Você está na página 1de 19

DTD 5

ARTICLE IN PRESS

Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx – xxx


www.elsevier.com/locate/ecolecon

ANALYSIS

Second-order sustainability—conditions for the development of


sustainable innovations in a dynamic environment
Christian Sartorius *
Fraunhofer Institute for Systems and Innovation Research, Breslauer Str. 48, D-76139 Karlsruhe, Germany
Received 5 September 2003; received in revised form 6 July 2005; accepted 6 July 2005

Abstract

In particular radical innovations can be important means to achieving improved sustainability. Due to the existence of path
dependency and lock-in, however, the transition from one technological trajectory to another, more sustainable one is often
impeded by significant barriers. Fortunately, these barriers are by their nature subject to substantial changes in time; so, it makes
sense to carefully distinguish between periods of stability (showing high barriers) in which the given trajectory can hardly be
left and periods of instability (characterized by low barriers) where a new trajectory can be reached more easily. The latter
distinction matters since sustainable innovations often rely on governmental regulation and the economic burden arising from
this regulation will be much lower in periods of instability. Moreover, due to the complexity and dynamics of change in their
respective environments, innovations are generally associated with fundamental uncertainty such that it becomes impossible to
predict the degree of sustainability yielded by specific innovations in the longer run. Under these circumstances, it is essential to
facilitate the change between trajectories and to allow for the possibility to select between a variety of alternative trajectories
within a process of trial and error. Sustainability as viewed from this evolutionary perspective is therefore better understood as
the general capability to adapt, that is, to readily change from less to more sustainable technological trajectories. Since the latter
kind of sustainability determines the conditions under which the former kind (i.e. sustainability related to a specific technology)
can be achieved, the two kinds are respectively called second-order and first-order sustainability.
Finally, a series of determinants (and corresponding indicators) from the techno-economic, political, and socio-cultural
sphere is identified which, after proper measurement and weighting, allow for making an assessment whether and when the
incumbent industry is sufficiently destabilized and the political system rendered sufficiently favorable to the new, more
sustainable technology such that a transition to the preferred trajectory is possible without too much effort.
D 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Sustainability; Innovation; Path dependence; Lock-in; Uncertainty; Indicators

1. Introduction

* Tel.: +49 721 6809 118. Innovations play a crucial role not only as the
E-mail address: c.sartorius@isi.fraunhofer.de. basis of the persistent economic growth prevailing
0921-8009/$ - see front matter D 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2005.07.010

ECOLEC-02304; No of Pages 19
ARTICLE IN PRESS

2 C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx

especially in developed countries since the beginning trajectory (Dosi, 1982, 1988). Accordingly, the fre-
of the industrial revolution (see Schumpeter, 1934; quency of environmentally sound and economically
Nelson and Winter, 1982, for evolutionary; Romer, profitable fundamental innovations will remain low
1986, for neoclassical perspectives on innovation- unless they are supported by policy instruments spe-
driven growth); they are also an important, if not cifically referring to the causes of paradigm formation
the only, means for maintaining the sustainability of and the related lock-ins. Klemmer et al. (1999) to
this development, that is, for avoiding destruction of some extent point in this direction when they
the natural environment and exhaustion of natural acknowledge that a mix of regulative measures is
resources that may be needed by all our descendents needed to properly account for the complexity of
in order to maintain at least the current level of circumstances in which innovation arise.
wealth (see Rennings, 2000 for an overview). How- In this paper, both time and uncertainty will be
ever, innovations towards sustainability are often accounted for more thoroughly as crucial conditions
associated with substantial costs. From the point of of technological development in general and espe-
view of environmental economics this is due to the cially with regard to sustainability. In particular, it is
fact that environmental innovations internalize exter- assumed that, along with the change in circumstances,
nal costs for which the innovator does not receive a periods of stability of a given technological trajectory
compensating benefit. By contrast, Porter and Van (where establishing a new paradigm requires much
der Linde (1995) claim that these costs can be sub- effort) alternate with periods of instability (where such
stantially reduced, if, rather than merely redressing a shift is more easily achieved). It is further assumed
the consequences of existing technologies (e.g. by that it is possible to identify and even strategically use
end-of-pipe solutions), innovation is understood as the latter phases of instability in the search for the
an integrated process avoiding environmental extern- lowest possible cost of achieving a higher degree of
alities right from the beginning. The remaining costs sustainability. In order to justify this claim, Section 2
can even be turned into a benefit, if, due to its more starts with a discussion of the relevance of innovation
fundamental character, an innovation avoids both in the context of sustainability from both the neoclas-
external and internal costs. sical and ecological economics’ perspective. In Sec-
Despite the basic attractiveness of this kind of tion 3, an evolutionary framework is used to show
innovation, employing them is far from rendering how potential progress towards greater sustainability
the path towards sustainability self-sustaining for by means of innovations may be hampered by com-
two reasons. On the one hand, all environmentally plexity, uncertainty, path dependency and lock-in.
more benign substitutes after a while tend to give rise While identifying the strategic elements for overcom-
to unforeseen environmentally hazardous side effects ing these shortcomings, Section 4 specifies the con-
such that, in the longer run, new technological ditions for the more ready identification and
(including organizational) substitutes have to be gen- implementation of sustainable innovations—a prop-
erated again and again. Moreover, the development erty we call second-order sustainability because it
and becoming effective of new substitutes takes time, refers to the dynamic interrelation between innova-
allowing related technology branches to exhibit envir- tions rather than the innovations themselves. In order
onmental externalities in their turn. Due to the higher to make use of this dynamic concept of sustainability,
uncertainty associated with fundamental innovations, Section 5 identifies a variety of its potential determi-
they will show this tendency even more markedly nants and indicates how they may be applied. Finally,
than incremental innovations succeeding within one conclusions are drawn in Section 6.
paradigm. As a consequence, sustainability will gen-
erally remain temporary and more or less incomplete.
On the other hand, fundamental technological 2. Innovation and sustainability
change requires the transition from one technology
paradigm to another and, therefore, is not only less A very wide-spread understanding of innovation is
likely to occur and but also associated with higher reflected in the definition used by the OECD (1997),
uncertainty and risk than innovation along a given which distinguishes (1) process innovations allowing
ARTICLE IN PRESS

C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx 3

to produce a given quantity of output (i.e. goods or of ecological sustainability.2 Neoclassical environ-
services) with less input, (2) product innovations mental economics tried to resolve this trade-off by
characterized by the improvement of existing, or the determining (shadow) prices for those uses of nature
development of new, goods or services and (3) orga- giving rise to negative external effects and imposing
nizational innovations including new forms of man- them by means of Pigou taxes and allowance trading
agement. While the exact meaning of even this (Pigou, 1920; Coase, 1960). Although functional in
relatively simple definition of innovation depends on the neoclassical setting, both approaches often proved
the methodological and normative background to be ineffective in practice for two reasons. First, due
assumed by its respective applicator, it is even more to asymmetries in the stakeholders’ endowment with
difficult to relate to each other the concepts of innova- knowledge and other resources and the public good
tion and sustainability. In this section, I will try to character of most parts of the environment, it is
elucidate this relationship first from the neoclassical impossible to determine the true willingness to pay
and then from the ecological economics’ perspective. (i.e. the price) for the services of nature with sufficient
accuracy. And, second, even if this price could be
2.1. Environmental innovation in the neoclassical determined sufficiently exactly, it may be doubted
context whether the two targets of satisfying the needs and
wants of humans and meeting the requirements for the
While, in the above-quoted OECD definition, pro- natural environment to sustain could be brought to
cess innovation is explicitly efficiency-oriented, the coherence. Reasons for this are, among other things,
meaning of improvement or novelty in the definition the difference in time horizon between myopic
of product innovations is not further specified. If, as is humans and long-term processes in nature and, most
often done in economic contexts (see e.g. Rennings, of all, the basic ignorance of most individuals con-
2000), the notion of innovation is further qualified by cerning the wide variety of cause–effect relationships
its distinction from the term invention, the explicit in nature (I will deal with this point more extensively
reference to the marketability of an innovation implies in Section 3). From the neoclassical perspective, this
that also product innovation is considered in terms of implies that the economy within or, respectively, with-
efficiency, providing more benefit (as revealed by the out its natural environment would not converge to the
customers’ willingness to pay) at the same cost or the same equilibrium and, therefore, possible disturbances
same benefit at the lower cost. So, in the (neoclassi-
cal) economic context, the complete monetary com- 2
Since the Brundtland report (WCED, 1987) sustainability is
mensurability of costs (for inputs) and prices (for usually discussed as a state or, better, a development in which three
outputs) renders it fairly easy to identify innovations kinds of interests are met simultaneously: (1) the interest of the
in a given set of new processes or products.1 By present generation to generally improve their actual living condi-
contrast, maintaining this commensurability is essen- tions (i.e. economic sustainability), (2) the search for an equalization
tially impossible, if the above concept of innovation is of the living conditions between rich and poor (i.e. social sustain-
ability), and (3) the interest in an intact natural environment that is
to be extended beyond the realm of human prefer- capable of supporting the needs of future generations (i.e. ecological
ences—for instance into ecological sustainability sustainability). Since social sustainability including the (re)distribu-
(compare Munda, 1997). tion of natural resources and the benefits drawn from their use are
In particular since the beginning of the industrial subject to intense political discussion and continued negotiations
especially between developed and developing countries, the norma-
revolution growing human production and consump-
tive character of this issue is readily accepted as an argument to
tion led to ever more frequent, more persistent and exclude it from the scientific discourse. Although balancing the
more severe adverse impacts on the natural environ- interests of succeeding generations is a normative issue as well,
ment, representing an overall increase in economic the lacking possibility of the future generations to participate in the
sustainability (i.e. persistent growth) at the expense corresponding political discussion is in this case taken as a justifica-
tion and as a potential for science to make fruitful contributions.
Consequently, the discussion of sustainability particularly among
1
In this context, organizational innovations are not mentioned economists essentially focuses on the question how to allow for the
explicitly because, with regard to their input–output relation, they strongest possible growth now without compromising the potential
can be treated like either process or product innovations. for growth to persist in the future.
ARTICLE IN PRESS

4 C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx

of the economy–ecology relationship cannot be cor- essential functions of the environment (e.g. assimila-
rected by merely relying on the market mechanism tion of waste or supply with resources), the ecosystem
(Rennings, 2000). or at least certain parts of it have to be kept intact.
Accordingly, substitutability has to be proven in each
2.2. Strong sustainability and innovation specific case rather than simply being assumed.
Although this approach does not exclude monetiza-
As a consequence of the failure of market competi- tion in principle (e.g. in terms of the opportunity costs
tion alone to induce the innovations necessary to bring of the avoided or restricted use of the environment),
about ecological sustainability, a different approach the (how ever aggregated) monetary figure does not
has to be used. In search for such an approach, it is suffice to eventually specify the state of sustainability.
worthwhile to look more closely at the distinction Instead, it is necessary to follow the following three-
between weak and strong sustainability and at the step procedure and to (1) identify those elements of
sustainability indicators developed in relation to the the natural capital that are essential for the mainte-
latter concept. nance of the ecosystem’s stability or, better, its ability
From the anthropocentric point of view, sustainable to recover from distressing impacts (i.e., resilience),
development implies the preservation of a pool of (2) select those elements that are related to, and
natural resources and man-made capital that provides possibly endangered by, economic activities, and (3)
each generation with the opportunity to have its activ- derive a set of indicators each of which reflects the
ities based on equivalent sets of man-made and natural actual condition of a specific aspect of the environ-
capital. This conceptualization of sustainable devel- ment and puts it into relation to the sustainable state as
opment as bnon-declining wealthQ (Pearce et al., 1989) determined by any suitable management rule (see
finds two basically different expressions. On the one Opschoor and Reijnders, 1991). Typical examples of
hand, economists in the tradition of Hartwick (1978) the latter approach are Pressure-State-Response (PSR)
and Solow (1974, 1986) argue that a society using an indicators like the one employed by the OECD. Here,
exhaustible stock of resources could enjoy a constant the causes of environmental problems (bpressureQ),
stream of consumption over time if it invested all the the actual state of the environment (bstateQ), and
rents from tapping on those resources, that is, if it held efforts to solve the problem (bresponseQ) are moni-
the overall capital stock constant. Evidently, this weak tored and quantified in separate modules (OECD,
approach to sustainability is based on the implicit 1993).
assumption that both natural and man-made capitals The role of innovation in the latter framework
are complete (i.e. reversible) substitutes. While this consists in modifying existing, or implementing
assumption may be met in some cases, it does not new, technologies in such a way that identified pres-
hold in general because, first, for many types of sures are relaxed and problematic environmental
natural assets (e.g. an endangered species, a habitat states are improved. So far, however, this concept is
or the ozone layer) technical substitutes do not exist still quite limited such that it needs further qualifica-
and once brought about many changes turn out to be tion and extension.
irreversible (Munda, 1997). Moreover, the argument
developed above clearly indicates that the mechan- 2.3. Critical loads and non-linearity
isms for specifically identifying and implementing
suitable technologies or inducing necessary innova- An important qualification of PSR-like schemes
tions do not exist in the neoclassical framework refers to their implication that it is generally possible
underlying weak sustainability. to quantify the effect of an innovation in terms of
On the other hand, concepts of strong sustainabil- reduction of those processes or their side-effects that
ity, which are characteristic for ecological economics, caused the corresponding pressure in the first place. In
specify the natural capital in terms of its physical reality, however, many counter-measures later turn out
function rather than the costs of actual damage caused to be themselves not without side-effects such that the
to it. The logic of this approach is based on the relaxation of pressure in their target field may go
assumption that, in order to continue to rely on certain along with the increase of pressures in other fields.
ARTICLE IN PRESS

C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx 5

Rennings and Wiggering (1997) explain how this lack action between a wide variety of elements in the
of innovative efficiency arises. The logic underlying economy as well as in the natural environment; it is
the PSR approach implies a correlation according to even more due to the specific temporal interrelated-
which stronger (weaker) efforts to counteract an envir- ness of these elements. In order to deal with these
onmental problem by means of the best-available difficulties, a closer look will be taken at concepts like
technology generally lead to the alleviation (enhance- uncertainty, irreversibility, path dependency and coe-
ment) of the pressure and, thus, to the improvement volution which are closely related to innovation in the
(deterioration) of the condition of the environment. sustainability context and in general and extensively
Unfortunately, in the natural environment, such a discussed in the evolutionary branch of economics.
blinearQ relation between causes and effects is not
the rule. In contrast, effects like the following are 3.1. Fundamental uncertainty and the trial-and-error
frequently observed. Although in an agriculturally approach of evolution
dominated region the intense use of mineral fertilizers
was common practice for quite a while, contamination It is the wide variety and high complexity of
of the ground-water with nitrate could be observed interactions between human actors and between the
only recently—with a strongly increasing rate. In this latter and their natural environment that renders
case, the existence (and transgression) of carrying human (economic) activities as well as their environ-
capacities or buffer capacities gives rise to non-linear mental effects highly unpredictable particularly in the
processes which typically show sudden changes or long run (see also Section 2.3). However, the uncer-
even jumps. Returning to a sustainable state then tainty accruing in this context is not just a matter of
not only requires the reduction of emissions below probability distributions within a known or assumed
the respective critical load or critical level. Since the set of possibilities and therefore cannot be accounted
latter may itself be adversely affected by the harm, it for by the concept of risk. Instead uncertainty is better
additionally requires the repair of the damages that characterized as ignorance in the face of novel, fun-
had so far been caused by the excess emissions. damentally unpredictable, events. So the question
With regard to the role of innovation as a consti- arises how to deal with this fundamental uncertainty.
tuent of response in the PSR scheme, the non-linearity If complete knowledge about the set of available
basically implies a substantial element of uncertainty. alternatives is lacking, actors cannot maximize the
However, uncertainty is not limited to the adverse expected utility of alternative choices and, thus,
effects that innovation is supposed to reverse. The rational decisions cannot be made. One approach to
innovation itself is a source of uncertainty in so far the solution of this problem was made by Simon
as it can be the source of lacking sustainability unfore- (1957) who proposed that human decision-making
seen at the moment of its implementation. More about in situations of incomplete knowledge may better be
the causes of uncertainty and approaches to deal with described as being based on bounded rationality.
it will be said in the following. However, the boundedly rational decision-maker’s
striving for an acceptable (i.e. dsatisficingT) rather
than a maximum level of utility still requires some
3. Sustainable innovations and the evolutionary knowledge as to which goals are attainable in princi-
perspective ple. Additionally, even bounded rationality assumes
fixed sets of individual preferences that basically
Section 2 has elaborated on the possible impact of include all possible alternatives—an assumption that
innovation on ecological sustainability and on the simply turns out to be underdetermined in the face of
dependence of this impact on the underlying concepts real novelty.
of sustainability and the economic paradigms related Therefore, it may be advisable to look at the solu-
to them. It could be shown that the preconditions for tion of (long-run) problems related to fundamental
innovations effectively responding to emerging eco- uncertainty and endogenously changing preferences
logical challenges are rather demanding. This is not from a completely different perspective: Darwin’s
only due to the basic structural complexity of inter- approach to evolution in nature. Like society, nature
ARTICLE IN PRESS

6 C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx

is characterized by the complex interaction between petition as a process of selection (and detection) of
its constituents, the living organisms and their physi- innovations by means of the willingness-to-pay on the
cal environment, and thus by the existence of funda- demand side; and Nelson and Winter (1982) show
mental uncertainty and non-linearity which together how profit may serve as the selecting force that
can give rise to the formation of new species or the leads to the persistence of some innovations and to
sudden extinction of major parts of the existing bio- the vanishing of most others. A particular case of
sphere as well as for the persistence of existing spe- evolution leading to the solution of unprecedented
cies over prolonged periods of time. In order to problems is the selection of cooperation rules on the
bmanageQ such unpredictable processes, nature relies group level, a task that could never be fulfilled by
on the principles of heritance, random variation and individuals on the basis of their mere rationality
natural selection—with diversity created by random (Hayek, 1988; Sartorius, 2002). In this context, envir-
mutation and recombination within the existing onmental and social sustainability can respectively be
genetic pool and selection resulting from continuous interpreted as cooperation (i.e. fair behavior with the
competition between species with inherited properties potential of win–win situations) between succeeding
for a limited set of resources. generations and different parts of the same generation.
A further step toward an increased problem solving The relevance of fundamental uncertainty and the
capability in nature and, ultimately, in man is based on corresponding problem-solving capability for sustain-
the capability of an organism to undergo specific or ability is quite evident. Human activities frequently
individual adaptation to varying circumstances and to generate adverse environmental side-effects which,
transmit the acquired knowledge to other organisms— due to the complexity of their interaction with the
that is to learn and communicate. While evolution on environment, are often unforeseen (see Section 2.3).
this level is based on social norms, individual values, In the search for (long-term) sustainability, it therefore
and ideas rather than material genes, the basic princi- makes little sense to exclusively rely on the causes of,
ples nevertheless remain essentially unchanged (Sar- and solutions to, specific environmental problems
torius, 2003, especially chap. 4). Initially, the since they may be subject to considerable variation
perception of a problem leads to the assessment of a over time. This does not at all imply that the determi-
variety of alternative approaches to its solution. Those nation of critical substances and the application of
approaches giving rise to the solution of the problem critical thresholds do not make sense. Especially in
are selected; those that fail are rejected. The solutions the short run they are even indispensable. However, in
with the better performance are further modified and the long run, that is, in the time perspective in which
tested in subsequent rounds of selection.3 The wider the sustainability concept is usefully applied, the pro-
the variety of alternative approaches the higher is the cess leading to sustainability also has to account for
probability that at least one of them may perform the conditions under which the identification of pro-
better than in the status quo. With respect to human blems as well as the search for the corresponding
behavior, special use of evolutionary principles has solutions and their translation into the appropriate
been made by many proponents of evolutionary eco- measures takes place. Rather than referring to specific
nomics: in his search for new business opportunities, innovations whose characterization as being sustain-
for instance, Schumpeter’s (1934) entrepreneur able can only be temporary, sustainability should be
assumes significant risk but, at the same time, gives viewed as a property of the system and determined
rise to novelty; Hayek (1978) interprets market com- with reference to the system’s general capability to
bring about a variety of potentially useful innovations
3
Note that selection of the best alternative would only be possible and, should the occasion arise, to allow for the ready
in a static environment with very low complexity. In reality, the implementation of the most promising alternative. In
higher degree of complexity leads to the emergence of local rather short, sustainability also, and from the evolutionary
than global optima and, due to the dynamics of the system, the perspective predominantly, includes the flexibility and
successive choice of better alternatives influences the actual speci-
fication of the respectively best alternative. Therefore, selection in versatility of the entire system to allow for a quick and
the evolutionary approach adopted here refers to the better, but not effective response to whichever environmental pro-
to the best (see also Rammel, 2003). blem arises (see Erdmann, 2000).
ARTICLE IN PRESS

C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx 7

3.2. Coevolution and the extension of innovation Third, the coevolution (especially the Red Queen
beyond the technological sphere effect) is an intriguing example of path dependence
where the developmental path can not easily be shifted
The concept of coevolution basically refers to the from one trajectory to another (see Section 3.3).
fact that the development of an organism does not Forth, and most evidently, coevolution implies that
simply follow the conditions set by its environment, successful innovation in general, and successful sus-
but that, in the process of adaptation, the organism tainable innovation in particular, has to acknowledge
itself is a source of change for this environment. In the involvement of, and mutual interaction between,
biology, coevolution usually describes the mutual more than the mere technical and economic spheres.
adaptation of ecologically related species such as The current human way of life being coherent with the
butterflies and plants (e.g. Ehrlich and Raven, 1964) existing institutions (including codified rules and
which, under certain circumstances, can give rise to an social value and belief systems) and giving rise to
arms’ race known as the Red Queen effect. In ecolo- technology-caused transgressions of the sustainability
gical economics, coevolution refers to the socio-eco- boundary in many and profound ways and, contra-
nomic development as a process of adaptation to a riwise, the support of this lifestyle by just these
changing environment while being itself a source of techno-economic conditions are an evident instance
this change (Norgaard, 1994; Gowdy, 1994). While of coevolution. Accordingly, efficiency changes under
evolution in the socio-economic sphere was shown to the proviso of sustainability may be achieved more
have the potential of giving rise to better adaptation to readily through an integrated approach employing
the natural environment (Cavalli-Sforza and Feldman, institutional or social in addition to technical innova-
1981; Boyd and Richerson, 1985), coevolution in this tions. With regard to the aim for increased sustain-
context typically accounts for the mutual interference ability, it is therefore necessary to broaden the view
between socio-economic and natural developments from the merely technical towards the social and
which, depending on their specific characteristics, political aspects of innovations. In accord with these
can facilitate or hinder innovation processes leading thoughts, Klemmer et al. (1999, see also Rennings,
to lesser or greater sustainability. In the case of spray- 2000) broadly define the term denvironmental
ing pesticides in agriculture, for instance, the forma- innovationT as all measures of relevant actors that
tion of resistance is a clear indication for a decrease in lead to the development and application of new
sustainability. ideas, behavior, products and processes and, thereby,
With regard to sustainability-related innovations, contribute to a reduction of environmental burdens or
coevolution has several crucial implications. First, to ecologically specified sustainability targets. This
the mutual interaction between several social spheres may include process and product innovations, organi-
increases complexity giving rise to a higher degree of zational changes in the management of firms, and, on
uncertainty that needs to be managed by human actors the social and political level, changes in environmen-
trying to pursue a sustainable development (see Sec- tally counter-productive regulation and legislature,
tion 3.1). consumer behavior, or lifestyle in general. This
Second, coevolution involving the social or cul- emphasis on social innovations is all the more impor-
tural sphere has the potential of giving rise to a high tant because unsustainable development itself is often
degree of diversity with regard to flexibility and the result of btechnology outpacing changes in social
adaptability to temporally or spatially varying condi- organizationQ (Norgaard, 1994, p. 16). Moreover, after
tions (Munda, 1997). This potential is however con- an intense and extended discussion in environmental
trasted by the possibility of the Red Queen effect economics about the brightQ instruments towards an
which is likely to give rise to maladaptation and the environmentally sound, sustainable development, it
reduction of diversity. These two opposing effects are more and more turns out that there is not a single
the basis for the trade-off between diversity and flex- suitable instrument. Instead, it seems to depend on the
ibility on the one hand and economic efficiency on the respective circumstances (e.g. type of competition or
other (Rammel, 2003), which will be further discussed existence of information asymmetries), whether Pigou
in Section 4. taxes, markets for pollution rights, the setting of stan-
ARTICLE IN PRESS

8 C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx

dards, or even temporary subsidization of promising pened to be arranged in a sufficiently complex system
innovations is the more effective instrument of mutual interaction, the entire system is stabilized
(Rennings, 2000). Jaenicke (1999) even goes one against further change (Waddington, 1969). Interest-
step further by claiming that the relevance of instru- ingly, the parameter decisive for the stability of the
ments for environmental policy has generally been system is the average number of interaction from one
overemphasized. Instead, the discussion should element to others and not so much the number of
focus on other elements of a successful environmental genes (Kaufman, 1995).
policy such as long-term goals, mixes of instruments, With regard to sustainability, path dependence
policy styles, and constellations of actors. plays a particularly important role in three respects.
Altogether, the above emphasis on social and First, as shown above, the wide variety of life forms in
political aspects makes clear that the success of nature represents a large source of solutions for pro-
sustainable innovations depends on more than their blems not only in the natural environment but also in
mere technical (or even economic) superiority. This the human sphere—for the assimilation of wastes, the
is all the more evident when, following the sugges- production of food, and the design of pharmaceuticals,
tion of Section 3.1, sustainability is considered as the to mention just a few examples. Every species evi-
property of an entire system rather than a specific dently represents a piece of knowledge that could
innovation. potentially be useful for present or future generations.
Against the backdrop of path dependence, however, it
3.3. Irreversibility and path dependence is also clear that the loss of any species leads to a loss
of such knowledge that is irreversible. For every
Beside fundamental uncertainty and the need for species is the outcome of a succession of phylogenetic
diversity following from the preceding sections, the stages in which the formation of every single stage is
complexity of multiple-interaction systems has based on the existence of its respective predecessor—
another at least equally important consequence for a fact that renders it impossible to reconstruct a spe-
the sustainability discussion. If the sequence of events cies once it has been lost.
within a complex system was described by means of Second, even when knowledge is not directly
several independent parameters, careful analysis acquired from models in nature, but derived through
would reveal non-ergodicity. That is, of all basically trial and error in the scientific process, this does not
possible states only some are likely to occur in any imply that all knowledge is equally accessible.
single moment. Whether or not a given state is likely Instead, technical knowledge generation is character-
to arise accordingly depends on the past or, more ized by technological paradigms (Dosi, 1982, 1988).
exactly, on the succession of states preceding the Within such paradigms, knowledge acquisition occurs
actual state—a phenomenon called path dependence. gradually along the respective trajectories—by the
In biology, this issue is discussed among evolutionary systematic variation of single parameters and the
biologists and ecologists in the context of the phylo- selection of those variants showing the desired effect
genetic development of organisms and successions in most markedly. Incremental innovations proceeding
ecosystems. Gould and Eldredge (1977), for instance, along such a path are to some extent predictable but
emphasize that the complex architecture of all more the marginal cost-to-effect ratio is subject to increase
advanced organisms strongly limits the potential for such that maintaining the profitability (in economic
successful further mutations and, thus, better adapta- terms) of innovations becomes increasingly more dif-
tion. The reason for this is that most changes that may ficult. With regard to sustainability, end-of-pipe solu-
be advantageous from an isolated perspective may not tions fit into this category because they add
be so in a complex context in which advantageousness environmental soundness to an existing technology.
requires the meeting of many strict preconditions. As According to economic wisdom, they do this at
a consequence, a variety of mutations would have to increasing marginal costs.
come up simultaneously which is very unlikely to An alternative route is the search for radical
occur. So, once a certain amount of genetic informa- innovations leading to a transition between trajec-
tion has accumulated within an organism and hap- tories in different paradigms. While this approach
ARTICLE IN PRESS

C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx 9

has the potential of achieving much better profitabil- sustainability and then point to possible alternatives,
ity in economic contexts, it is characterized by a high the implications of fundamental uncertainty, coevolu-
degree of uncertainty representing a substantial tion and path dependency go far beyond such an
threshold for typically risk-averse people. In the sus- assessment of specific innovations. In order to accord-
tainability context, Porter and van der Linde (1995) ingly develop a more comprehensive conception of
emphasize that integrated environmental innovations sustainability, it is necessary to return once again to
(where harm is avoided from the beginning rather the shortcomings of the traditional approach of attain-
than redressed after its generation) can be so efficient ing sustainability.
that the environmentally beneficial effect induced by
suitable regulatory measures is achieved at no addi- 4.1. Knowledge gain through trial-and-error
tional cost.
The third aspect of path dependence to be First, in most societies, and all the more in all
addressed here refers to the induced resistance-to- advanced economies, the common wealth is yielded
change and, thereby, to some extent relates to the by the complex interaction of numerous individuals in
second. It plays an important role in the discussion the context of a variety of technologies and social and
about technology development and is of central political institutions. Due to the uncertainty prevalent
importance for the objective of this paper: the search in such complex systems (see Section 3.1), it is
of determinants for a sustainable technology develop- impossible to predict all the specific effects of any
ment. Innovations and the introduction of new tech- human intervention. This argument explains the some-
nologies often are the key instruments to the times low success in fitting a new technology or
(temporary) avoidance or redressing of adverse envir- institution into a given setting in general. And it
onmental effects. However, even if negative external particularly explains the frequent failure of technical
effects were completely internalized and the new or institutional innovations in terms of sustainability.
technology turned out to be technologically and envir- As a consequence, the search for increased sustain-
onmentally superior to the existing one, successful ability, while in principle being the result of human
commercialization and diffusion into the market can- action, will usually not be the well-specified outcome
not be taken for granted. A frequently quoted example of a man-made plan. Hayek (1973) referred to this
for this kind of failure of a superior technology to phenomenon as the bfailure of constructivist
prevail refers to the design of typewriter and computer rationalismQ and identified man’s constitutive lack of
keyboards (David, 1985). Although the totality of knowledge as its main cause. Instead of looking for
users could benefit from the use of a better design the one and only perfect substitute, Hayek suggests, it
that allows for a significantly higher writing speed, the therefore appears much more promising to engage
traditional QWERTY keyboard is maintained because into a trial-and-error process based on a variety of
just for the first users of any new alternative, a devia- potential substitutes.
tion from the dominant design would cause costs that
are much higher than the expected benefits (Arthur, 4.2. Diversity as precondition for trial-and-error
1988). While network externalities are the relevant
factor in the latter case, a variety of other effects The second argument in disfavor of the specific
will be identified in Section 5 that lead to the lock- replacement of a non-sustainable technology (or insti-
in of a conventional technology and, accordingly, to tution) also refers to the uncertainty aspect, but it
the lock-out of its superior challenger. focuses on the effect of dynamic change rather than
the mere lack of knowledge. Since, in a complex
system, the change in one component always gives
4. Second-order sustainability rise to a change of the restrictive conditions for all
others (compare the discussion of coevolution in
While traditional approaches to achieving (strong) Section 3.2), it is little surprising that sustainability
sustainability typically start with the identification of as achieved by the employment of whichever technol-
the technical or social causes of a current lack of ogy or institution (e.g. property rights or social pre-
ARTICLE IN PRESS

10 C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx

ferences) can only be a temporary state of a system. one between (short-term) economic and (long-term)
Even those interventions that successfully redress sustainability-related efficiency.
instances of lacking sustainability at first will them-
selves change the entire system in such a way that 4.3. Lock-in resolution as precondition for
new losses of sustainability are likely incurred in the trial-and-error
future—either due to their interaction with other com-
ponents or directly by themselves. In order to main- In contrast to the preceding arguments, the third
tain sustainability over longer periods of time, it is argument against the possibility of an easy substitu-
therefore not sufficient to simply solve a given pro- tion of more sustainable technologies–and respec-
blem; rather the problem-solving capacity must keep tively the second precondition for the successful
pace with the rise of new problems. So, the Darwinian employment of trial-and-error processes–relates to
process of trial-and-error has to cope with time—a the systemic integration of established technologies
scarce resource especially in dynamic systems; and in and institutions rather than their potential substitutes.
order to do so, two preconditions need to be met For even in the presence of a variety of alternative
which at first appear to be given quite naturally, but solutions, selection and further development of the
in fact do not come for free. Variation, the first pre- most suitable technology by means of the market
condition, implies the existence of a wide variety of forces will remain ineffective so long as the estab-
potential alternatives on which selection can act. For lished technology is subject to strong stabilization and
socioeconomic systems in general, Matutinovic withstands its displacement by even strongly superior
(2001) shows that diversity is a systematic and resi- alternatives.4 In Section 3.3, this resistance to change
lient property the lack of which could provoke of the established technology known as lock-in was
instability and eventually lead to the collapse of the shown to be caused by a wide variety of effects of
system. Since in present-day economies the selective which a more complete account will be given in
effect of market competition is rather strong, self- Section 5. Sustainability is particularly affected by
sustained maintenance of a high degree of diversity such a lock-in because the more radical–and thereby
cannot be taken for granted. Especially with regard to often more effective–innovations (Rennings, 2000;
the uncertainty associated with long-term sustainabil- Ashford, 2002) face more opposition than the less
ity problems, it may therefore even be necessary to effective incremental ones because they belong to a
actively keep competition in a more early stage— new paradigm. To the extent that lock-in effects are to
against the self-enforcing advantages of productiv- be undermined, economic actors again have to bear
ity-increasing specialization (see Kemp, 1997). the cost of refraining from the realization of the
Accordingly, it is evident that this diversity is costly corresponding economies of scale, learning and net-
since, (1) for the supply of promising technologies work effects, etc. (see Section 4.2). Although, this
society needs to promote learning, that is, to invest time, the trade-off between short-term and long-term
into human capital. More specifically, incentives for efficiency is basically a purely economic one, it has
an engagement into R&D have to be provided for the important consequences for sustainability.
respective firms. (2) Prior to eventually reaching mar-
4
ket diffusion and successful commercialization, parti- The careful reader will have recognized that, on the one hand,
cularly the more radical inventions may additionally the proposed approach relies on the selective capacity of (market)
competition to identify and gradually improve more sustainable
need governmental support (e.g. through subsidization
technologies while, on the other hand, competition has to be par-
or the creation of niche markets). (3) Finally, the tially suspended in order to create the diversity on which selection
partial suspension of market forces needed to maintain can act. This apparent contradiction is resolved by temporal, spatial
a certain degree of diversity and keep competition in or functional disjunction of the two functions. While temporal
an early stage not only leads to the less efficient disjunction can be achieved by the mere alternation of phases of
adaptation of technologies to the existing uses; (4) it variation and selection, spatial and functional disjunction, respec-
tively, imply implementation and testing of new technologies on a
also prevents part of the cost-saving potentials of locally or application-specific markets. The latter two approaches
economies of scale and scope or learning effects also constitute the basis for strategic niche management (Kemp et
from being realized. The trade-off we face here is al., 1998).
ARTICLE IN PRESS

C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx 11

4.4. Second-order sustainability as adaptive flexibility also this optimum can be approached in a trial-and-
error manner—by the gradual change and subsequent
While the specific problem-solving capacity of cer- assessment of the conditions for second-order sustain-
tain innovations gives rise to sustainability in specific ability particularly in those industries and economic
circumstances and for limited periods of time, it is the sectors where the most severe violations of first-order
total number of such solutions or, more concisely, the sustainability are encountered.
context-dependent trial-and-error process giving rise to
their implementation that brings about sustainability in
more general terms—in the long run and in dynamic 5. Determinants of second-order sustainability
contexts. The latter idea conforms well with the view of
Kemp (1997), Van den Bergh and Gowdy (2000), In Section 3.3, it was suggested that certain struc-
Rammel and Van den Bergh (2003) and Rammel tural properties of a given technology can severely
(2003) that sustainability is the result of a strategic restrict the probability with which new innovations
process (rather than a certain state) trying to deal may become effective. The way in which these states
with uncertainty and unpredictable emerging properties of rigidity are sometimes discussed (David, 1985) or
by means of badaptive flexibilityQ. This emphasis of the modeled (Arthur, 1988) in the literature could imply
process character does, of course, not render specific that such states of stability are omnipresent and, once
sustainable innovations dispensable in the search for they turn up, tend to persist for prolonged periods of
sustainability in general, but due to their conditional time. Not surprisingly, many economists (e.g. Lie-
effectiveness they represent sufficient (rather than bowitz and Margolis, 1994) are convinced that latter
necessary) conditions of sustainability whereas the position crossly overstates the relevance of network
conditions for the effective working of the basic trial- externalities, as this would allow them to become the
and-error process are necessary (but not sufficient) cause of almost ubiquitous market failure. In the latter
ones. Since, from the functional perspective, bgeneralQ debate, an intermediate position is taken by Witt
sustainability determines the conditions under which (1997) who, while principally acknowledging the
bspecificQ sustainability can be achieved, the two kinds relevance of network effects, limits their general
of sustainability describe the function of a system on importance for the function of the market to certain
two different levels with general sustainability repre- restricted periods of time. So periods of stability tend
senting the more basic level. Since sustainability, and to alternate with periods of instability where new
more so its lack, is immediately perceived as specific networks can be formed. Such a period in which the
instance of resource or environmental problems direction of technological progress is flexible is
whereas the working of its general problem-solving referred to as a bwindow of opportunityQ (Witt,
capacity (albeit more fundamental) is less immediately 1997). Disregarding these windows could severely
evident, I refer to the two aspects as first-order and hamper, if not completely inhibit, the introduction of
second-order sustainability, respectively. any useful innovation. And even when, in the pursuit
In the preceding parts of this section, a variety of of sustainability, a new (sustainable) technology was
measures was mentioned that would increase diversity, successfully pushed by governmental regulation with
improve selection and, thus, support second-order sus- no regard at the specific circumstances, the difference
tainability, but most of these measures would come between stable and unstable phases would be worth a
with significant (opportunity) costs only. Conversely, lot of money. It will therefore be the main objective of
the lack of second-order sustainability caused by the this section to identify those factors that allow poli-
unwillingness to pay this price leads itself to the incap- tical and other decision makers to make a well-
ability to adapt to changing circumstances and, thus, to founded judgement as to whether the preference for
a loss of welfare that arises from the high cost of a potentially sustainable innovation is based on eco-
redressing or functionally replacing a damaged envir- nomic, social and political feasibility.
onment. In this trade-off between the costs and benefits The first set of factors will be economic ones. It
of second-order sustainability, the optimum degree of will become evident in the following that the variety
diversity is not easily determined ex ante. However, of relevant effects is wider and their respective time
ARTICLE IN PRESS

12 C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx

pattern more diverse than may have been implied by dependencies between existing processes renders it
the repeated reference to network externalities in pre- more difficult for a radically new technology to
vious parts of this paper. Additionally, it is a special become competitive.
characteristic of many sustainable technologies that,
beyond the competitive disadvantage frequently aris- 5.1.3. Learning by doing
ing from their failure to internalize reduced external Unlike the cases of economies of scale and econo-
costs, the government typically plays a crucial role in mies of scope, the cost decreasing effect of growing
overcoming existing barriers to competitiveness in the experience in designing, constructing (dlearning by
relevant markets. In doing so the government inevi- doingT), and using production facilities (dlearning by
tably faces opposition from those whose interests are usingT) is usually expressed as the percentage of cost/
negatively affected: the incumbent industry and other price reduction per doubling of the cumulative pro-
groups paying the price for the measures taken. Typi- duction output in the respective branch. While learn-
cally, a government or policy makers in general are ing effects give rise to a large potential for further cost
not inclined to neglect such an opposition unless the reductions for any new technology, they confront it
promoting forces from other parts of the society are with a high cost disadvantage in the beginning.
sufficiently strong. More so, major techno-economic
changes require a general openness or even a readi- 5.1.4. Network externalities
ness to change (i.e. a phase of instability) on the part Network externalities refer to the fact that the
of the political system. For these reasons, the techno- utility derived from the use of a given technology is
economic factors will have to be supplemented by positively correlated with the number of its users.
both, political and social factors. The selection of Alternatively, a technology can be subject to network
these criteria occurred on the basis of a priori theore- externalities if it relies on another technology that
tical plausibility considerations and ex post after the forms a network in its turn. The weaker the depen-
screening of relevant case studies (Sartorius and Zun- dence on the established network or the better the
del, 2005). Due to the large number of relevant fac- compatibility, the smaller is the entry barrier for the
tors, it is not possible to present them here at length; new technology.
for a more detailed discussion, the reader is therefore
referred to Sartorius and Zundel (2005, ch.2). 5.1.5. Sunk cost
Investment into a new technology can cause sig-
5.1. Determinants of (in)stability in the nificant sunk costs if it renders useless an old technol-
techno-economic system ogy prior to its complete depreciation. While sunk
costs represent opportunity costs of any new technol-
5.1.1. Economies of scale ogy, they do not come to bear in competitive markets.
Economies of scale account for the greater effi- Instead, they are relevant whenever market access is
ciency of larger manufacturing devices. They are typi- restricted by other causes. The rate of capitalization in
cally measured on the firm level in terms of average the relevant industry and data about the investment
unit cost as a function of output rate. As these average cycle can be used to assess sunk costs; but this
costs decrease with increasing scale, they give rise to analysis needs to be supplemented by the competitive
strong competitive disadvantage for new technologies structure of the industry in question (see below).
which, at the beginning of their life cycle, cannot
immediately engage into large-scale production. 5.1.6. Market structure
Although natural or regulated oligopolies or mono-
5.1.2. Economies of scope polies do not exclude competition in principle, such
Economies of scope account for synergies between market structures will provide the corresponding firms
different production lines from the common use of with strong incentives to maintain the existing market
certain resources, intermediate products, or production barriers, engage in strong activities to preserve these
facilities. While economies of scope lead to important monopoly rents and neglect innovative activities.
cost decreases for the established industry, the mutual While the innovation-related forces of market competi-
ARTICLE IN PRESS

C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx 13

tion may be characterized as biased in favor of the dition for this to happen, the political system either
established technology by (above-mentioned) increas- must be in favor of the new technology from the
ing returns to adoption, any non-competitive market beginning or it needs to be destabilized itself in the
structure will stabilize the technological status quo first place. While in the former case, structural char-
even more because it does not give rise to innovation acteristics of the political system play the most impor-
in the first place. tant role, both structural and procedural aspects are
important in the latter. The following enumeration will
5.1.7. Potential versus risk begin with the structural factors.
In order to replenish their earned innovation rent
and, thus, maintain their current profit margins within 5.2.1. Institutional embeddedness
a competitive market environment, entrepreneurs Many technologies, particularly those related to
occasionally have to complement their technological environmental protection, are subject to substantial
portfolios with more radical innovations. Since the political regulation determining which external effects
latter are associated with higher risk, an (expected) a technology is allowed to exert and which (and how)
strong potential (including its regulatory conditions) others must be avoided. In this context, the close
will be decisive for the success or failure of this mutual relationship between the established technol-
technology being adopted. ogy and its regulatory environment tends to adversely
influence the competitive position of any (radically)
5.1.8. Demand new competitor. An example for the self-stabilizing
To be considered an economic substitute for an effect that needs to be overcome by a new technology
existing technology, a new technology at first has to is the reference many regulations make to the state of
fulfill certain functions of the former. In order to the art (related to the established technology) for
attract the attention and raise the specific demand of solving an environmental problem.
consumers and investors that would prefer the more
familiar, established technology over its otherwise 5.2.2. Interest groups
quite dissimilar counterpart, a new technology has to While it is a matter of political culture how influ-
fulfill certain extra-functions to overcome this inertia. ential corporate bodies or individual actors can be in
principle, it depends on the specific circumstances
5.1.9. Niche markets which effects they actually give rise to. Basically,
If the entry barrier for a new technology is high, it the power of an interest group is known to be crucially
may need a long period of subsidization until general dependent on the size of the group, the homogeneity
competitiveness is achieved. At the same time, partial of its interests, its organization, and the resources it
competitiveness may be achieved much sooner under controls (Olson, 1965). Other important factors are the
certain, geographically or culturally specified, favor- economic relevance of the industry or its history and
able conditions—often called a niche market. Since cultural integration. Particularly in mature industries
the existence and extent of niche markets can be with strong market power, lobbying may pay even for
decisive for reaching competitiveness of a new tech- single firms as investing in a useful regulatory envir-
nology in general, the strategic use or the artificial onment is more profitable than investments in tech-
(regulatory) creation of such niche markets can be an nological innovations (Berg, 1995)—with the
important approach to the successful implementation corresponding stabilizing effect for the established
of a new technology as suggested by the strategic- technology.
niche-management approach of Kemp et al. (1998).
5.2.3. Asymmetry of knowledge
5.2. Determinants of in-/stability in the political system For the solution of environmental problems, gov-
ernments and political administrations need external
The basic characteristics of the political system advice. As long as the problem has not attracted too
generally play an important role in allowing a new, much public attention, the necessary information is
more sustainable technology to prevail. As a precon- most convenient obtained from the industry that
ARTICLE IN PRESS

14 C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx

Table 1
Factors determining the stability or instability in each of the three subsystems and the indicators used for their operationalization
Effect Indicators Operationalization
Economies of scale cost (or price) development as a function of actual output
Sunk costs average capitalization of industry statistical data
identification of investment cycles recurrent phase-shifted cycling of prices and investment
political regulation cost of retro-fitting after regulation,
delayed investment due to expectation of uncertain measures
Economies of scope pattern of interactions between number and relevance of interactions between the old (new)
production lines technology and the entire production network
Techno-economic subsystem

Learning by doing cost (or price) development as a function of cumulative output


Network externalities direct competition with (an)other market share(s) of the competitor(s),
network(s) availability of gateway technologies
need for compatibility with comple-
menting infrastructure or periphery:
• existence of public standards which requirements are met?
• availability of an adapter cost of the adapter, legal admission possible, payable royalties
Market structure degree of competition as a function of market share of the biggest firm(s), Herfindahl index, legal
market concentration regulations
Potential / risk riskiness ↔ availability of capital marginal interest rate, capital share of venture capitalists
problem solving capacity ↔ technical properties (benchmarks), associated costs
realization of an innovation rent
Extra-demand readiness to pay for extra-functions market research
existence of natural niche markets higher prices, non-applicability of the established technology
creation of artificial niche markets by (eco-)taxes, tradable certificates, cost of retro-fitting the old
means of regulation technology
Institutional subsidies financial support, tax breaks
embeddedness protection duties, other barriers to trade
norms and standards specificity of specification
Interest groups resources under control (power) number and economic importance of represented firms/sector
structure; degree of homogeneity market shares, concentration index
influence; earlier success (qualitative)
Asymmetry of influence of industry in hearings (qualitative)
knowledge number of industry-independent number, financial support, number and size of commissioned
research institutions/projects projects
Parliamentary stability of majorities size of majority, stability of constituting coalition (number and
Political subsystem

majorities relation of parties)


Election cycle distance to the next election ditto.
Singular constraints political scandals deception by possible interest holders
catastrophes accidents, unexpected discoveries
Decision-making probability of legislative initiatives number and relevance of potential initiators, number of cases
procedures legislative vs. administrative number of laws referring to ordinances, actual number of
regulation ordinances
reassessment and resubmission cycles deadlines, frequency, possible consequences
corporate structure number, size, and frequency of political involvement of
corporate organizations
participation frequency and extent of incorporation of political “outsiders”
(e.g. NGOs) into the decision process
supranational structures share of regulation that is not subject to national legislation
Scientific confirm- relevant publications in scientific number of relevant articles (keyword search) in journals etc.;
ation of threat to literature, contributions to conferences identification of seminal articles and quotation circles
Socio-cultural

sustainability independence of research sources and quantity of research sponsoring


subsystem

Public concern about relevant articles in newspapers, reports number of articles/reports over time
lack of sustainability in broadcast,
Public acceptance of formation of major protest campaigns number and size of campaigns
possible solutions
Source: own compilation.
ARTICLE IN PRESS

C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx 15

caused the problem. According to the life cycle theory exogenous) events like political scandals and envir-
of bureaucracies, initially independent (regulatory) onmental or other disaster can bring about sudden
authorities will thus successively merge their interests changes.
with those of the established industry (Martimort,
1999). This bregulatory capture of bureaucraciesQ 5.2.7. Decision-making procedures
often leads to quick and at most half-hearted solutions Since it is not possible here to extensively analyze
related to the dominant technology. By contrast, more the entire political decision-making process, just a few
radical changes can only be expected, if the necessary criteria will be presented that may allow for a basic
knowledge comes from more independent sources— characterization of the procedural aspects of a political
notably state-financed scientific research. system with regard to the stabilization or destabiliza-
tion of a specific technology.
5.2.4. Parliamentary majorities
Especially more radical changes are often not (1) It is an important aspect of political culture
unanimously supported since the associated improve- whether the initiatives for regulatory acts typi-
ments go at the expense of the established regime. cally come from single actors (e.g. president,
Even if its basic attitude would tend to render a members of parliament) or major bodies (gov-
government supportive of the corresponding change, ernment, parties, or the parliament). In general,
its actual realization will ultimately depend on the the former tends to give rise to more radical
strength and stability of the majority on which it can (i.e. destabilizing) changes than those of the
rely. From this perspective, a large, stable majority latter.
basically opens the potential for more radical changes (2) The relation between legislative bodies and
than does a minute or unstable one. executive administration determines whether
a regulation is enacted by means of a law that
5.2.5. Election cycle has to pass a lengthy parliamentary approval
One of the most prominent stylized facts in poli- procedure or whether this can be done by refer-
tical science states that more radical political changes ring to an ordinance that is quickly adopted by
usually occur at the beginning of an election period the administration alone.
while incremental changes, if not political standstill, (3) Obligatory reassessment and resubmission
follow at the end (Troja, 1998). With regard to envir- cycles ensure that any existing regulation does
onmental innovations this implies a potential for a not lead to the stabilization of the respectively
political window of opportunity in the post-election benefiting technology.
period. Unfortunately, empirical tests so far failed to (4) Participation of larger parts of the society (e.g.
confirm this effect of the election cycle (Horbach, NGOs, public research institutes) in the search
1992). A special popularity of environmental regula- for more sustainable solutions will not only
tion, an eminent problem pressure or, like in Germany, facilitate the search for knowledge but also
the temporal alternation between state and federal increase and widen the support for (often more
elections could be reasons for this. radical) solutions.
(5) Finally, it is important how a country is incor-
5.2.6. Singular constraints porated into supranational structures (e.g. EU,
The costs and, thus, the scope of each regulatory WTO). While this limits a country’s possibility
measure is subject to a budget constraint. While the to implement innovations in an idiosyncratic
power of the interest groups behind technologies gen- manner, it broadens the scope and efficacy of
erally influences the allocation of governmental many sustainable innovations.
resources, it depends on the social appreciation of
environmental protection or the reputation of the 5.3. Factors of change in the socio-cultural system
involved parties whether the incumbent industry can
defend its subsidies or has to share it with its more Public attention to a (perceived) problem and
sustainable competitors. In this respect, singular (i.e. subsequent worry about its potential consequences
ARTICLE IN PRESS

16 C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx

play a key role in provoking political reactions direc- (= flexibility) of the established technological regime
ted to solving the problem or, at least, alleviating its and the political and social conditions supporting it.
consequences. This is all the more true in the context So, second-order sustainability will be strongest
of environmental protection since due to their long- when the window of opportunity is most widely
term relevance and public-good nature, environmental open and it will be weak when the window is closed.
problems and their solutions are rarely issues that In order to identify a window of opportunity, an
allow a politician to derive major benefits for himself. aggregation of its determinants is necessary. Since
While awareness and concern by a considerable part the direct comparison of all these indicators on the
of the population is neither sufficient nor necessary basis of a common denominator (e.g. monetary
for political action to be initiated, their lack will value) is not possible, however, any comparison
usually lead to a failure or, at least, major delay in can in the end only be of qualitative nature. There-
acting accordingly. fore, the following scheme of aggregation is used to
Mass media play an important role not only as arrive at least at a relative measure of second-order
transmitters for the corresponding information but sustainability.
also for the assignment of meaning and valuation In the techno-economic sphere, all factors essen-
to the underlying problem. The relation between the tially work in parallel. High sunk costs add to the
media and their readers, listeners, or watchers is stability of the incumbent technology as well as does
characterized by mutual interaction giving rise to extended learning. Niche markets for the new tech-
positive and negative reinforcement The scientific nology on the other hand destabilize the incumbent
verification of an environmental problem, which technology. None of these factors relies on another
often stays at the beginning of such an dissue atten- one to become effective. So, even if one effect became
tion cycleT (Downs, 1972), is identified through zero, the other factors would remain unaffected. Their
scanning the scientific literature for relevant key- mode of aggregation is additive.
words and trying to identify seminal publications By contrast, in the socio-cultural system, (scienti-
through the tracing back of references. On the fic) verification of an environmental problem is a
other hand, public concern about these problems necessary (but not sufficient) prerequisite for the for-
can be measured to some extent by counting relevant mation of public concern. Conversely, public concern
articles in newspapers and reports in other mass alone sometimes is little effective until the exact
media. Additionally, it may be necessary to account causes for an environmental problem are scientifically
for the more qualitative aspects of concern and verified and unless an acceptable solution exists. So,
valuation, as the authors of relevant articles often all factors work in sequence with the combined effect
differ in their basic attitude towards a given environ- yielded by multiplying the constituents.
mental problem. It is also important to realize that In the political system, both effects are found.
the attention of mass media to any given problem While structural and procedural factors in general
usually tends to decline more rapidly than the atten- appear to complement each other in a multiplicative
tion of the public in general. way, the specific structural (or procedural) factors tend
Table 1 summarizes the comprehensive list of to work in parallel.
determinants of periods of instability elaborated With regard to the relationship between the entire
above including the corresponding indicators and systems, the political system not surprisingly is of
their potential operationalization. central importance because in the end, it brings
about the regulation necessary to achieve greater sus-
5.4. Windows of opportunity as periods of higher tainability. However, the political system hardly
second-order sustainability works on its own; it needs impulses from the other
systems: destabilizing impulses (for the existing
In order to identify periods of greater or lesser regime) come from the society disapproving the lack
second-order sustainability by means of these indi- of sustainability and from the new, more sustainable
cators, it needs to be pointed out first that sustain- technological or institutional alternatives; opposite
ability correlates strongly with the instability stabilizing impulses come from the incumbent indus-
ARTICLE IN PRESS

C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx 17

try that caused the environmental problem and the than in the latter. Second, due to the complexity and
loss of sustainability in the first place. Fig. 1 changes in their respective environments, innova-
summarizes how the composite indicator of sustain- tions are generally associated with fundamental
able technology development is constructed from its uncertainty such that it becomes impossible to pre-
constituents. dict the degree of sustainability resulting from spe-
cific innovations in the long run. Under these
circumstances, it is essential to ensure flexibility
6. Conclusion including the possibility to select between a variety
of different trajectories in a process of trial and error.
In particular radical innovations can be important Sustainability as viewed from this evolutionary
means to the achievement of improved sustainability. perspective may therefore better be understood as
Due to the existence of path dependencies, however, the general capability to readily change between
the transition from one technological trajectory to different technological trajectories. Since the latter
another, more sustainable one is often impeded by kind of sustainability determines the conditions
significant barriers. Fortunately, these barriers are by under which the former kind can be achieved,
their nature subject to substantial changes; so, it we call the two kinds first-order and second-order
makes sense to carefully distinguish between periods sustainability.
of stability (with high barriers) in which the given In order to undergo successful diffusion, most
trajectory can hardly be left and periods of instabil- sustainable innovations rely on regulatory measures
ity (characterized by low barriers) where a new especially in the beginning of their (economic) life-
trajectory can be reached more easily. With respect cycles. When looking for the factors determining
to sustainability, the latter distinction is particularly periods of (in-)stability, the political system enacting
important for two reasons. First, more sustainable this regulation therefore is of central interest. How-
innovations often rely on governmental regulation. ever, while basically allowing for the convergence
In periods of instability, the economic burden arising of both technological progress and sustainability, the
from this regulation will be much lower than in political system itself can neither give rise to the
periods of stability; so, a given budget will yield a search for sustainability nor bring about the appro-
much better sustainability effect in the former case priate innovations in the first place. This is where
the socio-cultural and, of course, the techno-eco-
nomic sphere itself enter the focus of attention as
emitters of positive impulses. Additionally, negative
impulses like those coming from the incumbent
industry need to be taken into account. After all, a
series of factors (and corresponding indicators)
could be identified which, after proper weighting
and prioritization, allow to make an estimation
whether, and possibly when, the incumbent industry
is sufficiently destabilized and the political system
rendered sufficiently favorable to the new, more
sustainable technology such that a transition to the
preferred trajectory is possible without the lowest
effort possible.

Acknowledgement
Fig. 1. Reconstruction of a measure of second-order sustainability
from its constituent factors in the techno-economic, political, and Funding of this research by the German Federal
socio-cultural sphere. Ministry for Education and Research (grant
ARTICLE IN PRESS

18 C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx

07RIW5C) is gratefully acknowledged. I thank Guido Horbach, J., 1992. Neue Politische Ökonomie und Umweltpolitik.
Bünstorf, Jan Nill, Stefan Zundel and an anonymous Campus, Frankfurt/Main.
Jaenicke, M., 1999. Policy patterns and innovation impacts: an
referee for valuable comments on earlier versions of international comparison. Paper presented at the International
this paper. Conference dInnovation-oriented Environmental Regulation—
Theoretical Approaches and Empirical AnalysisT, May 27–29,
1999 in Potsdam, organized by IPTS (Spain), ZEW (Germany)
References and MERIT (Netherlands).
Kaufman, S., 1995. At Home in the Universe. Oxford University
Arthur, W.B., 1988. Self-reinforcing mechanisms in economics. In: Press, New York.
Anderson, P.W., Arrow, K.J., Pines, D. (Eds.), The Economy as Kemp, R., 1997. Environmental Policy and Technical Change. A
an Evolving Complex System. Addison-Wesley, Redwood City, Comparison the Technological Impact of Policy Instruments.
pp. 9 – 31. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
Ashford, N.A., 2002. Government and environmental innovation in Kemp, R., Schot, J., Hoogma, R., 1998. Regime shifts to sustain-
Europe and North America. American Behavioral Scientist 45 ability through processes of niche formation: the approach of
(9), 1417 – 1434. strategic niche management. Technology Analysis and Strategic
Berg, C., 1995. Technologischer Fortschritt und ökonomische Reg- Management 10 (2), 175 – 195.
ulierung. Lang Publ., Frankfurt/Main. Klemmer, P., Lehr, U., Löbbe, K., 1999. Environmental Innovation,
Boyd, R., Richerson, P.J., 1985. Culture and the Evolutionary vol. 3. Analytica, Berlin.
Process. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Liebowitz, S.J., Margolis, S.E., 1994. Network externality: an
Cavalli-Sforza, L.L., Feldman, M.W., 1981. Cultural Transmission uncommon tragedy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 8 (2),
and Evolution: a Quantitative Approach. Princeton University 133 – 150.
Press, Princeton, NJ. Martimort, D., 1999. The life cycle of regulatory agencies: dynamic
Coase, R.H., 1960. The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and capture and transaction costs. Review of Economic Studies 66,
Economics 3, 1 – 44. 929 – 947.
David, P.A., 1985. Clio and the economics of QWERTY. Matutinovic, I., 2001. The aspects and the role of diversity in
American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 75 (2), socioeconomic systems: an evolutionary perspective. Ecological
332 – 337. Economics 39, 239 – 256.
Dosi, G., 1982. Technological paradigms and technological trajec- Munda, G., 1997. Environmental economics, ecological economics
tories. Research Policy 11, 147 – 162. and the concept of sustainable development. Environmental
Dosi, G., 1988. Sources, procedures and microeconomic effects Values 6, 213 – 233.
of innovation. Journal of Economic Literature 26 (Sept.), Nelson, R.R., Winter, S.G., 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of
1120 – 1171. Economic Change. Harvard University Press (Belknap),
Downs, A., 1972. Up and down with ecology. The issue-attention Cambridge.
cycle. The Public Interest 28, 38 – 50 (Summer). Norgaard, R., 1994. Development Betrayed. Routledge, London.
Ehrlich, P., Raven, P., 1964. Butterflies and plants: a study in OECD, 1993. OECD core set of indicators for environmental
coevolution. Evolution 18, 586 – 608. performance reviews. OECD Environment Monographs, vol.
Erdmann, G., 2000. Innovation, time, and sustainability. Paper 83. OECD, Paris.
Presented at the International Conference bTowards Environ- OECD, 1997. OECD Proposed Guidelines for Collecting and Inter-
mental Innovation SystemsQ, September 27–29. Garmisch-Par- preting Technological Innovation Data—Oslo Manual. OECD/
tenkirchen, Germany. Eurostat, Paris.
Gould, S.J., Eldredge, N., 1977. Punctuated equilibria: the Olson, M., 1965. The Logic of Collective Action. Harvard Uni-
tempo and mode of evolution reconsidered. Paleobiology 3, versity Press, Cambridge.
115 – 151. Opschoor, J.B., Reijnders, L., 1991. Towards sustainable develop-
Gowdy, J., 1994. Coevolutionary Economics: The Economy, ment indicators. In: Kuik, O., Verbruggen, H. (Eds.), In Search
Society and the Environment. Kluwer Academic, Dordrecht. of Indicators of Sustainable Development. Kluwer, Dordrecht,
Hartwick, J., 1978. Substitution among exhaustible resources pp. 7 – 27.
and intergenerational equity. Review of Economic Studies 45, Pearce, D.W., Markandya, A., Barbier, E.B., 1989. Blueprint for a
347 – 354. Green Economy. Earthscan, London.
Hayek, F.A., 1973. Law, Legislation and Liberty, Rules and Order, Pigou, A.C., 1920. The Economics of Welfare, 1st edition. Mac-
vol. 1. University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Millan, London.
Hayek, F.A., 1978. Competition as a discovery procedure. In: Porter, M.E., Van der Linde, C., 1995. Toward a new conception of
Hayek, F.A. (Ed.), New Studies in Philosophy, Politics, the environment-competitiveness relationship. Journal of Eco-
Economics, and the History of Ideas. Routledge, London, pp. nomic Perspectives 9 (4), 97 – 118.
179 – 190. Rammel, C., 2003. Sustainable development and innovations: les-
Hayek, F.A., 1988. The Fatal Conceit. The Errors of Socialism. sons from the Red Queen. International Journal of Sustainable
Routledge, London. Development 6 (4), 395 – 416.
ARTICLE IN PRESS

C. Sartorius / Ecological Economics xx (2005) xxx–xxx 19

Rammel, C., Van den Bergh, J.C.J.M., 2003. Evolutionary policies Solow, R.M., 1974. Intergenerational equity and exhaustible
for sustainable development: adaptive flexibility and risk mini- resources. Review of Economic Studies 67, 29 – 45.
mising. Ecological Economics 47, 121 – 133. Solow, R.M., 1986. On the intergenerational allocation of natural
Rennings, K., 2000. Redefining innovation—eco-innovation resources. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 88 (1), 141 – 149.
research and the contribution from ecological economics. Eco- Troja, M., 1998. Umweltpolitik und moderne Ökonomik: Der Beitrag
logical Economics 32, 319 – 332. der Neuen Politischen Ökonomie und der Neuen Institutionenö-
Romer, P.M., 1986. Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal konomik zur Erklärung umweltpolitischer Entscheidungspro-
of Political Economy 96, 1002 – 1037. zesse. LIT, Münster.
Sartorius, C., 2002. The relevance of the group for the evolution of Van den Bergh, J., Gowdy, J., 2000. Evolutionary theories in
social norms and values. Constitutional Political Economy 13, environmental and resource economics: approaches and appli-
149 – 172. cations. Environmental and Resource Economics 17, 37 – 52.
Sartorius, C., 2003. An Evolutionary Approach to Social Welfare. Waddington, C., 1969. The theory of evolution today. In: Koestler,
Routledge, London. A. (Ed.), Beyond Reductionism. New Perspectives in Life
Sartorius, C., Zundel, S. (Eds.), 2005. Time Strategies, Innovation Sciences. Hutchison, London.
and Environmental Policy. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK. WCED (World Commission on Environment and Development),
Schumpeter, J.A., 1934. The Theory of Economic Development: an 1987. Our Common Future, London.
Inquiry into Profits, Capital, Credit, Interest, and the Business Witt, U., 1997. dLock-inT vs. dcritical massesT—industrial change
Cycles. Harvard University Press, Cambridge. under network externalities. International Journal of Industrial
Simon, H.A., 1957. Model of Man. Social and Rational. Wiley, Organization 15, 753 – 773.
New York.

Você também pode gostar