Você está na página 1de 24

LICY ANALYSIS TRADE POLICY ANALYSIS TRADE POLICY ANALYSIS TRADE PO

December 21, 2010 No. 44

Protection Made to Order


Domestic Industry’s Capture and
Reconfiguration of U.S. Antidumping Policy
by Daniel Ikenson

Executive Summary
The Obama administration has pro- punishes normal, healthy competition at
posed changing several Commerce De- great cost to the broader economy.
partment antidumping procedures. Those Honest debate about the law’s purpose
changes would expand the scope for find- and consequences has been stifled by its
ings of dumping and precipitate a surge in complexity and by the persistence of highly
antidumping actions. inaccurate rhetoric about the propriety of
The evolution of U.S. antidumping pol- strong antidumping rules to redress unfair
icy is marked by distinct inflection points foreign practices. Armed with the pretense
corresponding to legal and administrative of a noble purpose, representatives of labor
changes favorable to protection-seekers. In unions and import-competing industries
the decades following World War II, the often cite the number of antidumping initi-
U.S. antidumping apparatus was gradually ations as evidence of the need for an even
captured by interested parties, and the law more accessible and restrictive antidumping
transformed from one predicated on pro- law to better protect “us” from “them.” But
tecting consumers and preserving competi- the causation implicit in that logic is back-
tion into a tool that suppresses competition ward.
in the name of remedying “injury” done to This paper shows that the increase in
domestic producers. antidumping activity reflects several develop-
The arcane mix of statutory rules and ments that have nothing to do with foreign
discretionary whimsy that emerged is a far behavior, including a progressive expansion
cry from the first antidumping law—in of the definition of dumping, relaxation of
both practice and intent. No longer are evidentiary standards, and a pro-domestic
anti-competitive or predatory pricing industry bias in the law’s administration.
practices the law’s target. Instead, the tar- Ultimately, the antidumping remedy is a
get is foreign competition writ large, and, much larger problem than the dumping it is
as such, antidumping practice routinely presumed to address.

Daniel Ikenson is associate director of the Center for Trade Policy Studies at the Cato
Institute and coauthor of Antidumping Exposed: The Devilish Details of Unfair
Trade Law (2003).
Antidumping the past, but it presently punishes normal,
borrows its rhetoric Introduction healthy competition that certain domestic pro-
ducers find objectionable.
from the past, but it The Obama administration is proposing to Honest debate about the law’s purpose and
presently punishes amend certain aspects of the Commerce consequences has been stifled by its complexity
Department’s oversight of the U.S. antidump- and by the persistence of highly inaccurate
normal, healthy ing law. Revised methods for estimating major rhetoric about the propriety of strong antidump-
competition that components of the dumping calculation, high- ing rules to redress unfair foreign practices.
certain domestic er thresholds for foreign companies to exceed Armed with the pretense of a noble purpose,
in order to demonstrate that they are not representatives of labor unions and import-
producers find “dumping,” tighter rules governing methods of competing industries often cite the number of
objectionable. paying estimated antidumping duties, and antidumping initiations as evidence of the need
other changes have been put forward, ostensi- for an even more accessible and restrictive anti-
bly to give the law more teeth. dumping law to better protect “us” from “them.”
History suggests that if those proposals are Granted, U.S. antidumping initiations have in-
implemented, a surge in antidumping actions— creased considerably over the decades, but not
at great cost to the broader U.S. economy—is because of an increase in anti-competitive behav-
likely to follow. The evolution of antidumping is ior among foreign producers.
marked by distinct inflection points correspond- Rather, antidumping use has increased be-
ing to legal and administrative changes imple- cause the law has been “strengthened” by ex-
mented at the behest of certain import-compet- panding the definition of “unfair” and granting
ing industries and their political allies. As the domestic industry too much access to the levers
utility of antidumping became evident to those of antidumping administration. Meanwhile,
industries, trade negotiators, and politicians in collateral damage to innocent victims and the
the decades following World War II, the law— broader economy continues to mount.
and its regulatory apparatus—was gradually This paper describes the evolution of U.S.
transformed from one predicated on protecting antidumping policy from an obscure offshoot of
consumers from collusive or predatory foreign competition law into the predominant instru-
trade practices into a tool to suppress competi- ment of contingent protection that it is today
tion in the name of remedying “injury” experi- and provides an account of some of the crucial
enced by domestic producers. The arcane mix of statutory and administrative changes that have
statutory rules and discretionary whimsy that occurred over the decades. Its purpose is to
emerged as contemporary antidumping policy is demonstrate that the increase in antidumping
a far cry from the first antidumping law—in activity reflects several developments that have
practice and intent. Today, antidumping is little nothing to do with foreign behavior whatsoever,
more than an elaborate excuse for run-of-the- including a progressive expansion of the defini-
mill protectionism. tion of dumping, relaxation of evidentiary stan-
No longer are anti-competitive or predato- dards, and a pro-domestic-industry bias in the
ry pricing practices the target of the antidump- law’s administration at the U.S. Department of
ing law. Rather, its target is price discrimina- Commerce. Ultimately, the antidumping reme-
tion—specifically, the act of a foreign firm dy is a much larger problem than the dumping
charging lower prices in the United States than it is presumed to address.
it charges in its home market for the same
product. But there is nothing inherently wrong
or predatory or unfair about such a pricing What Is Dumping?
strategy. Even if there were, evidence of anti-
competitive behavior is never required to initi- In economics, dumping is defined as the act
ate an antidumping case or to impose restric- of a firm charging lower prices in an export
tions. Antidumping borrows its rhetoric from market than in the domestic market for the

2
same product. Dumping is a fancy term for Without sufficient market power to set and
cross-border price discrimination, which itself maintain higher prices at home, the firm would
carries a malevolent connotation. have insufficient profits from which to cross-
But there is nothing sinister or even unusual subsidize lower-priced sales abroad. Without
about a firm engaging in price discrimination. high enough tariffs, transportation costs, or
Indeed, U.S. firms charge different prices in dif- other market barriers to sufficiently segregate
ferent regional markets for the same goods for a the home market, reimportation of the lower-
variety of legitimate reasons. For example, an priced imports into the home market would
incumbent firm that has operated in New arbitrage away any dumping-enabling profits.
England for many years and whose brand is well And if the demand of customers in the export
known and respected by consumers might be market is less price elastic than the demand of
able to charge higher prices in that market than customers in the home market, the price of the
it can charge in California, where it is an un- good in the export market could equilibrate at
known entity attempting to enter the market. In a level higher than the price at home. In other
California, the firm might have to induce con- words, the home-market profits needed to en-
sumers to try its product by offering lower prices. able a dumping strategy might in fact require
The same strategy can be employed without home-market prices that are lower than
sinister motive if those markets happen to be in export-market prices, rendering such a strategy One would be
different countries. A foreign firm that sells its self-defeating or impossible. hard-pressed to
widgets in the United States at lower prices Although economic theory provides for these find any real-world
than it charges at home may be trying to reap conditions, one would be hard-pressed to find
the benefits of the brand it has cultivated and any real-world examples of dumping causing examples of
nurtured at home by charging higher prices, competitive markets to become monopolistic. dumping causing
while simultaneously pursuing a common Nevertheless, the U.S. antidumping law is osten-
market-entry strategy of charging lower prices sibly concerned with the kind of international
competitive
where its brand is relatively unknown. In that price discrimination that stems from those con- markets to become
regard, price discrimination is not a problem in ditions. To be more precise, the antidumping law, monopolistic.
need of a remedy. There are perfectly rational, according to its defenders, exists to remedy or
legitimate, profit-maximizing justifications for countervail the effects of those anti-competitive
engaging in a strategy of price discrimination. conditions, which are presumed to exist because
Accordingly, dumping is not systemically of various foreign government policies. A 2002
predatory, anti-competitive, or unfair. Bush administration submission to the World
However, in some cases when certain condi- Trade Organization Negotiating Group on
tions are present, dumping can be a cause for Rules put it this way:
concern. A sustained strategy of cross-border
price discrimination could prove to be anti-com- A government’s industrial policies or
petitive and welfare-reducing if: (1) the foreign key aspects of the economic system
firm in question has market power (i.e., can set supported by government inaction can
prices in one or both markets); (2) the markets enable injurious dumping to take
are sufficiently segregated to foreclose the possi- place. . . . For instance, these policies
bility of price arbitrage; and (3) demand for the may allow producers to earn high
product in the export market is more price elas- profits in a home “sanctuary market,”
tic than demand in the home market. The pres- which may in turn allow them to sell
ence of those conditions could enable the kind abroad at an artificially low price. Such
of predatory, anti-competitive practices that are practices can result in injury in the
commonly—although mistakenly—presumed importing country since domestic
to be the target of the U.S. antidumping law. firms may not be able to match the
Without those conditions present, however, artificially low prices from producers
a dumping strategy would be unsustainable. in the sanctuary market.1

3
Thus, antidumping is portrayed as a legiti- the causes of price discrimination and, as a
mate government response to anti-competitive result, perfectly unobjectionable business prac-
foreign government policies. However, the first tices are routinely punished at great expense to
major shortcoming of that justification is that, innocent victims.
under the law, no evidence is required to demon- A law that once required close examination of
strate that (nor does the administering authority underlying market conditions and the motives of
investigate whether) any of those anti-competi- foreign sellers now simply grants the worst
tive conditions exist—let alone that they are the assumptions without requiring any meaningful
product of some foreign government policies. evidence of anti-competitive behavior or the
The existence of price discrimination (i.e., some underlying market distortions that are presumed
sales that are priced lower in the United States to give it rise.4
than in the home market) is simply assumed to The explosion of antidumping in recent
be proof positive of the existence of those anti- decades is in no small part attributable to
competitive conditions, and those conditions are changes in U.S. law and administration that have
assumed to be the product of foreign govern- expanded the definition of dumping to include
ment policies, even though there are plenty of routine and unobjectionable pricing practices
legitimate reasons for a firm to price discrimi- and made antidumping protection increasingly
nate. easy to obtain. Over the course of about eight
Under U.S. law, dumping is defined as the decades, antidumping evolved from an instru-
sale of a commodity in the U.S. market at a ment of law aimed at preserving competition to
price that is less than “normal value.”2 Normal a bureaucratic apparatus devoted to restricting it.
value is derived either from the selling price of How did such an obscure policy instrument
the same or a similar product in a comparison evolve into what some economists consider to be
market (normally the home market of the for- the most prevalent impediment to international
eign producer) or from the cost of producing trade today?5 What explains the continuous
the product in question, plus allowances for broadening of the scope of U.S. antidumping
selling expenses, administrative expenses, and law? Why does a practice that is so antithetical
profit.3 The amount of dumping is calculated to free trade have sanction within the rules of
by subtracting the export price from the nor- the World Trade Organization? What explains
mal value, and the dumping margin, expressed the near total disregard for the interests of con-
as a percentage, is that difference divided by the sumers and consuming industries in the con-
export price. Thus, if a foreign producer sells a temporary administration of the antidumping
product for $11 in his home market and for law? The complex history of U.S. trade politics
$10 in the U.S. market, the amount of dump- sheds some light on these questions.
Over the ing is $1 and the dumping margin is 10 per-
cent.
course of about For antidumping duties to be imposed, the Antidumping’s
eight decades, administering authorities must also determine Original Charter
antidumping that the domestic industry is materially injured
or threatened with material injury, or that the Prior to the signing of the General Agree-
evolved from an development of an industry is materially retard- ment on Tariffs and Trade in 1947, antidump-
instrument of law ed by reason of the dumped imports in ques- ing laws of the United States were premised
tion. upon the logic of antitrust.6 Like antitrust, the
aimed at preserving Thus, any price discrimination that causes purpose of the antidumping law was to prevent
competition to a or threatens injury to a domestic industry is the unfair competition, which could be the result of
bureaucratic trigger for imposing duties—and not just price monopolies engaging in predatory pricing. For
discrimination that arises from anti-competi- better or worse, governments seeking to curtail
apparatus devoted tive conditions abroad. Under the law, there is the exercise of market power by domestic firms
to restricting it. simply no requirement or effort to distinguish could turn to their antitrust laws. But it was far

4
more complicated for governments to apply and need of revising the general tariff structure. That The discovery of
enforce their antitrust laws against foreign firms. the first firm investigated for antidumping was antidumping as a
And since it was apparent that foreign govern- U.S. Steel, a perennial target of U.S. antitrust
ments might be less thorough in applying their authorities, helps explain the lack of indignation vehicle through
antitrust rules to their own firms’ behavior in the on the part of Canada’s trading partners.12 And which protection
U.S. market, the U.S. government turned to the discovery of antidumping as a vehicle
antidumping.7 through which protection could be doled out
could be doled out
Prior to passage of the first U.S. antidumping conditionally and at the discretion of politicians conditionally and at
law in 1916, unfairly traded imports were regu- proved internationally appealing. Rather than the discretion of
lated under the Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890, condemn the Canadian policy, Australia, New
which “declared illegal any effort to combine or Zealand, the United Kingdom, and France politicians proved
conspire to monopolize a particular market,” adopted antidumping policies of their own.13 internationally
and the Wilson Tariff Act of 1894, which ex- The United States joined the antidumping
panded the prohibitions of the Sherman Act to club in 1916, when the Wilson administration
appealing.
firms outside the United States. The Wilson was under pressure from industry for an increase
Act made it “unlawful for foreign producers to in U.S. tariffs on the grounds that Germany was
combine or conspire to monopolize the U.S. engaged in economic warfare in the form of
market.”8 By federal statute, violations of these predatory dumping. Sympathetic to those
laws mandated criminal prosecution. Anti- claims but averse to antagonizing free traders in
competitive practices concerning imports cov- the Democratic Party, Wilson asked Congress
ered under the Sherman and Wilson Acts were to put antidumping provisions into the Revenue
punishable by substantial fines or imprison- Act of 1916. Congress obliged, inserting lan-
ment.9 guage that criminalized the importation of mer-
In 1904, the Canadian government became chandise at prices lower than “actual market
the first to have an antidumping law, when the value” when such practices are undertaken with
parliament enacted legislation authorizing the “intent to injure, destroy, or prevent the estab-
imposition of “a special duty of customs” equal lishment of an industry in the United States or
to the difference between the “fair market value” to restrain competition.”
and the “selling price,” whenever “it appears to Like the Sherman and Wilson Acts before
the satisfaction of the minister of customs . . . it, the Antidumping Act of 1916 was a criminal
that the export price . . . is less than the fair mar- statute. But unlike the Canadian law of 1904,
ket value thereof.”10 the first U.S. antidumping law did not grant
The primary purpose of the Canadian law customs the authority to levy special duties on
was to enable the government to respond to dumped imports. Rather, the U.S. law sought to
competing demands from two vital constituen- remedy predatory dumping with severe penal-
cies—agriculture and steel. Agricultural inter- ties, including punitive fines (triple damages)
ests wanted a significant cut in tariffs across the and imprisonment.14 But demonstrating preda-
board, while the Canadian steel industry want- tory intent under the 1916 Act proved difficult,
ed protection from its principal competitor, and few cases were brought.15
U.S. Steel.11 The government worried that rais- In 1919, the U.S. Tariff Commission pub-
ing tariffs on steel would be too risky, as it lished the results of a study on foreign competi-
would encourage every other interest to lobby tion, which was informed largely by surveys of
for higher protection of their industries. domestic manufacturing firms. The study rec-
By establishing a “special duty” to be admin- ommended that the Antidumping Act of 1916
istered separate from the general tariff and at the
discretion of customs authorities instead of the be revised and strengthened, and that
courts, the Canadian government produced an some official body, moving along lines
appealing solution to its dilemma—a mecha- sanctioned by Congress in the Federal
nism to grant contingent protection without Trade Commission Act, may realisti-

5
cally be specifically instructed to deal [was] replaced by a ‘diversion of business’ stan-
with dumping as a manifestation of dard, the sort of diversion that is a normal part
unfair foreign competitive methods . . . of the competitive process.”19
that in the case of imports, bonds pro- Despite the relative ease of obtaining contin-
viding for the collection of dumping gent protection under the 1921 Antidumping
duties subsequently assessed may be Law, U.S. industry was largely shielded from
useful, and that the President or the foreign competition thanks to the high levels of
Secretary of the Treasury may be em- tariff protection afforded by the Fordney-
powered to impose additional duties, McCumber Act of 1922 and the Smoot-
or even to refuse entry when industri- Hawley Tariff Act of 1930. Antidumping would
ally destructive dumping is proven or begin to emerge as an attractive alternative after
impending.16 World War II, as the multilateral endeavor to
liberalize world trade gained momentum.
Congress adopted the recommendations of
the Tariff Commission study in the Anti-
dumping Act of 1921, which authorized the Antidumping in the GATT
secretary of the Treasury to levy “a special
Responsibility for dumping duty” equivalent to the difference The U.S. government requested that lan-
enforcing the between the “exporter’s sales price” and the guage permitting the use of antidumping be
antidumping law “foreign market value (or, in the absence of included in the GATT. In fact, as noted by eco-
such value . . . the cost of production)” when- nomic historian Douglas Irwin, the Anti-
shifted from the ever “an industry is likely to be injured, or is dumping Act of 1921 provided the “textual
judiciary to the prevented from being established, by reason of basis” for the initial GATT rules on antidump-
the importation into the United States of for- ing.20 Indeed, the WTO Antidumping Agree-
executive branch. eign merchandise of such class or kind is being ment in effect today authorizes member states
sold or is likely to be sold in the United States to impose antidumping duties when administer-
or elsewhere at less than its fair value.”17 ing authorities find that imports determined to
With passage of the new act, responsibility be sold at less than normal value are causing or
for the enforcement of the antidumping law threatening injury to a domestic industry or
was shifted from the judiciary to the executive materially retarding the establishment of an
branch, while the object of regulation was industry.21
transformed from predatory pricing to injuri- The view widely held—or at least the excuse
ous price discrimination. Economist J. Michael given—by U.S. negotiators during the early
Finger characterized the changes to U.S. law decades of GATT was that the existence of
between 1890 and 1921: “Trust-busting re- antidumping made greater trade liberalization
mained the rallying cry, but the object of the possible because it assured Congress that certain
regulation shifted from trusts to imports, the fallback contingencies were available if general
instrument from law to bureaucracy.”18 tariff cutting exposed domestic interests to too
The impact of the Tariff Commission study much competition. Without antidumping, the
was profound. By elevating injury to U.S. pro- argument went, Congress might not have sup-
ducers as the primary rationale for having an ported general tariff liberalization.22 That a dis-
antidumping law—and in the process marginal- tinctly protectionist policy should be considered
izing concern about the impact of predatory an element of trade liberalization was a bit coun-
pricing or the imposition of duties on U.S. con- terintuitive. However, that assertion was made
sumers—the report was the catalyst that sparked at least partially credible by the fact that the U.S.
a dramatic transformation of the antidumping government exercised considerable restraint in
regime. The welfare of consumers was no longer its administration of U.S. antidumping policy.
a concern of the antidumping law. As Finger Between 1921 and the end of 1967, over 89 per-
puts it: “the ‘injury to competition’ standard cent (631 out of a total of 706) of all U.S.

6
antidumping investigations ended with negative averaging net prices of sales of the same or simi-
determinations of injurious dumping.23 lar merchandise and comparing those averages
The U.S. argument that instruments of con- between markets. Under either approach,
tingent protection could facilitate trade liberal- though, all home-market sales “made in the ordi-
ization was tested during the Kennedy Round nary course of trade” factored into the determi-
of GATT negotiations (1964−1967), when nation of the average home-market price. The
American negotiators found themselves in the idea was to make an apples-to-apples compari-
awkward position of advocating the expansion son. But at the behest of various domestic pro-
of GATT rules to other nontariff trade barriers, ducer interests, who had been trying for some
while simultaneously resisting the attempts of time to persuade the Treasury Department of the
their counterparts to bring antidumping under propriety of more aggressive dumping margin
stricter multilateral discipline. Those advocat- calculation techniques, Congress amended the
ing stronger disciplines on antidumping pre- law to include a provision for a “cost test” in the
vailed in the Kennedy Round by agreeing to Trade Reform Act of 1974.26
guidelines for injury determinations that were The purpose of the cost test was to eliminate
more rigid (gave less latitude to the administer- from determination of the average home-
ing authorities) than those applied by the U.S. market price those home-market sales made at
Tariff Commission, which had taken over prices below the full cost of production. Only
responsibility for injury determinations from those sales made at prices above the cost of pro-
the Treasury Department in 1954, under U.S. duction would now factor into the average
law.24 home-market price, and if less than 10 percent
Congress did not acquiesce to this en- of the sales of a given product “model” were
croachment on its jurisdiction, and made made at those prices, then all sales of that model
explicit in the legislation authorizing the would be disregarded and the home-market
Kennedy Round agreements that the United comparison would be based on a “constructed
States would be bound only by those provisions value” that included approximations for the cost
of the antidumping code consistent with exist- of production, selling, general and administra-
ing U.S. law.25 It would not be the last time that tive expenses, and an amount for profit. By elim-
Congress asserted its authority to shield the inating lower priced home-market sales, the
U.S. antidumping law from reform. effect of the cost test was to produce higher
The launch of the Tokyo Round of GATT home-market average prices or to necessitate
negotiations (1973–1979) provided U.S. law- use of constructed values, both of which inflated
makers occasion to once again revisit—and dumping margins.
expand—the definition of dumping under U.S. The fig leaf of a legal justification offered The launch of
law. Until 1974, dumping was defined as the for the change was that sales made at prices the Tokyo Round
practice of a firm selling in an export market at below the full cost of production could not be
prices lower than those it charged in its home considered sales “made in the ordinary course of GATT
market. Price discrimination—regardless of its of trade.” If the ordinary course of trade is for a negotiations
cause or intent—was the target of the U.S. firm to be profitable, then sales below the full
antidumping law. There was no requirement, cost of production must be anathema to that
provided U.S.
nor were efforts undertaken, to ascertain objective, as they detract from profit. Why lawmakers occasion
whether the price discrimination in question would a firm sell below cost if its objective is to to once again
had an innocent explanation. Accordingly, in make profits?
1974 the deck was already stacked in favor of But basic microeconomic theory holds—and revisit—and
domestic protection-seekers. economists, cost accountants, and analysts have expand—the
Measuring price discrimination usually en- noted—that selling at prices below the full cost
tailed comparing the net prices of the same or of production is often the profit-maximizing
definition of
similar merchandise sold by a given firm in both course of action for firms, and that selling below dumping under
markets and calculating an average difference, or the full cost of production is clearly a practice U.S. law.

7
Ultimately, that is “in the ordinary course of trade.” Many Prior to the 1974 act’s mandate of a cost
domestic industry firms—particularly those operating in high test, the Treasury Department addressed the
fixed-cost industries—drop their prices below issue of sales below cost in two different cases.
prevailed upon the full costs of production when facing reduced In both, Treasury acknowledged the funda-
Congress to adopt demand for seasonal or cyclical reasons. As long mental economic principle that selling below
as the price charged is high enough to cover the the full cost of production was sometimes the
a below-cost firm’s variable costs, any price above variable cost optimal decision. Treasury also noted that sales
provision in the contributes toward coverage of the firm’s fixed were made at prices below the full cost of pro-
Trade Reform Act costs. If the alternative is to stick to a higher duction in both the U.S. and home markets,
price and sell nothing, then there are no variable which made for a fair comparison.27
of 1974. costs to cover, but there is no contribution to Ultimately, domestic industry prevailed
fixed costs either. Under those circumstances, upon Congress to adopt a below-cost provision
the accounting losses would be higher for the in the 1974 Act, which mandated that sales
firm. below the full cost of production be disregarded
Consider the production of hot-rolled car- in the calculation of average home-market prices
bon steel, which involves the use of iron ore, (but, unsurprisingly, made no such requirement
coke, and other minerals; electricity; water; and on the U.S. side of the calculation). In cases
other variable inputs—inputs that are consumed where all home-market sales were at prices
in some proportion to output and consumption below the cost of production (and, thus, evi-
of which increases with output. But steel pro- dence of a protected, sanctuary home market in
duction also involves high fixed costs—costs which high profits could be used to cross-
that are incurred regardless of the amount of subsidize cheap export sales entirely absent), the
output—on account of the need for expensive foreign firm would be further penalized by bas-
production facilities and the high cost of pur- ing the dumping calculation on a comparison of
chasing and operating the necessary capital its U.S. prices to “constructed value,” which was
equipment. Regardless of whether the factory to be the sum of the full cost of production plus
produces one million tons or nothing at all, the the larger of actual or estimated amounts for
total fixed costs are the same. All of the fixed selling, general, and administrative expenses,
costs have to be incurred in order to produce the plus a minimum of 8 percent for profit.
first ton of steel, which is also the total amount The effect of the cost test on the dumping
of the fixed cost necessary to produce one mil- calculation can be profound. To demonstrate,
lion tons of steel, or more. in Table 1 there are five hypothetical sales of a
If the per-ton total fixed cost is $100 and particular type of widget in the U.S. market at
the per-ton total variable cost is $100, then ide- prices ranging from $1.00 to $5.00. Likewise,
ally, the firm would be able to sell at a price there are five sales of identical products in the
above $200 and make a profit. But if econom- home market also ranging from $1.00 to $5.00.
ic conditions are such that the market will bear Assuming the volumes sold in each transaction
a price of only $150 per ton, it is still profit- are the same (to simplify the process of weight
maximizing for this firm to sell at that price, averaging the prices), the weighted-averaged
even though it is below the full cost of produc- price in both markets is $3.00 and the dump-
tion and even though the firm will incur a loss. ing margin should be zero because there is no
If the firm does not sell the steel, it incurs a loss price discrimination at all.
of $100 (the fixed cost). If it sells at $150, the But the cost test introduces another step to
firm incurs a loss of only $50. In this case, the calculation methodology, which produces a
profit maximization means loss minimization. different end result. The cost test restricts the
Selling below the full cost of production, as eligibility of home-market sales that can factor
long as the price is above the average variable into the weighted-average price. Specifically,
cost of production, is the rational course of only sales at prices above the full cost of pro-
action. duction factor into the average. Accordingly,

8
Table 1
Cost Test (U.S. Dollar)

Net Home-market Net Home-market


Net U.S. Price Price Unit Cost Cost Test Price (used)

1.00 1.00 2.50 Fail --


2.00 2.00 2.50 Fail --
3.00 3.00 2.50 Pass 3.00
4.00 4.00 2.50 Pass 4.00
5.00 5.00 2.50 Pass 5.00
Average 3.00 3.00 2.50 4.00

Table 2
Cost Test (U.S. Dollar)
Net Home- Net
Net U.S. market Unit Cost Home-market Seller’s Constructed
Price Price Cost Test Price (used) Cost Expense Profit Value

1.00 1.00 5.50 Fail — 5.50 0.55 0.44 6.49


2.00 2.00 5.50 Fail — 5.50 0.55 0.44 6.49
3.00 3.00 5.50 Fail — 5.50 0.55 0.44 6.49
4.00 4.00 5.50 Fail — 5.50 0.55 0.44 6.49
5.00 5.00 5.50 Fail — 5.50 0.55 0.44 6.49
Average 3.00 3.00 5.50 — 5.50 0.55 0.44 6.49

the two home-market sales priced below the 1974 Act) plus an allowance for profit (a min-
unit cost of production, which is $2.50 in Table imum of 8 percent under the statute after the
1, are eliminated, causing the average home- 1974 Act).
market price to rise to $4.00. This change gen- At a minimum, the constructed value in this
erates a dumping margin of $1, or 33 percent, example would be $6.49 ($5.50 for cost; $0.55
despite the fact that there are no price differ- for expenses; $0.44 for profit) and the dumping
ences between the markets. margin would be $3.49 ($6.49 minus $3.00), or
By mandating a
If the cost of production were $5.50 instead 116 percent. That is a pretty substantial margin cost test under
of $2.50, then all sales in both markets would of dumping—particularly for a firm that is U.S. law, Congress
be at prices below the full cost of production. charging identical prices in both markets and is
The average U.S. price would still be $3.00, but by definition not price discriminating. ensured that
since all home-market sales would be ineligible A 2002 Cato study exposing the method- dumping
for calculation of the average home-market ological distortions of the U.S. antidumping calculations would
price, a “constructed value” would be calculated regime included a table of counterfactuals—
to serve as a surrogate for home-market price. results that would have been obtained in 18 no longer be
The constructed value would be equal to the real-life antidumping cases, had particular the product of
cost of production plus allowances for selling, methodologies been changed or forgone alto-
general, and administrative expenses (a mini- gether. In 17 of 18 cases, the cost test was em-
pure price
mum of 10 percent under the statute after the ployed. Had the cost test not been employed in comparisons.

9
Import those 17 cases, the average calculated dumping innocuous change was enormously consequen-
Administration margin would have been 59.7 percent lower.28 tial.
In 5 of the 18 cases, calculation and use of con- While both agencies have been delegated
fancies itself structed value was necessary. Had the build-up roles in the administration of U.S. economic pol-
responsible of constructed value not included an element icy, the prevailing institutional objectives diverge
for profit, the margins would have been 11 per- in many respects. Whereas Treasury’s mission is
for writing, cent lower.29 one of commitment to the broader macroeco-
adjudicating, By mandating a cost test under U.S. law, nomic well-being of the United States, the
and enforcing Congress ensured that dumping calculations benchmarks of success at Commerce have been
would no longer be the product of pure price aligned historically with firm-specific outcomes.
antidumping rules. comparisons—a development that further Whereas Treasury officials would be more
divorced the legal definition of dumping from inclined to regard import duties resulting in
its economic meaning. And, as evidenced deadweight economic loss as anathema to their
above, it served to inflate dumping margins mission, Commerce officials are expected to pro-
and antidumping duty rates, and subsequently mote the narrow interests of domestic producers.
heightened the appeal of the antidumping Indeed, the mission of Import Administration,
remedy to importing-competing industries. the agency within the Department of Com-
merce tasked with antidumping oversight, is to
“safeguard American industries and jobs against
Regulatory Capture unfair trade practices.”30 Import Administration
works to “enforce effectively the U.S. unfair trade
In addition to the technical changes to laws (i.e., the antidumping and countervailing
antidumping calculation methodology, the duty laws) and to develop and implement other
Trade Reform Act of 1974 also provided busi- policies and programs aimed at countering for-
ness a formal channel of access to antidumping eign unfair trade practices.”31 In that description,
and other trade policymaking. The act man- one can detect that Import Administration fan-
dated the establishment of a private sector cies itself responsible for writing, adjudicating,
advisory committee system to ensure the inclu- and enforcing the antidumping rules, all of
sion and incorporation of business viewpoints which should comport with a design to protect
in the negotiation, monitoring, and implemen- U.S. industry.
tation of GATT agreements and related poli- In the words of Ronald Cass, former vice
cies. The private sector consultation system was chairman of the U.S. International Trade Com-
divided into three vertically integrated compo- mission, Commerce Department officials “see
nents: the President’s Advisory Committee for themselves as advocates for domestic business.”32
Trade Policy and Negotiations; four policy ad- And the advisory committee system established
visory committees; and 22 industry-trade advi- after the 1974 Act provided private-sector stake-
sory committees, jointly administered by the holders with direct channels of access to staff-
Department of Commerce and the Office of level decisionmakers throughout the Commerce
the United States Trade Representative. Department’s international trade bureaucracy.
As the 1974 Act included language authoriz- A 1994 Congressional Budget Office study
ing U.S. participation in the Tokyo Round of of GATT and U.S. trade policy included com-
GATT negotiations, the Trade Agreements Act mentary on the shift of antidumping jurisdic-
of 1979 implemented U.S. obligations commit- tion from Treasury to Commerce:
ted during the Round. And it made several
important changes to U.S. antidumping admin- The move reflected a Congressional
istration, including transfer of jurisdiction for desire for more zealous enforcement of
determining the existence and magnitude of the AD/CVD [antidumping/counter-
dumping from the Department of Treasury to vailing duties] laws and for less concern
the Department of Commerce. This seemingly about their being used in a protection-

10
ist manner. Its significance goes beyond tinely exploits gray areas in the law to favor the
the difference in the institutional sym- domestic interests that seek protection—and,
pathies. One of [Commerce]’s func- according to the verdicts of U.S. courts, some-
tions is to serve as an advocate for U.S. times violates the law in the process. In the
firms. Thus, the move placed responsi- 18-month period ending in June 2005, IA pub-
bility for deciding AD/CVD cases in lished 19 antidumping redeterminations pur-
the hands of an advocate of U.S. parties suant to court orders to revise its assumptions or
to cases.33 calculations to become compliant with the law.
In 14 of those redeterminations, the revised
The methodologies and procedures adopt- antidumping rates were lower than those origi-
ed by the Commerce Department in adminis- nally calculated.”37
tering antidumping have led many observers to According to interviews with former con-
question the agency’s impartiality. Some of the gressional and Commerce Department staff
Commerce Department’s curious method- conducted by the Office of the Inspector
ological techniques and their margin-inflating General:
effects have been documented in previous Cato
publications. This bias is illustrated by the actions of
In addition to the cost test and the use of career Commerce Department officials The Commerce
constructed value (discussed earlier), practices through whom must pass all Depart- Department is
such as the arm’s-length test, zeroing, the asym- ment of Commerce [antidumping] granted enormous
metric treatment of indirect selling expenses as a determinations in steel cases. The
deduction from price, and the deduction of prof- members and staff of the congressional discretion in its
it from U.S. prices in so-called constructed Steel Caucus meet with them regularly administration of
export-price transactions are some of the most to discuss ongoing antidumping and
obvious methodological distortions that pro- countervailing duty proceedings pend-
the law, and often
duce egregiously skewed results.34 ing before the Department of Com- its actions are
The table of counterfactuals from the 2002 merce. At some of these meetings, deemed by the
Cato study cited above demonstrates that those these officials have shared advance draft
various methodological distortions significantly investigation results with the congres- courts to run afoul
impact the bottom-line result. For example, had sional Steel Caucus well before they of the law.
zeroing been precluded from the Commerce were announced in final form, allowing
Department’s calculation methodology in the the Steel Caucus to “comment” on
18 actual cases reviewed, the dumping margins them. Time and again high level offi-
would have been 43.6 percent lower.35 Had the cials within the agency have exerted
asymmetric treatment of indirect selling expens- pressure on lower level Department of
es been disallowed, margins would have been Commerce staff conducting investiga-
9.1 percent lower.36 tions of foreign steel producers to rerun
Of course, the standard methodological dis- calculations and alter methodologies,
tortions employed as a matter of course in the resulting in increased AD/CVD tar-
calculation of antidumping margins at the iffs.38
Commerce Department do not cover all of the
channels through which agency bias affects Commerce investigators endeavor to sub-
antidumping policy. The Commerce Depart- stantiate allegations of dumping and measure its
ment is granted enormous discretion in its extent through lengthy, English-language ques-
administration of the law, and often its actions tionnaires consisting of five sections and seven
are deemed by the courts to run afoul of the law. appendices, which are mailed to selected foreign
As presented in a 2005 Cato study about the companies and their embassies in Washington.
exercise of discretion at the Commerce These voluminous questionnaires seek full
Department, “IA [Import Administration] rou- descriptions of virtually every aspect of the com-

11
Figure 1
Disposition of 1,091 Antidumping Initiations, 1980−2009

panies’ immediate and related business activities, Judge R. Kenton Musgrave labeled the practice
supplemented with databases containing records a “predatory ‘gotcha’ policy.”40
of the costs of producing and selling all subject The data do little to dispel perceptions of
merchandise in the United States, the home bias. Between 1980 (when Commerce took
market, and various third-country markets. The over the administration of antidumping from
process almost always requires that the foreign Treasury) and the end of 2009, a total of 1,091
respondents enlist the services of law and eco- antidumping cases were initiated in the United
nomics firms with expertise in the law’s admin- States.41 Antidumping orders were imposed in
istration. Agency guidelines stipulate that for- 590 of those cases.42 Figure 1 (above) accounts
eign firms under investigation must respond for the dispositions of those 1,091 cases.
within 37 days (and that Section A of the ques- What stands out is that in only 46 of those
tionnaire is due within 21 days).39 If responses to 1,091 cases did the Commerce Department
Petitioners have the questionnaire are late, incomplete, or other- render a negative finding of dumping at the pre-
had a 96 percent wise deemed unsatisfactory, Commerce investi- liminary or final stage of the investigation. In
gators are authorized by Congress to utilize the other words, petitioners have had a 96 percent
success rate at the “best information available” in determining success rate at the Commerce Department since
Commerce whether dumping has taken place. Since the that agency took over antidumping administra-
best information available to the Commerce tion from Treasury. What prevented more of
Department since Department is often culled from the allegations those initiations from resulting in antidumping
that agency took put forth by domestic competitors in their peti- orders was the International Trade Commis-
over antidumping tions for antidumping measures, this procedure sion, which issued negative injury determina-
is often punitive and unfair. In an opinion tions in 359 cases.
administration addressed to the Court of International Trade By contrast, during its oversight of the
from Treasury. (the appellate court for U.S. antidumping cases), dumping determination, the Treasury Depart-

12
ment was far less likely to render affirmative period ending in June 2005, IA issued The Commerce
findings. Between 1934 and 1954, a total of 146 38 final determinations in original Department’s
U.S. antidumping cases were initiated and antidumping investigations, finding
Treasury rendered negative dumping findings in dumping in 36 of those 38 determina- standing as an
at least 90 of those 146.43 tions. In 11 of those final determina- impartial arbiter
The Commerce Department’s standing as tions, there were 5 or fewer issues raised
an impartial arbiter is further undermined by a by the parties; in 13 of those determi-
is further
well-documented tendency to calculate exces- nations, there were 10 to 20 issues undermined by a
sive dumping margins. Foreign producers are raised; and in 14 of those cases there well-documented
routinely found to be selling at prices so far were 21 or more issues that IA was
below fair value as to raise serious doubt about required to adjudicate. A total of 650 tendency to
the accuracy and fairness of the Department’s issues—an average of more than 17 per calculate excessive
methodology. As noted by Bruce Blonigen and case—were presented and required
Thomas Prusa, the Commerce Department adjudication by IA in those 38 final
dumping margins.
determinations. Thus, dumping calcu-
not only finds dumping, they almost lation involves more than simply plug-
always find unbelievably large dumping ging objective numbers into a comput-
margins. Any argument that [anti- er program. In many cases, IA’s judg-
dumping] law is designed to ensure “fair ment calls determine the numbers
trade” looks ridiculous when confronted themselves.45
with [the Commerce Department’s]
margins. According to the statute, the
dumping duties are designed to make Relaxing “Material Injury”
the dumped imports “fairly traded” Standards
imports. Yet, the average dumping mar-
gin over the past decade is about 60 per- With an affirmative finding of sales at less
cent.44 than fair value by the Commerce Department
all but assured after 1980, the last best hope for
Even under the most extreme market condi- foreign firms (and U.S. importers) facing the
tions (i.e., perfect monopoly in the exporting specter of antidumping restrictions was to pre-
country, perfect competition in the U.S. domes- vail on the “injury side” of the investigation. If
tic market), price undercutting of 60 percent there was no reasonable indication that the
would be overkill for all but the most aggressive domestic industry was “materially injured or
of predators. But that is often the outcome of a threatened with material injury,” or that “the
process in which dozens of decisions are made establishment of an industry was materially
by bureaucrats exercising judgment and discre- retarded” by reason of less than fair value
tion that may be influenced by the underlying imports, then an antidumping order could not
agency mission. be imposed, regardless of what the Commerce
As noted in a 2005 Cato study: Department decided with respect to its dump-
ing determination.
When IA [Import Administration] During its 25-year oversight of the injury
publishes its final determinations, it determination function (from 1954 through
often includes a list of the issues raised 1979), the Tariff Commission rarely found
by the parties concerning methodolo- material injury to have been caused by dumping.
gies employed, calculations made, and Out of 641 antidumping case initiations during
decisions rendered, along with a sum- this period, the Tariff Commission rendered
mary of each party’s arguments and an affirmative injury findings in 97 cases—15 per-
explanation for its ultimate judgment cent of the time.46 Of those 97 affirmative find-
on each decision. In the 18-month ings, though, 73 occurred after 1970, a year in

13
which the Tariff Commission rendered a prece- the countries that fell under the 3 percent
dent decision to consider imports from more threshold “cumulatively” accounted for more
than one country—instead of imports from a than 7 percent of total imports of subject mer-
single country, as had been previous practice— chandise.
when determining whether less than fair value As was to be expected, the number of
imports caused or threatened material injury. antidumping initiations increased dramatically,
That decision seems to have sparked an as the number of targeted products held steady,
increase in the number of subsequent anti- suggesting that petitioners were aware of the
dumping filings, as well as the number of affir- benefits of the cumulation requirements. The
mative rulings, because domestic industry peti- “clarifications” of the 1984 Act moved anti-
tioners learned quickly that if exporters of the dumping administration even further away from
same or similar products from multiple coun- its theoretical underpinnings and signaled to
tries were simultaneously the subject of anti- U.S. industry and its trade lawyers that the rules
dumping investigations, the chances of obtain- of the game had once again changed in their
ing an affirmative injury finding were improved. favor.
Through the analytical practice now known as Antidumping was born nearly a century ear-
“cumulation,” if multiple countries are subject to lier as a mechanism to preserve and defend
U.S. antidumping an antidumping investigation of the same sub- competitive markets and ultimately to protect
policy evolved in ject merchandise, and if exports from any one of consumers. The 1984 Act completely trans-
such a way as to those countries, or all in combination, are found formed antidumping into a tool to suppress
to be a cause of material injury, then all must be competition in the name of protecting domestic
become more considered injurious and subject to an anti- producers from injury regardless of whether for-
accessible and more dumping order. eign producers benefited from any unfair advan-
Though the practice of cumulation had been tages in their home markets.
rewarding to U.S. discretionary in the years after the 1970 Tariff
import-competing Commission decision, the Trade and Tariff Act
industries. of 1984 codified the practice as a requirement of Identifying the Determinants
the ITC’s injury analysis. It became a matter of of Antidumping Use
law that imports from countries that alone could
not be demonstrated to be a cause of material As the foregoing history suggests, U.S.
injury could be subjected to antidumping duties. antidumping policy evolved in such a way as to
This analytical approach would seem to fly in become more accessible and more rewarding to
the face of any legitimate rationale for applying U.S. import-competing industries. That the
antidumping measures. Dumping is a firm- and volume of antidumping filings and the fre-
country-specific phenomenon. The artificial, quency of affirmative rulings underwent a dra-
unfair advantages that antidumping measures matic and sustained increase in the 1980s sug-
are presumed to offset are supposed to be mar- gests that domestic industry was responsive to
ket-specific and the product of particular foreign those changes.
government policies. If exports from a particular The definition of dumping had been
country are found to have no competitive expanded, domestic industry had been invited to
advantage in the U.S. market, then there are no play a greater role in antidumping policy formu-
advantages to offset with antidumping duties. lation and oversight (through the advisory com-
But after 1984, the rules changed in a way mittee system), and the U.S. government agency
that created incentives for bringing more cases most closely aligned with domestic producer
against more countries. Countries from which interests was made responsible for investigating
imports of subject merchandise accounted for dumping allegations. With the legislative
less than 3 percent of total imports of subject changes of 1984, U.S. firms seeking protection
merchandise were considered negligible and were given strong incentives to file even more
immune from antidumping duties unless all of antidumping petitions to increase their odds of

14
Figure 2
Number of U.S. Antidumping Initiations, 1947−2009
Case Initiations per Year

obtaining affirmative injury findings at the ITC. 59.1 percent in 1932. On the eve of U.S. entry
Figure 2 shows upticks in usage in years fol- into GATT in 1947 the average tariff stood at
lowing changes to the law, which would seem 20.1 percent and has fallen substantially in the
to confirm those characterizations. But there years since. The average collected rate in 1974—
are probably other reasons for the increase in when the “cost test” was introduced into the
antidumping use over time. For example, it is antidumping regime—was 7.8 percent. When
reasonable to assume that the demand for antidumping oversight was shifted from
antidumping protection would be inversely Treasury to Commerce in 1980, the average tar-
related to the level of general tariff protection iff on dutiable imports was 5.6 percent. The rate
afforded. In other words, firms in import- had fallen to 5.5 percent in 1984, when cumula-
competing industries might be more inclined tion was made a statutory requirement. And it
to seek antidumping protection in response to stood at 4 percent in 2008.48
reductions in general tariffs. The figure reveals an upward trend in the
Indeed, with the exception of a trend reversal overall number of U.S. antidumping initia-
in the 1920s and 1930s, declining tariff rates tions. Given the administrative changes that
have been evident throughout the history of the took place between 1974, 1980, and 1984, it is
antidumping law. The average tariff from 1890 not surprising that the number of initiations
to 1894 was 48.4 percent; from 1894 to 1897, it increased substantially during that period, or
was 41.3 percent; and when America’s first that the number of affirmative injury findings
antidumping law entered into force in 1916, the increased. Another interesting feature of the
average tariff had fallen to 30.7 percent.47 The data is that the number of products subject to
Fordney–McCumber Law of 1922 and Smoot- antidumping investigations has, to a far greater
Hawley Tariff Act of 1930 reversed that down- degree than either the overall number of initi-
ward trend, pushing the average up to as high as ations or the number of affirmative findings,

15
Figure 3
U.S. Antidumping Initiations against China (% of Total AD Initiations), 2000−2009

remained fairly consistent over time. That is Irwin’s analysis found that unemployment
suggestive of an increasing propensity of par- and exchange-rate appreciations were signifi-
ticular subsets of U.S. producers to bring more cant and positively related to the number of
cases. In fact, more than half of all currently antidumping case filings. That would seem to
outstanding U.S. antidumping and counter- make sense, since material injury is more easily
vailing duty orders (156 of 303) are against demonstrated when workers are let go and when
imported chemicals and steel products.49 The there is evidence of sales lost to imports (which
concentration of protection in these few indus- has been historically more likely when the U.S.
tries is likely a product of the ITC cumulation dollar is appreciating). Irwin found the average
rules giving incentive to petitioners to name rate of tariff protection to be significant and
more target countries, as well as evidence that negatively related to the number of filings (i.e.,
these industries have learned the ropes of falling Most Favored Nation tariffs lead to
antidumping administration and are no longer increased petitions), which is intuitive consider-
deterred by uncertainty about the process. ing that import competition tends to increase in
In 2004 Douglas Irwin published an analysis sectors where protection has been reduced. And,
of the various determinants of increased anti- Irwin found the legal and administrative
dumping use. Using data gathered from U.S. changes to have had a significant positive impact
government sources, Irwin conducted a series of on dumping filings after 1984—a trend likely
Since 2002 the regression analyses seeking to disentangle and attributable to mandatory cumulation, but also
measure the impact of independent variables, suggestive of a lagged impact of the Commerce
predominant including GDP growth rate, the unemployment Department’s takeover of dumping investiga-
targets of U.S. rate, the exchange rate, tariff rate changes, and tions.51
legal and administrative changes to the anti-
antidumping dumping law on the number of antidumping
Irwin’s analysis considered antidumping ini-
tiations through 2002. Since then, the predom-
activity have been cases filed per year between 1947 and 2002— inant targets of U.S. antidumping activity have
exporters in China. the dependent variable.50 been exporters in China. Nearly 39 percent of all

16
antidumping initiations since 2003 have target- by the Commerce Department in 2007, to start The application of
ed China, and that rate has been increasing on applying the countervailing duty law to Chinese the countervailing
an annual basis, as Figure 3 indicates.52 exporters is also a likely factor in the rise in cases
Certainly, imports from China increased against China over the past couple of years. duty law to Chinese
substantially between 2003 and 2009—which Since material injury (or the threat of material exporters is also a
might explain some of the increase, as Irwin injury) is a necessary condition of both anti-
found the average rate of tariff protection to be dumping and countervailing duties, there is lit-
likely factor in the
inversely related to the number of petitions. tle to lose and a lot to gain for U.S. industries by rise in cases against
But are Chinese exporters more likely to filing both kinds of petitions simultaneously. China over the past
benefit from unfair competitive advantages at The added incentive for doing so in Chinese
home than exporters in other countries, or could cases (as opposed to cases where the traditional couple of years.
it be that the increase in the number of cases market economy methodology is employed) is
against China is driven by the fact that the spe- that the combined duties can be especially puni-
cial nonmarket economy (NME) methodology tive. Under NME methodology, home-market
reserved for China and just a few other countries prices are disregarded entirely and “normal
is fertile ground for the exercise of discretion and value” is determined by estimating all of the
the escalation of dumping margins?53 Nonmar- inputs necessary to produce the good (labor,
ket economy methodology is probably an material, energy, overhead, etc.) and then assign-
important determinant of the rising number of ing an estimated value to those inputs based on
antidumping initiations against Chinese ex- their prices in another, similarly sized, similarly
porters because affirmative and high dumping developed economy—usually India, in Chinese
margins are more likely to be calculated under cases. The dumping margin is then calculated as
this approach.54 the average difference between the surrogates
Likewise, the change in practice, announced created and the U.S. prices.

Figure 4
U.S. Antidumping and Countervailing Duty Initiations against China, 2000−2009

17
As woefully inaccurate as the surrogate may abuse that its permissive rules and Commerce’s
be at approximating the Chinese home-market fox-guarding-the-henhouse oversight have en-
price, it is in fact a subsidy-free price. The cost gendered. No longer can the global economy be
build-up is based on market-oriented prices, characterized as a competition between “our”
and any subsidized prices or factors are elimi- producers and “their” producers. Numerous U.S.
nated from consideration. In other words, if interests—retailers, manufacturers, consumers,
one accepts the NME methodology as valid, logistics providers, financial service providers,
then the margin calculated is sufficient to rem- and more—are adversely affected when anti-
edy the dumping margin and the subsidy mar- dumping measures are imposed. Yet, under the
gin. The difference between the two captures law, the costs imposed on these groups are not
the full distortion. Nevertheless, the Com- even permitted to be considered by the admin-
merce Department still separately calculates istering authorities when rendering decisions
the benefit of the alleged subsidy and applies a about the propriety of antidumping measures.
separate countervailing duty on top of the anti- So far Congress has been loath to acknowl-
dumping duty, resulting in a double counting edge this reality. Instead, Congress considers
of the subsidy, thereby creating an extra incen- any presentation of the economywide costs of
tive for domestic industry to file an antidump- antidumping, any discussion of antidumping
It is reasonable to ing petition to supplement its countervailing reform, or any indictment of U.S. antidumping
conclude that the duty petition. practices from the WTO or other trade dispute
law need not be As Figure 4 demonstrates, there has been an settlement bodies to be an affront to its author-
increase in antidumping initiations against China ity and an encroachment on its jurisdiction.
made more since the Commerce Department changed its Efforts in 2002 by then−U.S. trade represen-
user friendly. countervailing duty policy in 2007. Indeed, for 22 tative Robert Zoellick to get antidumping rules
of the 23 countervailing duty cases initiated on the agenda of the Doha Round of multilat-
against China between 2007 and 2009, a com- eral trade negotiations (an absolute condition of
panion antidumping case was initiated simulta- getting the Round launched) were made notori-
neously. ously difficult by a Congress that insisted on
language that committed the USTR to “not
weaken” the antidumping law. When Zoellick
Congress’s Turf returned from the meeting that ultimately pro-
duced the Doha Declaration, he was summoned
Irwin’s statistical findings confirm what is to Congress to explain why he had agreed to
apparent to the naked eye from Figure 1 and include negotiations on antidumping on the
Figure 2: legal and administrative changes af- agenda, even though the language did not com-
fecting the antidumping law have been signifi- mit anybody to any reform.
cant determinants of subsequent antidumping In the debate over fast-track trade negotiat-
use. That finding is important for several rea- ing authority in 2002, Congress strongly consid-
sons. ered unbundling negotiations over antidumping
First, it provides a powerful rejoinder to from that authority, as proposed in the so-called
assertions that the antidumping law needs to be Dayton-Craig Amendment. That rule would
made more accessible and trade restrictive so as have given the president the authority to bring
to close loopholes in the battle against unfair back trade agreements for an up- or down-vote
trade. When the law’s ease of use and its effec- without amendments, but with the exception
tiveness at producing protection are more signif- that those same fast-track rules would not apply
icant determinants of antidumping use than any to any changes to antidumping rules, which
other factor, it is reasonable to conclude that the would require the full congressional treatment.
law need not be made more user friendly. And to this day, there is continued resis-
Second, Congress should seriously consider tance in Congress to implementing the find-
reform of the antidumping law to rein in the ings of the WTO dispute settlement body over

18
the issue of zeroing—the controversial method the proceedings and would likely find itself
for calculating antidumping duties.55 resorting to “Facts Available” findings with
One cannot help but acquire the impression greater frequently. Facts Available findings,
that Congress and the Department of Com- which usually substitute figures alleged in the
merce are unwilling to relinquish what they con- domestic industry’s petition for the exporter’s
sider a back channel for special favors to con- actual data, almost always produce higher
stituent interests that may find themselves in dumping margins for the company in ques-
need of assistance. tion—and for all the other companies that were
Emboldened by this institutional resistance not individually investigated—because their
to curbing antidumping abuse, import-compet- exports are subject to the average duty calculat-
ing interests have taken the initiative to push for ed for all investigated companies.
some new reforms of their own. However, those Economists Michael Moore of George
reforms would make antidumping measures Washington University and Thomas Prusa of
easier to obtain and more difficult for foreign Rutgers University summarized the problem
exporters and their U.S. customers to escape. with this recent example:
Based on a solicitation of comments from
“the public,” the Commerce Department Suppose three large firms account for
recently announced its intention to strengthen 90 percent of the subject imports while
the enforcement of U.S. trade remedies laws.56 20 others account for the remaining
Among the various reforms under consideration 10 percent. Under current rules the
is one that would make it impossible for indi- Department of Commerce samples the
vidual companies to get themselves out from big three firms. Under the proposed
under a dumping order even when they demon- rules, it can instead sample the pricing
strate that they are not dumping. Currently, by firms with, say, 1 percent of the
individual companies from a foreign country can imports. What is the logic of focusing
be excused from an antidumping order by on such small firms? The reason is that
demonstrating that they are not dumping for a small firms may not have the resources
certain period of time (usually three consecutive to spend the $2 million (or more)
years). The new proposal would eliminate that required to participate in a proceeding.
channel and force all exporters from a given Failure to respond to all questions
country to remain subject to the antidumping allows the Department of Commerce
order for as long as it exists. to use “facts available” (i.e., domestic
Another facially innocuous proposal that firms’ allegations) when computing
experts see as a cunning effort to make margins. Blonigen (2006) finds that
antidumping regulations even more restrictive using “facts available” increases the
would change the process by which the average computed margin by 30 per-
Commerce Department selects foreign respon- centage points.”57
dents in antidumping investigations and
reviews. Usually, Commerce chooses to investi- If these kinds of changes are implemented,
gate or review the producers accounting for the there should be little doubt of the impact on Episodes of
largest volume of exports to the United States. the number of case initiations. As has been relaxation of
But the proposal on the table would require demonstrated, episodes of relaxation of stan- standards and rules
Commerce to use random sampling in selecting dards and rules over the years have been fol-
the respondents, which would increase the lowed by increased usage. And with any causal over the years have
resource burdens on smaller firms that might be link between a foreign firm’s prices in the been followed by
unable to afford the legal and economic repre- United States and anti-competitive practices in
sentation that antidumping proceedings entail. the home market entirely severed by the pro-
increased usage of
Accordingly, Commerce would likely see less gressive lowering of evidentiary standards and the antidumping
compliance with the arduous requirements of the expansion of the definition of dumping, law.

19
Although the real- antidumping measures will be even more dis- This paper has presented a historical
world economic ruptive of trade and progress, benefiting only a account of the events punctuating antidump-
select few politicians and well-connected firms. ing’s metamorphosis and provided some num-
rationale for the bers explaining the increasing resort to anti-
antidumping status dumping. The data seem to support the
quo is virtually Conclusion hypothesis that increasing demand for anti-
dumping protection corresponds not with
extinct, political U.S. antidumping law no longer seeks to increased dumping, as defined by economists,
support for this advance the pro-competition objectives of its but rather with the increased flexibility of
original charter. What began as an outgrowth of antidumping, as defined by politicians. And
favor-doling antitrust intended to discipline predatory pric- ongoing efforts to make antidumping even
machine remains ing—and, therefore, to safeguard competition— more flexible are likely to induce more abuse—
was gradually transformed into a mishmash of at great expense to the U.S. and global econ-
strong and rules and discretion that enables inefficient, omies.
bipartisan. uncompetitive behavior on the part of domestic
firms at great cost to other domestic entities.
Antidumping has done little, if anything, to Notes
focus the spotlight on the alleged sources of The author owes a debt of gratitude to Todd Fox,
unfairness that presumably give rise to cross- whose excellent December 2009 graduate paper,
border price discrimination. By systemically “Changing the Definition of Fair: The Economic
disregarding that kind of inquiry, antidump- History of Antidumping in the United States,”
submitted to Johns Hopkins School of Advanced
ing’s overseers have blurred any distinctions International Studies, was the inspiration for this
between possibly objectionable price discrimi- paper and, indeed, the model for its structure.
nation and the kind that is the product of
1. “Basic Concepts and Principles of the Trade
profit-maximizing decisionmaking. Further- Remedy Rules,” communication from the United
more, market access barriers and transportation States to the WTO Negotiating Group on Rules,
costs have fallen precipitously since the estab- TN/RL/W/27, October 22, 2002.
lishment of antidumping policy, removing the
2. The antidumping statute is codified at 19
impediments to arbitrage necessary for cross- U.S.C. §§ 16731677n. The DOC’s antidumping
border price discrimination to occur without regulations may be found at 19 C.F.R. § 351.
undermining the market power of the foreign
3. In cases involving so-called nonmarket econo-
producer. mies, the DOC calculates constructed value, not
Although the real-world economic rationale with the foreign producer’s own cost data, but with
for the antidumping status quo is virtually data from “surrogate” market economies. For a
extinct, political support for this favor-doling comprehensive treatment of nonmarket economy
methodology, see Daniel J. Ikenson, “Nonmarket
machine remains strong and bipartisan. That Nonsense: U.S. Antidumping Policy toward
antidumping did a lousy job living up to its China,” Cato Trade Briefing Paper no. 22, March 7,
rhetoric did not stop policymakers from ex- 2005.
panding the definition of dumping and lowering
4. The antidumping regime’s failure to discern
the evidentiary requirements necessary for the causes of price discrimination represents a
industry to obtain antidumping protection. The fatal blow to its legitimacy. But beyond that, the
numerous legal and administrative changes, methodologies employed to determine and calcu-
such as enabling the attribution of material late the extent of price discrimination (i.e.,
“dumping margins”) are egregiously tilted in
injury to competitors in multiple countries, and favor of finding larger margins. For a comprehen-
disregarding home-market sales at prices below sive critique of those methodologies, see Brink
the full cost of production, further undermined Lindsey and Dan Ikenson, “Antidumping 101:
the rationale for antidumping and blurred its The Devilish Details of ‘Unfair Trade’ Law,” Cato
Trade Policy Analysis no. 20, November 21, 2002.
distinction from run-of-the-mill, everyday pro-
tectionism. 5. Michael P. Galloway, Bruce A. Blonigen, and

20
Joseph E. Flynn, “Welfare Costs of the U.S. Anti- ference Section B, Article 3: “In order to establish
dumping and Countervailing Duty Laws, Journal whether dumped imports have caused injury, all
of International Economics 49 (1999): 236. other factors which, individually or in combina-
tion, may be adversely affecting the industry shall
6. Douglas Irwin, “The Rise of U.S. Antidumping be examined, for example: the volume and prices
Actions in Historical Perspective,” NBER Work- of undumped imports of the product in question,
ing Paper 10582, June 2004, p. 4. competition between the domestic producers
themselves, contraction in demand due to substi-
7. Ian Wooton and Maurizio Zanardi, “Trade and tution of other products or to changes in con-
Competition Policy: Anti-Dumping Versus Anti- sumer tastes.”
Trust,” Department of Economics, University of
Glasgow, Working Papers 2002_6, October 2002, 25. Irwin, p. 7.
p. 2.
26. For a more detailed accounting of domestic
8. Irwin, p. 3. industry’s lobbying of Congress on this issue, see
William H. Barringer and Kenneth J. Pierce, Paying
9. J. Michael Finger, Antidumping: How It Works and the Price for Big Steel (Washington: American
Who Gets Hurt (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Institute for International Steel, 2000), p. 75.
Press, 1993), p. 21.
27. Barringer and Pierce, 75n93.
10. Ibid., p. 21.
28. Brink Lindsey and Dan Ikenson, “Antidumping
11. Ibid., p. 14. 101: The Devilish Details of ‘Unfair Trade’ Law,”
12. Ironically, U.S. Steel would emerge in subse- Cato Trade Policy Analysis no. 20, November 21,
quent decades as one of the prime users of anti- 2002, p. 14.
dumping. 29. Ibid.
13. Finger, p. 16. 30. Import Administration website, http://trade.
14. Ibid., p. 19. gov/ia/.

15. Irwin, p. 4. 31. Ibid.

16. Joshua Bernhardt, quoting the United States 32. Michael Anthony Lawrence, “Bias in the Inter-
Tariff Commission Report of 1919, in The Tariff national Trade Administration: The Need for
Commission, Its History, Activities and Organization Impartial Decisionmakers in United States Anti-
(New York: D. Appleton and Company, 1922), p. dumping Proceedings,” Case Western Reserve Journal
35, http://books.google.com/books?id=M-9AAA of International Law, Winter 1994, p. 3.
AAIAAJ&printsec=frontcover&dq=Joshua+Bernh 33. Congressional Budget Office, “How the GATT
ardt+The+Tariff+Commission,+Its+History,+Acti Affects U.S. Antidumping and Countervailing-
vities+and+Organization+1922&source=bl&ots= Duty Policy,” September 1994.
_XIb-PzaK0&sig=1d6792tLq4y4_46gLCSx81KL
WGY&hl=en&ei=ZQn9TJP8L8H7lweNpLyMBQ 34. For a detailed discussion of several of these
&sa=X&oi=book_result&ct=result&resnum=1&v methodological distortions and their impact, see
ed=0CBgQ6AEwAA#v=onepage&q&f=false. Daniel J. Ikenson, “Abuse of Discretion: Time to
Fix the Administration of the U.S. Antidumping
17. Congressional Budget Office, The Evolution of Law,” Cato Trade Policy Analysis no. 31, October 6,
U.S. Laws: An Economic Perspective, 1994, p. 21. 2005; and Brink Lindsey and Dan Ikenson,
18. Finger, p. 21. “Antidumping 101: The Devilish Details of ‘Unfair
Trade’ Law,” Cato Trade Policy Analysis no. 20,
19. Ibid., p. 22. November 21, 2002.

20. Irwin, p. 6. 35. Lindsey and Ikenson, p. 14.

21. World Trade Organization, Article VI, GATT 36. Ibid.


1994.
37. Daniel J. Ikenson, “Abuse of Discretion: Time
22. Finger, p. 26. to Fix the Administration of the U.S. Antidump-
ing Law,” Trade Policy Analysis no. 31, October 6,
23. Ibid. 2005, p. 1.

24. Per the Final Act of the 1964–1967 Trade Con- 38. Barringer and Pierce, p. 81.

21
39. U.S. Department of Commerce, Office of AD/ f5a6c0c5290985256a0a004dee7d/$FILE/orders%
CVD Enforcement. 20August%2012%202010.xls.
40. Lawrence, p. 3. 50. The legal and administrative changes tested
were those made pursuant to the Trade Reform Act
41. Compiled from databases available on the of 1974 (the inclusion of the “cost test”), the 1980
Import Administration website at http://ia.ita. shift of oversight from Treasury to Commerce, and
doc.gov/stats/iastats1.html. the codification of “cumulation” pursuant to the
42. The 599 antidumping measures include 25 Trade Agreements Act of 1984. Irwin used dummy
suspension agreements that are effectively settle- variables corresponding to the first full years of the
ments involving the agreement of the foreign new policies: 1975, 1980, and 1985, respectively.
exporters to sell above a certain price in the 51. Irwin, p. 25.
United States.
43. Cited in Irwin at p. 24, U.S. House of Represen- 52. Compiled from AD/CVD statistics available on
tatives, Committee on Ways and Means, “Hearings the website of the U.S. International Trade Com-
on Amendments to the Antidumping Act of 1921, mission, http://info.usitc.gov/oinv/sunset.nsf/0a9
as Amended,” 85th Congress, 1st Sess., 1957, p. 15. 15ada53e192cd8525661a0073de7d/96daf5a6c0c5
“At least” 90, and probably more, negative determi- 290985256a0a004dee7d/$FILE/orders%20August
nations were rendered because the data included in %2012%202010.xls.
the cited report aggregate “de minimis” findings of 53. For a detailed discussion of non-market econo-
dumping with “complaints withdrawn” and other my methodology, see Daniel J. Ikenson, “Nonmar-
reasons for non-affirmative findings. But de min- ket Nonsense: U.S. Antidumping Policy toward
imis findings are akin to negative finding of dump- China,” Cato Trade Briefing Paper no. 22, March 7,
ing and should have been counted as negatives. 2005.
44. Bruce A. Blonigen and Thomas A. Prusa, “Anti- 54. Ibid., p. 6.
dumping,” in E. K. Choi and J. Harrigan, Handbook
of International Trade (Oxford, UK and Cambridge, 55. For a detailed discussion of this issue, see
MA: Blackwell Publishers, 2003), p. 267. Daniel J. Ikenson, “Zeroing In: Antidumping’s
Flawed Methodology under Fire,” Cato Free Trade
45. Ikenson, October 2005, p. 3. Bulletin no. 11, April 27, 2004.
46. Tallied from Irwin, Appendix, p. 22. 56. U.S. Department of Commerce, Press Re-
47. Calculated as the ratio of duties collected over lease, August 26, 2010, “Obama Administration
the value of imports for consumption. Strengthens Enforcement of U.S. Trade Laws in
Support of President’s National Export Initia-
48. United States International Trade Commis- tive,” http://www.commerce.gov/news/press-releas
sion, Value of U.S. Imports for Consumption, Duties es/2010/08/26/obama-administration-strength
Collected, and Ratio of Duties to Values 1891–2008, ens-enforcement-us-trade-laws-support-pr.
ITC Statistical Services Division, April 2009.
57. Michael Moore and Thomas Prusa, “Straight
49. Compiled from AD/CVD statistics available Out of Mad Mend: US Markets Import Protection
on the website of the U.S. International Trade as Export Prompotion,” Vox Commentary, No-
Commission, http://info.usitc.gov/oinv/sunset. vember 8, 2010, http://www.voxeu.org/index.php
nsf/0a915ada53e192cd8525661a0073de7d/96da ?q=node/5751.

22
Trade Policy Analysis Papers from the Cato Institute

“The U.S. Generalized System of Preferences: Helping the Poor, But at What Price?” by Sallie James (no. 43; November 16,
2010)

“Made on Earth: How Global Economic Integration Renders Trade Policy Obsolete” by Daniel Ikenson (no. 42; December
2, 2009)

“A Harsh Climate for Trade: How Climate Change Proposals Threaten Global Commerce” by Sallie James (no. 41;
September 9, 2009)

“Restriction or Legalization? Measuring the Economic Benefits of Immigration Reform” by Peter B. Dixon and Maureen T.
Rimmer (no. 40; August 13, 2009)

“Audaciously Hopeful: How President Obama Can Help Restore the Pro-Trade Consensus” by Daniel Ikenson and Scott
Lincicome (no. 39; April 28, 2009)

“A Service to the Economy: Removing Barriers to ‘Invisible Trade’” by Sallie James (no. 38; February 4, 2009)

“While Doha Sleeps: Securing Economic Growth through Trade Facilitation” by Daniel Ikenson (no. 37; June 17, 2008)

“Trading Up: How Expanding Trade Has Delivered Better Jobs and Higher Living Standards for American Workers” by
Daniel Griswold (no. 36; October 25, 2007)

“Thriving in a Global Economy: The Truth about U.S. Manufacturing and Trade” by Daniel Ikenson (no. 35; August 28,
2007)

“Freeing the Farm: A Farm Bill for All Americans” by Sallie James and Daniel Griswold (no. 34; April 16, 2007)

“Leading the Way: How U.S. Trade Policy Can Overcome Doha’s Failings” by Daniel Ikenson (no. 33; June 19, 2006)

“Boxed In: Conflicts between U.S. Farm Policies and WTO Obligations” by Daniel A. Sumner (no. 32; December 5, 2005)

“Abuse of Discretion: Time to Fix the Administration of the U.S. Antidumping Law” by Daniel Ikenson (no. 31; October 6,
2005)

“Ripe for Reform: Six Good Reasons to Reduce U.S. Farm Subsidies and Trade Barriers” by Daniel Griswold, Stephen
Slivinski, and Christopher Preble (no. 30; September 14, 2005)

“Backfire at the Border: Why Enforcement without Legalization Cannot Stop Illegal Immigration” by Douglas S. Massey
(no. 29; June 13, 2005)

“Free Trade, Free Markets: Rating the 108th Congress” by Daniel Griswold (no. 28; March 16, 2005)

“Protection without Protectionism: Reconciling Trade and Homeland Security” by Aaron Lukas (no. 27; April 8, 2004)

“Trading Tyranny for Freedom: How Open Markets Till the Soil for Democracy” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 26; January 6,
2004)

“Threadbare Excuses: The Textile Industry’s Campaign to Preserve Import Restraints” by Dan Ikenson (no. 25; October 15, 2003)
Board of Advisers CENTER FOR TRADE POLICY STUDIES
James Bacchus
Greenberg Traurig LLP
T he mission of the Cato Institute’s Center for Trade Policy Studies is to increase public
understanding of the benefits of free trade and the costs of protectionism. The center
publishes briefing papers, policy analyses, and books and hosts frequent policy forums and
Jagdish Bhagwati
Columbia University conferences on the full range of trade policy issues.
Scholars at the Cato trade policy center recognize that open markets mean wider choices
Donald J. Boudreaux and lower prices for businesses and consumers, as well as more vigorous competition that
George Mason University encourages greater productivity and innovation. Those benefits are available to any country
that adopts free-trade policies; they are not contingent upon “fair trade” or a “level playing
Douglas A. Irwin field” in other countries. Moreover, the case for free trade goes beyond economic efficiency.
Dartmouth College The freedom to trade is a basic human liberty, and its exercise across political borders unites
people in peaceful cooperation and mutual prosperity.
José Piñera The center is part of the Cato Institute, an independent policy research organization in
International Center for Washington, D.C. The Cato Institute pursues a broad-based research program rooted in the
Pension Reform traditional American principles of individual liberty and limited government.

Russell Roberts For more information on the Center for Trade Policy Studies,
George Mason University visit www.freetrade.org.

Razeen Sally Other Trade Studies from the Cato Institute


London School of
Economics “The U.S. Generalized System of Preferences: Helping the Poor, But at What Price?” by Sallie
James, Trade Policy Analysis no. 43 (November 16, 2010)
George P. Shultz
Hoover Institution “A Free Trade Agreement with South Korea Would Promote Both Prosperity and Security”
by Doug Bandow, Trade Briefing Paper no. 31 (October 20, 2010)
Clayton Yeutter
Former U.S. Trade “The Miscellaneous Tariff Bill: A Blueprint for Future Trade Expansion” by Daniel Griswold,
Representative Trade Briefing Paper no. 30 (September 9, 2010)

“Manufacturing Discord: Growing Tensions Threaten the U.S.-China Economic


Relationship” by Daniel J. Ikenson, Trade Briefing Paper no. 29 (May 4, 2010)

“Made on Earth: How Global Economic Integration Renders Trade Policy Obsolete” by
Daniel Ikenson, Trade Policy Analysis no. 42 (December 2, 2009)

“A Harsh Climate for Trade: How Climate Change Proposals Threaten Global Commerce”
by Sallie James, Trade Policy Analysis no. 41 (September 9, 2009)

“Restriction or Legalization? Measuring the Economic Benefits of Immigration Reform” by


Peter B. Dixon and Maureen T. Rimmer, Trade Policy Analysis no. 40 (August 13, 2009)

Nothing in Trade Policy Analysis should be construed as necessarily reflecting the views of the
Center for Trade Policy Studies or the Cato Institute or as an attempt to aid or hinder the pas-
sage of any bill before Congress. Contact the Cato Institute for reprint permission. Additional
copies of Trade Policy Analysis studies are $6 each ($3 for five or more). To order, contact the
Cato Institute, 1000 Massachusetts Avenue, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20001. (202) 842-
0200, fax (202) 842-3490, www.cato.org.

Você também pode gostar