresponds to a firm in a given technology generation. The use of panel data helps
to control for potential sources of unobserved heterogeneity and enables us to test how the benefits of vertical integration change over time
during the course of a given generation. In our analysis, core and edge capabilities are the key explanatory variables, but they do not exhibit
intertemporal variation for a firm within a given generation. For this reason, we used a random-effects model (Baltagi 2005). We controlled
for unobserved differences across firms by including firm dummies in a firm-generation panel (Wooldridge 2002). We also included year
dummies to control for unobserved year-specific effects. We estimated the following equation:

yigt = β0 + Xigtb + Dil + Tt d + aig+uigt (1)

where yigt is firm i’s market share in a generation g in year t ; Xigt is the vector of independent and control variables; Di is the vector of dummies
for each firm; Tt is the vector of dummies for each year; aig is the unobserved heterogeneity for a firm in a generation that is assumed to be
uncorrelated with the explanatory variables; and uigt is the error term.

Selection of the Model Structure. In phase 2 (selection of the model structure), we introduced a graph-generating model aimed at representing
the evolution of control point constellations using a node-and-arc representation. In this approach, from graph theoretic notation, nodes
represent actors (companies) while arcs represent relationships, or ties, between actors in the network (Moody et al. 2005; Newman 2003).
This approach has been shown to be particularly effective in describing the structure and dynamics of socioeconomic networks (Brandes et
al. 2001) and we adopted it to visualize our ideas. Following Botafogo and Schneiderman (1991) and Pirolli et al. (1996), we augmented graph
theoretic analysis to include document content resulting in a rich understanding of domain structure and a taxonomy of the roles played. We
then incorporated an element of time evolution in the network structure and offered a plausible explanation in terms of growth dynamics of
the digital-enabled network.

Model Estimation and Validation. In order to estimate the model (phase 3), we discussed the emerging structure during two meetings with
practitioners and academics.

632 MIS Quarterly Vol. 37 No. 2/June 2013

View publication stats

Você também pode gostar