Você está na página 1de 15

International Journal of Auditing

Int. J. Audit. 8: 263–277 (2004)

Discretionary Pricing in a
Monopolistic Audit Market
Greg Shailer,1 Lorne Cummings,2 Eroni Vatuloka3 and
Stephen Welch
1
School of Business and Information Management, The Australian National
University.
2
Department of Accounting and Finance, Macquarie University
3
Auditor-General, Republic of Fiji

This paper investigates the possibility of discretionary


audit pricing in a monopolistic public sector market. The
underlying rational of the fee determinant model has different
expectations (in terms of profit-seeking behaviour, loss
functions and liability exposure) from that implicitly em-
ployed in the broader audit fee literature, but incorporates the
same variables. The opportunity for discretionary pricing is
considered in the context of different types of auditees for
which the auditor has varying degrees of monopoly power.
Results are consistent with audits having lower (higher) input
cost where loss exposure is lowest (highest) and acceptable
audit risk is highest (lowest), and with the cost savings being
appropriated by the auditor where monopoly power is the
greatest and with fee discounting for agencies for which the
auditor faces the greatest threat of competition.

Key words: Audit fees, public sector auditing, monopoly.

SUMMARY ences, between auditees, in the strength of


the ANAO’s monopoly. Any propensity for rent
The Australian National Audit Office is the extraction may vary across auditees because of the
statutory auditor of (federal) government-funded differential threat of competition.
entities. From 1991, the ANAO was able to charge This paper investigates this potential for
fees for its financial statement audits, thus creating discretionary audit pricing in the context of
an opportunity for monopolistic rent-extraction. expectedly different cost structures for the different
There is provision, however, for incorporated types of auditees for which the auditor has varying
entities (particularly those with commercial degrees of monopoly power and faces potentially
interests) to obtain ministerial approval for the conflicting (mitigating) loss exposure. The different
appointment of a private sector auditor. This types of agencies are government departments
differential threat of competition creates differ- (which pose the least threat of competition),
statutory authorities and government business
Correspondence to: Greg Shailer, School of Business and
enterprises (GBES, which pose the greatest threat
Information Management, Hanna Neumann Bldg #21, The of competition). The study is for the years 1992
Australian National University, Canberra ACT 0200, Australia to 1994.

ISSN 1090–6738
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004. Published by Blackwell Publishing, 9600 Garsington
Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.
264 G. Shailer et al.

Based on the traditional audit fee model with the seminal study by Simunic (1980), which
approach, which uses auditee size, complexity and was motivated by the suggestion of non-
risk proxies for audit input determinants, we look competitive pricing behaviour by private sector
for differences in: (1) constant pricing components audit firms. In this study, however, the auditor is
for different agency types; and (2) the partial slope not a profit-seeker, has a different loss criterion and
coefficients of variables intended to proxy agency- is not exposed to loss sharing through legal
based audit input determinants. The variables liability.
considered as cost drivers include organisational Following Simunic’s investigation of possible
structure and size (assets and expenditures), asset collusive pricing and rent extraction, other audit
composition and audit qualifications. fee studies have contemplated the possible effects
Complexity and size measures, as proxies for of imperfect competition, such as switching costs
audit inputs (costs) appear to differ significantly (e.g. Francis, 1984; Francis & Stokes, 1986), but
between auditee types. These results suggest that present little evidence of collusive or monopolistic
other audit fee studies concerned with price effects. This study extends the audit fee literature
premia should consider the likelihood of different beyond contested markets. The study is partly
slope coefficients for engagement size and com- motivated by anecdotal claims by some auditees’
plexity proxies for different types of engagements, managers of perceived discretionary pricing prac-
in addition to using classification variables to tices by the monopolistic auditor.
measure constant effects. The constant effects for The next section briefly describes the insti-
different auditee types are higher for departments tutional setting of this study and section 3
and lower for GBEs (relative to statutory discusses how fee determinants may apply in this
authorities). setting, followed by the usual sequence of data
Given the prevailing weaknesses in audit fee description, analysis and discussion.
model specifications, it cannot be confidently
concluded that discretionary pricing is present.
2. THE INSTITUTIONAL SETTING
However, the results are consistent with audits
having lower (higher) input cost where the The Auditor-General, who is served by the
auditor’s loss exposure is lowest (highest) and Australian National Audit Office (ANAO), is the
acceptable audit risk is highest (lowest), and with statutorily prescribed auditor of Commonwealth
the cost savings being appropriated by the auditor public sector entities in Australia. The portfolio
where monopoly power is the greatest and with fee of auditees can be divided into Commonwealth
discounting for agencies for which the auditor Statutory Authorities (SAs), government owned
faces the greatest threat of competition. trading corporations and departments.1 The
trading corporations and several SAs are identified
by the Department of Finance as Government
1. INTRODUCTION
Business Enterprises (GBEs), which have a profit
This study investigates potential discretionary objective.
pricing in a monopolistic government audit Since the financial year ending 30 June 1991, the
market. Although we use public sector data, we ANAO was permitted to charge fees to all auditees
believe the novel opportunity to examine potential for financial statement audits while enjoying
discretionary pricing is salient to any audit market monopoly rights to conduct such audits. No
where reduced competition is a prospect. previous study of monopoly is known to exist in
Our approach generally follows the methods the literature on audit markets in either the public
typical of previous audit fee determinant studies. or private sector and so the three-year window
Fees are regressed on proxies for engagement considered in this study (1992–1994) provides a
variables (size, complexity and risk) that are rare opportunity to examine audit pricing in the
expected to affect audit inputs. The model is absence of competition.2
simplified by the absence of auditor differences, Except for GBEs, public sector entities generally
allowing a narrower focus on auditee attributes are not perceived as having wealth or profit
where the opportunity for discretionary pricing oriented motives. The monitoring of expenditure
varies with types of auditees in relation to the and budget constraints by non-profit entities
strength of the auditor’s monopoly position. In implies a concern for cost containment and
this sense, our study has some complementarity possible dissatisfaction with audit fees (Roberts

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Int. J. Audit. 8: 263–277 (2004)


Discretionary Pricing in a Monopolistic Audit Market 265

et al., 1990). Some auditees have criticised the fees sensitivity to comparisons with private sector
charged to them by the ANAO, arguing that fees auditors is consistent with a concern for the threat
were not sufficiently related to costs and that of competition.
differences in fees appeared arbitrary. While the Claims by some auditee managers that audit fees
criticisms are not publicly documented, they are were excessive or discriminatory did not identify
acknowledged by a previous Auditor-General any particular motivation for such behaviour.
(1988–95) in Taylor (1996). Permitted fee-charging However, the ANAO had previously sought
by the ANAO was intended to be a cost recovery increased resourcing to expand its performance
mechanism but the concept of cost remained auditing activities for which it could not charge
undefined, providing considerable latitude for and so had to fund from its annual budget. It has
how fees may have been levied by the ANAO. been a regular feature in Auditor-General annual
Prompted in part by these concerns, this study reports, at least since 1991, to note favourably
investigates the extent to which differences in the increase in resources (both in absolute and
prices charged to auditees can be explained by relative terms) applied to performance audits. This
engagement specific factors, and tests for necessarily required a reduction in the proportion
discretionary price adjustments based on agency of net resources applied to financial statement
type. audits and this was accomplished by charging
audit fees.
In 1989–1990, the ANAO reportedly applied 85%
2.1 Discretionary pricing and competition
(gross) of its resources to financial statement and
The ANAO has actively lobbied to retain regulatory audits and recovered 28% of costs
monopoly rights to audit all types of public sector through audit fees. In 1991 the application of
agencies, as evidenced in their responses to resources to financial statements audits fell to 66%
government attempts to exclude the Auditor- with recoveries of 32%. In 1992 these proportions
General as the sole auditor of several agencies.3 were 64% and 40% respectively and in 1993
While the ANAO ostensibly retains the right to they were 71% and 65% respectively.4 That audit
audit all Commonwealth public sector agencies, fees were merely ‘cost recoveries’ is not obvious.
the capacity for some agencies to seek the For example, the ANAO’s 1992 annual report
appointment of private sector auditors is an (Auditor-General, 1992: 128) indicates that audit
implicit threat of competition that may influence fees of $17.8 m were received against expenditures
ANAO actions and pricing decisions. from appropriations of $17.4 m for financial
Departments constitute a class of agencies for statement audits in 1991–1992. In 1993 $31.6 m
which the ANAO has the greatest opportunity for was reportedly collected against expenditures of
extracting rents because it enjoys its strongest $27 m and in 1994 $31.6 m was collected against
monopoly position with respect to their financial expenditures of $26 m. The mixture of accrual
statement audits. Legislative provisions allow accounting for expenditures and cash based
most government corporations to seek ministerial reporting of fees, however, obscures the nature of
approval for the appointment of an alternative this relationship.
auditor from the private sector, reducing the
ANAO’s monopoly with respect to such agencies
3. FACTORS THAT MAY INFLUENCE
and so curtailing opportunity for extracting rents.
AUDIT FEES
The ANAO may have a competitive incentive
to show that they deliver ‘value for money’ to Research regarding engagement-specific factors
government corporations. This may induce fee that may influence fees has focused primarily on
discounting, thus eroding the nexus between audit proxies for auditee size and complexity, and
inputs and fees. The current Auditor-General, Pat engagement risks. The significant proxies have
Barrett, observes that public sector auditors are differed between public and private sector studies.
vulnerable to criticisms regarding their activities Both are examined here due to the diversity of
and that they must seek to maintain the confidence public sector agencies considered in this study. For
of their various stakeholders. He suggests that this example, GBEs have a strong commercial focus
might involve greater commercial focus and re- and so their accounting systems should have much
examination of the nature and scope of their audit in common with private sector auditees. Similarly,
products (Barrett, 1996, 143). This implied government-owned corporations are subject to the

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Int. J. Audit. 8: 263–277 (2004)


266 G. Shailer et al.

reporting and audit provisions of the Corporations complexity if they attract more extensive audit
Act. The regulatory aspects of the financial procedures or level of testing.
statement audits of all government agencies and The extension of audit fee modelling into the
the requirement that they be audited using ANAO public sector has focused mainly on the
standards creates sufficient ambiguity in the nature competitive US local government audits, as
of their audits that the findings of both public and illustrated by Baber et al. (1987); Copley (1989,
private sector studies are relevant in suggesting 1991); Rubin (1988, 1992); and Sanders et al. (1995).
potential proxies for fee determinants. Some proxies used for size, complexity and risk
Size and complexity variables found to be in the private sector studies do not have direct
significant in private sector studies are listed in equivalents in the public sector. The size and
Table 1. The identified studies provide strong complexity variables found to be significant in
evidence that auditee size (measured by total these public sector studies are described in Table 2.
assets or revenues) and audit complexity (proxied These studies also provide strong evidence that
by number of subsidiaries, foreign assets or current auditee size (measured by civilian population or
asset items divided by total assets) can explain a revenues) and audit complexity (proxied by
substantial proportion of the variation in audit number of services provided by the auditee) can
fees.5 Asset composition measures, such as explain a substantial proportion of the variation in
inventories and receivables or current assets on audit fees.
total assets, are typically adopted as risk proxies. Much of the discussion of these engagement
However, as suggested in Jubb et al. (1996), asset variables in the literature has moved away from
composition ratios can reasonably identify audit the rationale developed in Simunic (1980).

Table 1: Significant size and complexity variables in listed company audit fee studies
Study Complexity/risk Auditee size
Entity complexity Asset composition
(% of total assets)
Simunic (1980) Number of subsidiaries Foreign assets
Industry diversification
Taylor and Baker (1981) Number of subsidiaries Total assets
Francis (1984) Number of subsidiaries Current assets Total assets
Simon (1985)
Francis & Stokes (1986) Number of subsidiaries Inventories and receivables Total assets
Palmrose (1986) Number of locations Total assets
Number of reports by
auditor
Francis & Simon (1987) Number of subsidiaries Foreign assets Total assets
Inventories and receivables
Simon & Francis (1988) Number of subsidiaries Inventories and receivable Total assets
Foreign subsidiaries
(% of total subsidiaries)
Haskins & Williams (1988) Number of subsidiaries Total assets
Net income
Revenue
Gist (1992) Number of audit locations Total assets
Chan et al. (1993) Number of subsidiaries Revenue
Ownership diversification
Anderson & Zeghal (1994) Number of foreign Inventories and receivables Total assets
subsidiaries
Number of subsidiaries
Pong & Whittington (1994) Number of subsidiaries Total assets
Revenue
Butterworth & Houghton (1995) Number of subsidiaries Total assets
Jubb et al. (1996) Number of subsidiaries Inventories and receivables Total assets

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Int. J. Audit. 8: 263–277 (2004)


Discretionary Pricing in a Monopolistic Audit Market 267

Table 2: Significant size and complexity variables in public sector audit fee studies
Study Complexity Scale
Baber et al. (1987) Civilian population
Rubin (1988) Index of services provided Revenues of auditee
Civilian population
Copley (1989, 1991) Number of services provided Civilian population
Rubin (1992) Index of services provided Revenues of auditee
Type and number of reports issued Civilian population
Sanders et al. (1995) Civilian population

Simunic’s independent variables were intended to Third, the auditor and most auditees are not
capture two aspects of audit pricing: differences in exposed to legal liability for losses in the manner
loss exposure across auditees and differences prevalent in most other studies. The ANAO and its
in the proportion of losses borne by different staff have zero litigation risk for the audit of any
auditors. Central to Simunic’s analysis was the agency.6 Therefore, any loss transfer function rests
concept of risk-neutral profit-seekers (auditors solely in the political domain. This is intuitively
and auditees) exposed to joint and several appealing if the consequences of losses are also
liability for losses attributable to defects in primarily political.
audited financial statements. In our analysis, the
underlying model has some critical differences
3.1 Size measures
regarding profit-seeking, the nature of losses and
liability. The effect of auditee size on audit fees has
First, neither the auditor nor most auditees are dominated in the previous empirical results. The
profit-seekers in the usual sense. While GBEs have interest in size effects follows largely from Simunic
an identified profit motive, this is not shared by (1980) who conjectures that total assets are the size
agencies funded through budget appropriations. measure most closely related to the auditor’s
However, as described in subsection 2.1, the possible loss exposure which, he argues, drives
ANAO had some incentive for rent-seeking from the audit production function. Additional to our
financial statement audits to satisfy its internally argument that the auditor’s loss exposure varies
generated objectives in the performance audit area. with auditee-type, there remains the likelihood
Rent-seeking may, however, be ameliorated by that the extent of exposure within auditee-type will
potential political costs and threats to the auditor’s vary with some measures of auditee size.
monopoly position. The expected cost-benefit Later studies, however, seem to focus more on
trade-off for the auditor thus has strong non- the relationship between auditee size and the scale
financial elements. It is argued that the nature of of audit work, without reference to the auditor’s
this trade-off, and therefore pricing behaviour, potential loss exposure. Pong & Whittington (1994)
varies primarily with auditee type. argue that both assets and revenue may be relevant
Second, The nature of losses attributable to in this regard, capturing different aspects of the
deficient financial statements is closely related to audit work. Most public sector studies have
the concept of ownership and the purpose of the adopted the scale construct and used civilian
enterprise. In the public sector context, the absence populations to measure size. Rubin (1988, 1992)
of profit-seeking shareholders and the political found revenues accounted for a large proportion of
dimensions of programme delivery create a market the variation in municipal audit fees.7 It is plausible
based on political dimensions. Potential political that these measures also reflect the possible
costs (losses) may vary with the social and electoral non-financial loss exposure in a political setting.8
sensitivity of programmes, the level of resources Because revenues (appropriations) of budget-
consumed, and the extent of parliamentary funded agencies equate to total expenditures,
oversight. These potential losses should motivate total expenditure is the most comparable measure
different levels of acceptable audit risk and across all ANAO auditees. Because residual
consequent inputs. Acceptable audit risks are losses from liquidation are not a concern for
identified in 3.3. stakeholders in this setting, we contend that

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Int. J. Audit. 8: 263–277 (2004)


268 G. Shailer et al.

expenditures are more likely than total assets to procedures and the remaining risk of error (see
reflect auditee and auditor loss exposure for public Simunic, 1980). Foreign assets and inventories and
sector agencies.9 receivables are largely irrelevant for most of the
If size variables reflect user and auditor public sector agencies considered here. Current
loss exposure, then they should affect audit assets as a proportion of total assets (CA/TA) is
planning through materiality judgments. Nelson considered here as either a complexity measure
(1993: 38) states that the ANAO used total or risk proxy. It is also possible that this variable
payments or receipts as the materiality bases represents decreased audit complexity – its
for departments’ (cash-based) transaction state- reciprocal, the proportion of non-current assets,
ments.10 The 1990 efficiency audit report by the may pertain to complexity due to regulatory testing
independent auditor of the ANAO (Sharpe, 1990: of acquisitions, dispositions and disposals of assets
14) indicates that budgeted hours were allocated for many government agencies. If this is the case,
to each ANAO audit team on the basis CA/TA should appear to be fee decreasing and
of the materiality of the major account category be similarly relevant to all agencies. If it proxies
to be covered by the team (ignoring the risk for residual risks of undetected misstatements
of material error). Combining these two obser- (Simunic, 1980) CA/TA will be fee increasing.
vations implies that budgeted hours, and therefore The distinction between some complexity and
audit costs and presumably fees, should be closely risk proxies is more ambiguous in the government
related to the total payments of such auditees. audit setting with politically motivated stake-
holders. Audit qualifications are often identified
as significant in fee determinant models (e.g.
3.2 Complexity and risk proxies
Simunic, 1980; Francis & Stokes, 1986; Francis &
Using the number of subsidiaries as a complexity Simon, 1987; Simon & Francis, 1988; Butterworth
proxy is not directly applicable for government & Houghton, 1995). It is usually expected that
departments and SAs. Copley (1989, 1991) and qualifications are fee increasing as the auditor
Rubin (1988, 1992) identify significant complexity seeks additional evidence to justify the quali-
proxies in the form of the number of services or an fication or resolve disagreements. It is suggested in
index of services provided by local governments. Jubb et al. (1996) that a qualification may reduce
However, a service index for distinguishing the the risk to private sector auditors by reducing
variety of welfare, regulatory and commercial litigation risk. While this is not directly relevant to
auditees involved at the federal level cannot be the ANAO due to the absence of litigation risk, it
constructed objectively due to the difficulty of may be similarly suggested that accusations of
disaggregating and weighting the elements of the audit deficiencies by stakeholders may be avoided
broad service classes used in earlier studies. The or weakened if a report is qualified. Under these
structure of most government departments, in circumstances, a qualification may be associated
terms of divisions and sections, is a product of the with reduced fees. Risk abatement may also be
number of programmes that they support. While sought by ‘appeasement’ – reducing fees to reduce
it involves some subjectivity, the number of auditee reactions to qualifications. Any mixture of
programmes can be estimated from agencies’ ‘appeasement’ and ‘cost’ effects across auditees
annual reports. This measure may be comparable may induce an absence of statistically significant
to the number of subsidiaries and has similar association between qualifications and the
import to the service index measures used in variation in audit fees. There is also the potentially
previous public sector studies. The complexity of confounding effect of incentives for the monopolist
an organisation is measured as the number of auditor to signal their value in the political
subsidiaries for incorporated auditees (GBEs and accountability arena. Identifying misstatements
most SAs) and the number of programmes for and presenting qualifications may be a signal of
unincorporated auditees (departments and some audit effectiveness or value. In this context,
SAs). qualifications may be fee-decreasing if the
Asset composition measures, such as inventories auditor curtails the level of audit work once the
and receivables, current assets and foreign assets, desired qualification is identified. Overall,
have played an important part in private sector qualification effects may be idiosyncratic to
studies although they are typically intended as risk engagements and we offer no prediction of the
proxies because of the more demanding audit direction of any affect.

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Int. J. Audit. 8: 263–277 (2004)


Discretionary Pricing in a Monopolistic Audit Market 269

3.3 Agency type observe a negative adjustment to the regression


constant while the low audit risk requirement
In a discussion of the application of risk-based should result in a higher size coefficient.
auditing to government audits, Nelson (1993) Audit pricing for incorporated SAs may differ
comments that different levels of acceptable audit from the unincorporated SAs. Different reporting
risk pertain to different types of ANAO auditees. requirements may increase the auditor costs if it
Nelson notes (p. 37) that acceptable audit risk for requires additional expertise or has higher set-up
GBEs is ‘low’ (which he equated to ‘five percent costs. Consequently, a dummy variable is included
risk’). SAs generally are also given ‘low’ acceptable for incorporated SAs.
audit risk rating unless there are exceptional
circumstances. For departments, acceptable audit
3.4 The model
risk is set at ‘medium’ for expenditure and revenue
departments and ‘medium’ to ‘high’ for The most appropriate form of model summarized
policy departments with ‘high’ used only in in Equation (1) is considered in the context of the
exceptional circumstances. Therefore, audit costs data characteristics.
should be lower for departments and higher
for SAs and GBEs. This should be reflected in ÈÊ loss exposure ˆ
smaller coefficients for size measures for
audit fee = f ÍÁ expenditure˜ ,
departments. ÍÁ ˜
If Nelson’s differences in acceptable audit risk ÎÍË total assets ¯
for different agency types reflect the perceived loss Ê complexity risk ˆ
exposure of the auditor, then the analysis is Á incorporation ˜
complicated by the potentially off-setting effect of Á ˜
the auditor’s varying monopoly power. If this Á subsidiaries programs˜ ,
opportunity for rent extraction is exploited by not Á CA TA ˜
passing on the reduction in audit costs to GBEs and Á ˜
Ë qualification ¯
departments, then the cheaper audit will not be
observable in the absence of any controls for Ê monopoly powerˆ ˘
Á ˜
discretionary fee adjustments. Ë agency type ¯ ˙˚ (1)
Addressing this design issue requires some
assumptions pertaining to the implementation of How the variables should be combined or
discretionary pricing. Fully ad hoc pricing should transformed is partly an empirical issue and is
result in low explanatory power for the audit considered further after reviewing the nature of the
fee models. Systematic discretionary pricing may data.
be through lump-sum adjustments to fees or
by manipulating input prices. Lump-sum
4. DATA
adjustments based on agency types may be
revealed as adjustments to the constant term in the Data was obtained for the different types of
fee regression model by using dummy variables agencies for the financial years 1992–1994 from
for agency types. Input prices can be manipulated the annual reports to Parliament of the individual
by setting different auditee-dependent charge agencies.11 Sample sizes are given in Table 3.
rates for individual audit staff but this would Statutory authorities are the largest group.12
increase the observability (by auditees) of the rent Descriptive statistics of the basic variables are
appropriation and increase the auditor’s reported, by agency type, in Table 4.
administrative costs. In terms of expenditure, departments are much
Overall, if Nelson’s descriptions of agencies’ risk larger than other agencies on average, while GBEs
differentials are applicable for the study period, dominate in terms of total assets. In terms of
then we should observe smaller size coefficients CA/TA, number of programmes and number
for departments. If systematic discretionary audit of subsidiaries, there appears to be little to
pricing is practised to capture cost differentials, distinguish the agency subsets.
then we also should observe a higher constant term The much higher proportion (23%) of qualified
for departments. If the higher competitive threat reports for GBEs (compared to 18% of departments
for GBEs results in fee discounting, we should and 7% of SAs) is not attributable to incorporation

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Int. J. Audit. 8: 263–277 (2004)


270 G. Shailer et al.

as only 10% of all incorporated entities were all are of a nature that precluded testing. Therefore,
qualified. Five of the six qualifications for GBEs they are most likely to be fee-reducing. The
pertain to the valuation of assets through majority of SAs’ two ‘subject to’, three ‘unable to
uncertainties (‘subject to’) that appear more related form an opinion’ and six ‘except for’ qualifications
to policy (the transfer of functions) than accounting are likely to have required the collection of
or financial matters – thus they are unlikely to have additional evidence to identify the issues or
much effect on audit effort. The sixth qualification discrepancies involved, consequently increasing
is ‘unable to form an opinion’ regarding going- audit costs.13 Given these differences, the dummy
concern based on uncertainties regarding the variable for qualification is coded separately for
entity’s future control over assets because of muted each agency type.
plans for privatisation, departments’ qualifications
consist of three ‘subject to’ and two ‘unable to 4.1 Transformations
form an opinion’. While the former pertain to
expenditures and the latter to revenue collections, The statistical properties of the data do not signal
any particular cause for concern although the size
variables exhibit the degree of skewness and
heteroscedasticity present in most previous
studies.
Table 3: Number of ANAO audit fee cases by type The audit fee and size variables are typically
of agency transformed logarithmically in regressions against
Year Departments GBEs SAs n audit fees.14 Such transformations allow an
(excluding GBEs) apparently linear model to be developed using
OLS regression. Logarithmic transformations were
1992 9 8 48 65
tested for fees against all potential explanatory
1993 10 8 50 68
1994 9 7 49 65 variables and linear relationships are observed
(within logs) for expenditure and total assets. Some
Total 28 23 147 198
slight improvement in linearity within logs is

Table 4: Descriptions of basic explanatory variables by type of agency


n Mean Standard Minimum Maximum
deviation
Departments
Expenditure ($million) 28 3,323 5,499 29 17,620
Total assets ($million) 28 560 827 16 3,119
CA/TA 28 0.28 0.31 0.01 0.97
Qualification (0,1) 28 0.18 0.39 0 1
Number of programmes 28 5.79 2.23 3 11
Statutory authorities
Expenditure ($million) 147 103 177 0.26 875
Total assets ($million) 147 120 265 0.10 1,329
CA/TA 147 0.37 0.33 0.00 1.00
Incorporated entity (0,1) 147 0.69 0.46 0 1
Qualification (0,1) 147 0.07 0.26 0 1
Number of subsidiaries (incorporated SAs) 102 1.88 6.97 0 43
Number of programmes (unincorporated SAs) 45 4.49 2.38 1 10
GBEs
Expenditure ($million) 23 557 760 61 2,568
Total assets ($million) 28 1,200 1,151 26 3,481
CA/TA 23 0.34 0.28 0.08 0.98
Incorporated entity (0,1) 23 1 0 1 1
Qualification (0,1) 23 0.26 0.45 0 1
Number of subsidiaries 23 5.91 8.90 0 24

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Int. J. Audit. 8: 263–277 (2004)


Discretionary Pricing in a Monopolistic Audit Market 271

observed for subsidiaries and programmes against 5.2 Multicollinearity


fees but no improvement was observed for CA/TA
and so, consistent with previous studies, CA/TA is The possibility of multicollinearity is raised above
not transformed.15 where larger bivariate correlations are observed
among size and complexity measures in Table 5.
Based on condition indices and variance
4.2 Correlations proportions, there is no evidence of serious
Financial statement-based data typically presents multicollinearity for the regressions. Hair et al.
high levels of correlation between variables. As (1995: 153) advises that the threshold value for
expected, Table 5 indicates particularly high condition indices is usually in the range 15 to 30.
correlations (99%) between the competing size A collinearity problem is indicated where a
measures, log of total assets and log of condition index accounts for more than 0.90 of the
expenditures. The high correlations between the variance of two or more coefficients (not the
agency dummies and the continuous variables for constant). For Model 1, only dimension 15 has
each agency is of little concern given that the values at this level, but only one continuous
dummies are designed as adjustments to the variable (department expenditures) is associated
constant term in the regression. Of greater concern with it. The other high value is for the constant-
for the planned regression models are the high adjusting dummy for departments. Similar results
correlations (in bold in Table 5) between some are observed for departments and GBEs for Model
size measures and CA/TA for all agencies and 2 (dimensions 14 and 15). Consequently, we
programmes and size for departments. Each of conclude that multicollinearity does not pose a
these correlations is highly significant. The significant problem for these regressions.
potential for multicollinearity posed by these
correlations will be assessed after presentation of
6. DISCUSSION
the regression results.
Complexity effects appear to differ across agency
types. Incorporation is fee-increasing for SAs.
5. REGRESSIONS
Although this may also apply for GBEs, all of
The two primary regressions, differing only which are incorporated, this cannot be controlled
according to the size variable employed, are separately from the GBE dummy. The positive
reported in Table 6. The power of each model is coefficient of programmes (the complexity proxy for
reasonable (multiple R of 0.94 and 0.89 with highly unincorporated agencies) on departments’ and
significant F statistics) and an R2 of 0.88 the unincorporated SAs’ fees is consistent with prior
expenditure-based Model 1 and 0.78 for the TA- results for contested municipal audits (e.g. Rubin,
based Model 2. 1988, 1992; Copley, 1989, 1991). The equivalent
The remaining discussion concentrates on Model variable for incorporated agencies (subsidiaries) is
1, which is generally much stronger and in not significant in Model 1. (Although both
accordance with our expectations regarding the programmes and subsidiaries are significant for
greater suitability of expenditures (compared to Model 2, this may be a consequence of the poorer
total assets) as a loss-exposure proxy. size specification provided by total assets).
CA/TA is significantly fee decreasing for
departments and SAs, consistent with it acting
5.1 Model specification tests
as a proxy for reduced complexity or lower
Regression of the pooled data assumes that audit compliance auditing requirements. This is
input and fee decisions are made in responses consistent with the conjectured compliance
to individual engagement circumstances each requirements for asset acquisition and custody.
period, independent of previous period decisions. This distinguishes the use of asset decomposition
Differences between years were tested for Model 1 measures in private sector studies which typically
with separate regressions, reported in Table 7. identified the proportions of current assets as
Although significance levels vary, the results are fee-increasing risk proxies.
generally consistent with the pooled results in Rather than interpreting the qualified coefficients
terms of explanatory power and the signs on as risk proxies, they appear to reflect the likely
coefficients. impact on audit effort that coincidentally differed

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Int. J. Audit. 8: 263–277 (2004)


272

Table 5: Correlations of regressions variables


Incorporated Department GBE Qualified – Qualified Qualified CA/TA – CA/TA CA/TA Total assets Total Total Expenditures Expenditures Expenditures Subsidiaries Programmes

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004


SA department – GBE – SA department – GBE – SA – department assets assets – department – GBE – SA
– GBE – SA
Incorporated 0.000 0.264 0.003 0.352 0.173 0.000 0.454 0.000 0.000 0.269 0.000 0.000 0.269 0.000 0.017 0.000
SA (0,1)
Department -0.49 0.039 0.000 0.315 0.168 0.000 0.117 0.000 0.000 0.039 0.000 0.000 0.039 0.000 0.018 0.000
(0,1)
GBE (0,1) 0.05 -0.15 0.414 0.000 0.218 0.180 0.000 0.000 0.039 0.000 0.000 0.040 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
Qualified – -0.03 0.40 -0.058 0.691 0.585 0.776 0.535 0.056 0.000 0.416 0.000 0.000 0.415 0.000 0.352 0.000
department
(0,1)
Qualified – 0.03 -0.07 0.49 -0.03 0.549 0.514 0.000 0.036 0.317 0.000 0.000 0.318 0.000 0.000 0.177 0.070
GBE (0,1)
Qualified – 0.07 -0.10 -0.09 -0.04 -0.04 0.370 0.350 0.481 0.170 0.220 0.001 0.170 0.219 0.002 0.149 0.922
SA (0,1)
CA/TA – -0.32 0.65 -0.10 0.02 -0.05 -0.06 0.309 0.002 0.000 0.181 0.000 0.000 0.181 0.000 0.126 0.000
department
CA/TA – 0.01 -0.11 0.76 -0.04 0.26 -0.07 -0.07 0.001 0.119 0.000 0.000 0.119 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.005
GBE
CA/TA – SA 0.36 -0.34 -0.31 -0.14 -0.15 0.05 -0.23 -0.23 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.031 0.000
Total assets – -0.49 0.99 -0.15 0.44 -0.07 -0.10 0.62 -0.11 -0.34 0.040 0.000 0.000 0.040 0.000 0.019 0.000
department
(lg)
Total assets – 0.04 -0.15 0.99 -0.06 0.49 -0.09 -0.10 0.75 -0.31 -0.15 0.000 0.040 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
GBE (lg)
Total assets – 0.39 -0.66 -0.59 -0.26 -0.29 0.24 -0.43 -0.45 0.42 -0.66 -0.59 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.726 0.000
SA (lg)
Expenditure – -0.49 0.99 -0.15 0.42 -0.07 -0.10 0.63 -0.11 -0.34 0.99 -0.15 -0.66 0.040 0.000 0.019 0.000
department
(lg)
Expenditure – 0.04 -0.15 0.99 -0.06 0.49 -0.09 -0.10 0.75 -0.31 -0.15 0.99 -0.59 -0.15 0.000 0.000 0.000
GBE (lg)
Expenditure – 0.34 -0.67 -0.60 -0.26 -0.29 0.22 -0.44 -0.46 0.45 -0.67 -0.60 0.99 -0.67 -0.60 0.441 0.001
SA (lg)
Subsidiaries 0.15 -0.17 0.37 -0.06 0.10 0.10 -0.11 0.34 -0.15 -0.17 0.39 -0.03 -0.17 0.38 -0.06 0.000
(lg)
Programmes -0.88 0.58 -0.27 0.29 -0.13 0.01 0.31 -0.20 -0.28 0.59 -0.26 -0.29 0.59 -0.26 -0.24 -0.30
(lg)
Notes: n = 198 Coefficients are below diagonal Significance levels (2-tailed) are above diagonal.

Int. J. Audit. 8: 263–277 (2004)


G. Shailer et al.
Discretionary Pricing in a Monopolistic Audit Market 273

Table 6: Audit fee (lg) regressions


Model 1 Model 2
Coefficients Significance* Coefficients Significance*
R 0.941 0.890
Adjusted R2 0.876 0.775
F test (Anova) 100.453 0.000 49.536 0.000
Constant 1.101 0.000 1.830 0.000
Department (0,1) 1.153 0.012 1.394 0.070
GBE (0,1) -3.191 0.000 -0.486 0.548
Qualified – department (0,1) -0.154 0.162 -0.178 0.275
Qualified – GBE (0,1) 0.012 0.900 0.061 0.645
Qualified – SA (0,1) 0.262 0.000 0.206 0.028
Incorporated SAs (0,1) 0.180 0.014 0.200 0.043
Subsidiaries (lg) 0.067 0.220 0.160 0.032
Programmes (lg) 0.192 0.079 0.606 0.000
CA/TA – department -0.305 0.028 -0.205 0.290
CA/TA –GBE 0.166 0.307 0.029 0.895
CA/TA – SA -0.329 0.000 -0.208 0.005
Expenditures – department (lg) 0.346 0.000
Expenditures – GBE (lg) 0.835 0.000
Expenditures – SA (lg) 0.469 0.000
Total assets – department (lg) 0.212 0.018
Total assets – GBE (lg) 0.414 0.000
Total assets – SA (lg) 0.360 0.000
*2-tailed significance.

Table 7: Model 1 regressions by year


1992 (n = 65) 1993 (n = 68) 1994 (n = 65)
Coefficients Significance* Coefficients Significance* Coefficients Significance*
R 0.936 0.949 0.955
Adjusted R2 0.842 0.874 0.889
F test (Anova) 25.377 0.000 34.347 0.000 37.434 0.000
Constant 0.946 0.012 1.305 0.000 1.104 0.000
Department (0,1) 1.682 0.097 1.122 0.169 0.812 0.273
GBE (0,1) -3.799 0.020 -3.044 0.032 -2.260 0.139
Qualified – 0.039 0.889 -0.029 0.854 -0.726 0.003
department (0,1)
Qualified – GBE (0,1) 0.174 0.523 0.090 0.701 -0.051 0.761
Qualified – SA (0,1) 0.203 0.100 0.347 0.011 0.345 0.007
Incorporated SAs (0,1) 0.194 0.190 0.170 0.180 0.217 0.180
Subsidiaries (lg) 0.053 0.641 0.058 0.555 0.116 0.200
Programmes (lg) 0.241 0.267 0.135 0.477 0.266 0.257
CA/TA – department -0.273 0.258 -0.394 0.178 -0.566 0.041
CA/TA – GBE 0.352 0.267 0.214 0.408 -0.194 0.589
CA/TA – SA -0.256 0.019 -0.336 0.001 -0.413 0.000
Expenditures – 0.286 0.009 0.332 0.000 0.403 0.000
department (lg)
Expenditures – 0.916 0.000 0.794 0.000 0.735 0.000
GBE (lg)
Expenditures – SA (lg) 0.480 0.000 0.448 0.000 0.466 0.000
*2-tailed significance.

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Int. J. Audit. 8: 263–277 (2004)


274 G. Shailer et al.

across agencies but are not attributable to for qualifications and agency type do not capture
differences in agency type per se. The only the intricacies involved in the qualifications or
significant audit qualification control is for SAs, agency structures. These limitations, however, are
which has the more onerous qualifications, and is not unique to this study.
fee-increasing as expected. Our focus on reflecting differences between
The size measures, as in other fee model studies, entities in variable selection may warrant attention
are positive and particularly strong in both models. in private sector studies, such as with industry
Overall, the regression results seem reasonable and effects. Splitting samples by function (in this case
are consistent with previous studies regarding size departments, GBEs and SAs) may also yield more
and complexity effects. With this reassurance, we interesting results in other audit fee studies.
can have some confidence in the results for our key The results do not necessarily mean that the
test variables for input costs and agency pricing ANAO’s monopoly position was exploited to
effects. extract rents, but the results are sufficiently
Focusing on the stronger Model 1, the difference suggestive of differences in pricing to warrant
in the (size) slopes between department and GBE further attention. Should such discrepancies be
is significant at the 0.01 level. The observed supported by other analyses, then policy makers
difference is consistent with our argument that low concerned with contestability of audit engage-
acceptable audit risk for GBEs should attract ments or fee charging in this and comparable audit
higher input costs compared to the medium-to- markets may need to specifically consider such
high acceptable audit risk for departments. consequences of monopoly power.
The significantly positive coefficient for depart-
ment is consistent with unscaled fee adjustments
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
that may occur with opportunistic discretionary
pricing. The negative coefficient for GBE is We are grateful for the comments on earlier
consistent with unscaled discounting that may versions received from Max Aiken, Sudipta Basu,
occur with discretionary pricing behaviour. Keith Houghton, Gary Monroe, Dan Simunic,
Because we cannot separate the possible fee- Don Stokes, and an anonymous referee for this
increasing affect of incorporation for GBEs from journal.
the fee-reducing GBE dummy, it is possible that the
magnitude of GBE ‘discounting’ may be greater
NOTES
than indicated by the GBE coefficient.
1. Departments operate directly under a
7. CONCLUDING REMARKS Minister who is a member of the Executive
Government. SAs are established for particular
This study investigated the pricing of government purposes. Two particular types of statutory
audits in a monopolistic market. The results are authorities are Government Business
potentially useful in two areas: the significance of Enterprises (GBEs – trading or commercially
the threat of monopolistic behaviour for policy oriented organisations often structured as
setting (particularly regarding fee charging or cost companies) and statutory marketing au-
recoveries) in public sector audits; and the choice thorities (also often structured as companies).
of the size-based proxy for the auditor’s loss 2. The fee charging mechanism was announced
exposure in public sector audit fee studies in December 1990 with the first full financial
generally. year of operation as 1991–92. Supplementation
The observed size and agency effects are con- was provided to budget-funded agencies in
sistent with the expected variation in loss exposure the 1991–92 budget to meet the cost of audit
and discretionary pricing in accordance with fees. Full operation of the fee charging
varying monopoly power. Expenditure appears arrangement appears to have ended during
superior to TA as a proxy for auditor loss exposure 1995 with financial reports from then
for public sector agencies. indicating that audit fees for departments
However, this study is not without its were only notional and not charged. There
limitations. Using archival data from annual was a change of Auditor-General during
reports limits our ability to proxy engagement the 1995 financial year and substantial
conditions. Also, the use of dichotomous variables structural changes in the ANAO. Therefore the

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Int. J. Audit. 8: 263–277 (2004)


Discretionary Pricing in a Monopolistic Audit Market 275

cut-off for this study is the financial year 8. For a national auditor, all auditees serve the
1993–94. same civilian population and so ANAO
3. These included the Australian Wool Realisation auditees cannot be distinguished on this basis.
Commission and the Australian Wool 9. If losses are defined in political-cost terms, it is
Corporation (see Auditor-General, 1991a), the likely that the political dimensions of agencies
National Railway Corporation Limited (see and their activities will determine the auditee’s
Auditor-General, 1991b) and the National and auditor’s loss exposure. In the absence of
Media Liaison Service (see Auditor-General, any measures of the political sensitivity of
1995). The Senate Standing Committee on agencies’ programmes and activities, the level
Financial and Public Administration, in its of expenditure, which is funded from taxes, is
report on Government Companies and their the more reasonable proxy for this political
reporting requirements (tabled in Parliament cost exposure.
on 2 November 1989), endorsed the 10. Bill Nelson was the then Acting National
recommendations of the Joint Committee of Business Director, Financial Audit, for the
Public Accounts (JCPA) Report 296 that the ANAO.
Auditor-General alone be external auditor of 11. These were accessed in the Parliamentary
GBEs. As a result of the JCPA report, the Papers Collection held by the library of The
Government instigated a further review by Australian National University. Some gaps in
the then Auditor-General of South Australia, the audit fee data collected from this source
Tom Sheridan. The Sheridan Report (30 March were remedied with data provided directly
1990) recommended that the Auditor-General by individual agencies for which we are
should be the sole auditor of all GBEs and other particularly grateful. Consequently, the sample
Government bodies and that he be reinstated as of SAs and GBEs is not necessarily random
the external auditor where other arrangements but the nature of any bias is unknown. Three
had been put in place. In December 1990 the government owned corporations (Qantas,
Government announced that the Auditor- Telstra and Commonwealth Bank) were
General would be the sole external auditor for excluded a priori because they were all subject
all GBEs and SMAs, but that the Minister for to some degree of privatisation through public
Finance may allow exceptions. In 1991 there floats during or shortly after the study period,
were 20 government companies with private which may have significantly affected the
sector auditors and 11 joint arrangements. For audit process in the years concerned. A fourth
1992 there were 41 companies not audited by GBE, Defence Housing Authority, was sub-
the ANAO. Many of these were subsidiaries sequently excluded as an extreme outlier in
operating in other countries and so beyond the terms of audit fee.
ANAO’s effective jurisdiction. While these 12. While subsamples are small, the pooled series
numbers are not large, they are evidence of the is sufficiently large for most analytical
threat of competition. purposes (n = 198) provided pooling does not
4. 1994 figures are not available due to changes introduce variance inflation.
in ANAO disclosure practices. 13. Issues involved unauthorised or potentially
5. The number of product lines and locations as invalid transactions and difficulties with
complexity proxies have also been associated calculations. More ambiguous audit effects
with audit fees in some studies (Simunic, 1980; pertain to breaches of accounting standards
Simon, 1985; Palmrose, 1986; Chan et al., 1993). and some limitations of scope similar to the
6. s.70E of the Audit Act 1901 obliges the department qualifications.
Commonwealth to indemnify individuals 14. An exception is Pong & Whittington (1994).
against liability in the course of performing 15. Transformation of subsidiaries was lg(number
functions set out in the section. of subsidiaries + 1). Square-root trans-
7. While it is likely that municipal population formations were also tested for all variables.
and revenues will be highly correlated, the
variation in income and wealth between
municipalities leaves unanswered the question REFERENCES
of what underlying fee determinant is being Anderson, T. & Zeghal, D. (1994), The pricing of audit
measured and how it might be best proxied. services: evidence from the Canadian Market.

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Int. J. Audit. 8: 263–277 (2004)


276 G. Shailer et al.

Accounting and Business Research, 24(95), pp. 195– Haskins, M. E. & Williams, D. D. (1988), The
207. association between client factors and audit fees: a
Auditor-General (1991a), The Potential Erosion of comparison by country and by firm. Accounting and
Accountability to the Parliament: Australian Wool Business Research, 18(70), pp. 183–190.
Realisation Commission – Australian Wool Corporation. Joint Committee of Public Accounts (1994), An
Audit Report No. 35 1990–91 Canberra: Advisory Report on the Financial Management and
Commonwealth of Australia. Accountability Bill 1994, the Commonwealth
Auditor-General (1991b), Accountability Off the Authorities and Companies Bill 1994 and the Auditor-
Rails: National Railway Corporation Limited – Erosion General Bill 1994, and a Proposal to Establish an Audit
of Accountability to the Parliament. Audit Report Committee of Parliament. Canberra: Australian
No. 16 1991–92 Canberra: Commonwealth of Government Publishing Service.
Australia. Jubb, C. A., Houghton, K. A. & Butterworth, S.
Auditor-General (1992), Annual Report of the (1996), Audit fee determinants: the plural nature
Australian National Audit Office 1991–92, Canberra: of risk. Managerial Auditing Journal, 11(3), pp. 25–
Commonwealth of Australia. 80.
Auditor-General (1995), National Media Liaison Mackintosh, I. (1992), Accrual accounting for
Service: A Loophole in Accountability? Audit Report departments and the whole of government: costs,
No. 17 1994–95 Canberra: Commonwealth of benefits and opportunities. 1992 Annual Research
Australia. Lecture in Government Accounting. Melbourne:
Baber, W. R., Brooks, E. H. & Ricks, W. E. (1987), An Australian Society of CPAs.
empirical investigation of the market for audit Nelson, B. (1993), The role of the audit in improving
services in the public sector. Journal of Accounting financial reporting in the public sector. 1993 Annual
Research, 25(2), Autumn, pp. 293–305. Research Lecture in Government Accounting.
Barrett, P. (1996), Some thoughts about the roles, Melbourne: Australian Society of CPAs.
responsibilities and future scope of Auditors- Palmrose, Z. (1986), Audit fees and auditor size:
General. Australian Journal of Public Administration, Further evidence. Journal of Accounting Research, 24,
55(4), December, pp. 137–146. Spring, pp. 97–110.
Butterworth, S. & Houghton, K. A. (1995), Auditor Pong, C. M. & Whittington, G. (1994), The
switching: the pricing of audit services. Journal of determinants of audit fees: some empirical models.
Business Finance and Accounting, 22(3), April, Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 21(8),
pp. 323–344. December, pp. 1071–1095.
Chan, P., Ezzamel, M. & Gwilliam, D. (1993), Roberts, R. W., Glezon, G. W. & Jones, T. W. (1990),
Determinants of audit fees for quoted UK Determinants of auditor change in the public sector.
companies. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, Journal of Accounting Research, 28(1), Spring,
20(6), November, pp. 75–86. pp. 220–228.
Copley, P. A. (1989), The determinants of local govern- Rubin, M. A. (1988), Municipal audit fee determinants.
ment audit fees: additional evidence. Research in The Accounting Review, 63(2), April, pp. 219–
Government and Nonprofit Accounting, 5, pp. 3–23. 236.
Copley, P. A. (1991), The association between Rubin, M. A. (1992), Municipal selection of a state or
municipal disclosure practices and audit quality. external auditor for financial statement audits.
Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 10, Winter, Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 11,
pp. 245–266. pp. 155–178.
Francis, J. R. & Simon, D. T. (1987), A test of audit Sanders, G., Allen, A, & Korte, L. (1995), Municipal
pricing in the small-client segment of the US audit audit fees: has increased competition made a
market. The Accounting Review, 62(1), January, difference. Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory,
pp. 145–157. 14(1), Spring, pp. 105–114.
Francis, J. R. & Stokes, D. J. (1986), Audit Prices, Sharpe, M. (1990), Report of the Independent Auditor on
product differentiation, and scale economies: an Efficiency Audit of the Australian National Audit
further evidence from the Australian market, Office in accordance with the Audit Act 1901.
Journal of Accounting Research, 24(2), Autumn, Canberra: Australian Government Publishing
pp. 383–393. Service.
Francis, J. R. (1984), The effect of auditor firm size on Simon, D. T. (1985), The audit services market:
audit prices: a study of the Australian market. additional empirical evidence. Auditing: A Journal of
Journal of Accounting and Economics, 6, August, Practice and Theory, 5(1), Fall, pp. 71–78.
pp. 133–151. Simon, D. T. & Francis, J. R. (1988), The effects of
Gist, W. E. (1992), Explaining variability in external auditor change on audit fees: tests of price cutting
audit fees. Accounting and Business Research, 23(89), and price recovery. The Accounting Review, 63(2),
pp. 79–84. April, pp. 255–269.
Hair, J. F., Anderson, R. E., Tatham, R. L. & Black, W. Simunic, D. A. (1980), The pricing of audit services:
C. (1995), Multivariate Data Analysis. (4th edn) theory and evidence. Journal of Accounting Research,
Englewood Cliffs NJ: Prentice Hall. 18(1), Spring, pp. 161–190.

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Int. J. Audit. 8: 263–277 (2004)


Discretionary Pricing in a Monopolistic Audit Market 277

Taylor, J. (1996), What should be the role of the corporate governance, regulation, disclosure and
Auditor-General in the context of managerialist audit.
government and new public management?. Lorne Cummings is a Senior Lecturer at
Australian Journal of Public Administration, 55(4),
December, pp. 147–156.
Macquarie University. His research interests relate
Taylor, M. E. & Baker, R. L. (1981), An analysis of the to stakeholder theory, ethical investment, and
external audit fee. Accounting and Business Research, environmental/social accounting.
12(45), Winter, pp. 55–60. Eroni Vatuloka completed his research masters
degree at The Australian National University.
He is now the Auditor-General of the Republic of
Fiji.
Stephen Welch completed his research masters
AUTHORS PROFILES
degree at The Australian National University. He
Gregory Shailer is a Reader at the Australian is now in practice with a Big 4 accounting firm
National University. His research interests relate to where he specialises in public sector services.

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Int. J. Audit. 8: 263–277 (2004)

Você também pode gostar