Você está na página 1de 8

ISSUE 2006/03

APRIL 2006
bruegelpolicybrief

WELCOME TO EUROPE
by Jakob von SUMMARY Many more people would like to migrate to the EU than the
Weizsäcker EU is ready to absorb. But who should be allowed to enter and who
Research Fellow at Bruegel should not? The economic effects of high-skilled immigration are
jvw@bruegel.org
generally positive for the receiving country while low-skilled migration
has more ambiguous effects. The economic and political complexity of
low-skilled migration must not be used as an excuse for procrastina-
tion. The EU has already fallen behind in attracting high-skilled
migrants. By contrast, Australia, Canada and Switzerland are particu-
larly successful in attracting foreign graduates through “points” based
immigration systems. Europe should follow suit to position itself in the
global competition for talent.
% FOREIGN-BORN GRADUATES IN POLICY CHALLENGE
TOTAL POPULATION The EU should open up to skilled immi-
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 grants through a points system via a
POLAND “Blue Card” granting access to its entire
SPAIN labour market. This European version of
PORTUGAL the Green Card could become a powerful
DENMARK complement to any national effort to
NETHERLANDS attract top talent. In addition, students
FRANCE graduating with a Masters degree or
GERMANY
equivalent from European universities or
BELGIUM
from top universities abroad should be
UK
automatically eligible for a Blue Card.
This “Blue Diploma” would help attract
SWEDEN
young talent early. Finally, in future
US
rounds of EU enlargement, higher-skilled
SWITZERLAND
workers should be welcome immedia-
CANADA
tely, provided they reach an earnings
AUSTRALIA
threshold: the “External Minimum Wage”.
Source: see Table 1
WELCOME TO EUROPE

02 1. MIGRATION AND THE


The Governor of She asked ter at attracting talent from the rest of
Confucius about government. The GLOBAL SUPPLY OF SKILLS the world. The European Commission
Master said, “Make the local people has accordingly become active in this
happy and attract migrants from area (Box 1).
bruegelpolicybrief

afar.” Immigration rates in the EU-15 and the


The Analects, Confucius US remained at relatively moderate However, progress has been slow
levels during the 1960s, 1970s, and because many relevant stakeholders
ECONOMIC historians have shown most of the 1980s, as shown in Chart still use problematic concepts to dis-
that migration contributed more to 1. Migration rates only shot up in the cuss migration, most importantly the
the convergence of income across late eighties and early nineties. They “lump-of-labour” fallacy according to
the globe than trade did in the 19th rose again substantially in the early which the number of jobs in an eco-
century. However, in more recent 2000s in Europe in particular, driven nomy is fixed. This policy brief argues
years it has been strangely neglec- by immigration to the EU-15 from that the issue of economic migration
ted as a major economic force and Eastern Europe. In addition, there is should instead be framed in terms of
re-emerged only with accelerated significant illegal immigration. the skill level of immigrants.
globalisation in the aftermath of the
disappearance of the iron curtain. There are concerns in Europe over this The differences in both the extent and
influx of immigrants, and low-skilled the skill composition of migration,
Over the coming years, migration immigrants in particular. At the same among developed countries, are stri-
rates and migration pressures might king. In particular, the percentage of
well increase further. Globalisation is highly-skilled foreign-born in the
rapidly “shrinking” the world without entire population varies widely, as
shrinking worldwide income diffe- highlighted by Table 1, in which green
rences quite as fast. In particular, indicates a high percentage, yellow a
the near neighbourhood of Europe “Europe will need mid-range percentage and red a low
has around 500m inhabitants, many to become much percentage of high-skilled foreign-
keen to migrate to Europe. There cer- born in the population.
tainly are many more potential better at attracting
migrants than Europe seems willing Australia, Canada, and Switzerland
to absorb. talent from the rest have been phenomenally successful
of the world.” in attracting large numbers of
The argument of this brief is that migrants with a strong bias towards
significantly more high-skilled immi- high-skilled immigration. All three
gration would be a boon for Europe. countries have a points-based system
The economic and political com- for attracting high-skilled immigrants
plexity of the issue of low-skilled (Box 2).
immigration, which has much more time, to become a competitive and
ambiguous effects, must not be dynamic knowledge-driven economy In mid-range immigration countries,
used as a pretext to procrastinate. as spelled out in the Lisbon agenda, the picture is much more varied.
Europe will need to become much bet- Germany, for example, has attracted
Instead, Europe should attract
highly-skilled migrants at a greatly
CHART 1
accelerated rate to position itself in
the global competition for talent. The RECENT INCREASE IN IMMIGRATION TO THE EU AND THE US
time has come to tell those bright
young graduates of the world: 4
Welcome to Europe!
RATE PER 1,000 INHABITANTS

In Section 1, the basic facts of migra- US IMMIGRATION 3


tion, its skill content, and the increa-
sing supply of skills worldwide will
be examined. In Section 2 the basic 2
efficiency and distribution argu-
ments for and against high and low-
skilled migration are analysed. The 1
impact of emigration - “brawn drain” EU-15 NET MIGRATION
and “brain drain” - on developing
source countries is also discussed. 0
Finally, Section 3 proposes potential 1960-69 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-04
policy options for Europe.
Source: Eurostat, US Office of Imm. Statistics, US Census Bureau.
WELCOME TO EUROPE

TABLE 1
INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF THE EXTENT AND SKILL COMPOSITION OF MIGRATION 03

bruegelpolicybrief
% WITH TERTIARY EDUCATION AMONG: HIGH-SKILLED POINTS SYSTEM TO
% FOREIGN-
COUNTRY FOREIGN-BORN ATTRACT HIGH-
BORN NATIVES FOREIGN-BORN (% TOTAL POP.) SKILLED AS OF:
POLAND 2.1 10.4 11.9 0.2 N/A
SPAIN 5.3 19.4 21.8 1.2 N/A
PORTUGAL 6.3 7.7 19.3 1.2 N/A
DENMARK 6.8 18.8 19.5 1.3 N/A
UK 8.3 20.1 34.8 2.9 2007*
FRANCE 10.0 16.9 18.1 1.8 N/A
NETHERLANDS 10.1 19.5 17.6 1.8 N/A
BELGIUM 10.7 22.9 21.6 2.3 N/A
SWEDEN 12.0 22.8 24.2 2.9 N/A
US 12.3 26.9 25.9 3.2 N/A
GERMANY 12.5 19.5 15.5 1.9 N/A
CANADA 19.3 31.5 38.0 7.3 1967
SWITZERLAND 22.4 18.1 23.7 5.3 1996
AUSTRALIA 23.0 38.6 42.9 9.9 1984
Source: Dumont and Lemaître (2004)
*Expected date following announcement by BOX 1: EU-Level Activity on Economic Migration
UK Home Office in March 2006 A recent Policy Plan on Legal Migration1 outlines the initiatives the European
disproportionate numbers of low-skil- Commission intends to take over the 2006-09 period. This plan is based on the
led immigrants, consistent with its Green Paper, “On an EU Approach to Managing Economic Migration”, of January
historically large guest worker pro- 2005, and the wide consultation that followed.
gramme. English-speaking countries
may have a distinct advantage in In particular, a framework directive is planned in order to define a common set of
attracting high-skilled migrants, not basic rights granted to migrant workers. Furthermore, four specific directives
least through their universities. But would be designed to discipline the entry and residence of particular types of
contrary to popular perception, the US immigrants, namely highly-skilled and seasonal workers, intra-corporate transfer-
ees and remunerated trainees.
does not follow this pattern. This is the
result of a large influx of low-skilled One of the main objectives is to make the EU more attractive to high-skilled
immigrants from Mexico. migrants. Whether this could be achieved through an EU work permit, similar to the
Blue Card proposed in the brief, is under discussion.
But what if many more countries follo-
wed the examples of Canada, BOX 2: The Canadian Example of a Points-Based Immigration System
Switzerland, and Australia? Would
those other countries simply be com- The points system for immigration was pioneered by Canada in 1967 and
peting for the same scarce internatio- its skills bias was reinforced in 2001. Under the current rules, a foreign
nal supply of skilled labour? Chart 2 applicant must have previous work experience as a skilled worker to be eli-
comprehensively dispels this concern. gible for treatment under the points system. Then, to be able to become
Over the last 15 years, the number of established in Canada, a minimum of 67 points out of 96 have to be award-
students in tertiary education has ed on the basis of the following factors:
increased dramatically. •Education (up to 25 pts)
Today, the share of students in the •Proficiency in the official languages (up to 20 pts)
population is in fact lower in the old EU •Experience (up to 21 pts)
member states (EU-15) than in the new •Age with more points for younger migrants (up to 10 pts)
member states (EU-10) or the wider EU •Arranged employment (up to 10 pts)
•Adaptability including family ties to Canada (up to 10 pts)
neighbourhood (EU Neighbourhood
Policy Countries + Russia). Turkey is These factors aim at capturing not only the economic potential but also the 1
European
also catching up rapidly. likelihood of a successful integration. Commission (2005).
WELCOME TO EUROPE

04
Even more striking is the increasing CHART 2
supply of skill among the Pop-102, the
10 most populous economies outside NUMBER OF STUDENTS IN TERTIARY EDUCATION
the US and Europe. Over the last 15
bruegelpolicybrief

0 10m 20m 30m 40m


years, the Pop-10 have collectively COUNTRY (POP.)
increased their numbers of students EU & PROXIMITY*(958m) 21m
by 156%. As a result, they now have 36m (3.8%)
more students than the enlarged EU EU-15 (381m) 9,7m
and the US combined. 13.7m (3.6%)
EU-10 (74m) 1m
3.3m (4.5%)
Overall, tertiary education rates have EU ACCESSION COUNTRIES
been converging much faster than 0.4m 1990
(74m) 0.9m (3.0%)
incomes. As a result, no shortage of EU (POTENTIAL) 1m 2004 (% in pop.)
young and high-skilled migrants is to CANDIDATES (91m) 2.3m (2.6%)
be expected any time soon. If Europe TURKEY (72m) 0.7m
wants to welcome more high-skilled 1.9m (2.7%)
migrants, it can. EU NEIGHBOURHOOD & 9.3m
RUSSIA (382m) 16m (4.2%)
2. EFFICIENCY REASONS FOR RUSSIA (143m)
5.1m
8.1m (5.7%)
MIGRATION: A PRIMER
Economic migration can loosely be POP-10 (3,474m) 16.3m
defined as any cross-border migra-
tion that occurs to take on a better 3.8m 41.7m (1.2%)
CHINA (1,297m)
paid job. If pay is broadly in line with 15.2m (1.2%)
productivity, a move to a better paid INDIA (1,080m) 5m
11.3m (1.0%)
job thus increases global economic
output. This is the fundamental effi-
ciency argument in favour of migra- N. AMERICA & 16.2m
tion. ANTIPODES (350m) 19m (5.4%)
US (294m) 13.7m
But most people would prefer to stay 16.6m (5.7%)
at home if it wasn’t for the money.
Therefore, why not upgrade productiv- Source: Edstats (World Bank)
ity where the people currently are Nearest available year used when student
data missing for 1990 or 2004.
instead of having people chase more In summary, important factors driving
productive jobs abroad? International *Bosnia & Herzogovina, Armenia, Palestinian migration today include good institu-
trade and cross-border movement of Authority, and Syria not included in EU &
Proximity due to missing data. tions and agglomeration effects. In
capital are helping to do just that. both areas, Europe is well positioned.
According to the classic factor price
equalisation theorem of trade theory, opment problem by allowing workers In view of these important efficiency
wages might in principle be equalised move to locations with a better “pro- arguments3 for migration, why is free
internationally through the trade of duction function” immediately. migration such a remote prospect?
goods alone! However, there are Besides non-economic factors, distri-
important reasons why migration Second, agglomeration effects are an butional concerns are the main rea-
pressures are likely to persist even important rationale for migration. For son.
under free trade, full mobility of capi- example, France and the UK are large
tal, and flexible labour markets countries with fairly uniform institu- The basic argument is easily under-
domestically. tions, free trade and free movement of stood: Almost by definition, the
2
China, India, capital. Nevertheless, workers continue migrant himself or herself derives
Indonesia, Brazil, First, many poor countries suffer to migrate to extremely expensive and benefits from a higher wage abroad. In
Pakistan,
Bangladesh, Nigeria, from an inferior “production function” crowded places like London or Paris. The the host country, wages of workers
Mexico, Vietnam, because of poor institutions. Despite reason is, people become more produc- with labour market characteristics
Philippines. recent development success stories, tive by virtue of geographic concentra- similar to those of the migrant can be
upgrading poor institutions is a slow tion. By moving to a large agglomera- expected to marginally decline while
3
Strictly speaking, process. In the meantime, workers in tion, often in a foreign country, they can the income of those with different
agglomeration effects many developing countries will con- also hope to greatly improve the match skills increases. Beneficiaries typical-
need not improve ove-
rall efficiency. (See tinue to suffer from inferior wages. between their skill and their job, thus ly include people with different skills
Charlot et al, 2006) Migration can short-circuit this devel- boosting their productivity. and owners of capital and land. In the
WELCOME TO EUROPE

05
source country, the wage impact will negative wage impact of immigration concerns that come with low-skilled
be a mirror image: the wage prospects might be hidden by above-average migration, at this stage.
of workers similar to the emigrant are wages in areas that manage to attract
set to improve while those with com- the largest numbers of migrants. Assuming a welfare function that is

bruegelpolicybrief
plementary factors of production inequality averse, the efficiency and
would tend to suffer By applying an econo- distributional findings can now be
somewhat. metric approach brought together. High-skilled immi-
“High-skilled immune to this partic- gration is likely to increase welfare
On that basis, low-skilled immigration is ular concern, Borjas among the host country population
immigrants will tend to (2003) and Aydemir since both efficiency and equity are
increase income inequali- likely to increase and Borjas (2006) likely to be improved. By contrast,
ty among the native pop- obtain substantially low-skilled immigration has an
ulation in the host coun- welfare in the higher estimates of ambiguous welfare effect in the host
try as the already below- the wage impact of country. It increases efficiency from
average wages of low- host country migration for the US, the perspective of the native popula-
skilled natives will come since both effi- Canada, and Mexico. tion provided that there is sufficient
under additional pres- According to these adjustment in the capital stock while
sure. By analogous argu- ciency and studies, immigration widening the income gap between
ments, high-skilled- of 1% reduces wages rich and poor in the host country.
migration has a benign equity are likely at the respective skill-
distributional impact in level by between 0.3 The welfare argument in favour of
the host country and an to be improved.” and 0.4% and migra- high-skilled immigration and the wel-
adverse distributional tion could explain up fare ambiguity of low-skilled immigra-
impact in the source country. to one third of the increase in the tion are reinforced by a number of
Ultimately, these opposing effects wage gap between low-skilled and additional aspects that have so far
between different skill groups and dif- high-skilled wages in the US over been neglected:
ferent countries are likely to be at the recent decades. Furthermore, Borjas
core of any economic controversy finds in a simulation that any efficien- (i) The Fiscal Impact of Migration in a
over migration. cy gains may Welfare State.
well be tiny com-
However, while this theoretical argu- pared to these “The net fiscal Obviously, the net fiscal
ment is simple and compelling, it has adverse distribu- impact of a high-skilled
been surprisingly difficult to find con- tion effects. impact of a high- immigrant tends to be sub-
vincing empirical evidence to support
it. In their analysis of empirical sur- But those find-
skilled immigrant stantially more favourable
than the net fiscal impact of
veys, Longhi et al. (2005, 2006) find ings are unlikely tends to be more a low-skilled migrant.
only a minute “consensus estimate” to mark the end However, even low-skilled
of the distributional impact: a one per of the empirical favourable .” immigrants can make a pos-
cent increase in immigration only debate. Bonin itive net contribution to the
leads to a 0.12% decline in wages (2005) applies welfare state since pay-as-
within the relevant skill segment and Borjas’ methodology to German data you-go pensions impose a large bur-
a 0.024% decline in employment. and finds much smaller effects. Also, den on young migrants.
questions remain as to why the wage
If this were true, it would be wonderful effects of classic natural experiments (ii) Migration and Inflexible Labour
news. Essentially, one could stop wor- like the Miami Boatlift and the mass Markets.
rying about the distributional implica- emigration from the Commonwealth Low-skilled workers are typically more
tions of migration altogether. of Independent States (CIS) countries affected by poorly functioning labour 4
However, if the low-
However, as Borjas (2003) has point- have not been more marked. Finally, markets than high-skilled workers. skilled unemploy-
ed out, most of the empirical studies Ottaviano and Peri (2006) find signif- Chart 3 shows that the unemployment ment is due to cen-
that fail to find a significant distribu- icant complementarity of native and rate of low-skilled workers in Europe is tralised wage setting
tional impact of migration focus on foreign workers within the same skill systematically higher than for high- coupled with low
the impact of immigration on wages group and they argue that only the skilled workers. On average, the former mobility, additional
low-skilled immigra-
in small geographic areas. But such least skilled group of natives in the US stands at 10% in the EU while the latter tion might actually
an approach fails to control for the are likely to experience a negative is only 5% and can primarily be reduce unemploy-
endogeneity of migration. Migrants wage impact due to migration. explained by frictional unemployment. ment by reducing the
tend to be attracted to locations that This suggests that the labour market marginal producti-
have the most vibrant local But one thing is clear: the empirical lit- will be able to absorb high-skilled vity differentials bet-
economies and therefore typically the erature has not been able to compre- migrants more readily than low-skilled ween regions, as
explained in Boeri
most attractive wages. Hence, any hensively dispel the distributional migrants.4 and Brücker (2005).
WELCOME TO EUROPE

06
(iii) Dangers of an Ethnic Underclass The source country may suffer from fare of the source country. Hence,
an adverse efficiency and distribu- there need not be a conflict of interest
There are signs that certain immi- tional impact as a result of the brain between source and host country but
grant communities in Europe are drain. There will be fiscal loss since there may well be. This raises the ques-
bruegelpolicybrief

developing into an ethnic underclass. high-skilled emigrants will no longer tion how could the positions of host
It is clear that much better education pay taxes in their home country. And and source country be reconciled, if
and improved economic opportuni- just as high-skilled migrants help to indeed there were a conflict?
ties for the children of low-skilled uplift their ethnic communities
migrants already in Europe, need to abroad, they could have made notable
be provided. Migration policies can contributions to public life had they
usefully complement such integration stayed at home. FIGURE 1
measures by creating a high-skill bias THEORETICAL MIGRATION
among fresh immigrants. Low-skilled But a brain drain is not all bad for the PREFERENCES
immigrants already in Europe are the source country. The option to emi-
grate may substantially increase the

+
closest labour market substitutes to
new low-skill immigrants. Hence, by expected returns to education, there- HIGH-
reducing the inflow of additional low-
skilled immigrants, the economic
prospects of existing low-skilled
immigrant communities could proba-
by improving education incentive.
Finally, if migrants return to their
country of origin, and many of them
do, the skills and savings they have
SKILLED
MIGRA-
TION
?
+
bly be improved. acquired abroad become a powerful LOW-

For the source country, low-skilled emi-


gration or “brawn drain” typically
improves welfare as it improves both
force of development. Therefore, mod-
erate levels of brain drain may actual-
ly be beneficial for the source country
as, for example, argued in Beine et al.
SKILLED
MIGRA-
TION
?
efficiency and redistribution. This posi- (2003). RICH HOST POOR SOURCE
tive impact of low-skilled emigration is
The findings of the previous sections
reinforced by remittances. Low-skilled COUNTRY COUNTRY
are summarised in Figure 1: High-
emigrants will often help to support
skilled migration tends to improve the
poor relatives in the source country
with their higher earnings abroad. welfare of the host country while the
welfare impact of migration on the
By contrast, the welfare impact of source country is ambiguous. By con- Unlike trade, migration will generally
high-skilled emigration or “brain trast, low-skilled migration has an require international compensating
drain” is ambiguous. ambiguous welfare impact on the host transfers instead of purely national
country while generally improving wel- ones if efficiency gains are in part to
be used to compensate the losers. In
CHART 3 particular, it will typically be neces-
sary for a rich host country to share
UNEMPLOYMENT IN EUROPE BY SKILL-LEVEL*
some of the gains from high-skilled
8 migration, including the gains from
HIGH-SKILLED UNEMPLOYMENT (%)

7 the immigrants, with the poor source


GREECE country. Perhaps the most prominent
6 SPAIN proposal in this respect is the
GERMANY
ITALY Bhagwati tax, a special income tax on
5 FRANCE
EU-15 EU-25 the high-skilled immigrant the pro-
4 PORTUGAL FINLAND ceeds of which are to be transferred
SWEDEN LATVIA
CYPRUS DENMARK BELGIUM
LITHUANIA back to the source country in com-
3 LUXEMBOURG pensation for the migratory move.
NETHERLANDS SLOVENIA ESTONIA
UK MALTA
2 HUNGARY
IRELAND AUSTRIA This tax may be difficult to implement
in practice because of international
1
cooperation, and some forms of tax
0 discrimination based on the place of
2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 birth may not be constitutional under
LOW-SKILLED UNEMPLOYMENT (%) all circumstances, but Europe could
certainly go a long way towards gain-
Source: Eurostat ing the moral high ground simply by
*Unemployment rates for worked aged 25 and over(Q2 of 2005). “High-Skilled” = Tertiary edu-
cation; “Low-Skilled” = Primary and Lower Secondary only.
fulfilling last year’s commitments to
WELCOME TO EUROPE

07
significantly increase development (i) An EU-wide Blue Card for high- for Europe to compete for top talent
aid as a percentage of GDP. More skilled migrants. with countries like the US or Canada.
specifically, the EU could make a By contrast, the positive spill-over of
point of subsidising education sys- In a points system of immigration, low-skilled immigration is likely to be

bruegelpolicybrief
tems as an increasing function of the both definitions of skill can simply limited. Therefore, low-skilled migra-
net inflow from any particular source be used in parallel. In view of the tion could remain the responsibility
country. Alternatively, rich countries high flexibility of points systems and of the member states for the time
could allocate more work permits for their success in attracting high-skil- being, unless significant negative
low-skilled workers, since a mixed led migrants, it seems likely that spill-over effects are discovered in
strategy between high-skilled and low- many European countries will adopt specific areas that would need to be
skilled migration could also overcome them over the coming years. addressed collectively.
the potential conflict of interest depict-
ed in Figure 1. Additional possibilities This raises the question whether (ii) Blue Diplomas for Foreign Graduates
are discussed in the next section. there is any room for European invol-
vement regarding high-skilled migra- As one particular variant of the Blue
3. POLICY PROPOSALS tion. High-skilled migrants could give Card, an entirely qualification-based
rise to positive cross-border externa- “Blue Diploma” could be introduced.
If the potential distributional pro- lities within the EU similar to Any graduate of a Masters programme
blems with the source countries can research and development. In princi- (or equivalent) from a participating
be fairly resolved, how should Europe ple, this argument might even be university could be made eligible for a
go about attracting high-skilled used to justify subsidies for attrac- Blue card by virtue of his or her
migrants? Before answering this ting high-skilled migrants, perhaps degree. Such a comprehensive and
question, the term “high-skilled” in the form of a centrally financed predictable arrangement would
migrant needs a better practical defi- Erasmus style programme to attract greatly help to attract foreign talent to
nition. third country nationals. European universities and to the
European labour market afterwards.
Perhaps the most obvious definition However, before going down the In principle, it would make sense to
of skill would be based on formal route of explicit subsidies, the extend Blue Diplomas to universities
qualifications. This also makes some attractiveness of Europe could be outside Europe also. For a start, the
economic sense since formal qualifi- increased for free by providing third top 100 non-European universities,
cations tend to be a fairly good pre- country nationals immediate access as measured by academic excellence,
dictor of future ear- to the entire EU should also be included in the
nings potential. labour market. This scheme.
This is relevant will be more valuable
since most from the perspective Even from a development perspec-
migrants move in “The Blue Card would of the migrant than tive, the Blue Diploma could turn out
their 20s or early access to any natio- to be beneficial. By providing guaran-
30s when their cur- act as an insurance nal labour market teed access to the European labour
rent earnings are due to the option market without requiring a perma-
only a relatively policy for graduates value of the additio- nent presence, circular migration in
poor predictor of from developing nal markets. Also, the spirit of the proposal by Weil
future earnings such an EU wide (2006) would be encouraged. The
potential. countries.” immigration regime Blue Card would in effect act as an
would provide much insurance policy for graduates from
However, from an eco- greater visibility, developing countries in case they
nomic perspective, a predictability, and would like to take the risk of going
definition of skill transparency than back home. They could always return
ought to go beyond formal qualifications. 25 different national systems to Europe for a second chance.
As long as an immigrant is likely to
achieve high earnings in the host coun- Therefore, it is recommended to (iii) An External Minimum Wage
try, he could be argued to have suffi- introduce a “Blue Card”, a European
ciently rare talent so as to be regarded as Green Card that would provide highly It turns out that the skills-based
highly skilled. This is the salary-based skilled third country nationals with approach of migration also has an
definition of skill. It is a highly flexible instant access to the entire interesting application to EU enlarge-
definition, capturing all kinds of profes- European labour market. This Blue ment. For new rounds of EU enlarge-
sional excellence, including sports such Card would be allocated on the basis ment (Bulgaria, Rumania, eventually
as football and creative professions, of skill through a Europe wide points Turkey), the question arises of how
which are difficult to standardise. system. Overall, such a system to manage the transition to full
should make it significantly easier labour mobility.
WELCOME TO EUROPE

08
As with immigration from third coun- Germany and other countries who diately. Over the next 3 to 5 years,
tries, the old member states will typi- have not yet introduced full mobility this external minimum wage could
cally be more readily persuaded to from the 2002 round of enlargement then be progressively lowered in
open up their labour markets for high- would be well advised to apply this order to assure a smooth transition
bruegelpolicybrief

skilled than for low-skilled workers approach immediately to attract to full worker mobility in 2009 or
from new member states. 2011.
Furthermore, due to the strictly limi- “The complex issue of
ted duration of the transition process ***
While Europe would clearly benefit
to full labour mobility, the dangers of low-skilled migration by attracting more talent from
abuse are less pronounced than they
would otherwise be. Hence, a simple should not hold us abroad, continued low-skilled migra-
salary-based approach can be used to tion will not necessarily be harmful.
introduce full mobility for high-skilled back in finding a In this brief, it has merely been
workers while delaying access for low- argued that the complex issue of low-
skilled workers.
better approach to skilled migration should not hold us
back in finding a better approach to
skilled migration.” skilled migration.
Citizens of new EU member states
would be allowed to enter work high-skilled workers from the pre- By the same token, the introduction
contracts that pay above an external sent new member states in Eastern of better integration policies is a no-
minimum wage in all old member Europe. Germany could introduce an brainer that must not be delayed by
states. This wage floor could initially external minimum wage of €30,000 the continuing complex discussion
be set at the median wage in each per year for citizens of the new mem- of how restrictive or liberal migration
old member state. With time, the ber states in Eastern Europe. For policies for low-skilled migrants
external minimum wage could be young workers, this threshold could should be.
lowered at a jointly agreed minimum even be set somewhat lower, at
pace to reach full free mobility. Of €24,000. As a result, the low wage
course, any old member state would sector in Germany would continue to The author acknowledges the valua-
be allowed to open its labour market be protected for the time being while ble research assistance of Fulvio
faster, or even lift all restrictions Germany could start enjoying the Mulatero in the prepartion of this
immediately, if it chose to do so. benefits of skilled migration imme- policy brief.

REFERENCES
Abdurrahman Aydemir and George Borjas, “A Comparative Analysis of the Labor Market Impact of International Migration: Canada, Mexico, and
the United States”, Working Paper, April 2006.
Michel Beine, Frédéric Docquier, and Hillel Rapoport, “Brain Drain and LDCs' Growth: Winners and Losers”, IZA Discussion Paper 819, 2003.
Tito Boeri and Herbert Brücker, “Why are Europeans so tough on migrants?”, Economic Policy – A European Forum, 44, 629-703, 2005.
Holger Bonin, “Wage and Employment Effects of Immigration to Germany: Evidence from a Skill Group Approach”, IZA Discussion Paper 1875, 2005.
George Borjas, “The Labor Demand Curve Is Downward Sloping: Re-examining the Impact of Immigration on the Labor Market”, Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 118(4), 1335-1376, 2003.
Syvie Charlot, Carl Gaigné, Frédéric Robert-Nicoud, and Jacques-François Thisse, “Agglomeration and welfare: The core-periphery model in the
light of Bentham, Kaldor and Rawls”, Journal of Public Economics, 90, 325-47, 2006.
Jean-Christophe Dumont and Georges Lemaître, “Counting Immigrants and Expatriates: A New Perspective”, OECD Social, Employment, and
Migration Working Paper, 2004.
European Commission, “Policy Plan on Legal Migration”, COM(2005) 669 final.
Simonetta Longhi, Peter Nijkamp, and Jacques Poot, “A Meta-Analytic Assessment of the Effect of Immigration on Wages”, Journal of Economic
Surveys, 19(3), 451-477, 2005.
Simonetta Longhi, Peter Nijkamp, and Jacques Poot, “The Impact of Immigration on the Employment of Natives in Regional Labour Markets: A
Meta-Analysis”, IZA Discussion Paper 2044, 2006.
Gianmarco Ottaviano and Giovanni Peri, “Rethinking the Gains from Immigration: Theory and Evidence from the US”, Working Paper, January 2006.
Patrick Weil, “A Flexible Framework for a Plural Europe”, in The Hampton Court Agenda: A Social Model for Europe, Policy Network, 2006.

Bruegel is a European think tank devoted to international economics, which started operations in Brussels in 2005.
It is supported by European governments and international corporations. Bruegel’s aim is to contribute to the quality
of economic policymaking in Europe through open, fact-based and policy-relevant research, analysis and discussion.

The Bruegel Policy Brief series is published under the editorial responsibility of Jean Pisani-Ferry, Director.
Opinions expressed in this publication are those of the author(s) alone.
Visit www.bruegel.org for information on Bruegel's activities and publications.
Bruegel - Rue de la Charité 33, B-1210 Brussels - phone (+32) 2 227 4210 info@bruegel.org

Você também pode gostar