Você está na página 1de 49

Is Economic Volatility Detrimental to Global Sustainability?

Yongfu Huang March 2010

Tyndall Centre for Climate Change Research

Working Paper 142

Is Economic Volatility Detrimental to Global Sustainability?

Yongfu Huang

Tyndall Working Paper 142, April 2010

Please note that Tyndall working papers are "work in progress". Whilst they are commented on by Tyndall researchers, they have not been subject to a full peer review. The accuracy of this work and the conclusions reached are the responsibility of the author(s) alone and not the Tyndall Centre.

Is Economic Volatility Detrimental to Global Sustainability?


Yongfu Huang 4CMR, Department of Land Economy, University of Cambridge 19 Silver Street, Cambridge CB3 9EP March 8, 2010

Abstract This paper examines the eects of economic volatility on global sustainability in a dynamic panel data model allowing for error cross section dependence. It nds that output volatility and nancial market volatility exert strong negative impacts on sustainable development, with the impacts exacerbated in some subsamples such as higher energy intensity countries and lower trade share countries. The paper also identies a nancial development channel through which output volatility impedes global sustainability, highlighting the interaction between global nancial markets and the wider economy as a key factor inuencing the low carbon development path. The nding is signicant for the conduct of macroeconomic and environmental policies in an integrated global green economy. Keywords: Output Volatility; Financial Market Volatility; Global Sustainability; Genuine Savings; Cross Section Dependence JEL Classication: E32; O11; O16
I am very grateful to Vasilis Saradis, Philip Arestis, and Unai Pascual for their constructive comments and suggestions. I would also like to thank two Tyndall Centre referees, 4CMR colleagues and seminar participants at the Department of Land Economy of Cambridge University for helpful comments and discussions. The usual disclaimer applies. Correspondence: Email: yh279@cam.ac.uk; Tel: 0044-1223 764873; Fax: 0044-1223 337130; URL: http://www.landecon.cam.ac.uk/yh279/huangyf.htm.

Introduction

In the 1990s the world economy grew at an averaged rate of 2.7 percent per annum, while in the 21st century it has exhibited an exceptional performance, reaching 4.5 percent per annum by the end of 2007.1 Following the long period of economic booms, the world economy, especially developing economies, experienced considerable unstable growth, severe crises, and typically a period of uncertainty and volatility. On the other hand, climate change has become the most severe global challenge of our age, which is in large part due to human activities (IPCC, 2001).2 From 1981 to 2005, some 60 per cent of the worlds ecosystem have been considered degraded or unsustainably exploited (Barbier, 2009). This poses an important question: could economic volatility lead countries down an unsustainable path? Over the last decades, volatility, as an independent research area, has moved on from a second-order research area to currently occupy a central position in development economics (Aizenman and Pinto, 2005). In todays integrated global markets, every major nancial crisis has global repercussions. Together with unstable macro policies and political instability, nancial crises are among the main sources of endogenous volatility (Wolf, 2005). Similar to the Asian nancial crisis which spread quite rapidly across seven countries of the region after the outburst of the crisis in Thailand in July 1997, the global nancial crisis of 2007-2009 has been characterized by incredible speed at which volatility spread around the global nancial markets. In particular almost every stock market across the globe went through the episodes of volatility outbursts since the end of 2007. Breaking out against the background of other looming crises, for example, climate crisis, fuel crisis, and food crisis, the nancial crisis of 2007-2009 has caused enormous damage to the world economy and resulted in the most severe global recession in generations.3 Since the economy traditionally deAnnual data taken from the World Bank World Development Indicators (2009). The average global surface temperature has increased by 0.8 C in the past century and 0.6 C in the past three decades (Hansen et al., 2008). 3 A recent ADB report by Loser (2009) shows that the nancial assets around the world may have fallen in value by more than US$50 trillion during 2008, a loss equivalent to almost a years worth of world economic output. According to IMF (2009), US GDP and euro-area GDP contracted by about 4% and 5% in 2008, respectively.
2 1

pends on low energy eciency and unsustainable use of natural resources, any dramatic changes in demand for goods and manufacturing associated with output volatility and nancial crisis will inevitably lead to the wastes of natural resources and a high degree of climate risk. Lin (2009) points out that the current economic downturn is possibly turning a short-run macroeconomic adjustment into a long-term development problem. However, the empirical evidence on the impact of economic volatility on the long-run sustainable development has been as yet sparse. This paper takes up the issue of whether economic volatility has a damaging eect on global sustainability. It carries out a dynamic panel data study based on data for 122 countries between 1978-2007 and makes use of the genuine savings or adjusted net savings to measure sustainability. To address the issue of cross country dependence driven by the increases in international trade and private capital ows in recent decades, this research considers a common factor structure in the error term, to fully take into account the eects of global shocks which potentially cause error dependence across countries. More specically, it applies the system Generalized Method of Methods (GMM) method adjusted to allow for error cross section dependence due to Saradis et al. (2009). This paper nds that output volatility exerts a strong negative impact on sustainable development, with the impact exacerbated in low income countries, higher energy intensity countries and lower trade share countries. The eect of nancial market volatility on global sustainability has also been shown to be signicantly negative, especially for the higher energy intensity countries and lower trade share countries. The resilience of those countries to nancial crisis and economic volatility will no doubt play an important role in building a low carbon global economy. Therefore, understanding the nature of volatility and how to manage its consequences should be of considerable interest to governments of those countries, especially developing countries. Rather than an investment channel, this research also nds that private credit ratio acts as a nancial channel through which output volatility impedes global sustainability. This highlights the role of the interaction between global nancial markets and the wider economy in promoting global sustainability. 3

This paper contributes to the literature in several dimensions. First, it explores dierent dimensions of economic volatility, including output volatility and nancial market volatility. Second, it allows for the possibility of error cross section dependence and tries to correct for the issues of endogeneity and unobserved country-specic eects. Third, it is signicant for the conduct of macroeconomic and environmental policies in an integrated global green economy in the sense that development strategies and programs should take adequate account of the state of natural resources, including forests, soils, freshwater and sheries, on which future growth is dependent. The remainder of the paper proceeds in section 2 to review the literature. Section 3 describes the data and outlines the methodology of the system GMM estimation without and with cross section dependence. Section 4 presents the empirical results. Section 5 concludes.

Volatility, Growth and Sustainability

This section sketches the theoretical and empirical research in this eld, especially on the link between output volatility and growth. Volatility is a normal oscillation around a particular economic variable and usually measured by a standard deviation of that economic variable over some historical period. It provides a measure of the possible variation or movement in a particular economic variable or some function of that variable, such as growth rate (Aizenman and Pinto, 2005).4 Research on the link between output volatility and long-run growth has met with substantial controversies. Theoretically, one line of research nds that volatility is positively related to growth. Sandmo (1970) and Ghosh and Jonathan (1997) argue that, when households are more uncertain about their future income due to higher macroeconomic volatility they tend to save more of their money for precautionary reasons. The increases in savings lead to higher levels of investment, and therefore higher growth rates. In a two-sector learning4 For the growth rates of GDP, Wolf (2005) denes normal volatility as the dierence between the 25th and 75th percentile of the growth rate distribution, in contrast to the extreme volatility or crisis volatility which are dened as two sequential years of negative output growth.

or-doing model of endogenous growth, Canton (2002) claims that volatility exerts a positive eect on growth via the accumulation of human capital. On the contrary, the other line of research supports a negative impact of volatility on growth. For example, Kharroubi (2007) illustrates that in the presence of credit constraints and moral hazard when long-term nancial contracts are imperfectly enforceable, a bias towards short-term debt could generate maturity mismatches between assets and liabilities and result in liquidity crises. Based on this framework, this study shows that two sources of volatility, normal volatility and abnormal volatility, have independent negative eects on the averaged growth rate of GDP per capita; furthermore the negative growth eects of two sources tend to reinforce each other. Based on a two-period overlapping generations with two types of technologies, the model by Aysan (2007) demonstrates how volatility reduces growth by aggravating the nancial market imperfections. More specically, the model predicts that greater volatility induces nancial intermediaries to charge higher interest rates, and therefore increases the cost of borrowing associated with capital market imperfections. The higher cost deters people from obtaining and using more productive technologies, which is detrimental to growth. Empirically, Kormendi and Meguire (1985) and Grier and Tullock (1989) nd evidence that output volatility promotes growth, among others. However, the majority of cross country studies suggest that economic volatility negatively aects long-run growth, especially for the poorer countries.5 Starting with Ramey and Ramey (1995), the study of the negative eect of volatility on growth has ourished, for example, Hnatkovska and Loayza (2005) and Loayza et al. (2007). Ramey and Ramey (1995) show that countries with higher output volatility tend to have lower economic growth, by using a sample of 92 countries over 1960-1985 and a sample of OECD countries over 1950-1988. Hnatkovska and Loayza (2005), employing data for 79 countries over 1960-2000, nd that a signicantly negative link exists between macroeconomic volatility and long-run growth, depending on various
Koren and Tenreyro (2007) nd that poor countries tend to specialize in fewer and more volatile sectors, and are therefore more exposed to the frequent and severe aggregate shocks.
5

structural country characteristics including countrys overall level of development, the extent of nancial depth, the level of institutional development and the degree of scal policy procyclicality, but not the degree of trade openness. They also nd evidence that macroeconomic volatility exerts a harmful causal eect on economic growth, which is particularly so for lowincome and middle income countries. Loayza et al. (2007) further point out that macroeconomic volatility has a negative eect on output growth, future consumption and thus welfare, through its links with various economic, political and policy-related uncertainty and with the tightening of binding investment constraints. In terms of the channels through which volatility exerts a damaging eect on growth or long-run development, Ramey and Ramey (1995) emphasize the role of the level of investment while Aysan (2007) supports for the productivity of investment rather than the level of investment. A number of transmission channels have been discussed by Wolf (2005), including factor accumulation, domestic nance, trade, capital mobility, and political institutions. Economic development has been traditionally based on low energy efciency and unsustainable use of our ecological commons. Given the ecological limits of our planet, transition to a low-carbon economy has been believed to be signicant for our future, which will change our industrial landscape and contribute to signicant energy and resource savings and long-term development. Since high growth performances do not necessarily lead to high levels of development, in comparison to output growth, policy makers have increasingly laid emphasis upon sustainable development as the primary national objective, especially for developing countries. The concept of sustainable development or sustainability was created explicitly to reect the development path in which economic growth and industrialization can be achieved without environmental damage. The denition of sustainable development has evolved over the decades. It was dened as development that meets the needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own needs(World Commission on Environment and Development, 1987). Pezzey (1992) denes it as a development path based on net wealth accumulation where the rents from natural resource depletion are being transformed to alternative 6

forms of wealth and saved for the future, by which the change in the real values of net wealth is non-negative and the per capita welfare is not declining. Sustainability has been typically regarded as having three dimensions or three pillars, namely environmental, social and economic sustainability, which are not mutually exclusive and can be mutually reinforcing (United Nations, 2005). Apart from reducing growth rates and leading to occasional recessions and rising unemployment, volatility often results in prevailing famines, critical riots, persistent stagnation and unsustainable consumption and investment in developing countries. However, empirical evidence on the impact of macroeconomic volatility on sustainable development has been limited. This research will contribute to this emerging line of research.

3
3.1

Data and Methodology


The Data

This research studies whether economic volatility has any signicant impacts on sustainable development, controlling for the growth rate of GDP per capita, gross national income per capita, and age dependence ratio.6 Appendix Table 1 contains the description and sources of these variables. The dependent variable is the genuine saving or adjusted net saving, denoted by GEN SAV . Genuine saving, the widely-used sustainability indicator, is the true saving rate in an economy in terms of creating and maintaining total wealth, which is inclusive of manufactured capital, human capital, and natural capital.7 Based on standard national accounting
We also consider life expectancy ratio and urbanization rate as controlling variables, but we nd no evidence for them. Data for the life expectancy at birth (total years) and urban population (% of total) are taken from the World Bank World Development Indicators Database (2009). 7 As synonymous with genuine saving, Arrow et al. (2004) use genuine investment to measure sustainability. Genuine investment is the total values of changes in genuine wealth at constant accounting prices, which includes manufactured capital assets, human capital and natural capital. It may also depend on the level of technology. In assessing the measure of genuine investment, Arrow et al. (2004) also take into account the impacts of population growth and technological change; however, their results are sensitive to the choices of GDP-wealth ratio.
6

conventions, genuine saving takes into account the investments in human capital, depletion of natural resources and pullution damages8 . The data for the adjusted net savings, excluding particulate emission damage (% of Gross National Income), are taken from the World Bank World Development Indicators Database (2009). In the regression below we use the 3-year averages from 1978 to 2007 of the natural logarithm of one plus the adjusted net savings divided by 100, log(1 + GEN SAV /100). This analysis mainly focuses on the output volatility and nancial market volatility. The measure of output volatility, denoted by V GR, is dened as the standard deviation over 3-year interval from 1978 to 2007 of the natural logarithm of one plus the annual growth rate of GDP per capita (GR) divided by 100, log(1 + GR/100). The data for the annual growth rate of GDP per capita are from the World Bank World Development Indicators Database (2009). The nancial volatility in terms of private credit volatility is denoted by V P RIV O. It is measured by the standard deviation over 3-year interval from 1978 to 2007 of the logarithm of one plus the private credit ratio (P RIV O), log(1+P RIV O). The private credit ratio captures general nancial intermediary activities provided to the private sectors. More specically, it is the ratio to GDP of the credit issued to the private sectors by banks and other nancial intermediaries, excluding credit issued to government, government agencies and public enterprises. The data for private credit ratio are from the World Bank Financial structure and Financial Development Database (2009). Two potential channels will be investigated, namely KI and P RIV O. KI, the investment channel, is the investment share of real GDP per capita (RGDPL), taken from the Penn World Table 6.3 due to Heston et al. (2009). In the regression we use the logarithm of one plus the investment share of real GDP per capita (RGDPL) divided by 100, log(1 + KI/100). P RIV O, the nancial channel, is the private credit ratio as explained above. We use the
More specically, genuine savings deduct the value of depletion of the underlying resource asset and pollution damages from gross national savings, while adding the current educational spending to gross national savings, since this spending may be considered as an investment in human capital (World Bank Environmental Indicators, 2002).
8

logarithm of one plus private credit ratio in the analysis, log(1 + P RIV O). We control for GDP growth rate (GR), gross national income per capita (GN IP C), and age dependency ratio (AGE). GN IP C is the 3-year averages from 1978 to 2007 of the logarithm of gross national income per capita, log(GN IP C). For GR and AGE, this analysis makes use of the 3-year averages from 1978 to 2007 of the logarithms of one plus the annual growth rate of GDP per capita divided by 100 and age dependency ratio divided by 100, respectively. Data for the annual growth rate of GDP per capita, gross national income per capita and age dependency ratio (dependents to working-age population) are taken from the World Bank World Development Indicators Database (2009). The whole sample contains 122 non-transition economies over the period 1978-2007 with a maximum of 10 observations per country as listed in the Appendix Table 2. We exclude countries with less than 10 observations during the period studied. We consider three subsamples in this analysis, low income sample, higher energy intensity sample and lower trade share sample. The low income subsample contains 47 low income countries. Information on the classications of income levels is obtained from the World Bank Global Development Network Database (2002). The higher energy intensity sample contains 56 countries whose averaged nal energy intensities over 1978-2007 are above the median value of the averaged nal energy intensities. Data on nal energy intensity of GDP at purchasing power parities are taken from the Global Energy Market Data (2008) of Enerdata. The lower trade share sample has 67 countries whose averaged trade shares are below the median value of the averaged trade shares over 1978-2007. Data on trade share (% of GDP) are taken from the World Bank World Development Indicators Database (2009). Figure 1 presents the longer-run evolutions of genuine savings, output volatility and private credit volatility for the whole sample and three subsamples from 1978 to 2007. The gures display the prevailing volatility in the past three decades, especially from the end of 1990s to the beginning of the 21st century after the Asian nancial crisis and other regional economic crises. The gures also illustrate an increase of private credit volatility while a decline of output volatility. Figure 2 simply shows the scatter plots 9

Figure 1.1 Genuine Savings Over Time 0.1 0.08 whole_sample Genuine Savings 0.06 low_income_sample 0.04 0.02 0 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 -0.02 Year higher_energy_intensity_sampl e lower_trade_share_sample

Figure 1.2 Output Volatility Over Time 0.06 0.05 Output Volatility 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 Year whole_sample low_income_sample higher_energy_intensive_sampl e lower_trade_share_sample

Figure 1.3 Private Credit Volatility Over Time 0.025 Private Credit Volatilit 0.02 0.015 0.01 0.005 0 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 Year whole_sample low_income_sample higher_energy_intensive_sampl e lower_trade_share_sample

Figure 2: Scatter Plots of Genuine Savings and Output Volatility


A. Whole Sample .4
Genuine Savings MDV SGP BWA BTN CHN THACPV KORPAN CHENAM MYS HKG JOR MAR FJI JPN CYPBLZ SWE MUSFIN DZA LKA PAK PHL IDN NLD CANIRLNPL VNM KEN JAM IND BELPRT BRA DOM FRAAUT TUNHTI VCT TUR PER ITA DNK LAOHND CRI SWZ TON DMA SYC ESPGRC PRY NOR EGY ISLMEX BGD USA MNGCMR ERI NZL ZAF SLV GBR ISR AUS COL GMB BFA URY KHM BRN MLI ARG CIV VUT TZA GHA BENCHLSEN MDG GUY TGOZWE ETH GTM COM MRT NER BOL CAF GIN UGA SDN VENMWI GAB ZAR SAUIRN SYR ECU TTO LBN BDI NIC ZMB MOZ AGO COG

.2

RWA SLE GNB TCD

.4 .2 0

.02

.04
Output Volatility

.06

.08

B. Low Income Sample .4


Genuine Savings BTN CHN IDN VNM KEN HND NPL LAOIND BGD PAK MNGCMR ERI HTI ZWE ETH GMB BFA KHM MLI CIV TZA GHA BEN COM MRT SEN MDG NER CAF GIN UGA SDN TGOMWI ZAR BDI NIC ZMB MOZ AGO COG

.2

RWA SLE GNB TCD

.4 .2 0

.02

.04
Output Volatility

.06

.08

C. Higher Energy Intensity Sample .4


Genuine Savings BTN CHN KOR SWELAO IND JOR FJI I VNMPAK HND BEL CAN JAMDN NPL FIN KEN MNG SWZ ERI USA ZWE ETH MLI SLV SEN TZA GHA BEN CMR CIV CAF BFA GUY VEN GIN UGA IRN SDN TGO MWI GAB ZAR SAU SYR TTO LBN BDI ZMB MOZ AGO COG

.2

RWA SLE GNB

.4 .2 0

.02

.04
Output Volatility

.06

.08

D. Lower Trade Share Sample


CHN KOR MAR JPN DZA IDN FIN FRA PAK NPL ITA CAN IND LAO DOM TUR KEN ESP PRT BRA PER BGD USA NZL EGY HTI GRC MEX ZWE GBR AUSZAF SLVCMR URY MLI ARG ETH TZACOL GHA BFA GTM COMMDG NER BENCHLSEN CAF VEN BOL GIN IRN SDN MWI UGA ZAR SYR ECU BDI NIC MOZ Genuine Savings

.1

.2

RWA SLE GNB TCD

.1 0

.02

.04
Output Volatility

.06

.08

Note: Variables and data sources are described in the text.

between genuine savings and output volatility, suggesting a negative association between genuine savings and output volatility for the whole sample and three subsamples.

3.2

Methodology

This section reviews the methods used to study the impact of economic volatility on sustainable development in the context of globalisation. It employs the GMM methods adjusted to allow for error cross section dependence, recently proposed by Saradis et al. (2009) for a linear dynamic panel model. In recent decades, the cross country dependence has become an important phenomenon in a globalised world where the existence of common factors, either global, cyclical or seasonal eects, has the potential to cause stronger interactions in the world economy. To allow for error cross section dependence, the following AR(1) model has been found appropriate for this application:

GEN SAVit = i + GEN SAVi,t1 + 1 V OLi,t1 + 2 GRi,t1 + 3 GN IP Ci,t1 + 4 AGEit + i ft + vit i = 1, 2, ..., 122 and t = 2, ..., 10 where V OL denotes the volatility measure, which could be output volatility measures V GR, or private credit volatility measure V P RIV O. i is the individual eects. The autoregressive coecient is assumed to lie inside the unit circle, | | < 1, to ensure the model stability. The coecients 1 to 4 reect the existence and direction of any specic eect on sustainable development. ft is a (r 1) vector of unobserved time-varying common factors assumed to be nonstochastic and bounded, and i is a vector of factor 0 loadings assumed to be i.i.d., such that i ft = i1 ft1 + i2 ft2 + .... + ir ftr (here r is the number of common factors).9 The common factors could be either macroeconomic shocks, common technological shocks or environmental
Bai (2009) suggests an interactive eects model including the interaction between factors, ft , and factor loadings, i , which is more general than an additive eects model, the traditional one-way or two-way xed eects model. When we take r=2, we have ft = (1
9 0

(1)

12

shocks that lead to cross section dependence. The error term vit is the transitory disturbance term, which is assumed to be independently distributed with zero mean and nite variance. vit is assumed to be uncorrelated with the individual eects and common factors, but the correlations between, either individual eects or common factors (ft and subseqent shocks), and the regressors are possible. We assume that V OL, GR, and GN IP C are predetermined with respective to vit in the sense that these variables may be correlated with vi, t1 and earlier shocks, but is uncorrelated with vi t and subsequent shocks. The assumption on these explanatory variables, except for AGE, being predetermined rules out a potential endogeneity bias, but allows for feedbacks from the past realizations of GEN SAV to current values of these explanatory variables. Below is Equation (1) in rst dierences:

GEN SAVit = GENSAVi,t1 + 1 V OLi,t1 + 2 GRi,t1 + 3 GN IP Ci,t1 + 4 AGEit + i ft + vit i = 1, 2, ..., 122 and t = 3, ..., 10 where GEN SAVit = GEN SAVit GEN SAVi,t1 , which applies to AGEit . V OLi,t1 = V OLi,t1 V OLi,t2 , which also applies to GRi,t1 and GN IP Ci,t1 . ft = ft ft1 and vit = vit vi,t1 . When common factors are assumed to have an identical eect on each cross section unit, a number of methods have been proposed to estimate the dynamic panel data models with a short time dimension, in which rstdierencing is used to eliminate the individual eects. Arellano and Bond (1991) propose the rst-dierenced GMM estimator, denoted by DIF-GMM, which uses all lagged values of dependent variable and independent variables dated from t 2 and earlier as suitable instruments for the dierenced values of the original regressors, for example, GEN SAVi,t1 , V OLi,t1 , GRi,t1 , GN IP Ci,t1 , and AGEit in this context.
t ) , i = (i 1), and i ft = i + t , where i and t are the individual eect and time eect, respectively.
0 0 0

(2)

13

For simplicity, we let yit denote GEN SAVit and let xit be a vector of the independent variables, e.g. (V OLit , GRit , GN IP Cit , AGEit ). The moment conditions for errors in dierences on which the DIF-GMM estimator is based in this application can be written as,
t2 yi xt2 i

(vit ) = 0

(3)

t = 3, .., 10

t2 where yi = (yi1 , yi2 , ...., yi,t2 )0 and xt2 = (xi1 , xi2 , ...., xi,t2 )0 . i The weak instruments problem associated with the DIF-GMM estimator has been widely aware when data are highly persistent. To address this issue, Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998) develop a system GMM estimator, denoted by SYS-GMM, by considering a mean stationarity assumption on initial conditions.10 The additional mean stationarity condition of (yit , xit ) enables the lagged rst-dierences of the series (yit , xit ) dated t 1 as instruments for the untransformed equations in levels. More specically, in addition to the moments for errors in dierences described above, the SYS-GMM estimator is also based on the additional moments for errors in levels as follows,

yi,t1 xi,t1

( i + vit ) = 0

(4)

t = 3, .., 10

However, in reality common factors are typically having a dierential eect across cross-sectional units, causing heterogeneous error cross section dependence. Saradis and Robertson (2009) show that the standard DIF-GMM and SYS-GMM estimators are not consistent in the presence of
Blundell and Bond (2000) show that the joint mean stationarity of the series in the multivariate autoregressive model is a sucient condition for the additional moment conditions to be valid. Blundell and Bond (1998) argue that, combining the rst-dierenced equations (with suitably lagged levels as instruments), with levels equations (with suitably lagged rst-dierences as instruments), the SYS-GMM estimator is expected to have much smaller nite sample bias and greater precision than DIF-GMM estimator in the presence of persistent data.
10

14

heterogeneous error cross section dependence, for the standard instruments these estimators rely on with respect to lagged values of the dependent variable, in either levels or rst-dierences, are invalid. Under the assumption of heterogeneous error cross section dependence, Saradis et al. (2009) suggest a consistent rst-dierenced GMM estimator, denoted by DIF-GMM-C, and a consistent system GMM estimator, denoted by SYS-GMM-C. These two GMM estimators only rely on the partial instruments consisting of the regressors. More specically, based on the partial moment condition (5) as shown below the DIF-GMM-C estimator is consistent under the assumption of heterogeneous error cross section dependence. This applies to the SYS-GMM-C estimator, which is based on the partial moment conditions (5) and (6) in the following: E xt2 vit = 0 i (5)

t = 3, .., 10

E [xi,t1 ( i + vit )] = 0 t = 3, .., 10

(6)

A new testing procedure for detecting error cross section dependence in a linear dynamic panel model has been proposed by Saradis et al. (2009). Under the null hypothesis of homogeneous error cross section dependence (CSD), the CSD test enables the examination on whether any error cross section dependence remains after including time dummies. The CSD test is the Sargans dierence tests based on either the two-step rst-dierenced GMM estimator or two-step system GMM estimator.11 The nite sample simulation-based results in Saradis et al. (2009) show the good performance of the CSD test, especially for the version based on system GMM estimator.
The Sargans dierence test statistics based on two-step rst-dierenced GMM estimator is the dierence between the Sargan statistics for DIF-GMM with standard set of moment conditions (3) and the Sargan statistics for DIF-GMM-C using restricted set of moment conditions (5). The Sargans dierence test statistics based on two-step system GMM estimator is the dierence between the Sargan statistics for SYS-GMM with standard set of moment conditions (3) and (4) and the Sargan statistics for SYS-GMM-C using restricted set of moment conditions (5) and (6).
11

15

To avoid the possible overtting bias associated with using the full Arellano and Bond (1991) instrument set, this analysis uses restricted instrument sets suggested by Bowsher (2002), who proposes to selectively reduce the number of moment conditions for each rst-dierenced equation. More specically, we only use lagged values of yit and xit from t 2 to t 3 as instruments in this analysis.

Empirical Results

This section rstly presents the econometric evidence on whether macroeconomic volatility, either output volatility or nancial market volatility, is an impediment to global sustainability. The second subsection then moves on to examine the channels through which volatility adversely aects sustainable development. Every table contrasts the DIF-GMM and SYS-GMM estimates assuming cross-sectionally independence with their counterparts, DIF-GMM-C and SYS-GMM-C, under the assumption of errors being cross-sectionally dependent.12 A nite sample correction is made to the two-step covariance matrix using the method due to Windmeijer (2005) for both the rst-dierenced GMM estimator and system GMM estimator under either assumption. For any GMM estimators, three specication tests are conducted to address the consistency. The rst two are the Serial Correlation tests, M1 and M2, which test the null hypothesis of no rst-order serial correlation and no second-order serial correlation in the residuals in the rst-dierenced equation, respectively. Given that the errors in levels are serially uncorrelated, we would expect to nd signicant rst-order serial correlation, but insignicant second-order correlation in the rst-dierenced residuals. The third is a Sargan test of overidentifying restrictions, which examines the overall validity of the instruments by comparing the moment conditions with their sample analogue. For SYS-GMM and SYS-GMM-C, an additional test, namely the Dierence Sargan test denoted by Di-Sargan, is carried out. The Dier12 Under either assumption, the rst-dierenced GMM estimates and system GMM estimates in every model have been found to lie between the Within Group estimates, being downwards biased, and the OLS estimates, being upwards biased, for the lagged dependent variable (Bond et al., 2001; Bond, 2002).

16

ence Sargan test examines the null hypothesis that the lagged dierences of the explanatory variables are uncorrelated with the errors in the levels equations due to Blundell and Bond (1998).13 The new cross-sectional dependence (CSD) tests based on rst-dierenced GMM estimator and system GMM estimator as explained above are conducted, respectively.14

4.1
4.1.1

The Impacts of Volatility on Sustainability


Output Volatility

This subsection studies whether output volatility has led to unsustainability in the economy over the period from 1978 to 2007. Table 1 reports the evidence for the whole sample of 122 countries. Table 2, Table 3 and Table 4 present evidence for the lower income group, higher energy intensity group and the lower trade share group, respectively. Columns 1 and 2 in Table 1 are concerned about the case of crosssectional independence, whilst columns 3 and 4 are for the case of crosssectional dependence. The specication tests indicate that every model is well specied. More specically, we can reject no rst-order serial correlation but cannot reject the hypothesis that there is no second-order serial correlation in any of the four models. The Sargan tests do not signal that the instruments in any of four models are invalid. Under dierent assumption, both DIF-GMM and DIF-GMM-C suggest a strong negative impact of the output volatility on genuine savings. The Di-Sargan tests for SYS-GMM and SYS-GMM-C cannot reject the null of the additional moment conditions being valid, implying that system GMM is a more reliable estimator than the rst-dierenced GMM in this context. Under dierent assumption, both SYS-GMM and SYS-GMMC suggest that the impact of output volatility on global sustainability is negative, but it is signicant at 15% level. Both SYS-GMM and SYS-GMMC also provide evidence that GN IP C and AGE are negatively present in the model within 5% signicance level.
The statistic, called an incremental Sargan test statistic, is the dierence between the Sargan statistics for DIF-GMM (or DIF-GMM-C) and Sargan statistics for SYS-GMM (or SYS-GMM-C). 14 For all specication tests in all tables below, reported are the p-values.
13

17

Table 1 . Output Volatility and Global Sustainability: 1978-2007 (Whole Sample)


Dependent Variable: Cross-sectional independence DIF-GMM SYS-GMM 0.605 0.710 [0.000]*** [0.000]*** -0.205 -0.151 [0.062]* [0.118] -0.040 0.089 [0.870] [0.505] -0.072 -0.038 [0.217] [0.017]** -0.074 -0.419 [0.840] [0.011]** 0.02 0.00 0.12 0.14 0.44 0.68 0.32 787 0.76 0.60 910 Cross-sectional dependence DIF-GMM-C SYS-GMM-C 0.702 0.654 [0.006]*** [0.000]*** -0.250 -0.153 [0.040]** [0.147] -0.038 0.161 [0.886] [0.220] -0.085 -0.037 [0.203] [0.036]** -0.114 -0.442 [0.788] [0.032]** 0.06 0.01 0.11 0.13 0.46 0.59 0.56 787 910

GENSAVit
GENSAVi ,t 1
VGR i , t 1 GR i ,t 1 GNIPC
AGE
it

i , t 1

M1 M2 Sargan test Diff-Sargan test CSD test Observations

Notes: 122 countries over the period of 1978-2007. Global sustainability (GENSAV) is measured by the 3-year averages of genuine savings. Output volatility (VGR) is measured by the standard deviation over 3-year interval of the growth rate of GDP per capita. Controlled variables are the 3-year averages of per capita GDP growth rate (GR), per capita GNI (GNIPC), and age dependence ratio. (AGE). See text for their definitions. Under the assumption of cross-sectional independence first-differenced GMM estimates, denoted by DIFF-GMM, and system GMM estimates, denoted by SYS-GMM, are reported. When cross-sectional dependence is allowed, their counterpartes are reported, DIFF-GMM-C and SYS-GMM-C. Both first-differenced GMM and system GMM results are two-step estimates with heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors and test statistics; the standard errors are based on finite sample adjustment of Windmeijer (2005). M1 and M2 test the null of no first-order and no second-order serial correlation in first-differenced residuals, respectively. The Sargan tests the overidentifying restrictions for GMM estimators, asymptotically . Diff-Sargan tests the null of mean stationarity for system GMM estimators in which SYS-GMM or SYS-GMM-C use standard moment conditions. CSD test is to examine the null hypothesis of homogeneous error cross section dependence due to Sarafidis et al. (2009). Robust p values in brackets below point estimates. *, **, *** significant at 10%, 5%, 1%, respectively.

Table 2 . Output Volatility and Global Sustainability: 1978-2007 (Low Income Sample)
Dependent Variable: Cross-sectional independence DIF-GMM SYS-GMM 0.694 0.768 [0.000]*** [0.000]*** -0.246 -0.248 [0.054]* [0.073]* -0.088 -0.082 [0.770] [0.576] -0.061 -0.100 [0.268] [0.023]** -0.351 -0.686 [0.448] [0.014]** 0.02 0.01 0.14 0.15 0.55 0.90 0.34 282 0.97 0.72 331 Cross-sectional dependence DIF-GMM-C SYS-GMM-C 0.210 0.766 [0.655] [0.006]*** -0.168 -0.286 [0.293] [0.022]** 0.164 -0.186 [0.709] [0.558] 0.036 -0.113 [0.812] [0.187] 0.255 -0.720 [0.763] [0.020]** 0.80 0.09 0.12 0.13 0.62 0.83 0.78 282 331

GENSAVit GENSAVi ,t 1
VGR i , t 1 GR i ,t 1 GNIPC
AGE
it

i , t 1

M1 M2 Sargan test Diff-Sargan test CSD test Observations

Notes: The low income sample contains 47 low income countries. See Table 1 for more notes.

Table 3 . Output Volatility and Global Sustainability: 1978-2007 (Higher Energy Intensity Sample)
Dependent Variable: Cross-sectional independence DIF-GMM SYS-GMM 0.596 0.662 [0.000]*** [0.000]*** -0.240 -0.218 [0.003]*** [0.028]** -0.004 0.043 [0.987] [0.823] -0.077 -0.053 [0.249] [0.066]* 0.130 -0.597 [0.735] [0.018]** 0.02 0.01 0.48 0.55 0.90 0.98 0.64 348 0.90 0.74 406 Cross-sectional dependence DIF-GMM-C SYS-GMM-C 0.866 0.619 [0.059]* [0.001]*** -0.280 -0.235 [0.005]*** [0.051]* 0.016 0.076 [0.948] [0.699] -0.092 -0.057 [0.141] [0.111] 0.157 -0.618 [0.701] [0.069]* 0.11 0.02 0.49 0.57 0.86 0.96 0.87 348 406

GENSAVit GENSAVi ,t 1
VGR i , t 1 GR i ,t 1 GNIPC
AGE
it

i , t 1

M1 M2 Sargan test Diff-Sargan test CSD test Observations

Notes: The higher energy intensity sample contains 56 countries whose averaged final energy intensities over 1978-2007 are above the median value of the averaged final energy intensities. See Table 1 for more notes.

Table 4 . Output Volatility and Global Sustainability: 1978-2007 (Lower Trade Share Sample)
Dependent Variable: Cross-sectional independence DIF-GMM SYS-GMM 0.607 0.623 [0.000]*** [0.000]*** -0.118 -0.179 [0.413] [0.187] 0.162 0.162 [0.441] [0.282] -0.031 -0.034 [0.609] [0.061]* -0.016 -0.440 [0.965] [0.047]** 0.01 0.01 0.48 0.55 0.18 0.81 0.61 461 1.00 1.00 530 Cross-sectional dependence DIF-GMM-C SYS-GMM-C 0.746 0.628 [0.000]*** [0.011]** -0.140 -0.212 [0.406] [0.118] 0.096 0.132 [0.703] [0.402] -0.050 -0.046 [0.328] [0.026]** -0.022 -0.502 [0.947] [0.082]* 0.02 0.05 0.42 0.55 0.09 0.44 0.99 461 530

GENSAVit GENSAVi ,t 1
VGR i , t 1 GR i ,t 1 GNIPC
AGE
it

i , t 1

M1 M2 Sargan test Diff-Sargan test CSD test Observations

Notes: The lower trade share sample contains 67 countries whose averaged trade shares (% of GDP) over 1978-2007 are below the median value of the averaged trade shares. See Table 1 for more notes.

The CSD tests based on rst-dierenced GMM estimator and system GMM estimator fail to reject the null of homogeneous error cross section dependence for both the whole sample and the subsamples. However, under certain circumstances this test might lack power because it is based on the overidentifying restrictions test statistic, and accordingly this result should be interpreted with caution. Next subsection provides evidence for such a cross section dependence to exist when nancial market volatility is investigated. In principle, the rst-dierenced GMM and system GMM estimates impose homogeneity on all slope coecients, under assumption of either the cross-sectional independence or cross-sectional dependence. One concern over the GMM estimates is that these parameters may be heterogeneous across countries. To address this concern we simply need to look into some subsamples, which are more homogeneous. In what follows we turn to three subsamples with results presented in Table 2, Table 3 and Table 4, respectively. Table 2 focuses on the subsample of 47 low income countries. Under either assumption, the patterns of the specication tests including M1, M2 and Sargan tests, indicate that all four models are well-specied. Di-Sargan test further shows that system GMM is a more reliable estimator than the rst-dierenced GMM for this case. Both SYS-GMM and SYS-GMM-C provide evidence for a strong negative impact going from output volatility to genuine savings in the low income sample. Table 3 looks at the subsample of 56 higher energy intensity countries. These are countries having averaged nal energy intensities above the median value of the averaged nal energy intensities over 1978-2007. Under different assumption, both rst-dierenced GMM, DIF-GMM and DIF-GMM, and system GMM, SYS-GMM and SYS-GMM-C, consistently suggest a strong negative impact of output volatility on sustainable development in these countries. In Table 4 we turn to the subsample of 67 lower trade share countries. These countries in general have averaged trade shares over GDP under the median value of the averaged trade shares over 1978-2007. The specication tests continue to show that the models in four columns are well-specied 22

and the system GMM estimator is preferable to rst-dierenced GMM estimator. Both SYS-GMM and SYS-GMM-C nd a negative impact of output volatility on sustainable development, signicant at 19% and 12% levels. Under dierent assumption, both SYS-GMM and SYS-GMM-C estimates conrm that both GNIP C and AGE signicantly enter the model. In general, this subsection provides evidence that output volatility exerts an adverse eect on global sustainability, especially for the low income countries, higher energy intensity countries and lower trade share countries. 4.1.2 Financial Market Volatility

This subsection turns to nancial market volatility in terms of private credit volatility (V P RIV O). Table 5 reports evidence for the whole sample, while Table 6 and Table 7 present results for the higher energy intensity sample and lower trade share sample.15 Table 5 reports evidence for the whole sample of 122 countries. Serial correlation tests, M1 and M2, suggest that we can reject the hypothesis of no rst-order serial correlation but cannot reject no second-order serial correlation in any of the four models. The Sargan tests cannot reject the null that the instruments in any of four models are valid. The Di-Sargan tests for SYS-GMM and SYS-GMM-C cannot reject the null that the additional moment conditions are valid, supporting system GMM estimator for the more reliable estimator for this context. Based on system GMM estimator, the CSD test clearly rejects the null of homogeneous cross-sectional dependence.16 This points to the importance of taking into account the issue of cross-sectional dependence for this context and suggests that the SYS-GMM-C is a consistent estimator. The SYS-GMM-C estimates provide strong evidence on a negative eect of private credit volatility on global sustainability. According to Saradis and Robertson (2009), the standard SYS-GMM estimator is not consistent in the presence of heterogeneous error cross section dependence. Ideally, one would expect to see Sargans test for SYSWe nd no signicant evidence for the low income sample. The CSD test based on rst-dierenced GMM estimator rejects the null at 13% signicant level.
16 15

23

GMM rejecting the null while Sargans test for SYS-GMM-C failing to reject the null and CSD test rejecting the null. However, the p-value of Sargans test for SYS-GMM is 0.49, indicating that SYS-GMM is actually consistent in this context. On way to explain this contradiction is that Sargans test typically has low power. An interesting observation is that CSD test will reject the null when the estimated coecients for at least one regressor, except for the lagged dependent variable, are signicantly dierent. For example, for V P RIV Oi,t1 the SYS-GMM estimate is -0.170 while the SYS-GMM-C estimate is -0.234. Similar observation can be found in Table 8 below where the SYS-GMM estimate for GRi,t1 is 0.180 while SYS-GMM-C estimate is 0.244 (for nancial development channel). For the whole sample, the CSD test clearly rejects the null. Since parameter heterogeneity is a potential cause of cross-sectional dependence, it might be expected that for the subsamples below the CSD test fails to reject the null. Table 6 reports evidence for the subsample of 56 higher energy intensity countries. Neither Di-Sargan test nor CSD test based on system GMM can reject the null, calling for the attention to be paid to the SYS-GMM estimates. The SYS-GMM estimates conrm the strong negative impact of private credit volatility (V P RIV O) on sustainable development in these countries. In Table 7 we present evidence for the subsample of 67 lower trade share countries. Under dierent assumption, both DIF-GMM and DIF-GMM-C estimates provide strong evidence for the signicant eect of private credit volatility (V P RIV O) on sustainable development, but system GMM estimates suggest that the eect is signicant at about 18% level. This subsection nds a strong negative impact of private credit volatility on global sustainability in both the whole sample and two subsamples, higher energy intensity countries and lower trade share countries. This nding points to the possible damaging consequences of credit volatility for the economy as a whole, consistent with what has happened during global nancial crisis of 2007-2009. In the aftermath of the subprime crisis and housing bubbles burst in mid-2007, worldwide credit crunch became a major economic phenomenon, triggering a sustained period of stress and instability in 24

Table 5. Financial Market Volatility and Global Sustainability: 1978-2007 (Whole Sample)
Dependent Variable: Cross-sectional independence DIF-GMM SYS-GMM 0.377 0.644 [0.073]* [0.000]*** -0.116 -0.170 [0.186] [0.022]** 0.014 0.048 [0.928] [0.654] -0.065 -0.030 [0.272] [0.017]** -0.063 -0.474 [0.835] [0.008]*** 0.09 0.00 0.33 0.64 0.40 0.49 0.13 682 0.51 0.09 798 Cross-sectional dependence DIF-GMM-C SYS-GMM-C 0.545 0.807 [0.062]* [0.000]*** -0.172 -0.234 [0.090]* [0.007]*** -0.124 0.072 [0.489] [0.549] -0.105 -0.027 [0.106] [0.056]* 0.030 -0.302 [0.925] [0.176] 0.09 0.00 0.32 0.57 0.80 0.89 0.75 682 798

GENSAVit GENSAVi ,t 1
VPRIVO i , t 1 GR i ,t 1
GNIPC
AGE
it

i , t 1

M1 M2 Sargan test Diff-Sargan test CSD test Observations

Notes: 122 countries. The financial market volatility is in terms of private credit volatility (VPRIVO), which is defined in the text. See Table 1 for more notes.

Table 6. Financial Market Volatility and Global Sustainability: 1978-2007


(Higher Energy Intensity Sample) Dependent Variable: Cross-sectional independence DIF-GMM SYS-GMM 0.201 0.493 [0.499] [0.000]*** -0.068 -0.267 [0.652] [0.073]* -0.149 -0.127 [0.329] [0.414] -0.085 -0.052 [0.255] [0.046]** 0.122 -0.772 [0.768] [0.009]*** 0.42 0.03 0.53 0.61 0.55 0.80 0.47 294 0.82 0.61 349 Cross-sectional dependence DIF-GMM-C SYS-GMM-C 0.435 0.609 [0.252] [0.009]*** -0.193 -0.279 [0.303] [0.075]* -0.198 -0.048 [0.426] [0.820] -0.116 -0.041 [0.193] [0.174] 0.286 -0.552 [0.516] [0.144] 0.33 0.04 0.70 0.61 0.48 0.73 0.75 294 349

GENSAVit GENSAVi ,t 1
VPRIVO i , t 1 GR i ,t 1
GNIPC
AGE
it

i , t 1

M1 M2 Sargan test Diff-Sargan test CSD test Observations

Notes: The higher energy intensity sample contains 56 countries whose averaged final energy intensities over 1978-2007 are above the median value of the averaged final energy intensities. See Table 1 and Table 6 for more notes.

Table 7. Financial Market Volatility and Global Sustainability: 1978-2007 (Lower Trade Share Sample)
Dependent Variable: Cross-sectional independence DIF-GMM SYS-GMM 0.469 0.635 [0.000]*** [0.000]*** -0.266 -0.150 [0.078]* [0.181] 0.194 0.130 [0.192] [0.318] -0.020 -0.038 [0.712] [0.016]** -0.146 -0.526 [0.649] [0.010]*** 0.02 0.01 0.84 0.72 0.75 0.51 0.48 395 0.26 0.76 461 Cross-sectional dependence DIF-GMM-C SYS-GMM-C 0.601 0.648 [0.004]*** [0.007]*** -0.296 -0.166 [0.064]* [0.171] 0.174 0.148 [0.280] [0.265] -0.032 -0.021 [0.590] [0.185] -0.111 -0.363 [0.724] [0.047]** 0.04 0.03 0.86 0.76 0.74 0.33 0.15 395 461

GENSAVit GENSAVi ,t 1
VPRIVO i , t 1 GR i ,t 1
GNIPC
AGE
it

i , t 1

M1 M2 Sargan test Diff-Sargan test CSD test Observations

Notes: The lower trade share sample contains 67 countries whose averaged trade shares (% of GDP) over 1978-2007 are below the median value of the averaged trade shares. See Table 1 and Table 6 for more notes.

global nancial markets and the worst global recession for generations. In summary, we nd both output volatility and nancial market volatility cause damaging eects on global sustainability for 122 countries, by comparing the GMM estimation methods controlling for the possibility of endogeneity bias and omitted variable bias. The negative eects of output volatility are aggravated in low income countries, higher energy intensity countries and lower trade share countries. The negative eects of nancial market volatility have also been found in higher energy intensity countries and lower trade share countries. We also nd evidence for cross country dependence in this context when nancial market volatility is examined. The results are in general robust to the use of alternative estimation methods and data subsamples, and not due to unobserved heterogeneity, or endogeneity biases.

4.2

The Channels

In this subsection we go a step further to investigate the underlying mechanisms or channels through which volatility aects sustainable development. Table 8 presents evidence on whether output volatility works through either investment share or nancial development measure on sustainable development. When the investment share (KI) is examined, the specication tests show that the models in the rst four columns are well-specied and the system GMM estimator is better than the rst-dierenced GMM estimator. The CSD test suggests no heterogeneous cross-sectional dependence in this context, implying that DIF-GMM and SYS-GMM estimators are consistent. Both DIF-GMM and SYS-GMM nd no signicant evidence for investment share KI, while V GR continues to signicantly enter the models. This reveals that investment share, KI, doesnt seem to pick up any eect of output volatility on sustainable development, and therefore is not a channel for output volatility to aect sustainability. Next we explore the possible nancial development channel via private credit ratio (P RIV O). As suggested by the specication tests, four models are again well-specied and system GMM performs better than the rstdierenced GMM. The CSD test based on the system GMM estimator

28

Table 8 . Channels Through Which Output Volatility Affects Global Sustainability: 1978-2007
Dependent Variable:

GENSAVit GENSAVi ,t 1
VGR i , t 1

KI i ,t 1 PRIVO i ,t 1
GR i ,t 1
GNIPC
AGE
i , t 1

DIF-GMM 0.610 [0.000]*** -0.165 [0.067]* -0.161 [0.542]

Investment Channel SYS-GMM DIF-GMM-C SYS-GMM-C 0.738 0.612 0.615 [0.000]*** [0.064]* [0.001]*** -0.143 -0.206 -0.154 [0.100]* [0.106] [0.125] -0.081 -0.192 -0.006 [0.677] [0.647] [0.976]

DIF-GMM 0.467 [0.003]*** -0.111 [0.307]

Financial Development Channel SYS-GMM DIF-GMM-C SYS-GMM-C 0.709 0.676 0.778 [0.000]*** [0.049]** [0.000]*** -0.046 -0.193 -0.037 [0.606] [0.101] [0.678]

it

M1 M2 Sargan test Diff-Sargan test CSD test Observations

0.002 [0.991] -0.059 [0.276] -0.137 [0.698] 0.01 0.12 0.53 0.63 787

0.094 [0.459] -0.031 [0.157] -0.400 [0.014]** 0.00 0.14 0.71 0.71 0.36 910

0.060 [0.843] -0.052 [0.491] -0.244 [0.641] 0.14 0.11 0.38

0.162 [0.156] -0.040 [0.051]* -0.501 [0.016]** 0.03 0.13 0.77 0.92 910

-0.035 [0.712] 0.011 [0.959] -0.075 [0.337] -0.031 [0.901] 0.03 0.35 0.32 0.21 698

787

-0.116 [0.037]** 0.180 [0.316] 0.014 [0.604] -0.120 [0.540] 0.00 0.46 0.19 0.17 0.08 811

-0.017 [0.875] -0.117 [0.595] -0.144 [0.163] 0.013 [0.973] 0.09 0.34 0.41

-0.125 [0.006]*** 0.244 [0.071]* 0.023 [0.257] 0.025 [0.885] 0.00 0.44 0.41 0.37 811

698

Notes: 122 countries. The investment channel via investment share of GDP (KI) and the financial development channel via private credit ratio (PRIVO) are examined separately. See text for the definitions of KI and PRIVO. See Table 1 for more notes.

clearly rejects the null of homogeneous cross-sectional dependence, suggesting that SYS-GMM estimator is not consistent and we shall instead rely on the SYS-GMM-C estimator. The SYS-GMM-C estimates clearly indicate that V GR is no longer signicant in the model while P RIV O enters the model signicantly. In contrast to investment share, KI, private credit ratio, P RIV O, apparently picks up the eect of output volatility on sustainable development and is indeed the channel through which output volatility hampers global sustainability. To identify the transmission channels for the negative eect of nancial market volatility on global sustainability to work through, various channels have been examined, including investment share, nal energy intensity, and energy consumption per capita.17 However, there is no evidence for either nal energy intensity or energy consumption per capita to enter the models signicantly; for investment share, it doesnt seem to pick up any eect of nancial market volatility, either. This remains an interesting area for further research. The nding regarding a nancial development channel has signicant implications and sheds some light on the interaction between economic downturn and nancial crisis during the 2007-2009 global nancial crisis. A number of research has suggested that global nancial turmoil and economic volatility have cut demand for goods and services from some developing countries, reduced trade and investment ows to and from these countries, and led to a long-run economic decline in these countries. Any associated dramatic changes in demand for goods and manufacturing could potentially lead to the wastes of natural resources, unsustainable consumption and production, and a high degree of climate risk.18 In the process of unsustainData for the investment share of real GDP per capita (RGDPL) are taken from the Penn World Table 6.3 (2009). The analysis uses the logarithm of one plus the investment share of real GDP per capita (RGDPL) divided by 100. Data on nal energy intensity of GDP at purchasing power parities are taken from the Global Energy Market Data (2008) of Enerdata. The analysis uses the logarithm of one plus the nal energy intensity. Data for energy use (kg of oil equivalent per capita) are from the World Bank World Development Indicators Database (2009). The analysis uses the logarithm of energy use per capita. 18 Many Economists also argue that the global economic downturn has compounded and exacerbated persistent social problems of job losses, social-economic insecurity and poverty which threaten social stability in both developed and developing countries. It has
17

30

ability caused by economic volatility, nancial markets might have played a crucial role. After the collapse of the U.S. subprime mortgage market in 2007, especially the failure of Lehman Brothers in 2008, the global economic downturn further impacted the nancial system by increasing the credit risk and the levels of uncertainty. As a result, investors refused to provide funds to the banks while banks were reluctant to provide sucient credit to creditworthy borrowers due to the loss of condence. The credit conditions and nancial markets were severely impacted with the availability of credit and insurance that facilitate manufacturing and trade being curtailed. The sharp drop in global demand for commodities and global manufacturing has been further amplied by restricted access to nance and considerable uncertainty. This further eroded the ability of economic system to maintain sound productivity and ecological processes into the future, with damaging consequences for national economy. The ndings highlight the interaction between global nancial markets and the wider economy as a key factor inuencing the low carbon development path.

Summary and Conclusions

This paper investigates the issue of whether economic volatility has a damaging eect on global sustainability. It carries out a dynamic panel data study based on data for 122 countries over 1978-2007 and makes use of the genuine savings or adjusted net savings to measure the level of sustainable development. To address the issue of cross country dependence caused by global shocks, this research applies the system GMM method adjusted to allow for error cross section dependence due to Saradis et al. (2009). This analysis nds both output volatility and nancial market volatility cause damaging eects on global sustainability for the whole sample. The negative eects of output volatility are aggravated in low income countries, higher energy intensity countries and lower trade share countries, while the
hampered the eorts of developing countries towards achieving their Millennium Development Goals, and the eorts of international community towards helping deliver improved living standards for the most vulnerable people and countries.

31

negative eects of nancial market volatility have also been found prominent in higher energy intensity countries and lower trade share countries. This analysis also identies a nancial development channel with respective to private credit ratio through which output volatility prevents sustainable development. The results are in general robust to the use of alternative estimation methods and data subsamples, and not due to unobserved heterogeneity, or endogeneity biases. This analysis also provides evidence for cross country dependence in this context when nancial market volatility is examined. This is perhaps due to the fact that nancial markets are typically associated with crossborder nancial linkage or nancial integration; accordingly nancial crisis and macroeconomic volatility in one country tend to spread around global nancial markets rapidly. The adverse eect of output volatility on sustainable development has been found exacerbated in countries that have low income per capita, higher energy intensities and lower trade shares. However, the ability to tackle volatility impacts in those countries might be constrained by weak institutions, an underdeveloped nancial sector, and other political economy considerations. Empirical research continues to show that weak institutions and underdeveloped nancial sector in developing countries could even amplify the adverse eects of volatility on long-run growth and sustainable development, and result in permanent setbacks and a long-run development problem relative to developed countries. Therefore it is suggested that governments of developing countries should aim for lower energy intensities, more open trade policies as well as strong institutions, good governance, and eective and equitable social and economic policies. They should also aim to liberalize nancial sectors with adequate regulation and supervision and strengthen capacities to mobilize and manage nancial resources and deliver public services eectively. Any eorts by governments to strengthen energy-saving development mode and macroeconomic fundamentals could help lay the foundation for a long-run sustainable development. Internationally, it is recommended that supportive frameworks should be created for facilitating nancial development, energy savings, climate change adaptation and mitigation, and low carbon economy. Dedicated resources 32

for development should be made available for vulnerable nations and people around the world. The increased and better nancial assistance will enable those countries to cope more eectively with economic volatility or crisis, and improve safety nets and basic services like health and education.

References
[1] Aizenman, Joshua and Brian Pinto. 2005. Overview In J. Aizenmann and B. Pinto, eds., Managing Economic Volatility and Crises. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press. [2] Arellano, Manuel and Stephen Bond. 1991. Some tests of specication for panel data: Monte carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies 58: 277-297. [3] Arellano, Manuel and Olympia Bover. 1995. Another look at the instrumental-variable estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics 68: 29-51. [4] Arrow, Kenneth, Partha Dasgupta, Lawrence Goulder, Gretchen Daily, Paul Ehrlich, Georey Heal, Simon Levin, Karl-Gran Mler, Stephen Schneider, David Starrett, Brian Walker. 2004. Are we consuming too much? Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(3): 147-172. [5] Aysan, Ahmet F. (2007). The eects of volatility on growth and nancial development through capital market imperfections. METU Studies in Development 34(1): 1-18. [6] Bai, Jushan. 2009. Panel data models with interactive xed eects. Econometrica 77(4): 1229-1279. [7] Barbier, Edward B. 2009. A global green new deal. UNEP nal report. [8] Bond, Stephen. 2002. Dynamic panel data models: A guide to micro data methods and practice. Portuguese Economic Journal 1: 141-162.

33

[9] Bond, Stephen, Anke Hoeer and Jonathan Temple. 2001. GMM estimation of empirical growth models. CEPR discussion paper no. 3048. [10] Bowsher, Clive G. 2002. On testing overidentifying restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Economics Letters 77: 211-220. [11] Blundell, Richard and Stephen Bond. 1998. Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics 87: 115-43. [12] Blundell, Richard and Stephen Bond. 2000. GMM estimation with persistent panel data: An application to production functions. Econometric Reviews 19: 321-340. [13] Canton, Erik. 2002. Business cycles in a two-sector model of endogenous growth. Economic Theory 19: 477492. [14] Global Energy Market Data (2008), the Enerdata. www.enerdata.fr. [15] Ghosh, Atish R. and Jonathan D. Ostry. 1997. Macroeconomic uncertainty, precautionary saving, and the current account. Journal of Monetary Economics 40(1): 121-139. [16] Grier, Kevin B. and Gordon Tullock. 1989. An empirical analysis of cross-national economic growth, 1951-1980. Journal of Monetary Economics 24: 259-76. [17] Hansen, J. E., R. Ruedy, M. Sato and K. Lo. 2008. GISS surface temperature analysis. NASA Goddard Institute for Space Studies, New York. [18] Heston, Alan, Robert Summers and Bettina Aten. 2009. Penn World Table version 6.3, Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP). [19] Hnatkovska, Viktoria and Norman Loayza. 2005. Volatility and growth. In J. Aizenmann and B. Pinto, eds., Managing Economic Volatility and Crises. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press. 34

[20] IMF. 2009. World Economic Outlook. International Monetary Fund. [21] Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. 2001. Climate Change 2001. Synthesis Report. Cambridge University Press. [22] Kharroubi, Enisse. 2007. Crises, volatility and growth. World Bank Economic Review 21(3): 439-460. [23] Koren, Mikls and Silvana Tenreyro. 2007. Volatility and development. Quarterly Journal of Economics 122(1): 243287. [24] Kormendi, Roger and Philip Meguire. 1985. Macroeconomic determinants of growth: Cross-country evidence. Journal of Monetary Economics 16: 141-63. [25] Lin, J. Yifu. (2009). Learning from the past to reinvest the future. Opening remarks at the Seoul ABCDE. [26] Loayza, Norman V., Romain Ranciere, Luis Servn, and Jaume Ventura. 2007. Macroeconomic volatility and welfare in developing countries: An introduction. World Bank Economic Review 21(3): 343-357. [27] Loser, Claudio M. 2009. Global nancial turmoil and emerging market economies: Major contagion and a shocking loss of wealth? Asian Development Bank. [28] Pezzey, John. 1992. Sustainable development concepts: An economic analysis. World Bank Environmental Paper Number 2. [29] Ramey, Garey and Valerie A. Ramey. 1995. Cross country evidence on the link between volatility and growth. American Economic Review 85(5):113851. [30] Sandmo, Agnar. 1970. The eect of uncertainty on saving decisions. The Review of Economic Studies 37(3): 353-360. [31] Saradis, Vaslis and Donald Robertson. 2009. On the impact of error cross-sectional dependence in short dynamic panel estimation. Econometrics Journal, 12: 62-81. 35

[32] Saradis, Vaslis, Takashi Yamagata and Donald Robertson. 2009. A test of cross section dependence for a linear dynamic panel model with regressors. Journal of Econometrics, 148: 149-161. [33] United Nations. 2005. 2005 World Summit Outcome, nal document. [34] Windmeijer, Frank. 2005. A nite sample correction for the variance of linear ecient two-step GMM estimators. Journal of Econometrics 126(1): 25-51. [35] Wolf, Holger. 2005. Volatility: Denitions and consequences. In J. Aizenmann and B. Pinto, eds., Managing Economic Volatility and Crises. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press. [36] World Bank. 2002. Environmental Indicators. Environment Department, World Bank. [37] World Bank. 2002. Global Development Network Database. [38] World Bank. 2009. World Development Indicators. [39] World Bank. 2009. Financial Structure and Economic Development Database. [40] World Commission on Environment and Development. 1987. Our Common Future, Oxford University Press.

36

Appendix Table 1. The Variables


Variable Description Source GENSAV Adjusted net savings, excluding particulate emission World Bank World damage (% of Gross National Income). The regression Development Indicators (WDI) (2009) uses the 3-year averages of the natural logarithm of one plus the adjusted net savings divided by 100, log(1+GENSAV/100). VGR Standard deviation over 3-year interval from 1978 to 2007 of the natural logarithm of one plus the annual growth rate of GDP per capita divided by 100. Standard deviation over 3-year interval from 1978 to 2007 of the natural logarithm of one plus the annual inflation rate divided by 100. Standard deviation over 3-year interval from 1978 to 2007 of the natural logarithm of one plus the private credt over GDP. Calculated based on data from WDI (2009) Calculated based on data from WDI (2009) Calculated based on data from the Financial Development and Structure Database (FDS) (2009) Calculated based on data from FDS (2009)

VINFL

VPRIVO

VLLY

Standard deviation over 3-year interval from 1978 to 2007 of the natural logarithm of one plus the liquid liabilities of banks and non-bank financial intermediaries (currency plus demand and interestbearing liabilities) over GDP.

KI

The investment share of real GDP per capita (RGDPL). Penn World Table 6.3 (PWT) The regression uses log(1+KI/100). (2009) The ratio to GDP of credit issued to private sector by banks and other financial intermediaries. The regression uses log(1+PRIVO). The annual growth rate of GDP per capita. The regression uses log(1+GR/100). The gross national income per capita. The regression uses GNIPC in log. The trade share (% of GDP). The regression uses log(1+TRADE/100). FDS (2009)

PRIVO

GR GNIPC TRADE AGE

WDI (2009) WDI (2009) WDI (2009)

The age dependency ratio (dependents to working-age WDI (2009) population). The regression uses log(1+AGE/100).

Appendix Table 2: The List of Countries in the Full Sample


Code AGO* ARG AUS AUT BDI* BEL BEN* BFA* BGD* BLZ BOL BRA BRN BTN* BWA CAF* CAN CHE CHL CHN* CIV* CMR* COG* COL COM* CPV CRI CYP DMA DNK DOM DZA ECU EGY ERI* ESP ETH* FIN FJI FRA GAB Country Name Angola Argentina Australia Austria Burundi Belgium Benin Burkina Faso Bangladesh Belize Bolivia Brazil Brunei Darussalam Bhutan Botswana Central African Republic Canada Switzerland Chile China Cote d'Ivoire Cameroon Congo, Rep. Colombia Comoros Cape Verde Costa Rica Cyprus Dominica Denmark Dominican Republic Algeria Ecuador Egypt, Arab Rep. Eritrea Spain Ethiopia Finland Fiji France Gabon Code GBR GHA* GIN* GMB* GNB* GRC GTM GUY HKG HND* HTI* IDN* IND* IRL IRN ISL ISR ITA JAM JOR JPN KEN* KHM* KOR LAO* LBN LKA MAR MDG* MDV MEX MLI* MNG* MOZ* MRT* MUS MWI* MYS NAM NER* NIC* Country Name United Kingdom Ghana Guinea Gambia Guinea-Bissau Greece Guatemala Guyana Hong Kong, China Honduras Haiti Indonesia India Ireland Iran, Islamic Rep. Iceland Israel Italy Jamaica Jordan Japan Kenya Cambodia Korea, Rep. Lao PDR Lebanon Sri Lanka Morocco Madagascar Maldives Mexico Mali Mongolia Mozambique Mauritania Mauritius Malawi Malaysia Namibia Niger Nicaragua Code NLD NOR NPL* NZL PAK* PAN PER PHL PRT PRY RWA* SAU SDN* SEN* SGP SLE* SLV SWE SWZ SYC SYR TCD* TGO* THA TON TTO TUN TUR TZA* UGA* URY USA VCT VEN VNM* VUT ZAF ZAR* ZMB* ZWE* Country Name Netherlands Norway Nepal New Zealand Pakistan Panama Peru Philippines Portugal Paraguay Rwanda Saudi Arabia Sudan Senegal Singapore Sierra Leone El Salvador Sweden Swaziland Seychelles Syrian Arab Republic Chad Togo Thailand Tonga Trinidad and Tobago Tunisia Turkey Tanzania Uganda Uruguay United States St. Vincent & Grenadines Venezuela, RB Vietnam Vanuatu South Africa Congo, Dem. Rep. Zambia Zimbabwe

Note: This table lists the country codes and names for 122 countries considered in the whole sample. Countries with * are made up of the low income sample in this analysis according to the World Bank Global Development Network Database (2002).

Tyndall Working Paper series 2000 - 2010

The Tyndall Centre working paper series presents results from research which are mature enough to be submitted to a refereed journal, to a sponsor, to a major conference or to the editor of a book. The intention is to enhance the early public availability of research undertaken by the Tyndall family of researchers, students and visitors. They can be downloaded from the Tyndall Website at: http://www.tyndall.ac.uk/publications/working_papers/working_papers.shtml The accuracy of working papers and the conclusions reached are the responsibility of the author(s) alone and not the Tyndall Centre.

Papers available in this series are: Dendler, L.(2010) Sustainability Meta Labelling: A Discussion of Potential Implementation Issues. Tyndall Working Paper 145; McLachlan, C.(2010) Tidal stream energy in the UK: Stakeholder perceptions study. Tyndall Working Paper 144; The Role of Global Cities Melbourne. Tyndall Working Paper 138; Seyfang, G., I. Lorenzoni, and M. Nye., (2009) Personal Carbon Trading: a critical examination of proposals for the UK. Tyndall Working Paper 136.

HTompkins E. L, Boyd E., Nicholson-Cole S, Weatherhead EK, Arnell N. W., Adger Upham, P., and Julia Tomei (2010) W. N., (2009) An Inventory of Adaptation to climate change in the Critical Stakeholder Perceptions of Carbon and Sustainability Reporting in UK: challenges and findings: Tyndall Working Paper 135; the UK Renewable Transport Fuel Obligation. Tyndall Centre Working Paper Haxeltine A., Seyfang G., (2009) 143; Transitions for the People: Theory and Hargreaves, T. (2010) The Visible Practice of Transition and Energy Trial: Insights from Qualitative Resilience in the UKs Transition Interviews. Tyndall Working Paper 141; Movement: Tyndall Working Paper 134; Newsham, A., and D. Thomas. (2009) Agricultural adaptation, local knowledge and livelihoods diversification in North-Central Namibia. Tyndall Working Paper 140; Starkey, R.. (2009) Assessing common(s) arguments for an equal per capita allocation. Tyndall Working Paper 139; Tomei J., Upham P., (2009) Argentinean soy based biodiesel: an introduction to production and impacts: Tyndall Working Paper 133; Whitmarsh L, O'Neill S, Seyfang G., Lorenzoni I., (2008) Carbon Capability: what does it mean, how prevalent is it, and how can we promote it?: Tyndall Working Paper 132;

Bulkeley, H., and H. Schroeder. (2009) Huang Y., Barker T., (2009) Governing Climate Change Post-2012: Does Geography Matter for the Clean Development Mechanism? :

Tyndall Working Paper 131; Huang Y., Barker T., (2009) The Clean Development Mechanism and Sustainable Development: A Panel Data Analysis: Tyndall Working Paper 130;

Wang T., Watson J, (2008) Carbon Emissions Scenarios for China to 2100: Tyndall Working Paper 121

Bergman, N., Whitmarsh L, Kohler J., (2008) Transition to sustainable development in the UK housing Dawson R., Hall J, Barr S, Batty M., sector: from case study to model Bristow A, Carney S, Dagoumas, A., Evans implementation: Tyndall Working Paper S., Ford A, Harwatt H., Kohler J., Tight M, 120 (2009) A blueprint for the integrated Conway D, Persechino A., Ardoin-Bardin assessment of climate change in S., Hamandawana H., Dickson M, Dieulin cities: Tyndall Working Paper 129; C, Mahe G, (2008) RAINFALL AND Carney S, Whitmarsh L, Nicholson-Cole WATER RESOURCES VARIABILITY IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA DURING THE S, Shackley S., (2009) A Dynamic Typology of Stakeholder Engagement 20TH CENTURY: Tyndall Centre Working Paper 119 within Climate Change Research: Tyndall Working paper 128; Starkey R., (2008) Allocating emissions rights: Are equal shares, Goulden M, Conway D, Persechino A., (2008) Adaptation to climate change in fair shares? : Tyndall Working Paper 118 international river basins in Africa: a Barker T., (2008) The Economics of review: Tyndall Working paper 127; Avoiding Dangerous Climate Change: Tyndall Centre Working Paper 117 Bows A., Anderson K., (2008) A bottom-up analysis of including Estrada M, Corbera E., Brown K, (2008) aviation within the EUs Emissions Trading Scheme: Tyndall Working Paper How do regulated and voluntary carbon-offset schemes compare?: 126; Tyndall Centre Working Paper 116 Al-Saleh Y., Upham P., Malik K., (2008) Estrada Porrua M, Corbera E., Brown K, Renewable Energy Scenarios for the (2007) REDUCING GREENHOUSE GAS Kingdom of Saudi Arabia: Tyndall EMISSIONS FROM DEFORESTATION Working Paper 125 IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES: Scrieciu S., Barker T., Smith V., (2008) REVISITING THE ASSUMPTIONS: Tyndall Centre Working Paper 115 World economic dynamics and technological change: projecting interactions between economic output Boyd E., Hultman N E., Roberts T., Corbera E., Ebeling J., Liverman D, Brown and CO2 emissions :Tyndall Working K, Tippmann R., Cole J., Mann P, Kaiser Paper 124 M., Robbins M, (2007) The Clean Development Mechanism: An Bulkeley H, Schroeder H., (2008) Governing Climate Change Post-2012: assessment of current practice and future approaches for policy: Tyndall The Role of Global Cities - London: Centre Working Paper 114 Tyndall Working Paper 123 Schroeder H., Bulkeley H, (2008) Governing Climate Change Post-2012: Hanson, S., Nicholls, R., Balson, P., The Role of Global Cities, Case-Study: Brown, I., French, J.R., Spencer, T., Los Angeles: Tyndall Working Paper 122 Sutherland, W.J. (2007) Capturing coastal morphological

change within regional integrated increased sea-level rise. : Tyndall assessment: an outcome-driven fuzzy Centre Working Paper 105 logic approach: Tyndall Working Paper Dawson R., Hall J, Barr S, Batty M., No. 113 Bristow A, Carney S, Evans E.P., Kohler J., Tight M, Walsh C, Ford A, (2007) A Okereke, C., Bulkeley, H. (2007) blueprint for the integrated Conceptualizing climate change governance beyond the international assessment of climate change in cities. : Tyndall Centre Working Paper regime: A review of four theoretical 104 approaches: Tyndall Working Paper No. 112 Doulton, H., Brown, K. (2007) Ten years to prevent catastrophe? Discourses of climate change and international development in the UK press: Tyndall Working Paper No. 111 Dawson, R.J., et al (2007) Integrated analysis of risks of coastal flooding and cliff erosion under scenarios of long term change: Tyndall Working Paper No. 110 Okereke, C., (2007) A review of UK FTSE 100 climate strategy and a framework for more in-depth analysis in the context of a post-2012 climate regime: Tyndall Centre Working Paper 109 Dickson M., Walkden M., Hall J., (2007) Modelling the impacts of climate change on an eroding coast over the 21st Century: Tyndall Centre Working Paper 103 Klein R.J.T, Erickson S.E.H, Nss L.O, Hammill A., Tanner T.M., Robledo, C., OBrien K.L.,(2007) Portfolio screening to support the mainstreaming of adaptation to climatic change into development assistance: Tyndall Centre Working Paper 102 Agnolucci P., (2007) Is it going to happen? Regulatory Change and Renewable Electricity: Tyndall Centre Working Paper 101

Kirk K., (2007) Potential for storage of carbon dioxide in the rocks beneath the East Irish Sea: Tyndall Centre Gardiner S., Hanson S., Nicholls R., Zhang Z., Jude S., Jones A.P., et al (2007) Working Paper 100 The Habitats Directive, Coastal Arnell N.W., (2006) Global impacts of Habitats and Climate Change Case abrupt climate change: an initial Studies from the South Coast of the assessment: Tyndall Centre Working UK: Tyndall Centre Working Paper 108 Paper 99 Schipper E. Lisa, (2007) Climate Lowe T.,(2006) Is this climate porn? Change Adaptation and Development: How does climate change Exploring the Linkages: Tyndall Centre communication affect our perceptions Working Paper 107 and behaviour?, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 98 Okereke C., Mann P, Osbahr H, (2007) Assessment of key negotiating issues Walkden M, Stansby P,(2006) The at Nairobi climate COP/MOP and what it means for the future of the climate effect of dredging off Great Yarmouth on the wave conditions and erosion of regime: Tyndall Centre Working Paper the North Norfolk coast. Tyndall Centre No. 106 Working Paper 97 Walkden M, Dickson M, (2006) The response of soft rock shore profiles to Anthoff, D., Nicholls R., Tol R S J, Vafeidis, A., (2006) Global and regional exposure to large rises in sea-level: a

Kuang C, Stansby P, (2006) Sandbanks for coastal protection: Few R., Brown K, Tompkins E. L, implications of sea-level rise. Part 3: (2006) Public participation and climate wave modelling, Tyndall Centre Working change adaptation, Tyndall Centre Paper 88 Working Paper 95 Corbera E., Kosoy N, Martinez Tuna M, (2006) Marketing ecosystem services through protected areas and rural communities in Meso-America: Implications for economic efficiency, equity and political legitimacy, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 94 Kuang C, Stansby P, (2006) Sandbanks for coastal protection: implications of sea-level rise. Part 2: current and morphological modelling, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 87

sensitivity analysis. This work was prepared for the Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change: Tyndall Centre Working Paper 96

in the Literature, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 89

Stansby P, Kuang C, Laurence D, Launder B, (2006) Sandbanks for coastal protection: implications of Schipper E. Lisa, (2006) Climate sea-level rise. Part 1: application to Risk, Perceptions and Development in East Anglia, Tyndall Centre Working El Salvador, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 86 Paper 93 Tompkins E. L, Amundsen H, (2005) Perceptions of the effectiveness of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change in prompting behavioural change, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 92 Bentham M, (2006) An assessment of carbon sequestration potential in the UK Southern North Sea case study: Tyndall Centre Working Paper 85

Anderson K., Bows A., Upham P., (2006) Growth scenarios for EU & UK aviation: contradictions with climate Warren R., Hope C, Mastrandrea M, policy, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 84 Tol R S J, Adger W. N., Lorenzoni I., (2006) Spotlighting the impacts Williamson M., Lenton T., Shepherd functions in integrated assessments. J., Edwards N, (2006) An efficient Research Report Prepared for the numerical terrestrial scheme (ENTS) Stern Review on the Economics of for fast earth system modelling, Climate Change, Tyndall Centre Working Tyndall Centre Working Paper 83 Paper 91 Warren R., Arnell A, Nicholls R., Levy P E, Price J, (2006) Understanding the regional impacts of climate change: Research Report Prepared for the Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 90 Barker T., Qureshi M, Kohler J., (2006) The Costs of Greenhouse Gas Mitigation with Induced Technological Change: A Meta-Analysis of Estimates Bows, A., and Anderson, K. (2005) An analysis of a post-Kyoto climate policy model, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 82 Sorrell, S., (2005) The economics of energy service contracts, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 81 Wittneben, B., Haxeltine, A., Kjellen, B., Khler, J., Turnpenny, J., and Warren, R., (2005) A framework for assessing the political economy of post-2012

projects to low-income global climate regime, Tyndall Centre sinks Working Paper 80 communities, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 71 Ingham, I., Ma, J., and Ulph, A. M. Abu-Sharkh, S., Li, R., Markvart, T., (2005) Can adaptation and mitigation be complements?, Tyndall Centre Ross, N., Wilson, P., Yao, R., Steemers, K., Kohler, J. and Arnold, R. (2005) Can Working Paper 79 Migrogrids Make a Major Contribution Agnolucci,. P (2005) Opportunism to UK Energy Supply?, Tyndall Centre and competition in the non-fossil fuel Working Paper 70 obligation market, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 78 Tompkins, E. L. and Hurlston, L. A. (2005) Natural hazards and climate what knowledge is Barker, T., Pan, H., Khler, J., change: Warren., R and Winne, S. (2005) transferable?, Tyndall Centre Working Avoiding dangerous climate change by Paper 69 inducing technological progress: scenarios using a large-scale Bleda, M. and Shackley, S. (2005) econometric model, Tyndall Centre The formation of belief in climate change in business organisations: a Working Paper 77 dynamic simulation model, Tyndall Agnolucci,. P (2005) The role of Centre Working Paper 68 political uncertainty in the Danish Turnpenny, J., Haxeltine, A. and renewable energy market, Tyndall ORiordan, T., (2005) Developing Centre Working Paper 76 regional and local scenarios for change mitigation and Fu, G., Hall, J. W. and Lawry, J. climate (2005) Beyond probability: new adaptation: Part 2: Scenario creation, methods for representing uncertainty Tyndall Centre Working Paper 67 in projections of future climate, Turnpenny, J., Haxeltine, A., Tyndall Centre Working Paper 75 Lorenzoni, I., ORiordan, T., and Jones, M., Ingham, I., Ma, J., and Ulph, A. M. (2005) Mapping actors involved in (2005) How do the costs of adaptation climate change policy networks in the affect optimal mitigation when there UK, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 66 is uncertainty, irreversibility and Adger, W. N., Brown, K. and learning?, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 74 Tompkins, E. L. (2004) Why do resource managers make links to Walkden, M. (2005) Coastal stakeholders at other scales?, Tyndall process simulator scoping study, Centre Working Paper 65 Tyndall Centre Working Paper 73 Peters, M.D. and Powell, J.C. (2004) Lowe, T., Brown, K., Suraje Dessai, Fuel Cells for a Sustainable Future II, S., Doria, M., Haynes, K. and Vincent., K Tyndall Centre Working Paper 64 (2005) Does tomorrow ever come? Few, R., Ahern, M., Matthies, F. and Disaster narrative and public perceptions of climate change, Tyndall Kovats, S. (2004) Floods, health and Centre Working Paper 72 climate change: a strategic review, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 63 Boyd, E. Gutierrez, M. and Chang, M. (2005) Adapting small-scale CDM

Barker, T. (2004) Economic theory and the transition to sustainability: a comparison of approaches, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 62

Turnpenny, J., Carney, S., Haxeltine, A., and ORiordan, T. (2004) Developing regional and local scenarios for climate change mitigation and adaptation Part 1: A framing of the East of England Tyndall Brooks, N. (2004) Drought in the Centre Working Paper 54 African Sahel: long term perspectives and future prospects, Tyndall Centre Agnolucci, P. and Ekins, P. (2004) The Announcement Effect And Working Paper 61 Environmental Taxation Tyndall Centre Few, R., Brown, K. and Tompkins, Working Paper 53 E.L. (2004) Scaling adaptation: climate Agnolucci, P. (2004) Ex Post change response and coastal management in the UK, Tyndall Centre Evaluations of CO2 Based Taxes: A Survey Tyndall Centre Working Paper 52 Working Paper 60 Anderson, D and Winne, S. (2004) Modelling Innovation and Threshold Effects In Climate Change Mitigation, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 59 Bray, D and Shackley, S. (2004) The Social Simulation of The Public Perceptions of Weather Events and their Effect upon the Development of Belief in Anthropogenic Climate Change, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 58 Agnolucci, P., Barker, T. and Ekins, P. (2004) Hysteresis and Energy Demand: the Announcement Effects and the effects of the UK Climate Change Levy Tyndall Centre Working Paper 51 Powell, J.C., Peters, M.D., Ruddell, A. and Halliday, J. (2004) Fuel Cells for a Sustainable Future? Tyndall Centre Working Paper 50

Awerbuch, S. (2004) Restructuring our electricity networks to promote Shackley, S., Reiche, A. and decarbonisation, Tyndall Centre Working Mander, S (2004) The Public Paper 49 Perceptions of Underground Coal Gasification (UCG): A Pilot Study, Pan, H. (2004) The evolution of Tyndall Centre Working Paper 57 economic structure under technological development, Tyndall Vincent, K. (2004) Creating an Centre Working Paper 48 index of social vulnerability to climate change for Africa, Tyndall Centre Berkhout, F., Hertin, J. and Gann, Working Paper 56 D. M., (2004) Learning to adapt: Organisational adaptation to climate change impacts, Tyndall Centre Working Mitchell, T.D. Carter, T.R., Jones, Paper 47 .P.D, Hulme, M. and New, M. (2004) A comprehensive set of high-resolution Watson, J., Tetteh, A., Dutton, G., grids of monthly climate for Europe Bristow, A., Kelly, C., Page, M. and and the globe: the observed record Pridmore, A., (2004) UK Hydrogen (1901-2000) and 16 scenarios (2001- Futures to 2050, Tyndall Centre Working 2100), Tyndall Centre Working Paper 55 Paper 46

Purdy, R and Macrory, R. (2004) Geological carbon sequestration: Tompkins E. L and Hurlston, L. critical legal issues, Tyndall Centre (2003). Report to the Cayman Islands Government. Adaptation lessons Working Paper 45 learned from responding to tropical cyclones by the Cayman Islands Shackley, S., McLachlan, C. and Government, 1988 2002, Tyndall Gough, C. (2004) The Public Centre Working Paper 35 Perceptions of Carbon Capture and Dessai, S., Hulme, M (2003). Does Storage, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 44 climate policy need probabilities?, Anderson, D. and Winne, S. (2003) Tyndall Centre Working Paper 34 Innovation and Threshold Effects in Pridmore, A., Bristow, A.L., May, A. Technology Responses to Climate Change, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 43 D. and Tight, M.R. (2003). Climate Change, Impacts, Future Scenarios Kim, J. (2003) Sustainable and the Role of Transport, Tyndall Development and the CDM: A South Centre Working Paper 33 African Case Study, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 42 Xueguang Wu, Jenkins, N. and G. (2003). Integrating Watson, J. (2003), UK Electricity Strbac, Scenarios for 2050, Tyndall Centre Renewables and CHP into the UK Electricity System: Investigation of Working Paper 41 the impact of network faults on the Klein, R.J.T., Lisa Schipper, E. and stability of large offshore wind farms, Dessai, S. (2003), Integrating Tyndall Centre Working Paper 32 mitigation and adaptation into climate Turnpenny, J., Haxeltine A. and and development policy: three research questions, Tyndall Centre ORiordan, T. (2003). A scoping study of UK user needs for managing climate Working Paper 40 futures. Part 1 of the pilot-phase integrated assessment Tompkins, E. and Adger, W.N. interactive (Aurion Project), Tyndall (2003). Defining response capacity to process enhance climate change policy, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 31 Centre Working Paper 39 Hulme, M. (2003). Abrupt climate Brooks, N. (2003). Vulnerability, change: can society cope?, Tyndall risk and adaptation: a conceptual Centre Working Paper 30 framework, Tyndall Centre Working Brown, K. and Corbera, E. (2003). A Paper 38 Multi-Criteria Assessment Framework Carbon-Mitigation Projects: Ingham, A. and Ulph, A. (2003) for Uncertainty, Irreversibility, Putting development in the centre Precaution and the Social Cost of of decision-making, Tyndall Centre Carbon, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 37 Working Paper 29 Krger, K. Fergusson, M. and Skinner, I. (2003). Critical Issues in Decarbonising Transport: The Role of Technologies, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 36 Dessai, S., Adger, W.N., Hulme, M., Khler, J.H., Turnpenny, J. and Warren, R. (2003). Defining and experiencing dangerous climate change, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 28

systems: implications for hydrogen, Tompkins, E.L. and Adger, W.N. Tyndall Centre Working Paper 18 (2003). Building resilience to climate Dutton, G., (2002). Hydrogen change through adaptive management of natural resources, Energy Technology, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 17 Tyndall Centre Working Paper 27 Brooks, N. and Adger W.N. (2003). Country level risk measures of climate-related natural disasters and implications for adaptation to climate change, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 26 Xueguang Wu, Mutale, J., Jenkins, N. and Strbac, G. (2003). An investigation of Network Splitting for Fault Level Reduction, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 25 Xueguang Wu, Jenkins, N. and Strbac, G. (2002). Impact of Integrating Renewables and CHP into the UK Transmission Network, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 24 Adger, W.N., Huq, S., Brown, K., Conway, D. and Hulme, M. (2002). Adaptation to climate change: Setting the Agenda for Development Policy and Research, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 16 Khler, J.H., (2002). Long run technical change in an energyenvironment-economy (E3) model for an IA system: A model of Kondratiev waves, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 15 Shackley, S. and Gough, C., (2002). The Use of Integrated Assessment: An Institutional Analysis Perspective, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 14

Dewick, P., Green K., Miozzo, M., Paavola, J. and Adger, W.N. (2002). Technological Change, Justice and adaptation to climate (2002). Structure and the change, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 23 Industry Environment, Tyndall Centre Working Watson, W.J., Hertin, J., Randall, T., Paper 13 Gough, C. (2002). Renewable Energy Dessai, S., (2001). The climate and Combined Heat and Power Resources in the UK, Tyndall Centre regime from The Hague to Marrakech: Saving or sinking the Kyoto Protocol?, Working Paper 22 Tyndall Centre Working Paper 12 Watson, W. J. (2002). Renewables Barker, T. (2001). Representing and CHP Deployment in the UK to 2020, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 21 the Integrated Assessment of Climate Change, Adaptation and Mitigation, Turnpenny, J. (2002). Reviewing Tyndall Centre Working Paper 11 organisational use of scenarios: Case Gough, C., Taylor, I. and Shackley, study - evaluating UK energy policy options, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 20 S. (2001). Burying Carbon under the Sea: An Initial Exploration of Public Pridmore, A. and Bristow, A., Opinions, Tyndall Centre Working Paper (2002). The role of hydrogen in 10 powering road transport, Tyndall Barnett, J. and Adger, W. N. (2001). Centre Working Paper 19 Climate Dangers and Atoll Countries, Watson, J. (2002). The Tyndall Centre Working Paper 9 development of large technical

Adger, W. N. (2001). Social Capital and Climate Change, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 8 Barnett, J. (2001). Security and Climate Change, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 7

Barker, T. and Ekins, P. (2001). How High are the Costs of Kyoto for the US Economy?, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 4 Berkhout, F, Hertin, J. and Jordan, A. J. (2001). Socio-economic futures in climate change impact assessment: using scenarios as 'learning machines', Tyndall Centre Working Paper 3

Goodess, C.M., Hulme, M. and Osborn, T. (2001). The identification and evaluation of suitable scenario development methods for the estimation of future probabilities of Hulme, M. (2001). Integrated extreme weather events, Tyndall Assessment Models, Tyndall Centre Centre Working Paper 6 Working Paper 2 Barnett, J. (2001). The issue of Mitchell, T. and Hulme, M. (2000). A 'Adverse Effects and the Impacts of Response Measures' in the UNFCCC, Country-by-Country Analysis of Past Tyndall Centre Working Paper 5 and Future Warming Rates, Tyndall Centre Working Paper 1

Copyright 2010

For further information please contact Javier Delgado-Esteban

Você também pode gostar