Você está na página 1de 8

ISSUE 2009/02

APRIL 2009
bruegelpolicybrief
HANDLE WITH CARE! POST-
CRISIS GROWTH IN THE EU
by Jean Pisani-Ferry SUMMARY As long as the crisis was expected to be short-lived, Europe could
Director of Bruegel
jean.pisani-ferry@bruegel.org
afford not to reflect on its potential consequences for medium-term
growth. Urgent tasks ahead and the longer-term agenda could remain dis-
and Bruno van Pottelsberghe connected. This is no longer justified. Indeed, the seeds of future growth
Senior Research Fellow at Bruegel
Professor at the Université Libre de
performance are sown – or not – during crises. Countries that have gone
Bruxelles through deep crises have found that the loss in output is generally not
bvp@bruegel.org
recovered rapidly, if at all, and that medium-term performance depends on
the choice of crisis management measures. Five factors can either help or
harm medium-term growth: the size and duration of stimulus packages;
their content; labour market policies; bank restructuring and lending
behaviour; and research and development expenditures.
POLICY CHALLENGE

Policies that can improve medium-term performance should be prioritised.


This leads to six policy recommendations: i) governments should explicitly
announce state-contingent, not time-contingent, budgetary strategies; ii)
stimulus packages should put more
Impact of major financial crises in
Japan and Sweden emphasis on pro-growth policies such
as education and innovation; iii) bank
Sweden restructuring should be speeded-up;
GDP
Trend (annual average 1985-90) iv) employment support should be
temporary, economy-wide, and should
avoid favouring particular firms or
sectors, or taking people out of the
labour market; v) support to large
firms in traditional industries should
be conditional on restructuring; vi)
the pro-cyclicality of innovation
Japan
GDP
efforts should be addressed in order
Trend (annual average 1991-96)
to limit the fall in R&D intensity during
the crisis and sow the seeds of pro-
1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

ductivity gains when recovery starts.


Source: Bruegel.
HANDLE WITH CARE! POST-CRISIS GROWTH IN THE EU

ALTHOUGH THE CRISIS ORIGINATED financial crises that led to deep businesses, and ultimately public
02 IN THE US, Europe’s outlook has
deteriorated more sharply, as indi-
recessions: Finland, Japan, South
Korea and Sweden, all in the 1990s.
finances, suffered major losses.
By contrast, Sweden reacted swift-
bruegelpolicybrief

cated by revisions of the ly. It recapitalised the viable


International Monetary Fund’s Figure 2 illustrates the main les- banks, nationalised the insolvent
forecasts over the last twelve son from these episodes. As a rule, ones and used the recession as an
months. Industrial production deep crises result in permanent opportunity for economic transfor-
indices in the US and the three loss of output: after the shock, the mation. In the years that followed
largest EU countries confirm that economy resumes growth at the the crisis, productivity slowed in
Europe is being hit at least as hard same rate, but labour input Japan, whereas it accelerated
as the US, and that this crisis is remains lower, and thus also the markedly in Sweden. Eventually,
worse than any of the severest growth path. This lesson from Japan settled for a lower growth
downturns observed during the crisis episodes in four advanced rate while Sweden was able to
post-war era (Figure 1). economies is confirmed by the recoup the output loss entirely
experience with crises among a (Frontpage figure and Table 1).
The latest monthly figures give wider sample of countries over a
hope that the bottom might be in longer period (Cerra and Saxena, What these opposite cases illus-
sight. The questions are then how 2008; Reinhart and Rogoff, 2008). trate is that policies implemented
to stimulate the rebound, what during a crisis and in response to it
type of recovery can be expected, But national policy choices matter can have a major bearing on long-
and what the crisis’s longer term in determining the outcome. The term growth. This is because a
consequences will be. Experience clearest contrast here is between deep crisis involves hysteresis. It
indicates that the answer to the Japan and Sweden. Japan’s leaves its mark even after it has
last two questions depends cru- actions turned out to be weak, passed because workers may – or
cially on policy choices made belated and ill-designed. Banks may not – remain jobless, and
while managing the downturn. were allowed to hide losses for too because innovation may falter – or
long and, as a consequence, they thrive. Policymakers must there-
1 LESSONS FROM PREVIOUS CRISES survived for an extended period fore systematically assess the
without being able to perform their longer-term consequences of the
In recent decades four developed economic role. As a result, choices they make in response to
countries have been hit by Japanese households and the needs of the moment.

Figure 1: Industrial output in Europe and the US, current and previous While managing the crisis, govern-
recession episodes ments need to target three closely
United Kingdom United States related objectives:
5 5
0 0
-5 -5 • Eliminate the output gap pro-
1973 (Nov)
-10 1974 (Jun)
1979 (Jun)
-10
1981 (Aug) duced by the crisis,
-15 -15 1990 (Sep)
1990 (Jun)
2000 (Nov)
2000 (Jun) • Avoid a permanent loss of
-20 -20 2007 (Dec)
2007 (Dec) potential output resulting from
-25 -25
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36
Months since peak Months since peak
a contraction of the labour
Germany France
force, and
5 5 • Keep productivity gains on
0 0
-5
track.
-5
-10 -10 1974 (Aug)
1979 (Aug)
-15 1973 (Aug)
2001 (Feb)
-15 1992 (Mar) Section 2 of this Policy Brief inves-
1980 (Feb) 2001 (Aug)
-20
1992 (Feb) 2008 (Feb) -20
2008 (Feb) tigates five channels through
-25 -25
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 which crisis measures can either
Months since peak Months since peak
help or harm medium-term growth:
Sources: National statistical agencies, Bruegel calculations the size and duration of stimulus
HANDLE WITH CARE! POST-CRISIS GROWTH IN THE EU

Weizsäcker, 2009). This is signifi-


120
Figure 2: Impact of major financial crises in four economies
GDP Total hours worked GDP per hour worked
cant, but markedly less than advo-
cated by the IMF (two percent of
03

bruegelpolicybrief
115
GDP) and also less than what the
110
US stimulus is expected to deliver
105
(about two percent of GDP in
100
2009). This remains true even
95
when automatic stabilisers are
90
taken into account. According to
85
Bruegel’s calculations, the auto-
80 matic increase in spending as a
75 result of the crisis will only add 0.2
70 percent of GDP to the Europe’s
T-6 T-5 T-4 T-3 T-2 T-1 T T+1 T+2 T+3 T+4 T+5 T+6
discretionary stimulus.
Source: Bruegel calculations. The graph depicts the unweighted average of GDP, total hours worked Quantitatively, Europe is delivering
and GDP per hour before and after the major financial and economic crises that occurred in four
countries: Japan in 1997, Sweden in 1991, Finland in 1991 and South Korea in 1997. ‘T’ stands for
a timid Keynesian response to a
the year of the crisis. very Keynesian situation.

Table 1 Two factors are behind the


Labour productivity growth before and after the crises in Japan and Sweden relatively weak EU response, both
Wholesale and related to its fragmentation. First,
All sectors Manufacturing Construction retail trade, hotels for any given EU country a large
and restaurants
part of the benefits of a stimulus
Sweden 1984-1990 1.46% 1.73% 1.21% 1.23%
accrue not to itself but to its trade
Sweden 1991-1997 3.61% 7.72% 3.25% 4.53%
partners. Second, although the
Sweden 1998-2005 2.49% 6.94% -0.31% 3.55%
public debt ratio on the eve of the
Japan 1984-1990 3.73% 4.56% 4.99% 5.89%
crisis was roughly the same in the
Japan 1991-1997 0.99% 2.65% -4.57% 2.94%
US and the EU, individual fiscal sit-
Japan 1998-2003 1.41% 3.73% -0.57% -1.01%
uations vary significantly within
Source: GGDC 10-sector database, Bruegel calculations.
Europe. Italy, for example, is cau-
packages; their content; labour stimulus can be effective. tious because its public debt ratio
market policies; bank restructur- already exceeds 100 percent of
ing and lending behaviour; and Governments in Europe responded GDP and its rating is only A+, not
research and development expen- with unequal speed and intensity. AAA as for Germany and France.
ditures. Section 3 concludes and For the EU as a whole, the
makes policy recommendations. budgetary response in 2009 may Looking beyond the short-term
be estimated to be of the order of response, what budgetary policy
2 FIVE POLICY CHANNELS 0.95 percent of GDP (Saha and von can or cannot do depends on the
Table 2
a. The size of stimulus packages
Policy objectives and policy channels
Recourse to budgetary policy Eliminate Avoid permanent Keep productivity
output gap potential output loss on track
became necessary in autumn
2008 when demand was collaps- Size stimulus package
ing and that the dire state of the Content of stim. pack.
banking system was rendering Labour markets
monetary policy partially ineffec- Bank restructuring
tive. It was justified because R&D
macroeconomic conditions were Note: column headings indicate objectives; row headings indicate policy channels. Dark red
precisely those in which budgetary indicates primary effect, light red indicates secondary effect.
HANDLE WITH CARE! POST-CRISIS GROWTH IN THE EU

nature of the shock. Budgetary and the reasons why output is result is that packages differ wide-
04 support is an appropriate
response to the extent that it helps
lower than previously expected. It
also requires public spending itself
ly as regards their composition
(Figure 3). Evidently, national
bruegelpolicybrief

to offset a temporary demand to be sustainable. Sustainability- choices were not made in accor-
shock and replace private demand enhancing reforms of the type dis- dance with an agreed EU medium-
by public demand at a time when cussed in Pisani-Ferry et al. term strategy.
private agents cannot rely on (2008) and improvements in the
impaired financial markets to institutional framework of national For the EU as a whole, about half of
absorb shocks. Beyond its imme- budgetary policies are needed to the stimulus goes to tax cuts
diate impact on product and labour ensure that this is the case. (Figure 4), with the aim of boost-
markets, budgetary support may ing demand (few packages include
prevent lasting damage, such as b. The content of stimulus packages genuine tax reforms). The other
the failure of profitable companies large share (36 percent) goes to
and the writing-off of precious The composition of stimulus public investment, most of which
human capital. But in the case of a packages matters for medium- benefits non-traded domestic
longer term shortfall in supply, it term growth. Public spending on sectors such as construction. This
would be a major mistake to use education and innovation can help is often justified by reference to
budgetary policy in an attempt to build a platform for sustained pro- foreign trade ‘leakage’. However,
lift output above potential. ductivity gains in the long term. such a choice is open to criticism:
Properly targeted spending can first, it is essentially non-coopera-
As a consequence, budgetary sup- also help overcome resistance to tive; second, as indicated in Figure
port should be maintained as long efficiency-enhancing labour and 1, manufacturing suffers most
as a temporary demand shock pre- product-market reform. from the crisis, not the trade-shel-
vails. But it should be withdrawn tered sectors; third, low supply
as soon as the recovery is strong Choices made at end-2008 were in elasticity in some non-traded
enough to be self-sustaining, even some cases directed at pure goods sectors, such as public
if the post-recovery growth trajec- demand-side effects. The best works, may in fact result in higher
tory turns out to be lower than it examples are perhaps the United
was before the crisis. Kingdom and Austrian stimulus Figure 4: Composition of EU
packages, which rely mostly on tax stimulus package for 2009
This analysis implies that judge- cuts. Other countries made differ- 10.5% 35.5%
ment must be exercised regarding ent choices, sometimes more 5.2%
the underlying economic situation supply-side oriented, and the

Figure 3: Breakdown by spending category of selected EU stimulus


packages for 2009

1.8% Investment Permanent tax cuts Temporary tax cuts


and transfers and transfers
1.6%
Labour market Sector-specific
1.4% measures measures
29.0%
1.2%
19.8%
% of GDP

1.0%
Investment
0.8% Permanent tax cuts and
0.6% transfers
0.4%
Temporary tax cuts and
transfers
0.2%
Labour market measures
0.0%
DE AT UK ES NL FR PL SE BE Sector-specific measures
Source: Bruegel, Saha and von Weizsäcker (2009). Source: Bruegel.
HANDLE WITH CARE! POST-CRISIS GROWTH IN THE EU

prices in these sectors, a form of choices. It is relatively straightfor- crises in the 1990s reacted differ-
leakage that undermines impact.
Finally, the contribution of public
ward to deal with collective redun-
dancies and bankruptcies in the
ently. Sweden and Finland saw a
sharp increase in the unemploy-
05

bruegelpolicybrief
investment to future growth may case of an individual company or a ment rate and a slight decrease in
be low in Europe, where infrastruc- sector-specific shock. The key is to the participation rate. Japan and
ture is already well developed. smooth the transition into new to a lesser extent South Korea had
Japan’s experience with bridges jobs for those workers who are laid more stable unemployment and
from nowhere to nowhere in the off. The three typical policy mis- participation rates (Figure 5)1. So
1990s should serve as a reminder takes in such circumstances are: Japan, and to a smaller extent
of the potential cost of politically (i) large subsidies for ailing South Korea, retained idle workers
determined public investments. companies in order to keep them within companies more often than
alive against any economic logic; their European counterparts. But
One important way in which the (ii) labour market and unemploy- the two Nordic countries relied on
stimulus packages could be ment benefit regimes that exces- active labour market policies to
aligned with the promotion of sively prolong the transition time avoid laid-off workers exiting the
growth is by supporting research in unemployment; (iii) early retire- labour market altogether.
and innovation. While many of the ment schemes. All these mistakes
packages contain some such ele- have been committed in the past. Appropriate policies depend on
ments, the diversity of the meas- Early retirement policies in domestic labour market
ures makes any assessment of particular were used during the institutions but there are common
the total research and innovation 1980s in several European principles. Early retirement is
content of the stimulus packages countries, triggering a major drop clearly ill-advised as it overbur-
far from straightforward. But it in the participation rate in the 55- dens the pension system with peo-
would be hard to characterise the 65 age bracket. This proved to be a ple who should be active and in
European stimulus as innovation- socially controversial, fiscally many cases would like to work
friendly. If one takes a narrow view costly and economically ineffi- again. The same applies to all other
that excludes indirect support cient choice. measures having a permanent
such as construction and research effect. However, there can be a
subsidies to mature industries, But the question now is what to do case for temporarily discouraging
the proportion devoted to when confronting a deep, across- immediate payroll adjustment. In
innovation might be as low as one the-board recession. The four a severe crisis, allowing redundan-
percent. If a broader view is taken, countries witnessing significant cies to occur and subsequently
including the large construction
component for educational Figure 5: Male unemployment rate in Finland, Japan, Korea and Sweden
institutions in Germany and (1980-2007)
20%
innovation subsidies for mature
Finland
industries, spending on innovation 18%
Japan
could be in excess of 10 percent. 16% Korea
Whatever the measure, this is Sweden
14%
OECD countries
unlikely to deliver the innovation
12%
boost that was called for in the
10%
EU’s Lisbon strategy.
8%

c. Labour market policies 6%


1
4% We focus here on male
employment and par-
Figure 2 shows that labour mar- 2% ticipation rates (female
kets play a key role in determining 0% labour market data is
whether crises have lasting more difficult to com-
1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

pare owing to differing


effects. Policymakers are in this social trends between
respect confronted with unusual Source: Bruegel, based on OECD data. countries).
HANDLE WITH CARE! POST-CRISIS GROWTH IN THE EU

retraining workers may not be effi- to companies in order to avoid (Ahearne and Shinada, 2005).
06 cient if impaired markets block the
reallocation mechanism. Instead,
bankruptcies. In a financial crisis,
the Schumpeterian ‘cleansing’
This phenomenon is noticeable in
aggregate productivity figures
bruegelpolicybrief

keeping employees active in some effect of recessions does not (Table 1), and the significance of
form may be efficient. apply correctly because financial this channel can be verified at the
markets are unable to foster effi- microeconomic level. In the case
Such employment support should cient capital reallocation. On the of Japan, Caballero et al (2006)
be delivered through labour mar- contrary, companies first hit are have found that the higher the pro-
ket measures, for example the younger, cash-poor firms that portion of zombie firms in a given
government-subsidised short-time often have good growth potential. sector, the lower the investment
work, such as the Kurzarbeit It is therefore appropriate to use ratio of non-zombie firms. They
scheme in Germany. Temporary available channels to extend cred- also noted a correlation between
work-sharing arrangements and it to firms that are viable but at risk the density of ineffective firms in a
flexible working hours, which allow through liquidity shortage. As dis- sector and its total factor produc-
overtime when business is strong tressed banks tend to curtail credit, tivity (TFP) growth.
in return for additional leave when there is a case for requesting lend-
business is weak, may have a sim- ing commitments from them as a The victims of a dysfunctional
ilarly positive effect. In general, counterpart to capital injections. credit system are typically young
forms of labour-market flexibility innovative companies (‘YICs’), an
that do not have the negative side- However, there remains a risk of efficient means of improving long-
effect of accelerating the rise of distorting incentives. Big term growth prospects. The nega-
unemployment in the crisis can companies employ workforces tive impact of the crisis on YICs
contribute positively. that no government wants to see extends far beyond the direct
on the streets. Young innovators impact on their survival and the
Rather than acting through labour bring ‘only’ potential change and breakthrough innovations that
market instruments, there will have by definition little lobbying YICs generate. As these companies
always be a political temptation to clout. Political pressure and risk often trigger innovation by incum-
rescue particularly large industrial aversion can interact with each bent firms, their indirect effect is
companies using government other, resulting in banks favouring also significant. But they combine
funds. Such operations pose prob- companies they perceive as too the disadvantages of small scale,
lems from the design stage and big, or too politically protected, to a short credit history, lower
may be difficult to end. In addition, fail. The more the banks are them- retained earnings and more risky
there is a real risk of precipitating selves dependent on government projects, and are more likely to be
a low-growth scenario as occurred support, the more they may be financially constrained. Public
in Japan, where a significant pro- inclined towards such behaviour. policy should thus provide better
portion of the economy consisted access to finance for entrepre-
for a lengthy period of zombie These risks are illustrated by neurial projects typified by the
companies kept alive only at the Japan’s ‘lost decade’ example. As activity of YICs, as proposed in
discretion of the government. They indicated in Figure 6, bank rescue Veugelers (2009). And policy
stifle economic growth, while pre- operations in Japan extended over should first and foremost expedite
venting reallocation of resources more than a decade, whereas they banking system restructuring.
to sectors with higher growth moved much faster in Sweden.
potential. Throughout that period many e. The cyclicality of R&D
Japanese banks behaved as ‘zom- expenditures
d. Zombie lending and productivity bies’ and discriminated against
small enterprises. Notwithstanding the importance of
A natural response to the collapse YICs, large firms conduct most
in demand and credit restrictions Such behaviour has been identi- R&D. Their investments are driven
resulting from the state of the fied as a key cause of Japan’s low by (expected) returns, and will
banking sector is to extend credit productivity growth in the 1990s therefore be reduced when
HANDLE WITH CARE! POST-CRISIS GROWTH IN THE EU

(expected) profits are lower (van can increase demand for innova- sown – or not sown. In a situation
Pottelsberghe 2008), such as in
periods of economic crisis3.
tive products in recessions, so as
to mitigate the negative impact on
where the duration and depth of
the crisis remain uncertain, the
07

bruegelpolicybrief
Entrepreneurs’ ability to finance firms’ incentives to invest in inno- acid test for all policy is twofold:
innovation typically depends upon vative activities in the first place. • Is the policy course sustainable
their cash flow, which is in turn Governments can also subsidise even if recovery is delayed?
affected by the aggregate state of firms in recessions to help them to • Does the policy course con-
the economy: it is typically lower refinance innovative activities in tribute to medium-term eco-
in recessions than in booms. spite of tight cash flow. During the nomic performance?
crisis of the 1990s Japan actually
The evidence confirms that busi- succeeded in preserving a high This analysis leads to the following
ness R&D outlays are highly pro- level of R&D intensity, despite a recommendations:
cyclical. The quantitative analysis drop-off in economic activity. This
performed by Guellec and van policy allowed the country to stay 1. Budgetary policy: governments
Pottelsberghe (2003) suggests specialised in high-tech industries should formally announce that
that the long-run elasticity of busi- and to avoid a more abrupt eco- stimulus measures will remain
ness R&D outlays with respect to nomic collapse than would other- in place as long as economic
GDP is about 1.5 (ie, a one percent wise have been the case. conditions require, even if the
increase in GDP induces a 1.5 duration of the crisis turns out
percent increase in business R&D 3. CONCLUSIONS to be longer than expected. This
outlays). This relationship is illus- in turn implies ensuring medi-
trated in Figure 7, which shows the As long as the crisis was expected um-term public finance
growth rates of GDP, privately to be short-lived, Europe could sustainability through enacting
funded R&D and government- afford not to reflect on its potential reforms (for example of pen-
funded R&D over the past 25 consequences for medium-term sions) that improve the inter-
years. The pro-cyclicality of busi- growth. Urgent needs of the temporal budget balance and
ness R&D is clearly apparent, with moment and the longer-term policy investing in the quality of policy
a much higher volatility than GDP. agenda could remain disconnect- institutions to enhance the
ed. And until now they have been. credibility of commitments to
This negative impact of aggregate future retrenchment. By the
volatility on innovation calls for But this disconnect is no longer same token, governments
countercyclical government tenable. It is during crises that the should announce that stimulus
action. For instance, governments seeds of future performance are measures will be removed as

Figure 6: Distribution of bank losses over time in Figure 7: Growth of GDP, government-funded and
Japan and Sweden privately-funded R&D expenditures
35% 8%

30%
6%

25%
Percentage of total loss

4% 3
20%
The reverse could
however be argued,
Japan 2% based on inter-temporal
15%
Sweden substitution: the oppor-
0% tunity costs of achiev-
10%
ing growth are lower in
Growth of GERD financed by government recessions, and hence
5% -2%
Growth of GERD financed by industry firms have more incen-
GDP growth (million constant 2000 PPP$) tive to undertake R&D
0%
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 -4% in downturns and
1997

1999

2001

2003
1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

Years since first loss


launch new products in
upturns. This is,
Source: Figure 6: Hoshi and Kashyap (2008), Bank of Sweden, Bruegel calcula tions. Figure 7: Bruegel, from OECD/MSTI, three-year rolling averages in con- however, rarely
stant 2000 USD PPPs. GERD: Gross expenditure on research and development. observed.
HANDLE WITH CARE! POST-CRISIS GROWTH IN THE EU

soon as economic conditions bank restructuring should be 6. Innovation: procyclical behav-


08 show sustained improvement,
even if the pace of growth is
speeded-up, to avoid zombie
behaviour and the associated
iour should be countered
through specific tax incentives
bruegelpolicybrief

less than pre-crisis. In other misallocation of capital. or subsidies in order to limit the
words, measures should be fall in R&D intensity during the
accompanied by an exit 4. Employment support: should downturn and prepare the
strategy and be made state- be implemented through labour ground for productivity gains in
rather than time-contingent. market policies and designed in the recovery.
They should be accompanied a way that minimises the risk
by sustainability-enhancing of lasting damage. This implies Consistent with the EU’s Lisbon
reforms of public finances. avoiding all measures that take strategy, it is the task of the
workers out of the labour mar- European Commission and the EU
2. Stimulus packages: for 2010, ket altogether, and avoiding Council presidency to monitor
to be revised to put greater support for labour markets national initiatives, assess their
emphasis on priorities that are through direct aid to firms. effectiveness and promote debate
consistent with structural Governments may instead pro- on the medium-term impact of
improvements to Europe’s vide temporary, across-the- crisis management policies.
growth potential. Currently, EU board incentives for companies
priorities for education, to retain employees. Acknowledgements: This Policy Brief is
based on a paper prepared at the
innovation and other pro- request of the Czech presidency of the
growth policies have not been 5. Large firms in traditional indus- EU. It draws on the contributions and
sufficiently reflected. This is a tries: any aid should be condi- comments of several members of the
missed opportunity. tional upon restructuring. Bruegel team, including Philippe Aghion,
Financial support to the busi- Marco Cornia, Zsolt Darvas, David Saha,
3. Financial system: if dysfunc- ness sector should be reserved Indhira Santos, André Sapir, Nicolas
Véron, Reinhilde Veugelers and Jakob
tional, there is a high medium- to a significant extent to young von Weizsäcker. The authors are indebt-
term economic cost for produc- innovative firms that inherently ed to Martin Kessler for excellent
tivity and employment. Thus, face severe credit constraints. research assistance.

REFERENCES:
Ahearne A. and N. Shinada (2005) ‘Zombie firms and economic stagnation in Japan’, Hi-Stat Discussion Paper Series 95.
Caballero R., T. Hoshi and A. Kashyap (2006) ‘Zombie lending and depressed restructuring in Japan’, NBER Working Paper 12129
Cerra, V. and S. Saxena (2008) ‘Growth dynamics: the myth of economic recovery’, American Economic Review 98(1), 439-457.
Guellec, D. and B. van Pottelsberghe (2003) ‘The impact of public R&D expenditure on business R&D’, Economics of Innovation and
New Technology vol. 12(3), 225-243.
Hoshi, T. and A. Kashyap (2008) Will the US bank recapitalisation succeed? Lessons from Japan, paper presented at the 2009 AEA
Congress.
Pisani-Ferry J., A. Sapir and J. von Weizsäcker (2008) ‘A European Recovery Programme’, Bruegel Policy Brief 2008/09.
Reinhart, C. M. and K. S. Rogoff (2008) ‘This Time is Different: A Panoramic View of Eight Centuries of Financial Crises’, NBER
Working Paper Series vol. w13882.
Saha D. and J. von Weizsäcker (2009) ‘Estimating the size of the European stimulus packages for 2009: An update’, Bruegel Policy
Contribution 2009/02, available at http://www.bruegel.org/Public/Publication_detail.php?ID=1171&publicationID=14541.
Van Pottelsberghe B. (2008) ‘Europe’s R&D: missing the wrong target?’, Bruegel Policy Brief 2008/03.
Veugelers R. (2009) ‘A lifeline for Europe’s young innovators’, Bruegel Policy Brief 2009/01.

© Bruegel 2009. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted in
the original language without explicit permission provided that the source is acknowledged. The Bruegel
Policy Brief Series is published under the editorial responsibility of Jean Pisani-Ferry, Director. Opinions
expressed in this publication are those of the author(s) alone.
Visit www.bruegel.org for information on Bruegel's activities and publications.
Bruegel - Rue de la Charité 33, B-1210 Brussels - phone (+32) 2 227 4210 info@bruegel.org

Você também pode gostar